You are on page 1of 33

Credit risk: an agent-based model of post-credit decision actions and credit losses in banks

Sara Jonsson Ph. D. Centre for Banking and Finance, School of Architecture and the Build Environment, The Royal Institute of Technology KTH, Drottning Kristinas vg 30, 100 44 Stockholm, Sweden + 46 8 790 86 68 E-mail: sara.jonsson@abe.kth.se

Credit risk: an agent-based model of post-credit decision actions and credit losses in banks

Abstract The credit crisis in 2008 has increased the focus on bank credit risk. This paper uses an agentbased model (ABM) to investigate the impact of bankers post-credit decision actions on bank credit losses that are induced by lending to corporate clients. The banker agents are modelled according to results obtained from a survey that was distributed to bankers who are permitted to grant credit to firms. The results show that post-credit decision actions have substantial effects on bank credit losses, thus implying that regulators should consider organizational factors as a complement to bank assets when assigning capital requirements to banks. The study also aims to point to a new area of application of ABMs for both researchers and practitioners: Whereas previous research has used ABMs to simulate financial markets, this study suggests that financial organizations could be a vital area of application.

1. Introduction In 2007, the world suffered the worst financial crisis since 1930. The decade-and-a-half period of time leading up to the global financial crisis was characterized by extraordinarily tranquil macroeconomic conditionsnamely, low inflation, low nominal short-term interest rate and steady growthwhich provided a supportive environment for credit expansion. Conditions in housing markets were favourable for increased bank lending with what appeared to be limited risk, and banks were prepared to extend the scope of lending to include high-risk households and firms. When house prices started fallingmortgage defaults increased, thus triggering the financial crisis (e.g. Mizen, 2008).

Banks, however, differed in the extent to which they suffered from credit losses in this crisis. Researchers and practitioners have offered various explanations for these differences. Some have argued for bank-level governance explanations, such as poor incentive structures. For example, some banks rewarded short-term performance rather than long-term performance, thus influencing bankers to lend to high-risk firms and households. Some observers have attributed the existence of poor incentive structures to lax oversight by boards and investors that allowed bank management to develop such structures (Kirkpatrick, 2008). Others have supported country-level explanations. For example, Beltratti and Stulz (2009) found that banks in countries with stricter capital requirement regulations performed better during the crisis.

Because of differences in corporate management and/or country regulations, bankers exhibited different levels of risk aversion in credit decision processes and were thus exposed to various degrees of risk as the crisis emerged. In this article, the term credit decision process refers to the decision that a banker makes as to whether to grant credit to a client. The term post-credit decision process refers to the actions of a banker when clients are incorporated into the banks credit portfolio. Although the factors that affect the credit decision process have been previously investigated, the post-credit decision process has received less attention. Because a financial crisis can dramatically increase the credit risks of individual clients, postcredit decision actions are of substantial importance. The aim of this study is therefore to investigate the effects of individual bankers post-credit decision actions on bank credit losses. The empirical setting constitutes bankers with permission to grant credit to firms.

The method involved the distribution of a survey to bankers and an agent-based model (ABM). The survey provides information on the microfoundation of the banker agents, and

the ABM is used to investigate the implications of an individual bankers actions on the risk of the banks credit portfolio. Data on the firms were collected from a national database. According to the findings presented in this paper, post-credit decision actions, particularly the option to terminate contracts with risky clients, have a substantial impact on bank credit losses.

2. Background The field of ABM in economics has developed considerably in recent years, resulting in the application of ABMs in various economic environments (see Tesfatsion, 2003, for a review). Included in these studies are the modelling of financial markets and organizations.

Financial markets are well organized and centralized and relative to markets for other goods, they trade homogenous products in an efficient manner. As such, financial markets are particularly suited for ABM (LeBaron, 2001). Among the numerous ABMs of financial markets, the Santa Fe Institute Artificial Stock Market (SFI-ASM) (Arthur et al, 1997) is one of the pioneering models. Other ABMs of stock markets include the work by Chen and Yeh (2001), who constructed a stock market model that includes an additional social learning mechanism. Foreign exchange markets have proved to be difficult to model with any predictive power using conventional modelling approaches; however, they are suited for ABM. Izumi and Ueda (2001), for example, constructed an ABM in which the agents compete with each other to develop methods for predicting changes in future exchange rates.

Financial bubbles and crashes, or crises, in financial markets have received attention from researchers and a number of ABMs have been proposed in this field. For example Brock and Hommes (1998) present a model showing the bubble and crash dynamics when a majority of

agents switch from a fundamentalist strategy to a trend-following strategy. Friedman and Abraham (2009) later put forth a model of how bubbles and crashes arise from an endogenous market risk premium that responds to investors recent losses.

Financial markets are composed of amorphous collections of agents. By contrast, organizations have a formal structure and, commonly, an informal structure. The formal structure serves to define lines of communication and distribution of decision making, and the informal structure constitutes a channel for sharing information about mutual tasks. Whereas ABM studies of financial markets investigate the effects of particular types of firm behavioural rules on price dynamics and market structure, ABM studies of organizations commonly focus on the effects of a firms organizational structure on the firms own resulting behaviour (Prietula et al, 1998).

The neoclassical description of a firm is as a profit-maximizing entity. However, an agentbased approach means not having to assign an objective to an organization. Instead, the agents that comprise it are modelled with explicit attention given to how decisions are made and how the interactions of these decisions produce organizational output. A primary task for organizations is to constantly search for routines that improve performance. The objective of ABM in this field is to understand how firm performance is influenced by the way in which parallel searches are carried out among multiple agents (i.e. managers of different departments independently searching for new routines) (Burton and Obel, 1980). In some ABMs of organizations, various units work separately on solving similar problem such as selling a particular product line to consumers. In these models, activities map into performance in similar ways (e.g. Chang and Harrington, 2003). Other ABMs of organizations, which are based on the assumption that different departments (e.g. sales,

finance) solving different problems, investigate the interdependencies of conflicting needs (e.g. Siggelkow and Levinthal, 2003). Another line of ABM of organizations investigates the evolution of organizational structures (Ethiraj and Levinthal, 2002). Research has also recognized the cost of processing information, which has been explicitly modelled in some ABMs of organizations (Carley, 1992; Miller, 2001).

Although the application of ABMs has increased in studies of financial markets and organizations, limited application exists in financial organizations. Research in which ABM has been employed to investigate financial risks and crises has studied the implications of agent action in amorphous markets. However, ABM research is limited on the implications of agent actions within an organizational structure and their effects on credit risk. The present study puts forward a model of credit risk in banks and, as such, suggests a new area of application for ABMs that is of value to both bank management and regulators. For example, an ABM could serve as a complement to internal ratings-based risk (IRB) models in estimating credit risk.

3. Data Collection The model presented in this paper, hereafter referred to as the Bank Model, involves banker agents who have permission to grant credit to firms. The agents are modelled according to the results of a survey investigation conducted in 2007 at one of the largest Swedish banks, hereafter referred to as the Bank. The data collection was carried out by Volterra (www.volterra.co.uk), a consultancy agency. The survey was sent to 470 bankers who have permission to grant credit to firms. Of these 470 bankers, 321 answered the survey, yielding a response rate of 68%. A copy of the survey is presented in Appendix 1. In addition, data were collected from interviews with the management of the Banks credit risk department.

4. Description of the Bank Model The Bank Model comprises a formal organizational structure (including the local banker agents, the regional offices and the central office), an informal organizational structure and the firms that constitute potential bank clients. These elements are addressed in the following subsections.

4.1. The formal organizational structure The Banks formal organizational structure consists of 1 central office, 8 regional offices and 455 local offices. The Banks policy is that clients should be assigned the bank office that is closest to them. Geographical distance is therefore a parameter in the Bank Model. The Banks formal organizational structure is geographically represented by a circular space in the Bank Model (see Figure 1). The circular space is sliced into eight sections, with each section representing a regional office. On each of the eight sections of the circumference, 455 local bankers (each representing a local office) are located by randomly attributing an angle between 0 and 360 to them, which determines the position on the circumference. In the middle of the circle is the central office, to which all regional offices and local bankers are connected. Figure 1 also shows how the space is used to distribute firms (potential bank clients) across regions. Insert Figure 1 about here

The three formal organizational levelsthe local bankers, the regional offices and the central officeare described in the following sub-subsections.

4.1.1. Local banker agents


7

This sub-subsection describes the goal, actions, cognitive limitations, learning process and attributes (Table 1) of local banker agents.

Local bankers goal According to interviews the employees at the Bank make a career based primarily on how well they have avoided credit losses. Therefore, in the Bank Model, all local bankers are assigned the same goal: to avoid credit losses.

Local bankers actions The Bank is highly decentralized, meaning that credit decision authority and responsibility are assigned to the local bankers. Analogously, in the Bank Model, the local bankers are the main actors, in the sense that these individuals are the ones who do the following:

Decide whether to grant credit to firms that apply to them Make post-credit decisions by carrying out appropriate post-credit decision actions from a list of possible oneswhenever a firms credit risk exceeds the allowed levels

As a general rule, each local banker grants credit to a firm provided that the following is met:

The perceived credit risk is below a certain limit set by the management. The size of credit being applied for is below the specific regional limit to which all bankers in the same region are bound.

Local bankers limited cognitive abilities

Local bankers are assumed to have limited cognitive abilities in making assessments of the credit risk of firms. In this paper, the credit risk of a firm is defined as the firms probability of default (PD). When local bankers estimate a firms PD, they will make an error, . The bankers estimation of the PD is denoted as the perceived probability of default (PPD):

PPD = PD +

(1)

The survey results were used to construct a representation of the variation between bankers errors in evaluation, characterized by a mean (errorMean) and a standard deviation (errorStd). In terms of the respondents perception of their personal assessments of the credit applicants, the results showed that the majority of the respondents stated that they did not make any assessment errors. Accordingly, all local bankers in the Bank Model were assigned errorMean = 0, whereas the standard deviation varied, thus creating individual distributions of the error term. For each new client firm with a credit application, the local bankers make a firmspecific error drawn from this distribution.

The standard deviations were assigned based on information obtained in the survey. The survey respondents were asked about which sources of information they had used in their last credit-granting process (the answers are presented in Figure 2) and about the usefulness of different sources of information (see Figure 3). For example, 86% stated that they had used financial accounts, and 41% considered financial accounts to be a useful source of information. In addition, 86% stated that they had used other data from the client, which 30% considered to be a useful source of information. Five random numbers were drawn from a uniform distribution between 0 and 1 for each agent. If the first number was below 0.86, this agent would use financial accounts in its estimation. If the second number was also below

86%, the banker agent would also use other data from the client as a source of information and so forth until all options were considered. The set of activities was then translated by summing the usefulness indexes of the information sources (i.e. 0.41 + 0.30). Insert Figure 2 about here Insert Figure 3 about here A high usefulness index is then translated to a low standard deviation. Hence, the range of errors that banker agents make is narrowed if the source has been identified as being important in the survey.

Local bankers learning process Local bankers are assumed to have an individual, experience-based learning process. Accordingly, as local bankers become familiar with the firms in their portfolios, they learn more about their clients. This enhanced knowledge thus increases the accuracy of the bankers assessments of the firms (cf. McNamara and Bromiley, 1997). Therefore, the error in credit risk assessments is assumed to decrease in each time period, t, according to the following negatively autocorrelated process (j denotes the j-th firm):

(2)

where

is the autocorrelation coefficient, and

is the random component of the evolution

of the error term. When a firm that is already a client of the local banker applies for additional credit, the local bankers current error term for that firm is retrieved and used in the evaluation of the firm. Insert Table 1 about here 4.1.2. The regional and central offices

10

The main purpose of the regional and the central office in the Bank Model is to supervise the credit application process for which the local bankers in the region are responsible. If the PPD is below the PPD limit, but the credit size is above the local bankers credit limit, the regional office handles the case by re-evaluating the applicant. The effects of this re-evaluation were modelled according to survey results. Respondents were asked about the usefulness of contacting the regional office and the central office in the evaluation of a credit application; 3% stated that the regional office was a useful source, and 1% stated that the central office was a useful source. Correspondingly, in the Bank Model, if the regional office is contacted, it is assumed that the local bankers usefulness index increases by 0.03 according to the survey results; hence, the standard deviation of the error term decreases. If the credit size exceeds even the regional offices credit limit, the local banker will also seek credit approval from the central office. In this case, the usefulness index increases by an additional 0.01, and the standard deviation of the error term decreases accordingly. However, according to information obtained from the Bank, only 12% of the credit applications exceeded the local bankers credit limits, and only 1% exceeded the regional office limit. If the loan size conveys the involvement of the regional and possibly the central office and the firm is a previous client, the local banker will use the error that is the smallest of the current stored error for that firm (according to the local bankers learning process) and the error induced from the reduced standard deviation.

4.2. The informal organizational structure In addition to the formal structure, the Bank Model comprises an informal structure, which means that local bankers can communicate with other local bankers in their region. When banker agents are initialized, the local bankers are each assigned a random number (from zero to the number of bankers in the region) of other local banker agents to be included in their

11

network. According to the survey results, about 6% of the local bankers contacted other branches in their region when they were making their last credit-granting decision. Thus, in the Bank Model, 6% of the local bankers who handle a credit application use their informal contacts. It is assumed that their clients have PPD values that are closest to the PPDLimit. Hence, in each time period, the firms are sorted according to their PPD. First, the banker of the firm closest to PPDlimit is identified, followed by the banker of the firm that is second closest to PPDlimit and so on. This sorting process continues until 6% of the local bankers are identified. The informal network is assumed to convey social learning, meaning that agents are taught by other agents. Thus, in the model, the local bankers who use their informal contacts assumed the same errorStd as the local banker of their informal contacts who has the smallest errorStd.

4.3. The firms In the Bank Model, firms constitute potential bank clients (see Table 2 for a list of firm attributes). A firm is an instance of the firm class whose attributes are listed in Table 2. Similar to banker agents, firms are assigned an angle on a circular space, which represents their geographical location. When applying for credit, the firms address the banker that is closest to them on the circle.

To assess the credit risk of publicly owned firms, lenders can use stock market prices. A commonly used stock market-based credit measure is the expected default frequency (EDF) model of Moodys KMV (1995). Because the Bank uses a version of this model to estimate the credit risk of firm clients, it is also used in the Bank Model to model the firms. In this model, the firms equity is valued as a call option on the firms underlying assets, which implies that the firms equity holders have the option to repay the firms debts. When the

12

firms debts mature, the firms equity holders can exercise their right to buy the firms assets or choose to bankrupt the firm if the assets fall short of the debts. In three steps, the model estimates a firms PD during a certain time period. The first step involves estimating the market value of the firms assets (Vj), the volatility of the asset value ( ) and the value of the firms liabilities ( ).

In the second step, the firms default point and distance to default (DD) are calculated. The default risk of a firm increases as the value of assets approaches the book values of the liabilities until the firm finally reaches the default pointthat is, when the market value of the assets is insufficient to repay the liabilities. In the model used in the Bank Model, the default point is equal to Fj. In general, firms do not default when their asset values reach the book value of debts because the long-term nature of some of their liabilities provides some breathing space. The default point generally lies somewhere between total liability and shortterm liabilities (Crosbie and Bohn, 2003).

The distance to default (

), which is calculated according to equation 3, is the number of

standard deviations that the asset value must drop so as to reach the default point. Hence, the higher the risk of the firm the shorter the distance to default.

(3)

In the third step, an empirical mapping is constructed between the distance to default and the default rate, based upon historical default experiences of firms with different DD values. However, such data were not available. Therefore, the Bank Model approximates the

13

probability distribution of the firms asset values as a normal distribution, with a mean equal to and a standard deviation equal to . Hence, is estimated accordingly:

(4)

where N is the cumulative probability distribution function.

Each firm is also assigned an expected return on assets ( ) that is generated from a normal distribution, with a mean of 0.04 and a standard deviation of 0.02, according to information from the Bank. The expected return on assets is used when updating the PD in the simulation.

Figure 4 shows the distribution of the firms initial PD values generated by the Bank Model. These values ranged from 0 to approximately 0.45. Insert Figure 4 about here Insert Table 2 about here 5. Simulation The model was built with a library-oriented approach (cf. Macal and North, 2010), using the Java agent-based simulation (JAS) library (Sonnessa, 2004). The attributes of the Bank Model are presented in Table 3. A description of the event schedule is presented in Table 4.

Insert Table 3 about here Insert Table 4 about here Firms applying for credit In every time period, a random number of firms in the universe of firms apply for credit. A credit is an instance of the Credit-class; the attributes of which are listed in Table 5.
14

Insert Table 5 about here If a firm applying for credit is not a previous client of the bank, this firm is assigned to the closest local banker.

Local bankers credit decision actions In every time period, each local banker to whom a firm has approached with a credit application makes assessments of the firms PD; hence, the PPD is calculated. If a firm applying for credit is already in the local bankers credit book, the local bankers current error term for that firm will be retrieved. If a firm applying for credit is not a previous client, an error term will be drawn from the local bankers error distribution.

If the PPD is above the PPD limit, the credit application is rejected. If the PPD is below the PPD limit, and the credit size is below the bankers credit limit, the local banker makes an offer to the firm.

If the PPD is below PPD limit, but the credit size is above the bankers credit limit, the local banker sends the application to the regional office, where the PPD is recalculated according to the new usefulness index and the new standard deviation of the error term. If the new PPD is above the PPD limit, the local banker declines the firms credit application. If the new PPD is below the PPD limit, and the credit size is below the regional credit limit, the local banker makes an offer to the firm. If the credit size is above the regional credit limit, the local banker contacts the central office, where the PPD is recalculated according to a new usefulness index and a new standard deviation of the error term. If this PPD is below the PPD limit, the local banker makes an offer to the firm; otherwise, the local banker declines the firms credit application.

15

Local bankers post-credit decision actions The PDs, and thus the PPDs, of bank client firms changes for each time period potentially causing an excess of the PPD limit. In the survey, bankers were asked what type of action might be carried out if a client firms PPD exceeds the PPD limit. The survey results were transferred to available model actions (Table 6).

Insert Table 6 about here

Accordingly, three different post-credit decision actions are modelled in the Bank Model. All bankers adopt the same option in the same situation. These three options are compared so as to estimate the impact of post-credit decision behaviour. 1. No actions are carried out when a firms PPD exceeds the PPDlimit. 2. When the PPD exceeds the PPDlimit, exposure to the client is halved; however, the firm is still a customer of the bank. 3. The bank will terminate its contract with any firm with a PPD that exceeds the PPDlimit. In accordance with information obtained from the Bank regarding contract termination, a credit loss of 20% of the firms book value of liabilities (F) is assumed.

Update of firms PD At every time period, t, the PD of all firms is recalculated according to its actual return (rj) and expected return (j). rj of each firm evolves according to the following:

(5)

16

where ej is a firm-specific shock. The firm-specific shock is introduced at every time period, t, and is drawn from a normal distribution, with a mean of 0 and a variance equal to the volatility of the firms asset value. Each firm is allocated a goodness-of-fit measure, from 0 to 1. A new net asset value (the numerator in equation 2) for each firm is calculated using the values of rj, j, and the current contractual liabilities ( ): ,

exp

(6)

The equation can be described as a fractal Brownian motion, where t is the current time period, f is the frequency of change in asset value (annual: f = 1, monthly: f = 12, etc.). In the results presented in this paper, an annual frequency of change is assumed. The Hurst parameter, H, allows for the return process to be autocorrelated. If H is equal to 0.5, there is no autocorrelation; if H is more than 0.5, there is a positive autocorrelation; and if H is less than 0.5, there is a negative autocorrelation. In the Bank Model, H is randomly assigned from a uniform distribution ranging from 0 to 1. Using the new net asset value a new PD is calculated.

In this step firms with a DD value of 0 are identified. These firms are considered defaulted firms and are replaced with new firms. Hence, number of firms that can apply for credit is assumed to be constant.

Calculation of credit losses At each time period, a certain number of firms will reach their default point and the bank will incur a credit loss if the firm is a bank client. The loss given default (LGD) is a measure of the
17

exposure that the bank will lose if a firm defaults. In the model, the LGD is set at 45% of the firms book value of liabilities (F). A default can result from a banker not taking action on a firm that is approaching default (according to post-credit decision action option 1), an error in estimating the PPD and/or an unforeseen firm-specific shock.

Replacement of retired bankers Local bankers who have reached yearsToRetirement are replaced with new local banker agents. The new banker inherits the retired bankers portfolio of clients and assumes the same angle. However, the new banker will receive a new error distribution. Because of a lack of familiarity with the firms in the inherited portfolio, the replacement banker will make larger errors than the original banker in assessing the firms in the portfolio.

Update of local bankers error terms For each local banker, the bankers firm-specific error terms are updated according to the learning process.

6. Simulation results The simulation results of post-credit decision actions 1, 2 and 3 show the distribution of losses over 300 time periods when the PPD limit is set at 0.10. The credit losses were the lowest when the banker has the option to terminate the contract with client firms in which the PPD exceeds the PPD limit (option 3; Figure 5) compared with the option in which exposure to the client is halved (option 2; Figure 6) and the option in which no actions are carried out (option 1; Figure 7). Insert Figure 5 about here Insert Figure 6 about here

18

Insert Figure 7 about here

Figure 8 shows the means of the simulation results for all three post-credit decision action options at PPD limit values ranging from 0.01 to 0.45 (cf. the distribution of PD values illustrated in Figure 4). Each point in the figure represents the mean losses from t = 0 to t = 300. The means and standard deviations of each point are presented in Table 7

Insert Figure 8 about here Insert Table 7 about here

For all three options, the bank is assigned an equivalent PPD limit that represents equal risk aversion. As previously mentioned, one type of asset is assumed; hence, the differences at each PPD limit are not dependent on the composition of the banks credit portfolio.

The results show that the post-credit decision actions have a substantial effect on bank credit losses. When bankers half the exposure to clients where PPD exceeds the PPD limit (option 2) losses are reduced. The results further show that option 3 (terminate contracts with all clients whose PPD exceed the limit) has the greatest impact on reducing bank credit losses. For example, a PPD limit of 0.01 in option 1 approximately corresponds to a PPD limit of 0.20 in option 3, in terms of the proportion of the credit losses.

Figure 8 shows that under option 1 (no post-credit decision actions carried out), the degree of risk aversion has a substantial effect on credit losses that are already at low PPD limit values.

19

By contrast, under option 3 (termination of contracts), risk aversion begins to exhibit substantial effects on credit losses at PPD limit values above approximately 0.2.

Option 2 (exposure halved to clients whose PPD value exceeds the PPD limit) approximates a linear relationship between the PPD limit and expected credit losses. In the Bank Model, this option does not incur extra losses but still results in higher credit losses than option 3. However, as the PPD limit increases, the proportion of credit losses approaches that of option 3. Hence, if a firm should suddenly convey a high PPD value (e.g., caused by a shock), the option to halve the exposure might be considered above terminating the contract because the former action would allow the bank to keep a customer who could potentially recover and remain a profitable client.

The variables in the Bank Model were populated using empirical data obtained from a survey distributed to local bankers at the Bank and using information obtained from interviews with the management team of the Banks credit risk department. In this way, the agents actions, attributes and input value ranges are validated. Furthermore, the firm clients were operationalized using data from a database (www.largestcompanies.com) that provides information on the asset values of Swedish firms. Additional input values on the firm clients were obtained from the Bank.

The model output shows the impact of post-credit decision making on the extent of credit losses (i.e. through decreasing exposure or terminating contracts with clients when the PPD exceeds the PPD limit). These actions require early detection of credit deterioration and actors speedy decision making. If a firm has multiple banks, it is potentially easier to make the firm leave if one of these banks is the first to recognize the deterioration of a client. If one
20

of these banks is instead the last one to recognise the firms deterioration, the firm might feel that it has no other option than to stay with the bank even though interest rates and demands for collateral are raised. Bankers post-credit decision are made in an environment that is characterized by great uncertainty. In such environments organizations benefit from decentralising decision making because decentralisation promote responsiveness to markets (Lawrence and Lorsch, 1967).

The Bank has a history of decentralizing credit decision and post credit decision authority. Hence, the Bank has an organizational structure that is favourable to early access to information about clients as well as speedy action. Further, credit loss data obtained from the Swedish banks annual reports (1998-2010) show that the Bank has suffered lower credit losses than other Swedish banks (see Figure 9).

Insert Figure 9 about here

Conclusion and discussion The ABM presented in this paper simulates the impact of bankers post-credit decision actions on bank credit losses. The main analytical result is that post-credit decision actions have a substantial impact on banks credit losses and credit risks. The results show that terminating contracts with high risk client has the highest impact on reducing credit losses, followed by the option to halve the exposure to risky clients. In the validation discussion it is suggested that a decentralized organizational structure is beneficial to the possibility of terminating contracts.

21

Besides the suggested impact of a decentralized organizational structure to the possibility of terminating contracts the different post-credit decision action options might have motivational explanations. Agents have preferences (i.e. agents like financial rewards and career progress). How preferences translate into behaviour depends on an organizations incentive scheme for rewards and punishment (Chang and Harrington, 2006). Most organizations strive for profitability (e.g., Cyert and March, 1963), which creates pressure for profitability at the operating level (Bower, 1970). The profitability goals of bank organizations may be translated into credit growth targets at the operating level. Because profitability rises with increases in both sales of credits and services to clients, growth in credit portfolios is a way to improve performance (McNamara and Bromiley, 1997). If pressure for growth in credit portfolios is combined with an organizational setting where acknowledgement of a poor decision results in undesirable outcomes (e.g., the threat of increased oversight, reduced responsibility or loss of rewards), bankers might refuse to acknowledge the deterioration of a borrowers condition. Undesirable outcomes might even result in an escalation of commitment, which implies that banks may either increase or maintain credit lines for borrowers, despite their deteriorating financial positions (McNamara et al, 2002). Neglecting to carry out post-credit decision actions (option 1) may illustrate the behavioural outcome of such motivational settings.

If a bank rewards bankers for avoiding losses (i.e.bankers with a record of the lowest losses have the best career opportunities at the bank) and provides an organizational setting in which the deterioration of a creditor does not result in undesirable consequences bankers are more likely to behave by terminating a contract with a client whose PPD value exceeds the PPD limit value (option 3).

22

The present study answers the call for a greater focus on the needs of practitioners in ABM (Siebers et al, 2010) because it provides implications for both banks and regulators. The results provide implications for regulators to take into account banks post-credit decision actions when imposing capital requirements as a complement to the focus on bank assets. For banks, an ABM could be used as a potential tool in the IRB approach. The Basel framework encourages banks to initiate an IRB approach when measuring credit risk because banks are expected to be capable of adopting sophisticated techniques in credit risk management. In accordance with this approach, banks are allowed to develop their own credit risk models.

To increase the validity of the model, survey results should be collected from multiple banks. Future models should also explicitly investigate the impact of bankers motivations (i.e. rewards or individual preferences) to their post-credit decision actions.

References ARTHUR, W Brian, HOLLAND, John H., LEBARON, Blake, PALMER, Richard, Paul TAYLOR,. Asset pricing under endogenous expectations in an artificial stock market. In: ARTHUR, W Brian, DURLAUF, Steven N, David LANE (eds). The Economy as an Evolving Complex System II. Addison-Wesley: Reading, MA, 1997, 15-44. BELTRATTI, Andrea, Ren M STULZ. Why did some banks perform better during the credit crisis? A cross-country study of the impact of governance and regulations. Working Paper n. 15180, National Bureau of Economic Research: Cambridge, MA. 2009. BOWER, Joseph, L. Managing the resource allocation process: a study of corporate planning and investment. Division of Research, Graduate School of Business Administration, Harvard University: Boston, MA.1970.

23

BROCK, William A, Cars H HOMMES. Heterogeneous beliefs and routes to chaos in a simple asset pricing model. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, n 22, 1998, 12351274. BURTON, Richard M, Brge OBEL. A computer simulation test of the M-form hypothesis. Administrative Science Quarterly, n 25, 1980, 457-466. CARLEY, Kathleen. Organizational learning and personnel turnover. Organization Science, n 3, 1992, 20-46. CHANG , Myong-Hun Joseph, E. Jr.HARRINGTON. Multimarket competition, consumer search, and the organizational structure of multiunit firms. Management Science, n 49, 2003, 541-552. CHANG , Myong-Hun Joseph, E. Jr.HARRINGTON. Agent based models of organizations. In: TESFATSION, Leigh, Kenneth L JUDD (eds). Handbook of Computational Economics, n 2: Agent-based Computational Economics. Elsevier: Amsterdam , 2006, 1273-1337. CHEN, Shu-Heng, Chia-Hsuan YEH. Evolving traders and the business school with genetic programming: a new architecture of the agent-based artificial stock market. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, n 25, 2001, 363-393. CROSBIE, Peter J., Jeffery BOHN. Modeling default risk. Modeling methodology. White paper. KMV Corporation: San Francisco. 2003. CYERT, Richard M and James G. MARCH, A Behavioral Theory of the Firm. Prentice Hall: Englewood Cliffs, NJ.1963. ETHIRAJ, Sendil K., Daniel LEVINTHAL. Search for architecture in complex worlds: an evolutionary perspective on modularity and the emergence of dominant designs. Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania. pdf copy. , 2002 FRIEDMAN, Daniel, Ralph ABRAHAM,. Bubbles and crashes: gradient dynamics in financial markets. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, vol. 33 n 4, 2009, 922-937.

24

IZUMI, Kiyoshi , Kiyoshi UEDA. Phase transition in a foreign exchange market: analysis based on an artificial market approach. IEEE Transactions on Evolutionary Computation, 2001, n 5, 456-470. KIRKPATRICK, Grant. The Corporate Governance Lessons from the Financial Crisis. OECD: Paris. 2008. KMV Corporation. Introducing credit monitor, version 4. KMV Corporation: San Francisco.1995. LAWRENCE, Paul R., Jay, W LORSCH. Organization and Environment: Managing Differentiation and Integration. Irwin: Homewood, IL.1967. LEBARON, Blake. A builders guide to agent-based financial markets. Quantitative Finance vol. 1, n 2, 254-261. 2001. MACAL, Charles M, Michael, J. NORTH,. Tutorial on agent-based modelling and simulation. Journal of Simulation, n 4, 151-162. 2010. MCNAMARA Gerry, Philip BROMILEY. Decision making in an organizational setting: cognitive and organizational influences on risk assessment in commercial lending. Academy of Management Journal, n 40, 1997, 1063-1088. MCNAMARA Gerry, MOON Henry, Philip BROMILEY. Banking on commitment: intended and unintended consequences of an organizations attempt to attenuate escalation of commitment. Academy of Management Journal, n 45, 2002, 443-452. MILLER, John H.. Evolving information processing organizations. In: LOMI, Alessandro, Erik R. LARSEN (eds). Dynamics of Organizations: Computational Modeling and Organization Theories. AAAI Press/The MIT Press: Menlo Park, CA, 2001. MIZEN, Paul.The credit crunch of 2007-2008: a discussion of the background, market reactions, and policy responses. Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review, vol. 90, n 5, 2008, 531-568.

25

PRIETULA, Michael J, CARLEY, Kathleen M., Les GASSER (eds). Simulating Organizations: Computational Models of Institutions and Groups. The MIT Press: Cambridge, MA. 1998. SIEBERS, Peer-Olaf, MACAL, Charles M, GARNETT Jeremy, BUXTON, David, Michael PIDD. Discrete-event simulation is dead, long live agent-based simulation! Journal of Simulation, n 4, 2010, 204-210. SIGGELKOW, Nicolaj, Daniel A LEVINTHAL. Temporarily divide to conquer: centralized, decentralized, and reintegrated organizational approaches to exploration and adaptation. Organization Science, n 14, 2003, 650-669. SONESSA Michele . JAS: Java agent-based simulation library, an open framework for algorithm-intensive simulations. In: CONTINI Bruno, LEOMBRUNI Roberto, Matteo RICHIARDI (eds). Industry and Labor Dynamics: The Agent-based Computational Economics Approach. Proceedings of the Wild@Ace 2003 Workshop, Torino, Italy, 3-4 October 2003. World Scientific: Singapore. TESFATSION, Leigh (2003). Agent based computational economics. ISU Economics Working Paper, n 1, 2003.

26

Table 1 Local banker attributes


Local banker Attributes angle yearsToRetirement Comment The local bankers are each assigned a unique random angle between 0 and 360, which represents their geographical location. According survey results, the bankers have been working at the bank for a mean period of 10 years (SD = 4 years). From this distribution, N (10, 16), the banker agents are assigned a certain number of years that they will work in the bank. All banker agents are assigned an individual error distribution. All distributions, however, have the same mean (0). The bankers are assigned a different standard deviation of the error term. The minimum possible value for the autocorrelated component of the error (70%) The maximum possible value for the autocorrelated component of the error (90%) The minimum possible value for the random change of the error in any time period (2%) The maximum possible value for the random change of the error in any time period (2%) The local bankers client firms are recorded in a list (localPortfolio). Each firm is associated with a specific error term. Data on the credit limits were obtained from the survey. Regional credit limits ranged from 1 239 474 SEK to 15 000 000 SEK. These limits are distributed to the local bankers, according to region. All local bankers within the same region are assigned the same credit limit. The expected credit losses are calculated for various limits for perceived probability of default, PPD, ranging from PPD = 0.01 to PPD = 0.45. The local bankers are assigned a network of other local bankers, who constitute the local bankers informal contacts. The informal contacts are recorded in a list (informalContacts).

errorMean errorStd minRho maxRho minEta maxEta localPortfolio CreditLimit

PPDLimit informalContacts

Table 2 Firm attributes


Firm Attribute firmAngle assetValue Comment Firms are assigned a unique random angle between 0 and 360, which represented their geographical location. Information (www.largestcompanies.com) on total asset values was obtained from 26 532 public and private businesses. The total sample size was limited to 20 841 firms with asset values below 100 million Swedish kronor (MSEK). The data were fitted by an exponential distribution, with a mean equal to 15 MSEK. The market asset value of a firm in the Bank Model was randomly assigned from this exponential distribution. Volatility is a measure of the standard deviation of the annual percentage change in asset value, which is a measure of a firms business and industry risk. The annual volatility was derived from a uniform distribution with a range from 0.3 to 0.5, according to information from the Bank. Firms with larger asset values are assigned lower volatility. According to the Banks estimates of client firms proportion of debt to asset values, firms leverage ratios ( in the Bank Model are randomly generated from a uniform distribution with a range from 0.2 to 0.9, corresponding to a leverage of 20 to 90%. The leverage ratio is used to calculate the contractual liabilities, j expROA bankLoans . ) =V

volatility

leverageRatio

The expected return on assets is generated from a normal distribution N(0.04, 0.0004) List containing the credits obtained from the Bank

Table 3 Bank Model attributes


Bank Model attributes numberOfLocalBankers numberOfRegions numberOfCentralOffices Expected CreditLoss Time PostCreditDecisionOption numberOfFirms Comment 455 8 1 Calculated each time period Time is set to 300 Three options are available to the local banker: (1) noAction, (2) exposureHalved or (3) terminateContract. 2000

Table 4 The Bank Model event schedule


27

Step Step 1 Step 2

Step 3

Step 4

Step 5

Step 6

Step 7

Step8 Step 9

Event Initialization { Generate the initial population of local bankers, the banks formal and informal structure and the firms.} Firms apply for credit { Randomly select n (between 0 and numberOfFirms) firms that apply for credit For each firm that applies: If the firm is not a previous customer, assign the firm to the closest banker} Local bankers make the credit decisions { From the list of firms that apply for credit, if PPD < PPDLimit, grant credit} } Local bankers make post-credit decisions { If option = 1, go to step 5 If option = 2, for client firms with PPD > PPDLimit, halve the credit exposure If option = 3, for client firms with PPD > PPDLimit, terminate contract (remove the firm from the local bankers credit book) } Update firms PD { For each firm in the universe of firms, calculate a new PD } Calculate credit losses { For each client firm whose DD =<0, calculate loss (0.45 * debt level (F)) if option = 3, for each client firm whose PPD > PPDLimit, calculate loss (0.20 *debt level (F)) } Replace defaulted firms { Create n new firms equal to the number of defaulted firms } Replace retired bankers { For each local banker, if yearsInBank = yearsToRetirement, replace the local banker with a new banker update banker error term { according to the local bankers learning process } If t < time, go to step 2. End.

Table 5 Attributes of the Credit class


Credit Attribute creditID creditSize creditMaturity Comment The credit identification number The size of the credit is drawn from a uniform distribution with a range from * 0.05 to * 1.00. The credits are assigned a certain maturity, according to information from the bank. There is a 10% probability that the credit will mature and be repaid after 2 years. There is a 63% probability that it is repaid after 4 years, and a 27% probability after 8 years. The age of the credit increases by 1 for each time period.

creditAge

Table 6 Transfer of results for the question regarding available post-credit decision actions to Model action
Intervention options as stated in the survey No actions are taken Measures to facilitate for the client (e.g., extended credit) Measures to reduce the risk of loss Measures to reduce future exposure to the customer Measures to phase out the relationship Measures to terminate all credits to customer (For example by raising the interest rate or collateral to levels that will make the firm voluntarily leave the bank. ) The client is removed from the bank. Model action No action Exposure is halved, but the client is still a bank customer.

28

Table 7 Mean and standard deviation of expected credit losses at various PPD limits
PPDLimit Option 1 Mean SD Option 2 Mean SD Option 3 Mean SD 0.01 0.002 0.002 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.001 0.05 0.021 0.001 0.005 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.10 0.033 0.004 0.010 0.001 0.000 0.000 0.15 0.034 0.002 0.013 0.002 0.001 0.000 0.20 0.036 0.003 0.016 0.001 0.003 0.000 0.25 0.039 0.004 0.022 0.002 0.016 0.002 0.30 0.039 0.002 0.025 0.003 0.024 0.003 0.35 0.040 0.002 0.033 0.004 0.027 0.002 0.40 0.042 0.003 0.035 0.004 0.033 0.004 0.45 0.043 0.006 0.037 0.004 0.035 0.004

Note: Number of runs = 10.

29

Figure 1 The formal structure of the Bank Model

Figure 2 Responses to questions about information sources used in their last credit-granting decision

Figure 3 Responses to questions about the most useful information sources used in their last credit-granting decision
30

Figure 4 Distribution of initial probability of default (PD) values

Figure 5 Expected credit loss (percentage) when the bankers have the option to terminate the contract with all firms in which the perceived probability of default (PPD) exceeds the PPD limit of 0.10 (option 3).

31

Figure 6 Expected credit loss (percentage) when the bankers have the option to halve exposure to firms in which the perceived probability of default (PPD) exceeds the PPD limit of 0.10 (option 2).

Figure 7 Expected credit loss (percentage) when the banker take no actions of firms in which the perceived probability of default (PPD) exceeds the PPD limit of 0.10 (option 1).

32

Figure 8 Simulation results from all three post-credit decision action options; mean of expected credit losses as a percentage of the total borrowing at different limits for perceived probability of default (PPD limits) .

Figure 9 Credit losses (percentage) of the Bank and other banks in the Swedish market, 19982010.

33

You might also like