You are on page 1of 15

OUMM3203 PROFESSIONAL ETHICS

1.0

Introduction Bribery is an act of giving money or gift giving that alters the behavior of the recipient.

Bribery constitutes a crime and is defined by Black's Law Dictionary as the offering, giving, receiving, or soliciting of any item of value to influence the actions of an official or other person in charge of a public or legal duty. The bribe is the gift bestowed to influence the recipient's conduct. It may be any money, good, right in action, property, preferment, privilege, emolument, object of value, advantage, or merely a promise or undertaking to induce or influence the action, vote, or influence of a person in an official or public capacity. In economics, the bribe has been described as rent. Bribery in bureaucracy has been viewed as a reason for the higher cost of production of goods and services. 1.1 Forms of bribery Many types of bribes exist: tip, gift, sop, perk, skim, favor, discount, waived fee/ticket, free food, free ad, free trip, free tickets, sweetheart deal, kickback/payback, funding, inflated sale of an object or property, lucrative contract, donation, campaign contribution, fundraiser, sponsorship/backing, higher paying job, stock options, secret commission, or promotion (rise of position/rank). One must be careful of differing social and cultural norms when examining bribery. Expectations of when a monetary transaction is appropriate can differ from place to place. Political campaign contributions in the form of cash, for example, are considered criminal acts of bribery in some countries, while in the United States, provided they adhere to election law, are legal. Tipping, for example, is considered bribery in some societies, while in others the two concepts may not be interchangeable. In some Spanish-speaking countries, bribes are referred to as "mordida" (literally, "bite"); in Arab countries they are Baksheesh or Bakshish. However, Bakshish is more akin to tipping. French-speaking countries often use the expressions "dessous-de-table" ("under-the-table" commissions), "pot-de-vin" (literally, "wine-pot"), or "commission occulte" ("secret commission" or "kickback"). While the last two expressions contain inherently a negative 1

OUMM3203 PROFESSIONAL ETHICS

connotation, the expression "dessous-de-table" can be often understood as a commonly accepted business practice (for instance, on the occasion of a real estate transaction before the notary, a partial payment made between the buyer and seller; needless to say, this is a good way to launder money). In German, the common term is Schmiergeld ("smoothing money"). The offence may be divided into two great classes: the one, where a person invested with power is induced by payment to use it unjustly; the other, where power is obtained by purchasing the suffrages of those who can impart it. Likewise, the briber might hold a powerful role and control the transaction; or in other cases, a bribe may be effectively extracted from the person paying it, although this is better known as extortion. The forms that bribery take are numerous. For example, a motorist might bribe a police officer not to issue a ticket for speeding, a citizen seeking paperwork or utility line connections might bribe a functionary for faster service. Bribery may also take the form of a secret commission, a profit made by an agent, in the course of his employment, without the knowledge of his principal. Euphemisms abound for this (commission, sweetener, kick-back etc.) Bribers and recipients of bribery are likewise numerous although bribers have one common denominator and that is the financial ability to bribe. As indicated on the pages devoted to political corruption, efforts have been made in recent years by the international community to encourage countries to dissociate and incriminate as separate offences, active and passive bribery. From a legal point of view, active bribery can be defined for instance as the promising, offering or giving by any person, directly or indirectly, of any undue advantage [to any public official], for himself or herself or for anyone else, for him or her to act or refrain from acting in the exercise of his or her functions. (article 2 of the Criminal Law Convention on Corruption (ETS 173) of the Council of Europe). Passive bribery can be defined as the request or receipt [by any public official], directly or indirectly, of any undue advantage, for himself or herself or for anyone else, or the acceptance of an offer or a promise of such an advantage, to act or refrain from acting in the exercise of his or her functions (article 3 of the Criminal Law Convention on Corruption (ETS 173)). The reason for this dissociation is to make the early steps (offering, promising, requesting an advantage) of a corrupt deal already an offence and, thus, to give a clear signal (from a criminal policy point of view) that bribery is not acceptable. Besides, such a dissociation makes the prosecution of bribery offences easier since it can be very difficult to prove that two parties 2

OUMM3203 PROFESSIONAL ETHICS

(the bribe-giver and the bribe-taker) have formally agreed upon a corrupt deal. Besides, there is often no such formal deal but only a mutual understanding, for instance when it is common knowledge in a municipality that to obtain a building permit one has to pay a "fee" to the decision maker to obtain a favourable decision. 2.0 Overview of bribery The nexus between bribery and corruption must be fully comprehended at the outset of this paper. This is because there can be no bribery without corruption. Corruption refers to the misuse of entrusted power for private gain. Corruption is a broader term in which lesser evils such as bribery, nepotism and even misappropriation fall under as can be seen from Nyes definition of corruption: behaviour which deviates from the formal duties of a public role because of private regarding (personal, close family, private clique) pecuniary or status gains, or violates rules against the exercise of certain types of private regarding influence. This includes such behaviour as bribery (use of a reward to pervert the judgment of a person in a position of trust); nepotism (bestowal of patronage by reason of ascriptive relationship rather than merit); and misappropriation (illegal appropriation of public funds for private regarding uses). Bribery can also be an offer, a payment or a promise to pay money or goods, favour, an advantage, privilege, property or an object of value to a person in order to influence his views, actions or conduct. Bribery is viewed in two ways. These are bribery according to rule and bribery against the rule. Bribery according to rule is where a bribe is paid in order to receive preferential treatment for something that the bribe receiver is required to do by law. For instance, a builder offers to pay money to a building inspector in order that his building premises are inspected. Bribery against the rule is where a bribe is paid to receive preferential treatment or obtain services for which the bribe receiver is prohibited from doing. For instance, an accused person offers to pay money to the prosecuting officer in order not to get charged to court. For an act to be seen as a bribe, there will be an understanding that the thing offered, paid or promised to be paid is meant to influence the views, actions and conduct of the receiver who if he accepts must reciprocate the gesture by performing the 3

OUMM3203 PROFESSIONAL ETHICS

intended act. It is for this reason that general gifts and tips (usually given as a token of appreciation for good services) cannot be considered as bribes. Bribes are more or less illegal and immoral agreements between the bribe giver and receiver for the performance of an act in exchange for an object of value for the purpose of influencing the receiver views, actions or conduct in order to gain special treatment. In most jurisdictions bribery is seen as a crime, which is punishable by a term of imprisonment, a fine or a combination of the two. The bribe giver and receiver are both culpable and as such most jurisdictions treat them as offending parties. In some other jurisdictions bribery may be treated with less severity and may be more acceptable as a norm or part of the society. It is for this reason that bribes in such jurisdictions have been given names like grease money in order to oil the views of the receiver and make him swing into action. Bribery can take place in both public and private capacities. Public capacity involves public officials or people who are being paid by the taxpayer and private capacity involves anyone not being paid by the taxpayer. The saying it takes two to tango is an apt description of the problem of bribery. This is because there are two sides to it. These are the demand and supply side. The demand side of bribery involves the asking of the bribe by the receiver who can request this bribe for himself or on behalf of someone else. He can also make this request directly or indirectly. If the person demanding the bribe is acting on behalf of someone else he will be seen to be an accomplice to the crime. On the other hand, the supply side of bribery deals with the offer, the payment or the promise to pay the bribe by the giver to the receiver. Similar to the demand side, the giver of the bribe in the supply side can also be acting either for himself or on behalf of someone else or can also give the bribe directly or indirectly. Bribery can also be viewed vertically from top to bottom and vice versa. Bribery from top to bottom is where the bribery takes place at the highest levels of government and some of the bribe payments trickle down to the lower officials as hush money; while bribe from bottom to top is where numerous bribes are paid to lower officials and a percentage of the payment is passed on to higher officials in the level of hierarchy. Most international legal instruments deal with the supply side of bribery particularly bribery of foreign public officials. This is because the demand side is usually handled by the laws of the host country or the laws of the country in which the bribe receiver is subject. Some of these legal instruments will form the subject matter of the ensuing chapter 4

OUMM3203 PROFESSIONAL ETHICS

3.0

Economic analysis on the act of bribery Bribery is defined as "the offering, promising or giving something in order to influence a

public official in the execution of his/her official duties" (OECD Observer, 2000). Bribes can take the form of money, other pecuniary advantages, such as scholarship for a child's college education, or non-pecuniary benefits, such as favorable publicity. In the international context, bribery involves a business firm from country A offering financial or non-financial inducements to officials of country B to obtain a commercial benefit. Transparency International defines corruption as "the abuse of public office for private gain." The non-profit organization produces annually its survey of countries ranked on the basis of how corrupt they are perceived to be. Known as the Corruption Perceptions Index (CPI), it is based on "the misuse of public power for private benefit, with a focus, for example, on bribe taking by public officials in public procurement" (www.transparency.org). The CPI has emerged as a prominent measure of the extent of bribery in international business and is increasingly used by scholars to empirically ascertain patterns and relationships with other variables to understand this subject. The focus of this paper is on bribery, which is a major form of corruption. The enormous growth in international trade and investment over the past fifty years has been accompanied by an increase in bribery. The newspapers regularly report bribery scandals in the conduct of international business (e.g., Crawford, 2008). The World Bank estimated that five per cent of the exports to developing countries go to corrupt officials (Moss, 1997). It is estimated that more than US$1 trillion is paid in bribes each year (Labelle, 2006). The chairman of the U.S. branch of Transparency International, the non-governmental organization dedicated to combating corruption, has noted that many analysts feel "there has been a gradual escalation. At one point, five per cent (of a contract price) was standard. That's crept up gradually until now it's in the twenty to thirty per cent range" (Andelman, 1998). If bribery is a burden to international firms, it is even more costly to the countries where they are prevalent. It has been estimated that money lost to bribery is the largest potential source of funding available to many new democratic governments aside from foreign direct investment (Hamra, 2000). The World Bank believes that tackling bribery can lead to significant increases in

OUMM3203 PROFESSIONAL ETHICS

national income and faster economic growth and to improvements in quality of life issues such as child mortality rates (The Costs of Corruption, 2004). The seriousness of the issue has prompted governments, intergovernmental bodies, nongovernmental organizations, and commercial firms to control and discourage bribe giving and bribe taking. The U.S. was the first industrialized country to address this issue when, in 1977, it enacted the Foreign Corrupt Practices Act (FCPA) making it a crime for any American firm (and foreign firms which issue negotiable securities on U.S. stock exchanges) to offer, promise, or make payments or gifts of anything of value to foreign officials, politicians, and political parties with the intention of changing policies or to secure the suspension of a legal norm (U. S. Department of Justice). In 1999, the OECD Convention on Combating Bribery of Foreign Public Officials in International Business Transactions signed by the 30 member countries of the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD) and six other nations came into effect (OECD, 2002). The main goals of the treaty are to prevent bribery in international business transactions by requiring countries to make it a criminal offence to bribe a foreign public official, to have in place adequate sanctions and reliable means for detecting and enforcing the offence, and prohibit bribes from being considered a business expense and thus tax deductible. Financial agencies such as the World Bank, Asian Development Bank, and International Monetary Fund have linked aid disbursements to improvements in administrative practices to eliminate corruption (Lewis, 1997, Rose-Ackermann, 1997). The World Bank has barred firms which engage in bribery from doing business with it. It has established a program to let firms that have worked on bank-funded projects to voluntarily disclose and has found that a number of companies admitted to paying bribes (Corpwatch, 2006). The World Bank has created aggregate governance research indicators for 213 countries around six dimensions, one of which is control of corruption. These annual figures provide beth a snapshot and a trend line of the quality of governance in individual countries and on a comparative basis (Kaufmann, Kraay, and Mastruzzi, 2006). Non-governmental organizations such as Transparency International, through their annual rankings of perceived corruption among countries, spotlight this subject. Many businesses and industry groups have become conscious of their ethical conduct and the need to comply with the emerging web of laws. Consequently, they have created codes of conduct for their employees. Private trade associations such as the Business and Industry 6

OUMM3203 PROFESSIONAL ETHICS

Advisory Committee to the OECD and the International Chamber of Commerce have developed anti-bribery programs (Yannaca-Small, 1995). Thus, there have been worldwide efforts to address both the demand for and supply of bribes. Three strands of literature are reviewed here. They are (a) determinants of bribery and (b) determinants of economic growth. The World Bank has developed a simple formula to describe bribery: C = M + D-A-S where C standards for corruption, M for monopoly, D for discretion, A for accountability, and S for salary. The formula indicates that bribery tends to be high in societies where public officials earn low salaries but have a lot of discretion and limited accountability. Highly regulated economies create conditions for corruption to thrive. Businesses offer bribes and officials seek bribes to suspend the regulations. Husted (1999) examined the role of economic and cultural variables and found that a significant inverse relationship exists between perceived levels of bribery in a country and the per capita income in purchasing power parity terms. Cultural dimensions--using Hofstede's classification--of masculinity and power distance were significant factors (Hofstede, 1980). Sanyal and Samanta (2002) confirmed Husted's findings and found that income distribution in a country was another significant economic factor. Similarly, Getz and Volkema (2001) found that bribery in a country was related to wealth and so was power distance and uncertainty avoidance. Uncertainty avoidance moderated the relationship between economic adversity and bribery. Thus, there is an empirical basis to suggest that certain economic and cultural factors determine perceived levels of bribery. Sanyal and Samanta (2003) have also found that economic freedom and level of human development are associated with levels of perceived bribery in a country with open economies and high level of human development inversely related to bribery. All these studies found that per capita income is inversely related to bribery. The level of economic development in the world is very uneven. This is reflected in per capita gross national income (formerly gross national product) in purchasing parity terms of as high as $42,000 in the U.S.A. and as low as $830 in Yemen. Table 1 provides an overview of this worldwide disparity. Worldwide, between 1990 and 2004, the proportion of people living in extreme poverty fell from nearly a third to less than one-fifth. Economic growth in the developing world has averaged 4.8 per cent a year since 2000, more than double the rate of growth in high-income economies, which averaged 2.0 per cent a year. The decline in poverty has been limited in 7

OUMM3203 PROFESSIONAL ETHICS

countries that have experienced slower (or sometimes none at all) economic growth, usually measured by changes in the gross domestic income (GDI) from one period to another. Countries such as China, India, and Vietnam which have exhibited strong economic growth--between 1990 and 2003, the average annual GDP increases for these countries were 9.6, 5.9, and 9.5 percentage respectively--have been able to pull millions of people out of absolute poverty. In contrast, in Sub-Saharan Africa, where the growth rate was 2.8 per cent, in 2002, 300 million people lived on less than $1 a day, an increase of 139 million people over 1981. This is in sharp contrast with East Asia, where the number of extremely poor people fell by 580 million people, to 12 per cent of the population. World Development Indicators data indicate that economic growth is linked to sound policies, well-targeted aid, better governance, and a good investment climate (World Bank, 2006). The relationship between economic growth and bribery has been examined extensively in the literature, beginning with Mauro (1995). In general, the studies find a negative correlation between bribery and economic growth (Bardhan, 1997). Fisman and Svensson (2000) uses evidence from Uganda to confirm that bribery retards development at the micro level. They studied the relationship between bribe payments, taxes, and firm growth in Uganda for the period 1995-97 and found that a one percentage point increase in the bribery rate was associated with a three percentage point reduction in firm growth. Trade has proven to be an engine for growth in East Asia, equal to 81 per cent of the region's GDP, which far outstrips trade's 55-per cent share of GDP at the global level. Rapid expansion of China's trade has not only sustained its growth, but has also helped its regional trading partners integrate faster into global manufacturing. Experts of goods and services grew by 10 to 28 per cent in Malaysia, Thailand, the Philippines, Vietnam and Cambodia, and contributed to economic growth rates over six per cent in 2004 in all of these countries. In contrast, trade plays a much smaller role in Latin America and the Caribbean, making up barely 52 per cent of total output. Exports from Latin American countries have expanded by only 4.5 per cent a year since 2000, less than one-third the growth of exports by East Asia and less than half the growth of exports from South Asia and Europe and Central Asia. Foreign direct investment (FDI) is another engine of economic growth. A study by Habib and Zurawicki (2002) looked at aggregate investment flows from seven countries among themselves and 82 other countries over a three year period (1996-98) and related those flows to 8

OUMM3203 PROFESSIONAL ETHICS

the individual country's CPI. They concluded that "corruption is a serious obstacle to investment". They also found a negative effect due to the difference in bribery levels between home and host countries suggesting that investing firms are reluctant to deal with the conditions prevalent in an operating environment with a different level of bribery. In an undated World Bank document, Smarzynska and Wei studied the impact of bribery in a host country on the preference of foreign investors for a joint venture or a wholly-owned subsidiary. They conclude, based on firm-level data, that bribery reduces FDI and shifts the ownership structure towards joint ventures. They also report that U.S. firms are more averse to joint ventures in corrupt countries than investors of other nationalities. This latter finding is consistent with that of Hines (1995) who attributed the reluctance of U.S. multinational firms to avoid joint ventures in high bribe countries to the prohibitions embedded in the FCPA. In another study on the effect of bribery on FDI, Wei (2000) looked at bilateral investment from 12 source countries to 45 host countries and found that a rise in bribery in a country affected inward FDI there. The study also noted that while U.S. firms were averse to bribery in host countries, they were not necessarily more so than average OECD country, in spite of the FCPA. Sanyal and Samanta (forthcoming), in a study of U.S. outward FDI found that while high levels of bribery in recipient countries discouraged U.S. investment there, there were important exceptions. Countries with huge domestic markets (e.g., China) continued to attract U.S. FDI irrespective of the level of bribery. 4.0 Legal analysis on the act of bribery

Bribery in criminal law refers to the improper acceptance by a public official, juror, or someone bound by a duty to act impartially, of any gain or advantage to the beneficiary, including any gain or advantage to a third person by the desire or consent of the beneficiary. A gain or advantage may be a pecuniary benefit in the form of money, property, commercial interests or anything else the primary significance of which is economic gain. Every person who shall voluntarily offer or receive any benefit as consideration to influence an official act to be done or not done, shall be guilty of bribery, and upon conviction thereof shall be imprisoned for a period of not more than three years, and fined three times the value of the

OUMM3203 PROFESSIONAL ETHICS

benefit offered or received, or both. If the value of the benefit cannot be determined in dollars, the fine shall be not more than $5,000.00. In my opinion, Section 502s definition of bribery can very well cover the sort of payouts that ETG proposes in its brochure to make to Yapese citizens and the Yap State Government. Now, there are several issues. First, would ETGs promise of a payout to Yapese citizens who are not Yap State Government officials qualify as a bribe? In my opinion, this is likely so according to Section 502. Section 502 deals with the influencing of an official act to be done or not done, but the Section does not specifically restrict the crime of bribery to offers made to government officials who may receive bribes to influence their official acts. Given the way that Section 502 is worded, as long as any person who receives a benefit as consideration is in a position to influence an official act to be done or not done, then the voluntary offer of such a benefit to that person for the purpose of getting that person to influence an official act constitutes a bribe under Section 502. An enterprising lawyer can argue that ETGs promise of a payout to non-government-official Yapese citizens is intended to get those Yapese citizens to influence the Yap State Government to, among other things, repeal Yaps anti-gambling laws and allow for ETG to carry out casino operations in Yap. In that scenario, then, ETGs promise of a payout arguably constitutes a bribe under Section 502. The second issue is whether ETGs promise of an annual gaming tax to the Yap State Government constitutes a bribe under Section 502 of the Yap State Code. Of course, if a license fee or tax is legitimate and provided-for under relevant state/national laws and regulations, then the payment (or the promised payment) of such a fee/tax should not be considered a bribe. Section 502 accounts for this sort of possibility by limiting bribes to offers that are made voluntarily. This means that if ETG is required by law to furnish some sort of tax or fee, then ETGs furnishing of that tax or fee is not voluntar[y], and so ETGs payment (or promised payment) of that tax or fee should not be deemed a bribe. However, in this particular case, I believe that Yap State Law does not allow for any sort of gaming tax. Indeed, as far as I know, there are a limited number of taxes and fees that are paid to the State of Yapincluding excise tax, hotel occupancy tax, motor vehicle tax, and so forthand none of those items include a gaming tax. There are also no provisions under the 10

OUMM3203 PROFESSIONAL ETHICS

FSM Code for a gaming taxthe FSM primarily collects taxes/fees on wages and salaries, on gross revenues, and on fishing licenses, and although one may argue that a gaming tax is similar to a gross revenue tax, they are not, in my opinion, the same tax. (For one thing, a gross revenue tax is broader than a limited gaming tax. For another, tax codes are notoriously very keen on specificity in language, and if a tax code has no specific mention of a special provision for a gaming tax, then the common practice in tax law is to not recognize such a provision.) Even if the FSM Tax Code contains a provision for a gaming tax, that still should not matter, because ETGs brochure proposes that a gaming tax shall be paid to the Yap State Government, not the FSM National Government. In light of the foregoing discussion, it is my opinion that ETGs promise of an annual gaming tax to the Yap State Government is, in essence, a voluntar[y] offer according to Section 502 of the Yap State Code. If we are to assume that ETG makes such an offer as consideration to influence an official act to be done, e.g., to get the Yap State Government to legally support ETGs proposed Project in Yap, then that may constitute bribery under Section 502. 5.0 Ethical analysis on the act of bribery During the early 2000s, Ireland was categorized as a tiger economy, which is an economy that experiences brief but rapid growth. Since Ireland offers low corporate tax rates, companies like Google and IBM placed European headquarters in the country, and made Ireland a hub for big business. For a time, Ireland enjoyed this prosperitybut it soon came to a halt when the collapse of the U.S. economy triggered a worldwide domino effect. Now, Ireland is unable to pay off debt, and may need to be bailed out by other affluent countries like Germany. While the Irish government is trying to find ways to decrease the deficit, one startling proposal made by a blogger recommends that Irish officials bribe credit-rating agencies to inflate credit scores in order to keep interest costs on debt payments low. There are deficiencies in this proposal, however; it assumes that a higher credit score will solve all of Irelands financial problems. There is no guarantee that bribing a credit agency will bring about the change necessary to get Ireland out of debt. This argument also may not be feasible since bribery is an

11

OUMM3203 PROFESSIONAL ETHICS

illegal act, but lets assume that such a proposal is a viable option for Ireland. In terms of ethics, there are pros and cons. When doing ethical analysis, there are four models that serve as a framework to structure an argument: utilitarianism in terms of actions, utilitarianism in terms of rules, rights & duties, and virtue. Utilitarianism is the process of weighing benefits and harms, and choosing the option that offers the most benefits for the greatest number of people. Rule-utilitarian thought focuses on benefits and harms created by rules, while act-utilitarian thought calculates the consequences of actions themselves. The rights & duties model chooses the course that respects what others are entitled to (rights) and obligations a stakeholders has to fulfill them (duties). The last model, virtue, chooses the option that enforces good habits of character for yourself and others. Each model can be applied when evaluating whether bribery is ethical or not. In terms of benefits and harms to the Irish economy, the benefits of bribing credit-rating agencies would have a significant impact. Government would be able to get a handle on its interest payments and pay off debt quicker, without the financial support of other countries. Such benefits would likely reduce unemployment and drastically increase the quality of life for Irish citizens. For this argument, harms are minimalthere is no harm that comes to the credit-rating agencies if no one finds out of such bribery. If discovered, the reputation of the agency may be diminished, but that certainly does not outweigh the benefits associated with helping the 4.5 million citizens of Ireland. Another argument in favor of bribery has to do with duties. The Irish government has an obligation to do what it takes to ensure the health and happiness of its citizens. While Ireland enjoyed prosperity for a short time in the early 2000s, the government may have made poor choices that led to Irelands current financial position. One blogger claims the reason for the crisis stems from governments decision to guarantee all bank liabilities, a promise that Ireland could not keep. Doesnt the government then, have a duty to citizens to use whatever means are available to restore the economy to a normal state? If the government has the power to bribe credit-rating agencies to help stimulate the economy, it should fulfill its promise of serving in the best interests of citizens. While there are ethical arguments in favor of bribery, there are also arguments not in favor. Although the action of the bribery may bring more benefits than harms to the people of Ireland in this particular situation, the rule that forbids bribery brings more benefits than harms in 12

OUMM3203 PROFESSIONAL ETHICS

all situations. There are countless historical examples of individuals using bribery as a means to gain power or money that is used for evil; in fact, I argue that there are more examples of bribery used for immorality rather than for good. Because of the benefits that arise from outlawing bribery, it would be unethical for the Irish government to use such tactics, even if it greatly benefited its citizens. Although the blogger notes that credit-rating agencies are already involved with bribery, it would not be ethical to allow it in this case because it undermines the functional purpose of a credit-rating system. These agencies are created so that investors have a resource to be able to assess the risk with investing in bond markets. By using bribes to enhance credit scores, these scores become biased and are no longer a useful tool for potential investors. There is no way to ethically justify bribery in a credit-rating system because it goes against the very purpose of why such a system exists in an economy. The most powerful argument against bribery is related to the virtue model. Bribery is a form of corruption that alters a behavior or outcome based on a reward. Rather than encouraging good habits of character, such as hard work and judiciousness, the action teaches individuals to cheat in order to get ahead. By using such a tactic to pay off debt, the Irish government is justifying to citizens that the ends justify the means. Such examples will likely lead to corrupt behavior within the Irish economy, because the government did not fulfill its duty of being a moral representation of the country it administers. If the government engages in bribery, what would stop business owners, politicians, lobbyists, and other stakeholders from doing the same? This would open Pandoras Box. Based on my ethical analysis, I believe Darias proposal is unethical based on the principles of rule-utilitarian thought and virtue. While there are benefits for Ireland that arise from stimulating the economy, that harms that occur from distorting the credit-rating system as well as encouraging citizens to engage in immoral behavior outweigh such benefits. It may have to rely on neighboring countries to pay off debt, but bribing credit-rating agencies is certainly not the ethical means to solve Irelands problems.

13

OUMM3203 PROFESSIONAL ETHICS

Conclusion In conclusion bribery is not an issue that can be answered immediately at hand considering the type of situations that regulate its ethical character. We need to remeber that bribery is a constant ethical issue. And becuase bribery are only sometimes acceptable it is in a moral free space. Even with a deductive definition for bribey and its set of guidelines I cannot conclude that bribery is always unethical. However, if I was to limit business practices solely to our mother country (United States of America) I will stand by my argument that bribery is unjustifiable. A basic point to remember, is that bribery is unethical because it undermines the social and economic systems. It weakens market efficiency and predictability, thus denying people their right to a minimal standard of living. Consider the two roles, to be a "realist" is to justify bribery because "international business is a rough game and no place for the naive idealist," or the role of a "moralist" that believes that cultural relativity is no excuse for unethical behavior.

14

OUMM3203 PROFESSIONAL ETHICS

References Andelman, D. A. (1998), Bribery: The New Global Outlaw. Management Review Caves, R. (1982), Multinational Enterprise and Economic Analysis. New York: Cambridge University Press. Corpwatch (2006), Firms Admit Paying Bribes in World Bank Program. CA: Oakland. (www.corpwatch.org/article). Leonard J. B (2006). Business & Professional Ethics for Directors,Executives & Accountants, (4thEdition) ,Toronto,: ThomsonHigher Education. Dr. Muhammad Diah Jurini (2008). OUM320 Professional Ethics ,(cetakan kelapan) Seri Kembangan Selangor: Open UniversityMalaysia (OUM). Mok Soon Sang (2005),Siri Pendidikan PTK (Teras DanProfesional),Kuala Lumpur: Multimedia ES Resources Sdn Bhd. Abdul Rahim M. (2001) Ilmu Pendidikan Untuk KPLI,. SungaiBesi, Selangor: Sanon Printing Corporation Sdn Bhd.

15

You might also like