You are on page 1of 50

1

Dividend Payout Determinants for Australian Multinational and Domestic


Corporations




Shumi Akhtar*
#











JEL CODES: G37, F23, H20
Keywords: Dividend payouts, Multinational, Imputation tax system.





















All errors and omissions are my own.

# Please direct all correspondence to Shumi.akhtar@anu.edu.au , School of Finance and Applied Statistics, College of Business and
Economics, The Australian National University, ACT 2606, Australia. Ph: (+61) 2 6125 4723 and Fax: (+61) 2 6125 0087.


2
Abstract


This study investigates the determinants of dividend payments using a sample of Multinational Corporations
(MCs) and Domestic Corporations (DCs) listed on the Australian Stock Exchange. Six different measures of
dividend payout ratios are investigated and four international factors (multinationality, political risk, foreign
exchange risk, and diversification) are employed in addition to traditional firm specific factors. We find: MCs
pay significantly less regular cash dividends, special cash dividends, total dividends and net dividends relative to
DCs; the degree of foreign involvement is important in determining special cash and net dividend payments;
Australian MCs are comparatively more active than DCs in dividend increasing activities and the factors that
enable MCs to increase dividend payments are dependent on earnings received from a safer political
environment, availability of cash in hand and firms size; and Australian MCs are significantly less likely to be a
dividend payer relative to DCs and this is due to tax disadvantages coupled with unfavourable foreign risk
exposures.




























3
1. Introduction
While dividends have received considerable attention in the academic literature, few studies have examined the
determinants of various modes of dividend payments while distinguishing between Multinational corporations
(MCs) and Domestic corporations (DCs).
1
Yet this difference is important because MCs and DCs vary quite
significantly in relation to risk exposure, operational activities and financial activities all of which could affect
dividend payments. Typically, MCs are exposed to more risk (political, foreign exchange, different tax laws and
legal requirements) and are relatively more disperse in their operational activities (both geographically and
industrially diffused) relative to DCs. Also MCs have easier access to multiple markets and in the event of
financial need this may have a significant impact in determining the style of dividend payout. However, little is
known about, not only what factors determine the various dividend payout modes, but also, if those determining
factors vary across dividend payment modes for MCs and DCs.

The literature investigating dividend payout behaviour not only makes no distinction between MCs and DCs but
mostly uses U.S. data and thus is limited to dividend payout behaviour under a classical tax system. Australia
however, given its unique imputation tax system, provides a good case study to investigate the significance of
multinationality of a firm when considering modes of dividend payout. Its distinctive tax system favours
shareholders by eliminating double taxation on dividend income (compared to classical tax regimes). Pattenden
and Twite (2008) is the only Australian study that investigates the determinants of dividend payout ratios but the
distinction between MCs and DCs is not considered in their study. Hence, it is not known if an imputation tax
system plays any significant role in explaining various dividend payout ratios across MCs and DCs and the
difference that exists between these two types of firms.

In light of this, we use a sample of 973 Australian MCs and 1776 Australian DCs listed on the Australian Stock
Exchange to determine the extent to which the imputation tax regime plays an important role between cash,
share repurchase and other forms of dividend payout decisions. Six different measures of dividend payout ratios

1
The word corporations, firms and companies are used interchangeably.
4
are investigated and four international factors (political risk, foreign exchange risk, geographical diffusion and
diversification) are employed in addition to traditional firm specific factors.

Four main findings are reported in relation to various dividend payout measurements. i) Australian MCs pay
significantly less regular cash dividends, special cash dividends, total dividends and net dividends in comparison
to their counterpart DCs. This difference is mostly explained by Australian MCs being unable to offer tax credit
benefit to shareholders due to the imputation tax law which prohibits companies offering any tax credit on the
overseas income that is distributed as dividends; ii) foreign exchange risk and political risk, geographical
diversification and industrial diversification factors, not considered in past empirical research, are highly
important in explaining dividend payout ratios; iii) the degree of an Australian firms foreign connection is
reasonably important in determining special cash and net dividend payments. Interestingly, Australian MCs are
comparatively more active than DCs in dividend increasing activities and the factors that enable MCs to increase
dividend payments are dependent on earnings received from a safer political environment and availability of
cash in hand. iv) Australian MCs are significantly less likely to be a dividend payer relative to DCs and this
could be due mainly to tax disadvantages coupled with unfavourable political and foreign risk exposures that are
faced by Multinationals more so than their counterpart DCs.

Current theories do not provide a unique prediction on the firms decision between cash dividends, Off-market
and On-market share repurchase, special and other forms of dividends payments across domestic and
Multinational corporations. So, the extent to which different methods of dividend payments and the impact of
Multinationality of a firm has important implications for many of the existing finance theories. This is examined
below using ordinary least square and logistic regression analysis.
The rest of the paper proceeds as follows: section 2 describes the motivation and hypotheses. Section 3 explains
sample selection and methodology. Section 4 analyses the findings of the empirical univariate and multivariate
tests results and section 5 concludes the paper.


5
2. Theoretical Background and Hypotheses

Corporations distribute returns to their shareholders primarily via cash dividends. In addition, corporations
sometimes distribute dividends through share repurchases
2
, regular script dividends
3
, bonus share plans
4
, special
cash dividends
5
and special script dividends. Under an imputation tax regime, it is not known what impact
multinationality of a firm has on various forms of dividend payment. However, multinationality is important to
recognise since it influences the level of risk and diversity of a firms operational activities and hence is
important for both managers and shareholders.

2.1 Dividend Imputation Tax System and Dividend Payouts

The imputation tax system allows companies to pay dividends that carry credits for income tax paid by the
company. Such dividends are known as franked dividends
6
and the tax credits can be used by resident
shareholders to reduce income tax. The tax preference for the distribution of franked dividends following the
introduction of a dividend imputation tax system suggests that regular dividend payments by all firms will
increase (Pattenden and Twite, 2008). In Australia, while most dividends are paid in the form of regular semi-
annual cash payments, share repurchase type and other forms such as regular script dividends, bonus share plans,
special cash dividends and special script dividends are also adopted by firms from time to time. The imputation
tax system does not impose any discrimination between various types of dividend payments.

Grullon and Michaely (2002) argue that cash dividends and share repurchases should be a substitute payout
method holding all other things constant. However, they also argue firms can always adjust their sources of

2
The word Share repurchase and buy back and repurchase are used interchangeably.
3
Some companies offer a script dividend alternative, where shareholders are opted to receive extra shares in a company instead of the
cash dividend.
4
Bonus shares issued under the Bonus share plan are generally not treated as income under Australian taxation law and not subject to
imputation arrangements in the hands of the shareholder. Such shares are regarded as having been acquired at the same time as the
existing holding for no extra cost and the cost of the existing holding then becomes the cost of the aggregate of the existing holding and
the new shares.
5
A non-recurring distribution of company assets, usually in the form of cash, to shareholders. A special dividend is larger compared to
normal dividends paid out by the company. Also referred to as an extra dividend. Generally, special cash dividends are declared after
exceptionally strong company earnings results as a way to distribute the profits directly to shareholders. Special cash dividends can also
occur when a company wishes to make changes to its financial structure or to spin off a subsidiary company to its shareholders.
6
Dividends paid from earning that have been taxed the full corporate tax rate are referred to as franked dividends. Franked dividends are
paid out of the companys franking account. Dividends paid from earnings that have not attracted corporate tax are refereed to as
unfranked dividends. A dividend payment that includes both franked and unfranked dividends is referred to as partially franked dividends.
6
funds, and therefore it is possible that cash dividends and share repurchases are determined independently. For
example, it is possible that cash dividends are determined together with investment, as Miller and Rock (1985)
suggest, and that repurchases are determined independently.

Shares can be repurchased through on-market or off-market and by an offer to all shareholders or a particular
group of shareholders. The tax treatment of on-market and off-market offers differs. With on-market offers the
total purchase price is subject to tax, just as if the share had been sold by the shareholder. In on-market
repurchase there is no dividend component, only a capital component. In contrast, off-market repurchase has
both dividend and capital components. In Australia, off-market share buy backs are sold at discount (while in
U.S. they are usually sold at premium). We admit that it makes more sense to include off-market share buy back
in dividend payout analysis because companies can designate a portion of the repurchase price (off-market) as a
dividend and, providing the company has franking credits in its franking account balance, imputation tax credit
can be attached to that portion (Brown, 2007). This provides an advantage to the shareholders especially when
the off-market buyback price can be fully franked dividend in a large portion and capital component is a small
portion (incurring a capital loss given share is sold at discount). However, for a thorough investigation of share
repurchase, in this study both types of share repurchase are considered. Further, for a detailed investigation of
various dividend payout methods between Multinational and Domestic corporations, a multiple aspect of
dividend distribution (eg., regular script dividends, bonus share plans, special cash dividends and special script
dividends) is considered.

In relation to whether a difference exist in distribution of any of these various modes of dividend payments
between Multinational and Domestic corporation is an empirical issue.

2.2 Why do Multinational and Domestic Corporations have different payout policies?

Many of the factors that have been shown to influence dividend policy and firm value have been developed
through empirical research on listed corporations mainly in the U.S. Regard for whether the corporations are
DCs or MCs has not been considered. This is surprising given that the factors that have been identified as
7
determinants of dividend policy could differ substantially between these two different types of corporations.
Firms come in a multitude of different sizes and forms and one important distinction is between DCs and MCs.
Also, MCs control considerable amounts of assets and wealth, and obtaining evidence on their approach to
dividend policy is an area of research that is severely lacking. MCs have characteristics that are often very
different from DCs and it may be these differences that have driven the results. Obtaining a better understanding
of the differences in dividend policy in these two types of firms will shed light on and add to the existing body of
literature in relation to factors that may be influential in determining dividend pay outs between these two types
of firms. As a result, this study considers five new variables in addition to previously developed dividend policy
determinants theories and they are multinationality, political risk, foreign exchange risk, geographical and
industrial diversification.

2.2.1 Mulinationality

To identify the determinants of dividend payout ratios for MCs and DCs it is necessary to categorise
corporations as either MCs or DCs. This can be achieved by considering what constitutes a Multinational
Corporation. The remainder can then be regarded as Domestic Corporations. Several criteria have been
suggested in the literature to define MCs, including foreign sales ratio (Geyikdagi, 1981; Errunza and Senbet,
1984; Fatemi, 1988; Kim and Lyn, 1986; Shaked, 1986), foreign tax ratio (Lee and Kwok, 1988; Burgman,
1996; Chkir and Cosset, 2001) and the number of countries in which the firm operates through subsidiaries
(Errunza and Senbet, 1984; Kim and Lyn, 1986; Michel and Shaked, 1986; Shaked, 1986). The foreign sales
ratio has been popular but it does not differentiate between firms that earn income through export or firms that
generate foreign source income through subsidiary operations. We argue that to capture the combined effect of
all risk exposures and possible benefits from being an MC, it is important to know if foreign sales are generated
through export or through subsidiaries existence. If foreign sales are generated through export, then the exposure
of risks and benefit will be relatively lower than if the sales are generated through the existence of subsidiaries.
This is because when a foreign country experience unpleasant economic or financial crisis then it is easier and
less costly for the exporter to withdraw sales income as opposed to closing down an entire subsidiary in that
8
country. Therefore, in this study, we are cautious in defining an MC. In this paper MCs are defined as
corporations that have at least two subsidiaries in another country (other than the domicile country) in which a
firm operates and earns income from sales (Tallman and Li, 1996), earns profit and holds assets in those
subsidiaries. Domestic corporations (DCs), being the remainder. The importance of distinguishing
multinationality of a corporation from domestic corporations mainly lies in their uniqueness of operation; MCs
typically operate under multiple tax regimes and have easier capital market access.
2.2.1.1 Uniqueness of operational activities

Holding all other things constant, MCs operational risks are deemed to be different from DCs as they operate
in an international environment. Various risks that MCs subsidiaries face may lead the total business risk to be
higher (Burgman, 1996; Bae and Noh, 2001) which would not exist for corporation operating predominantly in a
domestic market.

MCs are also characterised by greater operational costs and operational complexity which may affect dividend
payouts. Monitoring, bonding and auditing costs are agency-related and are higher for MCs because of the
diversity of geographical locations, cultural differences, higher auditing costs, differing legal systems, and
language differences. These national differences increase the complexity of such standard tasks as generating
multi-country financial statements, hiring multi-country auditors and/or multiple auditors, and completing
consolidated balance and income statements (Burgman, 1996; Reeb et al., 2001) and there are complexities of
their operations as compared to DCs. According to Wright et al. (1997), these costs are due to the distance and
the difference in the corporate and national culture between the parent and the subsidiaries as well as the
difference in the level of economic development between the parent and the subsidiary host countries. Hence,
these characteristics of MCs may limit the amount of dividend they can pay out to shareholders.

Michael and Shaked (1986) evaluate the differences in financial characteristics and performance between MCs
and DCs. Their results show that while DCs have superior risk-adjusted, market-based performance to MCs,
9
MCs are more capitalised and less risky than DCs.
7
Hines (1996) argues that in the 1980s U.S. corporations paid
dividends at very high rates out of their after-tax profits, and that an unusually high fraction of those profits came
from foreign profits (non-U.S.) sources. Further, Hines (1996) argued that multinationals pay higher dividends
than domestic counterparts and their findings suggest MCs pay three times higher than DCs. So, the risk and the
benefit of diversification may have more of an impact on MCs dividend policy than their domestic counterparts.
2.2.1.2 Different tax regime

Any differential tax treatment of capital gains reltive to dividends might influence investor after-tax returns and,
ain turn, affect their demand for dividends (Lease et al., 2005). MCs operate in multiple countries meaning
income is earned in different types of tax environments. For example, an imputation tax system encourages
companies to pay more dividends to the shareholders since it is less taxable than the capital gains. As for MCs,
if firms are paying higher tax for their earnings in overseas countries then paying dividends out of profit might
be costly. Therefore, MCs will pay fewer dividends. Alternatively, it can be argued that if subsidiaries pay less
tax on the profit they make overseas then MCs are in a better position to pay higher dividends than DCs.
2.1.1.3 Easier capital market access

MCs are relatively in a better position to get access to international capital markets to raise debt than the DCs
due to their international operation and involvement. This means that in an economic crisis year in the home
country, MCs can borrow money (if necessary) overseas at a favourable rate to maintain the dividend policy with
the shareholders, which indicates MCs should have higher dividends than DCs (Hines, 1996). Following this,
MCs are expected to pay relatively higher dividends than domestic counterparts. However, if the borrowing rate
is unfavourable, then MCs may not pay higher dividends than DCs.
2.2.2 Political risks
Jodice (1985) suggests that political risk can be defined as changes in the operating conditions of a firm that
arise out of a political process, either through war, insurrection, or political violence, or through changes in

7
The average standard deviation of stock returns and the average systematic risk (beta) of DCs are significantly higher than those of
MCs.
10
government policies that affect the behaviour of firms and their financial decisions. Political risk can be
conceptualised as events in the national and international environments that can affect the profit level, physical
assets, personnel, and operations of firms. Such adverse effects often take place through constraints on the way
in which the MCs operate in foreign countries.
Kim and Mei (1994) and Bailey and Chung (1995) suggest that political risk has a significant impact on firms
profitability. Market volatility increases during political election and transition periods. Bailey and Chung
(1995) also document that political risk can have a significant effect on firms profit level and profit distribution
to its shareholders. This means that firms with significant foreign financing, foreign suppliers or customers, or
other international transactions or assets are relatively exposed to adverse changes in currency controls, capital
flow barriers and other laws and regulations that constitute political risk.

Examples of political risk attributes are host government appropriation, fund remittance control, differences in
governmental and cultural practices, greater tax uncertainty and regulations affecting only MCs (Mahajan,
1990). Therefore, depending on MCs and DCs earnings exposure to political risks in the domicile country and
foreign countries, it will affect their dividend payments accordingly. This exposure can have positive or
negative effects on dividend payout and this depends on whether the exposure is acting as a natural hedge to
their earnings. Given the fact that MCs are usually more exposed to international environments due to the nature
of their business, MCs are expected to have higher positive or negative effects to exposure to political risks and
therefore will have a subsequent effect on their dividend payout relative to DCs.
2.1.3 Foreign exchange risk

More exposure to foreign exchange fluctuations systematically increases the variation of foreign returns in
domestic currency. In a floating exchange rate regime, where the purchasing power parity does not hold
perfectly, an MC faces exchange rate risk (Solnik, 1974). MCs and DCs that are exposed to foreign exchange
risk affect the demand and supply of their products, prices and costs (Adler and Dumas, 1984; Jorion, 1990;
Bartov et al., 1996). Further, Black (1990) also suggests that all firms face foreign exchange exposure. The
more sensitive the firms are to foreign exchange rate fluctuations, the greater the chance of price fluctuations,
11
which ultimately shocks the profit level figures and cash flows from which dividends usually get distributed.
The greater the fluctuations of cash flows, the more the expected cost of bankruptcy risk increases and business
risk and consequently leads to generating less profit and therefore the lower the dividend payment to its
shareholders.

The effect of foreign exchange exposure can have positive or negative effects on both DCs and MCs depending
on the amount and type of foreign transactions (expenditure vs. revenue or assets vs. liability) they are dealing
with. However, in the international finance literature, it has been argued that MCs are more involved with
international operations than their DCs counterparts. As a result, MCs may have higher exposure to foreign
exchange risk than DCs, and depending on the favour or disfavour of the exposure on firms business operation
this will lead MCs to pay higher or lower dividend payments than the DCs.
2.1.4 Diversification

Diversification arguments can be explained in an industrial and geographical context. Cornell and Shapiro
(1987) explain the diversification influence on dividend payouts from stakeholder theories point of view.
Stakeholder theory predicts that firms that have both high potential implicit claim values and the desire to pay
those claims will attempt to distinguish themselves before stakeholders make the claims (Holder et al., 1998).
Shapiro (1990) indicates that managers signal their ability to honor implicit claims by paying lower dividends.
This keeps more cash in the firm to pay implicit claims and reduces the risk of a possible dividend cut.
Therefore, as Net Organizational Capital (NOC)
8
becomes higher, dividend payout should be lower. Valuation
of implicit claims is very difficult. However, Cornell and Shapiro (1987) note that this valuation is related to the
level of spillovers that a firm has across product lines, business lines and business divisions.
9
A firm that is
more diversified or has many divisions will have less spillover effects. Stakeholders recognize that focused

8
When a firm sells its goods and services that have comparatively larger amounts of implicit guarantees, the ability to fulfill these obligations increases the
value of the firms equity in the market. The belief is that the value, or price, stakeholders are willing to pay exceeds the actual costs that the firm will
incur to meet these promises. Therefore, the reduction of stakeholder risk has a greater value than the firms cost of reducing this risk. The result is that
the firm creates an organizational assets that exceed the organizational liabilities is the level of Net Organizational Capital (NOC) which accrues to the
shareholders.
9 For example, if a firm chooses to identify all of its products under a single brand name or business lines and those products are similar, then changes in
the value of implicit claims of one product can have considerable effects on the other products.
12
firms have more to loose when they default on an implicit claim. Therefore, stakeholders will place higher value
on an implicit claim for a focused firm than on that of a diversified firm. Holder et al. (1998) also suggest that a
less-focused firm is diversified into more business segments and likely to have fewer spillover effects. Of
course the relatedness of the business divisions across countries will impact the spillover relationship, but
overall, the more business lines a firm has, the less likely spillover will occur. The firms with low spillover
effects will then have lower NOC than will a firm that is more focused, since defaulting on implicit claims is less
injurious to less focused firms. This suggests that as corporate focus increases (less diversified), NOC should
also increase. This should lead to a decrease in the payout ratio for the more focused firms.

It is important to note that mixed findings have been reported regarding the diversification concept. For
instance, some researchers argue that international diversification brings benefits while others argue the
contrary.
10
Further, Hymer (1976), Eun and Resnick (1988), Eun et al. (1991) and Reeb et al. (2001) argue that
firms engage in foreign investments in order to exploit firm-specific advantages and to earn high returns on
investment and in exploiting these firm-specific advantages, MCs may get exposed to higher level of foreign
exchange risk, political risk, agency costs and information costs

Following the above diversification arguments, the impact of diversification on firm performance and dividend
distribution is an issue calling for additional empirical investigation. Given MCs operate across countries in
multiple business lines and usually their operations are more diverse than the DCs counterparts, a significantly
different positive or negative relationship is expected with dividend payout ratios between MCs and DCs
(depending on the costs and benefits of industrial and geographical diversification benefit).


10
Geographic diversification is valuable when the benefits from the creation of intra-firm markets for the transfer of firm-specific intangible assets related
advantages across borders, that bypass incomplete or non-existent external markets, exceed the organizational and agency costs associated with doing
business in foreign countries (Kim et al, 2009). In support of this notion, Morck and Yeung (1991), followed by many others, found that intangibles
associated with consumer goodwill and technical expertise increase the value of multinational firms (Morck and Yeung, 1992; Allen and Pantzalis, 1996;
Pantzalis, 2001). Others (Buckley and Casson, 1998; Kogut and Zander, 1993) have argued that MNCs derive benefits from operating a geographically
dispersed network of subsidiaries that enable them to absorb shocks and take advantage of growth opportunities not available to their local competitors in
foreign countries. These networks provide MNCs with operating flexibility and are sources for an array of valuable real options (Pantzalis, 2001). On the
other hand, it is a well known tenet in finance (Brealey and Myers, 1996) that firms cannot add value by diversifying since investors can do that better
themselves in a developed capital market. Furthermore, various studies in the U. S. have indicated that corporate diversification tends to destroy value
perhaps because of loss in focus. For example, Lang and Stulz (1994) and Berger and Ofek (1995) concluded that the stock market puts lower values on
diversified firms.
13
2.3 Controlling for Other Determinants

Much of what we know about dividend policy originates from a series of interviews conducted by Lintner
(1956). At a theoretical level Miller and Modigliani (1961) showed that dividend policy is irrelevant to firm
value. However, relaxing the assumptions associated with their model has shown that dividend policy may
affect firm value and is influenced by several firm specific factors. Research thus far has shown that dividend
policy can be explained by some firm specific factors such as tax (DeAngelo and Masulis, 1980, Pattenden and
Twite, 2008), earnings volatility (Asquith and Mullins, 1983; Miller and Rock, 1985), cash flow related agency
problem (Jensen, 1986; Jensen and Meckling, 1976), debt (Litzenberger and Ramaswamy, 1979; Fama and
French, 2002), growth opportunities (Rozeff, 1982; Smith and Watts, 1992; Schooley and Barney, 1994),
profitability (Barlett and Ghoshal, 1989; Fama and French, 2001), firm size (Barlett and Ghoshal, 1989; Fama
and French, 2001) and firm maturity (Grullon et al., 2002).
2.3.1 Tax

Differential taxes on dividends and capital gains alter the preference of individual investors for receiving income
in one form or the other. In July 1987, a full imputation system was introduced which eliminated the double
taxation of company income. Prior to this, company income distributed as dividends was taxed twice, thus
making returns in the form of dividends less attractive than other returns. This may have distorted investors
portfolio allocations away from equity. Prior to the introduction of dividend imputation, company tax was levied
on profits earned and after-tax profits distributed as dividends were taxed again in the hands of shareholders.
Dividend imputation ensures that company profits paid out as dividends are taxed only once. Companies credit
their franking accounts with the amount of income that can be distributed as franked dividends. Credits arise
mainly from tax payments made or from receiving franked dividends from the companys shareholdings.
Shareholders receive franking credits to the extent that company tax has already been paid on dividends
received. They are then able to offset these credits against taxable income that is derived from any source, not
just dividends. Therefore, it is very important that one controls for this issue in determining dividend payout
14
ratios. Given dividend imputation is seen as an advantage from shareholders point of view a positive
relationship is expected with dividends.

Callen et al. (1992) suggest that for overseas investors, the withholding tax is not imposed on fully franked
dividends. This extends the benefits of imputation to overseas investors. However, because the amount of the
withholding tax on a dividend will be less than the value of the imputation credit, overseas investors do not
receive the full benefits received by domestic investors. Further, any foreign income on which corporate tax has
been paid in the foreign country is not part of the imputation system (Pattenden and Twite, 2008).
11
This means
that the Australian MCs paying tax overseas are not counted as part of imputation tax credit. Therefore,
shareholders getting paid from overseas after tax income will not be able to claim tax credit on their dividends.
Based on this arguments, as for Australian MCs, given their subsidiaries are located in multiple countries, the
shareholders of MCs taking advantage of imputation credit are lower than domestic investors, and hence a less
positive effect is expected for MCs relative to DCs in determining dividend payout ratios.
2.3.2 Leverage

Debt can play a disciplinary role.
12
Theoretical studies based on international environmental factors predict that
MCs will have lower debt ratios than DCs (Shapiro, 1978; Burgman, 1996). However, it has been documented
that Australian MCs hold higher debt ratios than DCs (Akhtar, 2005). Therefore, it is expected that leverage will
have higher magnitude of negative relationship in explaining MCs dividend ratios than DCs.




11
Although, Cannavan et al. (2004) describes a scenario where imputation credit may be valuable to non-resident investors if the credits can be effectively
sold to a resident individuals and institutions. However, Officer (1988) concludes that franking credits would be fully valued but for the transaction costs
associated with their transfer. This is an argument based on the assumption that all investors benefit from imputation, either directly or indirectly by
selling the credits to reduce tax liabilities or indirectly by selling tax credits to investors who can use them.
12
For example, by increasing the debt level, the free cash flow will decrease (Grossman and Hart, 1982; Jensen, 1986 and Stultz, 1990). Indeed,
shareholders may expropriate wealth from bondholders by paying themselves dividends at the expense of bondholders who try to deal with this problem
through debt covenant restrictions (Jensen and Meckling, 1976; Kalay, 1982). The debt covenant hypothesis predicts that firms will decrease or not
increase dividends after debt issues. It is found that the stockholders of leveraged firms choose to pay dividends under debt contracts. Consistent with the
debt covenant hypothesis, DeAngelo and DeAngelo (1990), Jensen et al. (1992), and Long et al. (1994) find an inverse relationship between dividends and
debts. Therefore, the leverage ratio should have a negative impact on dividend payout ratios.
15
2.3.3 Cash

The principal agent problem is that managers may pursue their own goals at the cost of obtaining lower profits
for the owners (stockholders).
13
Dividend payouts can be used to reduce discretionary cash under managers
control that could be wasted in negative NPV projects. Therefore, a positive relationship is expected indicating
the reduction in agency related cash flow problem in the dividend payout decision. MCs operations in multiple
countries can increase the risks of agency costs. The agency risk of MCs is a potential decrease in the ability to
monitor managers multiple countries (Lee and Kwok, 1988). Monitoring these overseas agents is harder due to
the geographical constraints, cultural differences, timing issues, costly communications, and so forth. Also,
international market imperfections may also decrease the ability of the market for corporate control to discipline
international managers. As monitoring foreign operations becomes more difficult and less effective, the risk
(fluctuations) of anticipated cash flows from overseas operations may increase. Based on this argument, MCs
will have higher agency costs then DCs counterparts and therefore will pay less dividends.
2.3.4 Collateral value of assets

Collateral value of asset is seen as a buffering to mitigate an agency problem between shareholders and
bondholders. It can be argued that if a firm has to rely on external source of finance to maintain the dividend
payments, then it would be easier for firm to raise money if the firm holds substantial amount of fixed or
tangible assets.
14
In relation to MCs and DCs, it is found in Akhtar and Oliver (2009) that Australian MCs has

13
There are many ways of reducing agency costs. Dividend payments serve as one means of monitoring or bonding management performance. Greater
dividend payments to shareholders may force the firm both to raise capital by selling new shares and to go to the capital market more frequently. Agency
costs are reduced as a result of the increased scrutiny the capital market places on the firm (Easterbrook, 1984; Jensen, 1986). Jensen and Meckling (1976)
suggest that managers can allocate resources to activities that benefit them privately, but that are not in shareholders best interest. Easterbrook (1984)
views dividend payments as a potential solution to agency conflicts. Dividend payments force managers to raise funds in the external financial markets and
thus subject managers to scrutiny by outside professionals such as investment bankers, lawyers, and public accountants. Recognising the monitoring value
of external financial markets, shareholders will insist that managers pay dividends. Also, Jensen (1986) points out that managers have incentive to grow
their firms beyond optimal size as growth increases managers power by increasing the resources under their control.

14
Tangible assets are likely to have an impact on the borrowing decisions of a firm because they have greater value than intangible assets in case of
bankruptcy. Further, moral hazards risks are reduced when the firm offers tangible asset as collateral, because this constitutes a positive signal to the debt
holder. Therefore, an inference can be drawn on the basis that if collateral value of asset assists to raise external debt which helps to maintain stable
dividend payout ratios then a positive relationship is expected with dividend payments; however one could argue that if there is not enough collateral value
of asset is available for external financing then raising debt externally to meet the dividend payment may become very costly and in that case the positive
relationship may not be observed. Therefore an expected direction is unclear.

16
significantly less collateral value of asset than DCs. However, it is an empirical question whether collateral
values of asset play any role in determining MCs and DCs dividend payout ratios.
2.3.5 Risks

Firms facing high levels of earnings uncertainty are likely to pay low dividends, fearing cash shortfalls in the
future. In order to fund profitable future investment projects, firms with high earnings uncertainty will choose to
hoard cash today by keeping dividends payments low.
15
DCs operate mainly in only one economy while MCs
have affiliates located in multiple economies. The performances of these multiple countries economies are not
perfectly correlated, giving rise to diversification opportunities for the MCs. Given this opportunity, the overall
cash flow variability reduces the probability of bankruptcy and expected bankruptcy costs. This in turn will also
enable MCs to pay higher dividends to its shareholders relative to DCs counter parts. On the bother hand, it can
also be argued that foreign exchange rate fluctuations and political risk will increase MCs variability of cash
flows. In contrast, Reeb et al. (2001) counter that even foreign exchange and political risks specific to MCs may
be eliminated through international diversification. Based on these conflicting arguments, nevertheless, scholars
of international finance tend to give more weight to the benefits of international diversification. As a result,
MCs are expected to have less negative effect in explaining the dividend payout ratios than DCs.
2.3.6 Profitability

Fama and French (2001), document that the probability of a firm paying dividends is positively related to
profitability.
16
MCs have better opportunities than DCs to earn more profit mainly due to having access to more
than one source of earnings and better chances to have favourable business conditions in particular countries

15
Moreover, firms with unstable or volatile earnings may have to resort to external financing more often. In general, external funds are more expensive
than internal funds, but this is more so for firms with high earnings uncertainty; these firms generally have low credit ratings, a result of volatile earnings
streams, and thus must pay premium interest to raise money. Firms with high earnings uncertainty will thus pay lower dividends because of their greater
need to rely on internal funds (Pettit, 1972; Asquith and Mullins, 1983; Miller and Rock, 1985). Based on this discussion, it is expected that dividend
payouts will be negatively related to earnings volatility. This argument echoes survey evidence by Brav et al. (2005). They report that more than two-
thirds of chief financial officers of dividend-paying firms say that the stability of future earnings is an important factor affecting dividend decisions.
Beaver et al. (1970), Michael and Shaked (1986), Glen et al. (1995) and Baker et al. (2001) argue that the uncertainty of a firms earnings may lead it to
pay lower dividends because the existence of large fluctuations in earnings materially increases the risk of default.
16
The intuition is that higher profitability and greater size imply a greater capacity to distribute cash, whereas greater growth indicates superior investment
opportunities, thus a stronger incentive to retain cash. More profitable firms are expected to hold less debt, since it is easier and more cost effective to
finance internally and consequently pay higher dividends.
17
(Kogut, 1985a; Barlett and Ghoshal, 1989). Consequently, MCs being more profitable than DCs are expected to
have higher dividend payout than DCs after controlling for the other variables.
2.3.7 Size

Research by Lloyd et al. (1985) and Vogt (1994) indicates that firm size plays a role in explaining the dividend
payout ratio of firms.
17
It is often argued that MCs are larger than DCs. On this basis, MCs are expected to be
larger in size then DCs and therefore will enable MCs to pay higher dividends than DCs.
2.3.8 Age

Dividends tend to be paid by mature, established firms, plausibly reflecting a financial lifecycle in which young
firms face relatively abundant investment opportunities with limited resources so that retention dominates
distribution, whereas mature firms are better candidates to pay dividends because they have higher profitability
and fewer attractive investment opportunities.
18
MCs are claimed to be more mature than DCs (Akhtar and
Oliver, 2009). As a result, it can be hypothesised that MCs will pay higher or lower dividends than DCs
counterparts.
2.3.8 Future growth

Firms with many good investment opportunities have high cash needs, which may lead them to payout a low
fraction of earnings to shareholders as dividends (Smith and Watts (1992); Gaver and Gaver (1993); La Porta et
al. (2000)). If this is the case, a negative relationship is expected between investment opportunities and
payouts.
19
The value of future growth opportunities is augmented as far as a firm can exploit imperfections in the

17
They find that larger firms tend to be more mature and thus have easier access to the capital markets, which reduces their dependence on internally-
generated funding and allows for higher dividend payout ratios. It is argued that firms that are large have greater access to capital markets and they can
easily able to switch between debt and equity and take advantage of lower transaction costs, which allows for more stable and possibly higher dividend
payments of the firm. Hence a positive relationship is expected between the size and dividend payout ratio (Ali et al., 1993).
18
Fama and French (2001), Grullon et. al (2002), Grullon et al. (2002), DeAngelo and DeAngelo (2006) all advance lifecycle explanations for dividends
that rely, implicitly, on the trade-off between the advantages (e.g. flotation cost savings) and the costs of retention (e.g. agency costs of free cash flow).
The trade-off between retention and distribution evolves over time as profits accumulate and investment opportunities decline, so that paying dividends
becomes increasingly desirable as firms mature. However, one could also argue that as firm approaches to its maturity phase, the need for higher dividend
payment to attract new investors is not necessarily important for established firms because these firms can raise capital without relying on issuing
securities. Also, a firm needs to pay higher dividends during the growth phase of its business cycle to attract investors and also to be able to raise capital
through equity issues as external borrowing might be bit risky due to not having enough creditworthiness in the capital market.
19
Alternatively, some others argue that the relationship between investment opportunities and dividend is in fact positive (Brav et al., 2005). Survey
evidence suggests that firms are highly reluctant to cut dividends, and increase dividends only when sustainable higher earnings are expected (Lintner,
18
products and capital markets. MCs tend to be in a better position than DCs for taking advantage of such market
imperfections (Homaifer et al., 1998). Kim and Lyn (1986) report higher MB ratios for MCs than for DCs,
which indicates that the existence of monopoly rents. The gain from multinationalism, according to Kogut
(1985b), stems from the ability to exercise options not available to domestic corporations. Example of these
options is the ability to arbitrage institutional restrictions such as taxes, antitrust laws, and economies of scale
gained in distribution, marketing, and manufacturing. Since these options are only available to MCs, they
become a source of monopoly rents (Homaifer et al., 1998). Based on this argument, a more negative growth
opportunity relationship is expected for MCs than DCs in explaining dividend payout ratios.

Finally, industry effect
20
and time effect
21
will be also controlled for since these two elements have been argued
to be important in distribution of dividends.

3. Data and Method
3.1 Sample Selection

Table 1 presents the process of sample selection. Initially, all firms (6785 in total) listed on the Australian Stock
Exchange for each year from 1995 to 2008 are selected. For each firm, four databases have been used to extract
relevant data for this study. Segmental (industrial and geographical) data is obtained from OSIRIS
22
. Further,
OSIRIS and Compustat (global) have been used to extract annual balance sheet and income statement data.
Datastream has been used to get share price, market index (all ordinaries) and trade weighted index data. Lastly,

1956; Brav et al., 2005). This argument suggests that only firms with a variety of good investment projects pay high dividends today because the cash
flows earned from future projects support high dividends in the future. Given these two conflicting arguments on the relation between investment
opportunities and dividend payments, it is left to empirical tests results to determine which is indeed the more likely for Australian firms.
20
Industry may affect a firms dividend policy (Baker and Powell, 2000 and Michael and Shaked, 1986). Although variation in dividend payouts among
firms appear to be affected by firm-specific variables such as investment requirements and earnings variability, Lintner (1953) hypothesises that dividend
policy also is influenced by an industry effect. Such an industry effect, if it exists, presumably stands apart from other firm-specific variables that affect
payout decisions of the member firms within an industry and causes them to have varying dividend policies (Dempsey et al.,1993). Some evidence
suggests that there is significant variation in dividend payout ratios among industries (Michael, 1979; Baker, 1988). Richardson et al. (2003) confirm that
industry affiliation is a strong determinant of dividend and share repurchase policy. Several studies specifically examine the potential effect of industry
affiliation on dividend policies. Research by Michel (1979) and Baker (1988) among others suggests a positive relationship exists between industry
classification and dividend policy.
21
It is important to examine the effects of time-varying information and determinants on the dividend payout. Firstly, time series evidence of dividend
policies is relatively more plausible than cross-sectional evidence as time series analysis captures the dynamic changes of dividend payout policy across
time. Secondly, it would provide evidence on the robustness of the disappearing puzzle. Thirdly, it allows conducting a further test of the time
dependence variable changes. For example, when investment and dividend payment is primarily financed with internal funds, worsening conditions
should not have as larger an impact as when external funds account for the bulk of financing. Since this only happens in financial markets which are
imperfect (i.e. if internal and external funds are not perfect substitutes), the differential impact should be stronger when financing frictions are more
prevalent (Braun and Larrain, 2005).
22
https://osiris.bvdep.com/version-2009512/cgi/template.dll?product=20
19
political risk rating data were purchased from The PRS country ratings.
23
For each year, if a firm reported
business activity (sales earnings) from other than an Australian source (that is, non-Australian geographical
segment) and have at least two overseas subsidiaries, it is coded as multinational otherwise it is coded as a
domestic corporation.

Table 1
Sample Selection Procedure
Deleted Sample Description
Observations
for MCs
Observations
for DCs
Initial sample 2789 3996
a. Less foreign Multinationals -690 0
b. Less repurchase due to takeover, pure capital return
winding up, subsequently delisted. Also, repurchased for
convertible purpose.
-281 -398
c. Less Investment, Bank, Insurance and Trust -478 -285
d. Less inefficient sample period (minimum 3 years) -177 -1112
e. Less lack of detailed reporting of relevant Information -129 -336
f. Less different reporting period -61 -89
Total final samples 973 1776
Table 1 presents the summary of the total sample and data selection processes for Australian multinational corporations (MCs) and
domestic corporations (DCs). The first column lists the detailed description of the data selection process while the second and third
columns contain the number of observations for Australian DCs and MCs.


There are 973 MCs and 1776 DCs selected across 14 years. Foreign countrys MCs listed in the Australian
Stock Exchange are excluded because we are only studying Australian MCs that are incorporated in Australia.
Companies were also excluded if they completed off-market repurchase in response to a takeover or as an
alternative to a pure capital return when winding up, or if they subsequently became delisted. Further,
companies that issued publicly traded rights to participate in the repurchase activities and companies that
repurchased ordinary shares for convertible notes were also excluded.

Firms in the financial and regulated industries have dividend payout and capital structures that are determined by
levels of deposits and financial regulation. Determinants of dividend payout and capital structure for these firms

23
Since 1979, Political Risk Services has been known worldwide as the original system for quantifying and rating political risk, using methodology
developed by Professors William D. Coplin and Michael K. OLeary during 20 years of research at the Maxwell School of Citizenship & Public Affairs,
Syracuse University. Political Risk Services is the most widely accepted system of completely independent political risk forecasting. All publications
based on this system are included in the Political Risk Services product line. This methodology and research produce 100 Country Reports (sold
separately and also grouped into Regional Services and the World Service, available online as PRS Online).
20
are considerably different from other firms, and as a result are excluded (Fama and French, 2002; Flannery and
Rangan, 2006). The number of financial organisations excluded under this criterion are shown at (c.) in Table 1.
A minimum of two years of data was necessary for some variables. Firms with less than five years of data for
estimation of these variables are excluded as shown at (d.) in Table 1. Other firms are excluded as the reported
figure duration is less than 12 months. Since all the proxies required a full year of observation to be consistent
across other variables, a full year of reporting was important. This is indicated by (e.) in Table 1. Finally, two
important statistical conditions are also applied so that the final sample size is statistically valid to use in the
multiple regressions. The conditions include a reasonably large sample selected at random from large
populations which is, on average, representative of the characteristics of that population. Secondly, it is
statistically advisable that large groups of data show a higher degree of stability than a smaller data set. The
final sample resulted in selection of 973 MCs and 1776 DCs (on average 70 MCs and 127 domestic firms per
year).

Table 2 presents the number of MCs and DCs in each year for the samples. There has been a general increase in
DCs and MCs although a decline in numbers of DCs and MCs are observed since 2006 but it is due to meeting
the sample selection criteria not because there is a reduction in the numbers of firms in the ASX listings.
Overall, in the sample there are more listed DCs than MCs in any given year. Note that in year 2008, not many
data for firms were available at the time of the data collection, however, it is still an acceptable representation of
2008 ASX listed MCs and DCs.
Table 2
Sample Distribution across Years
Year MCs DCs Total
1995
51 74 125
1996
53 79 132
1997
66 105 171
1998
78 123 201
1999
79 127 206
2000
69 159 228
2001
74 167 241
2002
82 158 240
2003
85 153 238
2004
76 148 224
2005
74 141 215
21
2006
69 129 198
2007
61 113 174
2008
56 100 156
Total
973 1776 2749
Table 2 presents the summary of the total sample and data selection across 14 years for Australian multinational corporations (MCs) and
domestic corporations (DCs). The first column of the table lists the detailed description of the yearly observations for MCs and DCs.

Table 3 reports the sample distribution of each GICS
24
industry classification for MCs and DCs. It shows an
almost equal distribution of sample selection across industries between MCs and DCs with the exception of two
industries namely, Energy and Materials. For example, industries except Energy and Materials make up
approximately 70% of the DCs sample while the proportion of MCs in the other eight industries make up 64% of
the MCs sample. This table also shows that higher proportions of Australian MCs belong to the Materials
industry while the least number of industries that MCs are involved in is Utilities.
Table 3
Sample Distribution across GICS Industries
MCs
%
DCs
%
Total
%
Energy (10) 48 5 198 11 246 9
Materials (15) 299 31 341 19 640 23
Industrials (20) 115 12 299 17 414 15
Consumer Discretionary (25) 222 23 424 24 646 23
Consumer Staples (30) 97 10 106 6 203 7
Health Care (35) 71 7 149 8 220 8
Financials (40) 0 0 0 0 0 0
Information Technology (45) 75 8 188 11 263 10
Telecommunication Services (50) 34 3 23 1 57 2
Utilities (55) 12 1 48 3 60 2
Total 973 100 1776 100 2749 100
Table 3 provides the Global Index Classification System (GICS) for industry distribution of MCs and DCs including the proportion of the
total sample. The codes that are used in the GICS classification are reported in parenthesis. GICS has 10 main industry categories which
are: Energy; Materials; Industrials; Consumer Discretionary; Consumer Staples, Health Care; Financials; Information Technology;
Telecommunication Services and Utilities.

Table 4
Various dividend payment frequencies: 1995 - 2008

Regular
Cash
dividends
Off-
market
On-
market
Regular
script
dividend
Special
cash
dividends
Bonus
share
plan
Dividend
reinvestment
plan
Special script
dividends
1995 112 0 0
0
0 0 20 0
1996 118 0 0
0
2 0 21 0
1997 167 0 0
0
6 0 19 1
1998 179 2 7
0
7 0 21 0
1999 205 4 6
0
6 1 21 0
2000 229 4 10
0
13 0 25 2

24
GICS stands for Global Industry Classification Sectors. This classification has been acceptable globally than any other industry
classification. Therefore, for comparison reasons, GICS classification approach has been adopted.
22
2001 240 8 13
0
14 1 34 0
2002 241 8 8
0
8 2 38 0
2003 232 8 8
0
10 2 39 1
2004 224 4 11
0
12 1 39 0
2005 205 12 13
0
14 1 37 2
2006 197 8 14
0
11 1 43 0
2007 170 7 13
0
9 1 48 1
2008 167 5 4
0
8 1 50 0
Total 2686 70 107 0 120 11 455 6
This table provides number of companies that paid various form of dividends across years: 1995 - 2008. Various forms of dividends
payments are: regular cash dividends, off-market share repurchase, on-market share repurchase, regular script dividends, special cash
dividends, bonus share plan, and special script dividends. Cash dividends are defined as the regular dividends that paid every year. On-
market share repurchase is the amounts that are used to buy back share from its shareholder at any given year. Off-market share
repurchase is the amounts that are used to buy back share from its shareholder at any given year. Special cash dividend is the amount that
is paid by the company to its shareholder in some year. Regular script dividend is a form of dividend that is paid to the shareholder as a
share instead of cash payment. Bonus share plans is to allow shareholders to renounce their right to the dividend in favour of a bonus
issue. Dividend reinvestment plan plans allows allow shareholders to reinvest the dividends.


Table 4 details the number of companies that paid various forms of dividends per year. The results in Table 4
show that the number of firms pays regular cash dividends increased by two fold from 1995 to 2001 and then it
gradually declined. This decline may be justified with an increase in both off- and on-market share repurchase
activities and dividend reinvestment plan over the sample period. This is consistent with the argument that firms
catering to the increased demand for the distribution of imputation tax credits following the inclusion of pension
funds in the imputation tax system (Pattenden and Twite, 2008). From taxation point of view, dividend
reinvestment plan is treated as if the cash dividend upon receipts by shareholder was immediately applied to the
purchase of new shares.

3.2 Method

The following ordinary least square regression model is proposed to test the determinants and multinationality
effect on different measures of dividend payout ratios. The model attempts to isolate the multinationality effect
which is argued to capture the unique factors that cannot be quantified otherwise. The model also distinguishes
the difference across the explanatory variables between DCs and MCs. The test of industry influence and time
influence on dividend payment behaviour is also investigated by extending this model with 0 and 1 dummy
variables. Also, note that the independent variables are in lag terms. The justification for using lag terms of the
23
independent variable are justified by the fact that managers of any firms making a dividend payout decision this
year does rely on last years financial structures and firms financial stability. Also, all regression results are
conducted controlling for industry and time effects.
*
, 0 1 2 , 1 3 , 1 4 , 1
5 , 1 6

- 2
i t i t i t i t
i t
DIV Multinationality Political risk Foreign Exchange risk Geographical diversification
Industrial diversification digit Industrial diversificati
| | | | |
| |

= + + + +
+ +
, 1 7 , 1
8 , 1 9 , 1 10 , 1 11 , 1 12 , 1
13 , 1 14 , 1
- 4

+
i t i t
i t i t i t i t i t
i t i t
on digit Effective tax rate
Long term debt Cash Collateral value of asset Risk Profitability
Size Age
|
| | | | |
| |



+
+ + + + +
+ +
15 , 1 ,
- -
i t i t
Market to book value | c

+

Where Multinationality
i,t
represents the multinationality feature of a firm. This is the base model and various
extensions will be implemented to cater for various aspect of different theory testing purposes. In addition to
ordinary least square regression technique, Probit regression is considered specially when dependent variable
takes a form of 0 or 1 to indicate dividend payer vs. non-payer dividends and also dividend increase vs.
decrease.
4. Results
4.1 Summary Statistics
Table 5 (Panel A and Panel B) presents summary statistics. It shows that cash dividend payments for MCs are
39% of net income on average and for DCs it is 42%. This difference is statistically significant at the 5%
significance level. MCs having lower cash dividend relative to their counterpart DCs may be an indication that
Australian MCs face more risks through international operations leading to more volatile cash flows to distribute
as cash dividends. We observe a lesser proportion of off-market share repurchase, on-market share repurchase
and special cash dividend type dividend payments executed by MCs in comparison to DCs. The result of the
political risk factor shows that Australian MCs are experiencing relatively more uncertainty than DCs (75.99 vs.
82.66). The average diversification figure for MCs is 2.54, which is statistically higher than DCs (0.04).
However, no significant difference is detected between MCs and DCs for 2-digit and 4-digit industry level
diversification. Consistent with Akhtar (2005), on average Australian MCs have significantly lower long term
debt than (0.27 vs. 0.36). Profitability and firm age variables indicate that Australian MCs are more profitable
than their counterpart DCs and also more mature. Similarly, Australian MCs on average experience more
growth opportunities than DCs.
24

Panel B, shows individual linear relationships each variable has with the dependent variables and also within the
independent variables. No harmful multicolinearity is observed and correlations are reasonably within the
acceptable range of the correlation bench mark (Keller, 2008).
25
Table 5
Descriptive statistics for sample variables
Panel A

C
a
s
h

D
i
v
i
d
e
n
d

[
1
]

O
f
f

M
a
r
k
e
t

[
2
]

O
n

M
a
r
k
e
t

[
3
]

S
p
e
c
i
a
l

c
a
s
h

d
i
v
i
d
e
n
d

[
4
]

T
o
t
a
l

d
i
v
i
d
e
n
d

[
5
]

N
e
t

D
i
v
i
d
e
n
d
s

[
6
]

P
o
l
i
t
i
c
a
l

r
i
s
k

[
7
]

F
o
r
e
i
g
n

e
x
c
h
a
n
g
e

r
i
s
k

[
8
]

G
e
o
g
r
a
p
h
i
c
a
l

d
i
v
e
r
s
i
f
i
c
a
t
i
o
n

[
9
]

I
n
d
u
s
t
r
y

d
i
v
e
r
s
i
f
i
c
a
t
i
o
n

(
2

d
i
g
i
t
)

[
1
0
]

I
n
d
u
s
t
r
y

d
i
v
e
r
s
i
f
i
c
a
t
i
o
n

(
4

d
i
g
i
t
)

[
1
1
]

E
f
f
e
c
t
i
v
e

t
a
x

[
1
2
]

L
o
n
g

t
e
r
m

d
e
b
t

[
1
3
]

C
a
s
h

[
1
4
]

C
o
l
l
a
t
e
r
a
l

v
a
l
u
e

o
f

a
s
s
e
t
s

[
1
5
]

R
i
s
k

[
1
6
]

P
r
o
f
i
t
a
b
i
l
i
t
y

[
1
7
]

T
o
t
a
l

a
s
s
e
t

[
1
8
]

F
i
r
m
'
s

a
g
e

[
1
9
]

M
a
r
k
e
t
-
t
o
-
b
o
o
k

v
a
l
u
e

[
2
0
]

MCs



Mean 0.39 0.03 0.05 0.09 0.59 0.37 75.99 0.01 2.54 0.95 0.96 0.21 0.27 0.12 0.61 0.06 2.96 5.96 3.28 2.32
Median 0.37 0.05 0.09 0.15 0.54
0.28
80.50 0.00 2.01 1.00 1.00 0.26 0.17 0.06 0.63 0.05 0.46 5.88 3.22 1.73
Maximum 2.48 0.16 0.22 0.30 3.68
0.98
90.11 3.67 12.15 1.00 1.00 0.49 0.65 0.98 0.89 0.31 7.87 11.53 5.12 8.61
Minimum 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00
0.00
25.15 -3.52 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.16 0.00 0.00
Std. Dev. 1.12 1.98 1.18 1.53 1.25
0.37
14.74 0.43 1.60 0.07 0.13 1.73 0.53 0.16 0.21 0.04 2.38 1.95 0.92 1.84
DCs


Mean 0.42 0.04 0.07 0.10 0.63
0.35
82.66 0.00 0.04 0.95 0.97 0.16 0.36 0.12 0.62 0.06 1.10 5.28 3.09 2.23
Median 0.39 0.09 0.18 0.26 0.47
0.22
87.00 0.00 0.00 1.00 1.00 0.27 0.19 0.05 0.68 0.04 0.37 5.26 3.04 1.58
Maximum 3.18 0.86 0.25 0.56 4.29
0.97
89.00 3.43 5.91 1.00 1.00 0.51 0.52 0.99 0.95 0.62 3.92 11.40 5.14 8.42
Minimum 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00
0.00
35.50 -3.57 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00
Std. Dev. 1.17 1.64 2.17 2.68 1.28
0.29
13.53 0.41 0.29 0.08 0.12 0.71 0.56 0.18 0.25 0.05 2.04 1.84 0.94 1.88
The ordinary least square regression is conducted using full sample of 2749 of which 973 are MCs and the remaining being DCs (1776). The dependent variable DIV takes six different
dividend payment measurements. For example, regular cash dividend is defined as regular cash to net income; off-market is calculated as the total amount spent on off-market share
repurchase in the entire financial year scaled by on-market is calculated as total amount spent on on-market share buyback for the financial year scaled by net income; and total dividend is
calculated as sum of regular dividends, off-market share repurchase, on-market share repurchase amount for the financial year, special cash dividends, bonus share plan, special cash
dividends and scaled by net income and finally net dividend I calculated as total dividends minus new equity issue (via dividend reinvestment plans, right issue, public issues or private
placements). The independent variables are: Political risk is the sum of all the MCs subsidiaries countries political risk ratings exposed to the proportion of each sale that a subsidiary
makes overseas. Foreign exchange risk FX is proxied by regression coefficient of trade weighted index. The regression is performed on every firms weekly (52 observations per year)
against all ordinaries index and trade weighted index. Geographical diversification is measured as ln(Foreign sales proportion times by total number of subsidiaries across countries).
Industry level diversification is measured as 1 minus the Harfindahl index and this procedure is followed for both two digit GICS code industry level diversification and four digit GICS
codes industry level diversification. Effective tax rate is measured as tax paid scaled by pretax income. Leverage is measured as the total debt to total debt and market value of equity.
Leverage is measured as the total debt to total debt and market value of equity. Cash is estimated as proportion of cash to total assets. Collateral value of asset is measured as fixed asset to
total assets. Risk is measured as standard deviation of firms stock return over a year using weekly observations. Profitability is measured as net income over total assets. Size is calculated
as ln(total asset). Firms age is the natural logarithm of the age of the firm in years from date of incorporation. Market-to-book is sum of market value of equity and book value of equity
scaled by book value of total assets.
26
Panel B

C
a
s
h

D
i
v
i
d
e
n
d

[
1
]

O
f
f

M
a
r
k
e
t

[
2
]

O
n

M
a
r
k
e
t

[
3
]

S
p
e
c
i
a
l

c
a
s
h

d
i
v
i
d
e
n
d

[
4
]

T
o
t
a
l

d
i
v
i
d
e
n
d

[
5
]

N
e
t

D
i
v
i
d
e
n
d
s

[
6
]

P
o
l
i
t
i
c
a
l

r
i
s
k

[
7
]

F
o
r
e
i
g
n

e
x
c
h
a
n
g
e

r
i
s
k

[
8
]

G
e
o
g
r
a
p
h
i
c
a
l

d
i
v
e
r
s
i
f
i
c
a
t
i
o
n

[
9
]

I
n
d
u
s
t
r
y

d
i
v
e
r
s
i
f
i
c
a
t
i
o
n

(
2

d
i
g
i
t
)

[
1
0
]

I
n
d
u
s
t
r
y

d
i
v
e
r
s
i
f
i
c
a
t
i
o
n

(
4

d
i
g
i
t
)

[
1
1
]

E
f
f
e
c
t
i
v
e

t
a
x

[
1
2
]

L
o
n
g

t
e
r
m

d
e
b
t

[
1
3
]

C
a
s
h

[
1
4
]

C
o
l
l
a
t
e
r
a
l

v
a
l
u
e

o
f

a
s
s
e
t
s

[
1
5
]

R
i
s
k

[
1
6
]

P
r
o
f
i
t
a
b
i
l
i
t
y

[
1
7
]

T
o
t
a
l

a
s
s
e
t

[
1
8
]

F
i
r
m

s

a
g
e

[
1
9
]

M
a
r
k
e
t
-
t
o
-
b
o
o
k

v
a
l
u
e

[
2
0
]

[1] 1.00


[2] -0.04 1.00


[3] 0.30 0.59 1.00


[4] 0.57 -0.21 -0.15 1.00


[5] 0.83 0.79 0.73 0.90 1.00


[6] 0.60 0.68 0.66 0.59 0.64
1.00

[7] 0.05 0.09 0.12 0.04 0.05 0.04 1.00
[8] -0.06 0.22 -0.18 0.07 -0.05 -0.01 0.05 1.00
[9] -0.03 -0.12 -0.12 0.09 -0.01 -0.01 -0.36 0.00 1.00
[10] -0.07 0.06 0.06 0.07 -0.06 -0.10 -0.02 0.03 -0.03 1.00
[11] -0.06 0.05 0.05 0.07 -0.04 -0.02 -0.01 0.06 -0.07 0.64 1.00
[12] 0.04 -0.04 0.11 -0.26 0.03 0.00 0.04 -0.01 0.01 -0.01 -0.01 1.00
[13] 0.03 -0.10 -0.08 -0.07 0.00 0.14 0.06 0.00 -0.02 -0.03 -0.04 -0.03 1.00
[14] -0.25 0.27 0.30 0.00 -0.18 -0.09 -0.04 0.03 0.04 0.06 -0.06 -0.03 -0.19 1.00
[15] 0.02 -0.26 -0.19 -0.07 -0.01 -0.02 0.02 -0.02 -0.01 -0.07 0.01 -0.02 0.22 -0.50 1.00
[16] -0.32 -0.07 -0.03 0.06 -0.27 -0.15 0.06 0.13 -0.01 0.09 0.08 -0.07 0.08 0.30 -0.05 1.00
[17] 0.03 -0.02 0.16 0.29 0.02 0.02 0.01 -0.01 -0.01 0.00 0.00 -0.01 0.00 -0.03 0.00 -0.03 1.00
[18] 0.30 -0.13 -0.07 -0.19 0.25 0.21 -0.05 -0.06 0.21 -0.30 -0.27 0.05 0.19 -0.40 0.33 -0.51 0.05 1.00
[19] 0.14 0.04 -0.18 -0.03 0.12 0.11 -0.04 0.02 0.13 -0.18 -0.14 0.00 0.03 -0.12 -0.03 -0.15 0.04 0.28 1.00
[20] -0.03 0.35 0.13 -0.13 0.00 0.05 -0.04 -0.01 0.07 -0.07 -0.09 0.00 -0.34 0.22 -0.16 -0.05 0.00 -0.07 -0.095 1.00
27
4.2 Regression Analysis
4.2.1 Does multinational of a firm matter across different payout ratios and what are the determinants?

The regression analysis presented in Table 6 shows six sets of regression results on a pooled sample of MCs and
DCs. To observe whether multinationality of a firm has any impact in explaining the difference of firms
various forms of dividend payout methods, a dichotomous variable of MULT
i,t
(1 being multinational, 0
otherwise) has been employed. Interestingly, the results shows that Australian MCs pay significantly less cash
dividends (t=-1.96), special cash dividends (t=-2.50), total dividends (t=-2.03) and net dividends (t=-2.41) to its
shareholders relative to DCs but a similar significant result is not observed for off-market and on-market share
repurchase types of dividend payments.
25
multinationality effect on dividend payments can be multidimensional
(eg., the risks and benefits of holding assets in foreign countries, earning income through foreign sales and
having foreign subsidiaries in multiple countries) and this multidimentionality may be explained by the slope
difference of chosen international and firm specific factors; hence Table 7 investigates the slope difference of
each of the estimated coefficients. Continuing with Table 6 results, the significant determining factors across
different method of dividend payout vary. For example, political risk explains cash dividends (t=2.89), total
dividends (t=2.35) and net dividends (t=2.00) while foreign exchange risk is a significant determinant in
explaining cash dividend (t=-1.98), on-market share repurchase (t=-1.67) and total dividends (t=-2.36). Among
other variables, cash, collateral value of assets, risk and size factors became consistently significant in explaining
most methods of dividend payments.

The significant positive coefficient of political risk factor suggests that an increase in the ratings (indicating a
safe zone) assist firms to significantly increase cash, total and net dividends respectively (t=2.89, t=2.35 and
t=2.00). This result is consistent with Kim and Mei (1994) and Bailey and Chung (1995). They argue that
political risk has significant effect on firms profit level and profit distribution to its shareholders. The positive
significant estimate explain that Australian firms dividend distributions are complemented in a positive way by
their foreign countries subsidiaries when they are able to operate and earn income in politically safe

25
A further explanation of this result is investigated in Table 7 which will explore the determining factors that play role to produce such
result.
28
environment which are not adversely affected by the political changes such as expropriation, civil disorders,
currency controls, investment restrictions, and other laws and regulations.

Consistent with the theoretical arguments, an increase in foreign exchange exposure has significant negative
effect in the paying cash, on market and total dividends (t=-1.98, t=-1.67 and t=-2.36) and this is consistent with
Adler and Dumas (1984). This result indicates that firms operations are affected by exchange rates, especially
when their input and output prices are influenced by currency movements. This suggest that Australian firms are
sensitive to foreign exchange rate fluctuations which shocks the profit level figures and consequently effects
profit distribution as cash dividends, on-market share repurchase and total dividends. Results also shows that the
greater the foreign exchange risk exposure the more it will have negative impact on dividend distributions. The
regression analysis of on-market share repurchase activities presents some instinctive results for Australian
firms. Negative significant coefficient of foreign exchange risk exposure (t=-1.67) indicate that when the foreign
exchange risk exposure is high, it leads a reduction in on-market share repurchase activities. This may imply
that shareholders may become sceptical about the true price of the share and as a result their participation in on-
market share repurchases declines.

Long term debt has significant negative (t=-1.53, t=-2.93 and t=-2.95) relationship with off-market, on-market
share repurchase and special cash types of dividend payments. This may indicate that when firms are engaged in
raising long term debt, the firm significantly reduce their both type of share repurchase activities as well as
special cash dividend payments. Alternatively, it may also imply that share repurchase financed through
external borrowing may be costly and therefore we observe this significant negative impact in explaining
variation in both off-market and on-market share repurchase.

Although it has been argued in the literature that dividend payout can be seen as a technique to reduce agency
costs by distributing cash in hand (Easterbrook, 1984 and Jensen, 1986), the results in this paper produce an
opposite outcome to this argument. The significant negative result of cash availability may imply that, for
Australian firms, an increase in cash in hand may not help in reducing dividend related agency costs. This
29
indicates that managers may involve themselves in increasing their wealth at the costs of shareholders when it
comes to a point of making any form of dividend payments (t=-5.69, t=-2.31, t=-2.67, t=-6.26 and t=-8.62). This
finding may support the results found by Jensen and Meckling (1976).

A significant negative coefficient of collateral value of asset and its negative impact on various forms of
dividend payments can be explained from bondholder and shareholders related agency costs point of view. For
example, if there is not enough cash available to distribute regular cash dividends, managers may rely on
external financing to meet the dividend payment obligation. This action may impose a strenuous impact on the
collateral assets, leading to create a significant negative relationship across all six modes of dividend payments
(t=-5.33, t=-1.67, t=-1.98, t=-2.78, t=-6.25 and t=-7.86).

Earnings variation is captured through standard deviation of stock return. This coefficient has significant
negative association across all six different types of dividend payments (t=-7.24, t=-2.46, t=-2.73, t=-2.47, t=-
6.70 and t=-12.36). This result is consistent with the argument of firms facing high levels of earnings volatility
are likely to pay low dividends (Asquith and Mullins (1983); Miller and Rock (1985) and Brav et al. (2005)).
This result is also consistent with recent findings of Glen et al. (1995), and Baker et al. (2001) among others. A
negative significant relationship of stock return variation with off-market and on-market share repurchase type of
dividend payments implying that when a firms market performance becomes volatile, there will be a significant
reduction in share repurchase activities.

A strong positive relationship is observed with size variable and most of the dividend payment methods (t=6.20,
t=3.37, t=-4.16, 6.93 and t=8.40) except special cash dividends. This finding supports the arguments that as firms
become larger, they have greater access to capital markets and they can easily able to switch between debt and
equity and take advantage of lower transaction costs which in turn allows for more stable and possibly higher
dividend payments (Lloyd et al. (1985); Ali et al. (1993); Vogt (1994)).

Firms age can be a sign of firms maturity. The age coefficient shows a significant positive (t=1.79, t=1.70 and
t=2.46) relationship in explaining off-market share buy back and special cash dividends. This result may suggest
30
that as Australian firms mature, they tend to increase off-market type share repurchase activities and increase
special cash form of dividend payments.

Market to book-value has significant positive relationship (t=2.20) with on-market share repurchase. From
signalling theorys perspective, this may indicate that on-market share repurchase activities have positive
information content. For example, this result may show a supports for the signalling hypothesis argument that
management by repurchasing their own shares, they signal to the market that their shares are undervalued and
they have inside information supporting the higher value of their outstanding shares.

Overall, the significance of the regression model appears moderately significant (eg., the adjusted R-square
ranging between 25% to 35%) across various types of dividend payments. Also, the estimated coefficients
discussed above are obtained after controlling for time and industry effects.
Table 6
Dividend payment determinants across various dividend payout measurements and impact of multinationality
Following model is used to achieve the results:
*
, 0 1 2 , 1 3 , 1 4 , 1
5 , 1 6

- 2
i t i t i t i t
i t
DIV Multinationality Political risk Foreign Exchange risk Geographical diversification
Industrial diversification digit Industrial diversificati
| | | | |
| |

= + + + +
+ +
, 1 7 , 1
8 , 1 9 , 1 10 , 1 11 , 1
12 , 1 13 , 1 14 , 1
- 4


i t i t
i t i t i t i t
i t i t i t
on digit Effective tax rate
Long term debt Cash Collateral value of asset Risk
Profitability Size Age
|
| | | |
| | | |



+
+ + + +
+ + + +
15 , 1 ,
- -
i t i t
Market to book value c

+


Cash
dividend
Off-
market
On-
market
Special
cash
Total
dividend
Net
dividend
Coeff t-stat Coeff t-stat Coeff t-stat Coeff t-stat Coeff t-stat Coeff t-stat
C 0.32 1.61 -0.21 -1.06 -1.30 -1.58 0.00 0.02 0.44 1.95
c
0.48 1.14
MULT -0.07 -1.96
b
-0.03 -0.81 -0.04 -0.86 -0.09 -2.50
b
-0.08 -2.03
b
-0.04 -2.41
b

PR 0.00 2.89
a
0.00 1.04 0.00 1.52 0.00 1.41 0.00 2.35
b
0.00 2.00
b

FX -0.08 -1.98
b
0.01 0.82 -0.04 -1.67
c
-0.01 -1.00 -0.11 -2.36
b
-0.01 -0.72
G_DIVER -0.02 -1.27 0.01 0.65 0.01 0.36 0.05 1.36 -0.01 -0.63 0.00 -0.40
I_2_DIGIT 0.14 0.92 0.11 0.69 1.25 2.04
b
0.17 1.42 0.11 0.65 0.08 0.72
I_4_DIGIT -0.03 -0.25 -0.04 -0.82 -0.08 -1.03 -0.12 -1.80
c
-0.04 -0.35 -0.10 -1.33
ETR 0.00 0.42 0.00 -0.65 0.00 -0.22 0.00 -1.02 0.00 0.33 0.00 0.43
LTD -0.01 -0.22 -0.04 -2.53
b
-0.06 -2.93
a
-0.04 -2.95
a
-0.02 -0.62 0.02 0.89
CASH -0.76 -5.69
a
-0.06 -0.84 -0.24 -2.31
b
-0.32 -2.67
a
-0.86 -6.26
a
-0.57 -8.62
a

CVA -0.41 -5.33
a
-0.10 -1.67
c
-0.17 -1.98
b
-0.17 -2.78
a
-0.52 -6.25
a
-0.32 -7.86
a

RISK -3.30 -7.24
a
-0.75 -2.46
b
-0.75 -2.73
a
-1.00 -2.47
b
-3.37 -6.70
a
-3.08 -12.36
a

PROF 0.00 0.94 0.00 1.46 0.00 0.97 0.00 0.71 0.00 0.58 0.00 1.92
c

SIZE 0.07 6.20
a
0.05 3.37
a
0.06 4.16
a
0.01 1.15 0.08 6.93
a
0.05 8.40
a

AGE 0.03 1.62 0.02 1.70
c
0.01 0.56 0.04 2.46
b
0.01 0.40 0.01 0.76
MB 0.00 -0.51 0.01 0.84 0.02 2.20
b
0.00 0.60 0.00 0.28 0.01 3.12
a

Industry effect Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Time effect Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
31

Adj R-sqr 0.33 0.29 0.25 0.28 0.34 0.35
No. Of obs 2749 2749 2749 2749 2749 2749
The ordinary least square regression is conducted using full sample of 2749 of which 973 are MCs and the remaining being MCs (1776).
The dependent variable DIV takes six different dividend payment measurements. For example, regular cash dividend is defined as
regular cash to net income; off-market is calculated as the total amount spent on off-market share repurchase in the entire financial year
scaled by on-market is calculated as total amount spent on on-market share buyback for the financial year scaled by net income; and total
dividend is calculated as sum of regular dividends, off-market share repurchase, on-market share repurchase amount for the financial year,
special cash dividends, bonus share plan, special cash dividends and scaled by net income and finally net dividend I calculated as total
dividends minus new equity issue (via dividend reinvestment plans, right issue, public issues or private placements). The independent
variables are: Multinationality - this effect is measured where it takes a value of 1 when a corporation is a multinational otherwise it is 0.
It takes a place of unity (1) if a firm has foreign sales, foreign assets and at least two number countries involvement at any given year,
otherwise it is coded Zero (0) to represent domestic corporations. Political risk is the sum of all the MCs subsidiaries countries political
risk ratings exposed to the proportion of each sale that a subsidiary makes overseas. Foreign exchange risk FX is proxied by regression
coefficient of trade weighted index. The regression is performed on every firms weekly (52 observations per year) against all ordinaries
index and trade weighted index. Geographical diversification is measured as ln(Foreign sales proportion times by total number of
subsidiaries across countries). Industry level diversification is measured as 1 minus the Harfindahl index and this procedure is followed
for both two digit GICS code industry level diversification and four digit GICS codes industry level diversification. Effective tax rate is
measured as tax paid scaled by pretax income. Leverage is measured as the total debt to total debt and market value of equity. Leverage
is measured as the total debt to total debt and market value of equity. Cash is estimated as proportion of cash to total assets. Collateral
value of asset is measured as fixed asset to total assets. Risk is measured as standard deviation of firms stock return over a year using
weekly observations. Profitability is measured as net income over total assets. . Size is calculated as ln(total asset). Firms age is the
natural logarithm of the age of the firm in years from date of incorporation. Market-to-book is sum of market value of
equity and book value of equity scaled by book value of total assets. Mult* indicates slope variables for multinational
corporations for each independent variables. Note: a, b and c represents significance level of 1%, 5% and 10% for two tailed test.


4.2.2 The slope difference of determinant factors that explains the difference of dividend payout
ratios across MCs and DCs

Table 7 is an extension analysis of Table 6. The extension of the analysis is to identify the explanatory factors
that are liable in explaining the difference between MCs and DCs various forms of dividend payments.

The slope difference indicates that the interaction variable of effective tax rate and profitability have significant
negative relationship with regular cash dividend payments (t=-2.47 and -1.92, respectively). The negative
significant interaction slope variable of effective tax rate indicates that Australian MCs shareholders are not in
as good position as DCs shareholders to benefit from the dividend imputation tax credit. The resident
shareholders of Australian MCs are worse off in receiving cash dividends since they miss out in claiming tax
credit on the tax payments made in overseas countries. This result is consistent with the argument that
Australian MCs tax expense payment in the overseas countries cannot be part of the tax credit. As a result an
increase in the proportion of tax to its pre-tax income for MCs provide less benefit to its shareholders and
consequently it leads MCs to pay significantly less dividends to its shareholders in comparison to DCs. This
finding is very important and this supports the true benefit of how the dividend imputation tax system operates.
32
Further, given 97% of the sample MCs subsidiaries are located in classical tax countries, and earning profit
from those countries are less useful to the shareholders because the dividends that are paid out of those profit has
no tax credit components to it. Negative significant effective tax rate and profitability is also observed for
Australian Multinationals in payment of special cash dividend, total dividends and net dividend (t=-1.74 and t=-
1.98; t=-2.52 and t=-1.95; and t=-2.58 and t=-2.37). Further, the finding of this tax implication on dividends is
reliable because all the sample companies incorporated in this study pay fully franked dividends which means
the tax credit argument that has been used to justify results are valid.

The negative significant interaction variable of profitability implies that the Australian MCs receiving higher
profit than DCs has significantly negative impact on regular cash dividends, special cash dividends, total
dividends and net dividends. This finding is consistent with the effective tax rate arguments discussed above.
This result may suggest that from MCs point of view, receiving higher profit from overseas subsidiaries do not
add any additional benefit to attract shareholders because the tax that MCs subsidiaries pay in overseas countries
cannot be claimed as a tax credit by its shareholders. As a result, Australian MCs pay significantly lower
dividends to its shareholders relative to DCs counterparts.

Interestingly, no significant slope difference is found in explaining the variation of off-market share buy back
between MCs and DCs. However, for on-market share repurchase, a number of slope estimates became
significant. For example, geographical diversification (t=-1.98), industrial diversification (t=3.51) and size
(t=2.07). These results indicate that Australian MCs geographical expansions can significantly reduce their on-
market share repurchase activities relative to DCs counterparts. This may imply that Australian MCs find it
costly to involve in on-market share repurchase activities as they become more geographically dispersed relative
to DCs. Industrial diversifications- especially 2 digit level GICS, however, produce an opposite result for
Australian MCs. It shows that Australian MCs benefit in the 2-digit GICS industrial dispersion which assist
them to involve more in on-market type share repurchase activities in comparison to DCs. Also, Australian MCs
are significantly larger than DCs which also aids to increase in on-market share buy back activities. Lastly,
political risk factor explains the difference of MCs and DCs total dividend payments. The positive significant
33
slope estimate of political risk factor (t=2.03) implies that foreign subsidiaries sales earnings coming from safer
foreign countries helps Australian MCs to pay significantly higher total dividend relative to DCs. Finally, the
adjusted R-square across six different measurement of dividend payment shows a plausible fit of the regression
coefficient analysis.
Table 7
Interaction effects in dividend payout decision for Multinational corporations
Following model is used to achieve the results:
*
, 0 1 , 2 , 1 3 , 1 4 , 1
5 , 1 6

- 2
i t i t i t i t i t
i t
DIV Multinationality Political risk Foreign Exchange risk Geographical diversification
Industrial diversification digit Industrial diversific
| | | | |
| |

= + + + +
+ +
, 1 7 , 1
8 , 1 9 , 1 10 , 1 11 , 1
12 , 1 14 , 1 15 ,
- 4

Pr
i t i t
i t i t i t i t
i t i t i t
ation digit Effective tax rate
Long term debt Cash Collateral value of asset Risk
ofitability Size Age
|
| | | |
| | |



+
+ + + +
+ + +
1 16 , 1 17 , , 1
18 , , 1 19 , , 1 20 ,
- - *
* * * - 2
i t i t i t
i t i t i t i t i t
Market to book value Mult Political risk
Mult Foreign Exchange risk Mult Geographical diversification Mult Industrial diversification
| |
| | |


+ +
+ + +
, 1
21 , , 1 22 , , 1 23 , , 1
24 , , 1 25 ,
** - 4 * *
* *
i t
i t i t i t i t i t i t
i t i t i t
digit
Mult Industrial diversification digit Mult Effective tax rate Mult Long term debt
Mult Cash Mult Collateral
| | |
| |

+ + +
+ +
, 1 26 , , 1
27 , , 1 28 , , 1 29 , , 1 30 , , 1 ,
*
* * * * - -
i t i t i t
i t i t i t i t i t i t i t i t i t
value of asset Mult Risk
Mult Profitability Mult Size Mult Age Mult Market to book value
|
| | | | c


+
+ + + + +


Cash
dividend
Off-
market
On-
market
Special
cash
Total
dividend
Net
dividend
Coeff t-stat Coeff t-stat Coeff t-stat Coeff t-stat Coeff t-stat Coeff t-stat
C 0.06 0.18 -0.57 -1.46 0.61 0.77 -0.25 -1.26 0.15 0.40 0.32 1.85
c

MULT 0.27 0.66 0.59 0.72 -4.70 -3.52
a
0.28 0.98 0.27 0.57 0.15 0.65
PR 0.00 2.94
a
0.00 1.88
c
0.00 2.04
b
0.00 2.64
a
0.00 3.41
a
0.00 2.38
b

FX -0.09 -1.14 0.02 0.94 -0.02 -0.69 -0.01 -0.54 -0.10 -1.14 -0.01 -0.18
G_DIVER 0.06 0.72 -0.13 -1.34 0.44 2.02
b
-0.07 -2.15
b
0.08 0.92 0.05 1.46
I_2_DIGIT 0.13 0.56 0.27 1.04 -0.44 -0.60 0.34 1.77
c
0.09 0.32 -0.08 -0.51
I_4_DIGIT 0.04 0.19 -0.10 -1.51 -0.06 -0.80 -0.18 -1.20 0.00 -0.02 0.06 0.58
ETR 0.08 2.40
a
0.01 1.48 0.01 1.20 0.01 1.60 0.09 2.42
b
0.04 2.61
a

LTD 0.01 0.13 -0.04 -1.32 -0.05 -1.25 -0.04 -2.23
b
-0.01 -0.21 0.01 0.27
CASH -0.74 -2.68
a
-0.12 -1.45 -0.37 -1.48 -0.34 -2.57
a
-0.96 -3.70
a
-0.59 -5.61
a

CVA -0.53 -4.50
a
0.00 0.00 -0.27 -1.35 -0.27 -2.02
b
-0.64 -5.10
a
-0.33 -5.56
a

RISK -2.77 -4.44
a
-0.31 -1.13 -0.91 -1.81
c
-0.77 -1.89
c
-2.71 -3.97
a
-2.78 -8.28
a

PROF 0.02 1.93
b
0.00 1.09 0.00 1.61 0.00 1.73
c
0.01 1.95
c
0.00 2.51
b

SIZE 0.08 4.52
a
0.06 2.03
b
0.02 1.14 0.04 3.64
a
0.10 4.83
a
0.05 5.92
a

AGE 0.03 1.17 0.02 1.14 -0.01 -0.47 0.03 1.67
c
0.00 0.10 0.01 0.73
MB 0.00 0.01 0.02 1.78
c
0.01 0.67 0.00 0.30 0.02 1.13 0.02 2.88
a

M*PR 0.00 1.33 0.00 1.04 0.00 0.40 0.00 1.05 0.00 2.03
b
0.00 1.36
M*FX 0.04 0.40 -0.01 -0.47 -0.02 -0.50 0.00 -0.02 -0.01 -0.09 -0.01 -0.18
M*G_DIVER -0.07 -0.94 0.14 1.40 -0.43 -1.98
b
0.12 2.31
c
-0.09 -1.07 -0.06 -1.56
M*I_2_DIGIT 0.07 0.22 -0.36 -0.47 4.27 3.51
a
-0.25 -0.90 0.13 0.33 0.25 1.22
M*I_4_DIGIT -0.14 -0.55 0.12 1.23 -0.06 -0.52 0.07 0.45 -0.09 -0.30 -0.22 -1.58
M*ETR -0.09 -2.47
b
-0.01 -1.60 -0.01 -1.35 -0.02 -1.74
c
-0.09 -2.52
b
-0.04 -2.58
a

M*LTD -0.02 -0.32 -0.01 -0.19 -0.04 -0.82 -0.02 -0.54 -0.02 -0.35 0.01 0.45
M*CASH 0.02 0.05 0.10 0.81 0.20 0.75 0.04 0.20 0.20 0.67 0.03 0.20
M*CVA 0.25 1.54 -0.15 -1.25 0.16 0.77 0.18 1.26 0.23 1.35 0.02 0.27
M*RISK -0.67 -0.72 -0.70 -1.23 0.30 0.53 -0.30 -0.38 -0.83 -0.81 -0.43 -0.87
M*PROF -0.02 -1.92
c
0.00 -0.75 0.00 -1.39 0.00 -1.98
b
-0.01 -1.95
c
0.00 -2.37
b

34
M*SIZE -0.02 -0.81 -0.02 -0.61 0.06 2.07
a
-0.04 -1.61 -0.02 -0.84 -0.01 -0.77
M*AGE -0.02 -0.52 0.00 0.16 0.02 0.67 0.01 0.41 0.00 0.06 -0.01 -0.47
M*MB 0.00 -0.26 -0.02 -1.41 0.01 0.38 0.00 -0.11 -0.02 -1.19 -0.01 -1.17
Industry effect Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Time effect Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

Adj R-sqr 0.19 0.17 0.21 0.12 0.24 0.26
No. Of obs 2749 2749 2749 2749 2749 2749
The ordinary least square regression is conducted using full sample of 2749 of which 973 are MCs and the remaining being DCs (1776).
The dependent variable DIV takes six different dividend payment measurements. For example, regular cash dividend is defined as
regular cash to net income; off-market is calculated as the total amount spent on off-market share repurchase in the entire financial year
scaled by on-market is calculated as total amount spent on on-market share buyback for the financial year scaled by net income; and total
dividend is calculated as sum of regular dividends, off-market share repurchase, on-market share repurchase amount for the financial year,
special cash dividends, bonus share plan, special cash dividends and scaled by net income and finally net dividend I calculated as total
dividends minus new equity issue (via dividend reinvestment plans, right issue, public issues or private placements). The independent
variables are: Multinationality - this effect is measured where it takes a value of 1 when a corporation is a multinational otherwise it is 0.
It takes a place of unity (1) if a firm has foreign sales, foreign assets and at least two number countries involvement at any given year,
otherwise it is coded Zero (0) to represent domestic corporations. Political risk is the sum of all the MCs subsidiaries countries political
risk ratings exposed to the proportion of each sale that a subsidiary makes overseas. Foreign exchange risk FX is proxied by regression
coefficient of trade weighted index. The regression is performed on every firms weekly (52 observations per year) against all ordinaries
index and trade weighted index. Geographical diversification is measured as ln(Foreign sales proportion times by total number of
subsidiaries across countries). Industry level diversification is measured as 1 minus the Harfindahl index and this procedure is followed
for both two digit GICS code industry level diversification and four digit GICS codes industry level diversification. Effective tax rate is
measured as tax paid scaled by pretax income. Leverage is measured as the total debt to total debt and market value of equity. Leverage
is measured as the total debt to total debt and market value of equity. Cash is estimated as proportion of cash to total assets. Collateral
value of asset is measured as fixed asset to total assets. Risk is measured as standard deviation of firms stock return over a year using
weekly observations. Profitability is measured as net income over total assets. Size is calculated as ln(total asset). Firms age is the
natural logarithm of the age of the firm in years from date of incorporation. Market-to-book is sum of market value of equity and book
value of equity scaled by book value of total assets. Mult* indicates slope variables for multinational corporations for each independent
variables. Note: a, b and c represents significance level of 1%, 5% and 10% for two tailed test.


4.2.3 Is there a curvilinear relationship between firms international involvement and dividend payout
ratios?

Table 8 presents results for non-linear relationship across various dividend payments and the international
factors. This non-linear relationship indicates that there is an optimal point where holding more assets in
overseas does not provide any additional benefit to the firms to increase their dividends payments. This could be
due to additional risk exposure relating to firms expansion in overseas countries. Also, over-time the benefit is
reduced due to global integration which minimises the benefit of diversification. To capture this effect, three
additional variables are incorporated in the original model and they are foreign sales ratio, foreign asset ratio
and total subsidiaries and their squared terms accordingly. This result presented in Table 8 and reveals some
insights about Australian firms. Interestingly, firms holding higher proportion of assets, sales and increasing
number of foreign subsidiaries have no significant effect in most modes of dividend payments except special
cash and net dividend payments. Results shows that the increase in proportion of assets holding in foreign
35
countries decreases special cash dividend payment significantly (t=-1.66), however, there is an optimal level
where increase in holding assets in foreign countries will no longer be detrimental instead it would assist
significantly to increase special cash dividend payments. This is evidenced with the positive significant squared
term foreign asset ratio (t=2.00). Interestingly, un-squared terms of foreign sales ratio and total subsidiary
demonstrate significant positive impact on net payment decision (t=2.00 and t=2.16, respectively) while the
squared term foreign sales ratio and total subsidiary squared terms show significant negative relationship with
net dividend payments (t=-2.67 and t=-2.19, respectively). This result implies that as the foreign sales and
number of total subsidiary increase, it significantly raises the net dividend payment up to a point and then it
reduces the net dividend payment of dividends. This relationship is evidenced with the significant negative total
subsidiary squared term.

Table 8
Extent of international involvement and its impact on various dividend payout policies accounting for
multinationality
Following model is used to achieve the results:
*
, 0 1 2 , 1 3 , 1 4 , 1
5 , 1 6

- 2
i t i t i t i t
i t
DIV Multinationality Political risk Foreign Exchange risk Geographical diversification
Industrial diversification digit Industrial diversificati
| | | | |
| |

= + + + +
+ +
, 1 7 , 1
8 , 1 9 , 1 10 , 1 11 , 1 12 , 1
13 , 1 14 , 1
- 4


i t i t
i t i t i t i t i t
i t i t
on digit Effective tax rate
Long term debt Cash Collateral value of asset Risk Profitability
Size Age
|
| | | | |
| |



+
+ + + + +
+ + + +
15 , 1 16 , 1 17 , 1
2 2
18 , 1 19 , 1 20 , 1
2
- -
( ) ( )

i t i t i t
i t i t i t
Market to book value foriegn sales ratio foriegn asset ratio
Total subsidiary foriegn sales ratio foriegn asset ratio
| | |
| | |
|


+ +
+ + +
+
2
1 , 1 ,
( )
i t i t
Total subsidiary c

+



Cash
dividends
Off
market
On
market
Special
cash
Total
dividends
Net
dividends
Coeff t-stat Coeff t-stat Coeff t-stat Coeff t-stat Coeff t-stat Coeff t-stat
C 0.30 1.51 -0.27 -1.31 -1.44 -1.98
b
-0.12 -0.79 0.43 1.90
c
0.48 4.04
a

MULT -0.07 -0.92 -0.03 -0.68 0.00 0.06 -0.02 -0.52 -0.04 -0.56 -0.06 -2.05
b

PR 0.00 3.16
c
0.00 0.88 0.00 1.31 0.00 1.60 0.00 2.61
c
0.00 2.25
b

FX -0.08 -2.03
b
0.02 1.12 -0.04 -1.51 -0.01 -0.63 -0.11 -2.39
c
-0.01 -0.67
G_DIVER 0.01 0.28 0.00 0.01 0.02 0.54 0.05 0.71 0.03 0.59 0.03 0.87
I_2_DIGIT 0.16 0.98 0.11 0.67 1.34 1.98 0.19 1.56 0.12 0.69 0.09 0.87
I_4_DIGIT -0.09 -0.69 -0.04 -0.71 -0.06 -0.74 -0.12 -1.52 -0.11 -0.78 -0.15 -2.00
b

ETR 0.00 0.39 0.00 -0.24 0.00 -0.32 0.00 -0.23 0.00 0.27 0.00 0.44
LTD -0.01 -0.45 -0.06 -3.47
a
-0.08 -3.93
b
-0.06 -3.04
a
-0.04 -1.10 0.01 0.61
CASH -0.77 -5.70
a
-0.04 -0.55 -0.24 -2.09
b
-0.31 -2.83
a
-0.88 -6.27
c
-0.57 -8.52
a

CVA -0.43 -5.58
a
-0.10 -1.48 -0.19 -1.86
c
-0.14 -1.82
c
-0.54 -6.52
c
-0.32 -7.75
a

RISK -3.27 -7.23
a
-0.74 -2.61
a
-0.83 -2.64
a
-1.31 -2.40
b
-3.38 -6.73
c
-3.07 -11.90
a

PROF 0.00 0.78 0.00 1.05 0.00 0.94 0.00 -0.62 0.00 0.34 0.00 1.52
SIZE 0.07 6.34
a
0.05 3.45
a
0.07 4.19
a
0.01 0.79 0.09 6.92 0.05 8.51
a

AGE 0.03 2.04
b
0.02 1.82
c
0.01 0.75 0.04 2.38
b
0.01 0.76 0.00 0.50
36
MB 0.00 -0.40 0.01 0.90 0.02 2.21
b
0.00 0.81 0.00 0.24 0.01 2.99
a

FRGN ASSET -0.10 -0.45 -0.08 -0.43 -0.47 -1.55 -0.50 -1.66
c
-0.25 -0.93 -0.09 -0.79
FRGN SALES 0.05 0.25 -0.30 -1.35 -0.30 -1.22 -0.64 -1.42 -0.15 -0.61 0.11 2.00
b

TOTAL SUB 0.02 0.45 0.04 1.40 0.04 0.75 0.10 1.19 0.03 0.56 0.03 2.16
b

(FRGN ASSET)
2
0.14 0.61 0.03 0.19 0.38 1.54 0.55 2.00
b
0.26 0.97 0.07 0.57
(FRGN SALES)
2
-0.21 -0.91 0.37 1.32 0.34 1.29 0.44 1.28 0.01 0.03 -0.21 -1.67
c

(TOTAL SUB)
2
-0.01 -1.18 0.00 -0.47 0.00 -0.61 -0.01 -0.83 -0.01 -1.32 -0.01 -2.19
b

Industry effect Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Time effect Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

Adj R - sqr 0.24 0.23 0.18 0.22 0.23 0.26
No. of obs 2749 2749 2749 2749 2749 2749
The ordinary least square regression is conducted using full sample of 2749 of which 973 are MCs and the remaining being MCs (1776).
The dependent variable DIV takes six different dividend payment measurements. For example, regular cash dividend is defined as
regular cash to net income; off-market is calculated as the total amount spent on off-market share repurchase in the entire financial year
scaled by on-market is calculated as total amount spent on on-market share buyback for the financial year scaled by net income; and total
dividend is calculated as sum of regular dividends, off-market share repurchase, on-market share repurchase amount for the financial year,
special cash dividends, bonus share plan, special cash dividends and scaled by net income and finally net dividend I calculated as total
dividends minus new equity issue (via dividend reinvestment plans, right issue, public issues or private placements). The independent
variables are: Multinationality - this effect is measured where it takes a value of 1 when a corporation is a multinational otherwise it is 0.
It takes a place of unity (1) if a firm has foreign sales, foreign assets and at least two number countries involvement at any given year,
otherwise it is coded Zero (0) to represent domestic corporations. Political risk is the sum of all the MCs subsidiaries countries political
risk ratings exposed to the proportion of each sale that a subsidiary makes overseas. Foreign exchange risk FX is proxied by regression
coefficient of trade weighted index. The regression is performed on every firms weekly (52 observations per year) against all ordinaries
index and trade weighted index. Geographical diversification is measured as ln(Foreign sales proportion times by total number of
subsidiaries across countries). Industry level diversification is measured as 1 minus the Harfindahl index and this procedure is followed
for both two digit GICS code industry level diversification and four digit GICS codes industry level diversification. Effective tax rate is
measured as tax paid scaled by pretax income. Leverage is measured as the total debt to total debt and market value of equity. Leverage
is measured as the total debt to total debt and market value of equity. Cash is estimated as proportion of cash to total assets. Collateral
value of asset is measured as fixed asset to total assets. Risk is measured as standard deviation of firms stock return over a year using
weekly observations. Profitability is measured as net income over total assets. Size is calculated as ln(total asset). Firms age is the
natural logarithm of the age of the firm in years from date of incorporation. Market-to-book is sum of market value of equity and book
value of equity scaled by book value of total assets. Foreign sales ratio is proportion of assets held in foreign countries to total assets
while foreign sales is the proportion of foreign sales to total sales and total number of subsidiaries is the sum of total number of
subsidiaries in domicile and foreign countries. Squared terms are the taken square of these variables. Note: a, b and c represents
significance level of 1%, 5% and 10% for two tailed test.


4.2.4 Determinants of dividend increase and dividend decrease across DCs and MCs?

Table 9 presents the determinants of dividend increasing behaviour and differentiates if Australian MCs increase
dividends significantly more relative to DCs by employing a logistic regression. Dividends decreasing effect is
not investigated instead dividends increase is tested here only because in the sample a large proportion
(approximately 85%) of the observations in the sample is comprised of dividend increasing activities. Also,
dividend payment increment is examined based on total dividend payments only since it requires substantial
amount of year by year data across various form of dividend payments and for this analysis total dividend met
this requirement. Result shows that the likelihood of Australian MCs in increasing total dividend payment is
significantly higher than DCs (z=3.76) and the significant factors that are significant to explain the probability of
37
dividend payment increase are geographical diversification (z=-1.97), stock return variation (z=-4.64), firms
size (z=1.79) and market-to-book value (z=2.91). Results also suggest that geographical diversification and risk
(stock return volatility) have significant less positive effect in explaining the event of dividend increase while
firms size and market-to-book representing future growth has more magnitude of significant positive impact to
describe probability of dividend increase. To investigate if Australian MCs have any significant difference in
the slope coefficient in explaining the probability of dividend increase, a number of coefficients became
significant. These variables are political risk (z=1.91), cash (z=1.85) and size (z=-1.71). This evidence indicates
that the indication of safer political risk ratings and availability of cash in hand provides much stronger support
for the difference of Australian MCs likelihood of dividend increase behaviour than the negative slope
coefficients of size to explain the difference between MCs and DCs dividend payment.

Table 9
Probit regression of dividend increase and slope difference of DCs and MCs
Following model is used to achieve the results:
, 0 1 , 2 , 1 3 , 1 4 , 1
5 , 1 6

- 2
i t i t i t i t i t
i t
Dividend Increase Multinationality Political risk Foreign Exchange risk Geographical diversification
Industrial diversification digit Industri
| | | | |
| |

= + + + +
+ +
, 1 7 , 1
8 , 1 9 , 1 10 , 1 11 , 1
12 , 1 14 ,
- 4

Pr
i t i t
i t i t i t i t
i t i t
al diversification digit Effective tax rate
Long term debt Cash Collateral value of asset Risk
ofitability Size
|
| | | |
| |

+
+ + + +
+ +
1 15 , 1 16 , 1 17 , , 1
18 , , 1 19 , , 1 20 ,
- - *
* * *
i t i t i t i t
i t i t i t i t i t
Age Market to book value Mult Political risk
Mult Foreign Exchange risk Mult Geographical diversification Mult Industrial diversi
| | |
| | |


+ + +
+ + +
, 1
21 , , 1 22 , , 1 23 , , 1
24 , , 1 25 ,
- 2
* - 4 * *
*
i t
i t i t i t i t i t i t
i t i t i t
fication digit
Mult Industrial diversification digit Mult Effective tax rate Mult Long term debt
Mult Cash Mult
| | |
| |

+ + +
+ +
, 1 26 , , 1
27 , , 1 28 , , 1 29 , , 1 30 , , 1 ,
* *
* * * * - -
i t i t i t
i t i t i t i t i t i t i t i t i t
Collateral value of asset Mult Risk
Mult Profitability Mult Size Mult Age Mult Market to book value
|
| | | | c


+
+ + + + +

Dividends increase Dividends Increase
Coeff z-stat Coeff z-stat
C -0.62 -1.06 -0.93 -1.29
MULT 0.35 3.76
a
0.06 0.70
PR 0.00 0.21 0.01 1.68
c

FX 0.01 0.05 0.02 0.05
G_DIVER -0.05 -1.99
b
-0.10 -0.46
I_2_DIGIT 0.28 0.44 1.05 0.65
I_4_DIGIT 0.39 0.87 0.32 1.89
c

ETR 0.05 0.96 0.12 0.99
LTD -0.02 -0.32 -0.10 -0.60
CASH 0.51 1.19 0.41 0.19
CVA 0.12 0.58 0.05 0.10
RISK -0.03 -4.64
a
-0.22 -1.89
c

PROF 0.01 -1.02 -0.01 -1.63
SIZE 0.05 1.79
c
0.20 2.51
b

AGE 0.04 1.00 0.11 1.09
38
MB 0.06 2.91
a
0.12 2.06
b

M*PR 0.02 1.91
c

M*FX -0.01 -0.02
M*G_DIVER 0.00 0.00
M*I_2_DIGIT -0.26 -1.08
M*I_4_DIGIT -0.41 -1.52
M*ETR 0.07 0.39
M*LTD 0.08 0.35
M*CASH 1.17 1.85
c

M*CVA 0.24 0.36
M*RISK -0.66 -0.03
M*PROF 0.01 1.47
M*SIZE -0.17 -1.71
c

M*AGE -0.10 -0.74
M*MB -0.02 -0.21
R square 0.29 0.30
No. of obs 2245 2245
The Probit regression is conducted using full sample of 2749 of which 973 are MCs and the remaining being MCs (1776). The dependent
variable Dividend increase is identified as 1 in year t if a firm increased total dividends from year t-1 to t, 0 otherwise. The independent
variables are: Multinationality - this effect is measured where it takes a value of 1 when a corporation is a multinational otherwise it is 0.
It takes a place of unity (1) if a firm has foreign sales, foreign assets and at least two number countries involvement at any given year,
otherwise it is coded Zero (0) to represent domestic corporations. Political risk is the sum of all the MCs subsidiaries countries political
risk ratings exposed to the proportion of each sale that a subsidiary makes overseas. Foreign exchange risk FX is proxied by regression
coefficient of trade weighted index. The regression is performed on every firms weekly (52 observations per year) against all ordinaries
index and trade weighted index. Geographical diversification is measured as ln(Foreign sales proportion times by total number of
subsidiaries across countries). Industry level diversification is measured as 1 minus the Harfindahl index and this procedure is followed
for both two digit GICS code industry level diversification and four digit GICS codes industry level diversification. Effective tax rate is
measured as tax paid scaled by pretax income. Leverage is measured as the total debt to total debt and market value of equity. Leverage
is measured as the total debt to total debt and market value of equity. CASH is estimated as proportion of cash to total assets. Collateral
value of asset is measured as fixed asset to total assets. Risk is measured as standard deviation of firms stock return over a year using
weekly observations. Profitability is measured as net income over total assets. . Size is calculated as ln(total asset). Firms age is the
natural logarithm of the age of the firm in years from date of incorporation. Market-to-book is sum of market value of equity and book
value of equity scaled by book value of total assets. Mult* indicates slope variables for multinational corporations for each independent
variables. Note: a, b and c represents significance level of 1%, 5% and 10% for two tailed test.


4.2.5 What determines to pay or not to pay dividends across DCs and MCs?

Table 10 summarises probit regressions that document the effects of the chosen international and firm specific
factors on the likelihood that a firm pays dividends. Results show that Australian MCs are significantly less
likely to pay regular cash dividends, total dividends and net dividends relative to their domestic counterparts
DCs (z=-3.12, z=-4.42 and z=-3.35). Interestingly, multinationality does not appear to be significant in
explaining the likelihood of paying Off-market share repurchase and on-market share repurchase types of
dividends regressions.

The regression results (without slope difference) show that high ratings of political risk (indication of country
being safe to operate in) (z=3.83), geographical diversification (z=3.08) and industry diversification (especially
39
firms falls under the 2 digit GICS codes category) (z=2.04), larger firm size (z=11.10), firms maturity (z=5.51),
firms being profitable and firms experiencing high future growth (z=2.05) are more likely to pay total dividends.
These findings are consistent with Fama and French (1999 and 2001). In contrast, firms that have high level of
cash in hand, more collateral value of assets in hand and have high stock return variation are less likely to pay
total dividends and these evidence is supported by high statistical negative test statistics (z=-8.40, -8.03 and -
3.34 respectively). All these results are consistent with pecking order argument in which firms are reluctant to
issue risky securities because of asymmetric information problems (Myers and Majluf, (1984); Myers (1984)) or
simply because higher transaction costs. Greater asymmetric information problems and higher costs when
issuing securities can also explain why small firms are less likely to pay dividends.

Table 10 also reports results of determinants that explain the slope difference of MCs and DCs likeliness of
dividend payment behaviour. Interestingly, slope difference coefficients to explain Australian MCs likelihood
of regular cash dividend payments cannot be explained with any suggested explanatory factors. However, the
existence of less likelihood of Australian MCs payment of total dividend payments and net dividend payments in
comparison to DCs is explained by too much exposure of facing foreign exchange risk (z=-2.75 and z=-2.25)
and inconvenience of not being able to claim tax credit benefit (z=-1.91 an z=-2.75). The interaction variables
capture this effect and the results indicate that Australian MCs are less likely to make dividend payment decision
(relative to its counter part DCs) due to fear of too much exchange rate exposure and MCs paying taxes on their
income in majority of the non-imputation countries becomes costly to make total and net dividend payment
decisions. Lastly, we conduct a range of robustness tests and the initial results are found insensitive.
26

26
The proposed model has also been applied using all the suggested independent variables on a contemporaneous basis and the results are
almost 95% similar to the lag presented results. Also, it is worth noting that it hardly makes any difference in the Adjusted R
2
and the
individual coefficient when dependent variable is scaled by total asset and earnings before interest depreciation and amortisation. Further,
some alternative measurements have also been tested in the original regression and results remain insensitive.

40
Table 10
Probit regressions to explain which DCs and MCs pay dividends
Following model is used to achieve the results:
, 0 1 , 2 , 1 3 , 1 4 , 1
5 , 1 6

- 2
i t i t i t i t i t
i t
D i v i d e n d P a y e r M u l t i n a t i o n a l i t y P o l i t i c a l r i s k F o r e i g n E x c h a n g e r i s k G e o g r a p h i c a l d i v e r s i f i c a t i o n
I n d u s t r i a l d i v e r s i f i c a t i o n d i g i t I n d u s t r i a l
| | | | |
| |

= + + + +
+ +
, 1 7 , 1
8 , 1 9 , 1 1 0 , 1 1 1 , 1
1 2 , 1 1 4 , 1
- 4

P r
i t i t
i t i t i t i t
i t i t
d i v e r s i f i c a t i o n d i g i t E f f e c t i v e t a x r a t e
L o n g t e r m d e b t C a s h C o l l a t e r a l v a l u e o f a s s e t R i s k
o f i t a b i l i t y S i z e
|
| | | |
| |



+
+ + + +
+ + +
1 5 , 1 1 6 , 1 1 7 , , 1
1 8 , , 1 1 9 , , 1 2 0 ,
- - *
* * *
i t i t i t i t
i t i t i t i t i t
A g e M a r k e t t o b o o k v a l u e M u l t P o l i t i c a l r i s k
M u l t F o r e i g n E x c h a n g e r i s k M u l t G e o g r a p h i c a l d i v e r s i f i c a t i o n M u l t I n d u s t r i a l d i v e r s i f i c
| | |
| | |


+ +
+ + +
, 1
2 1 , , 1 2 2 , , 1 2 3 , , 1
2 4 , , 1 2 5 ,
- 2
* * - 4 * *
* *
i t
i t i t i t i t i t i t
i t i t i t
a t i o n d i g i t
M u l t I n d u s t r i a l d i v e r s i f i c a t i o n d i g i t M u l t E f f e c t i v e t a x r a t e M u l t L o n g t e r m d e b t
M u l t C a s h M u l t C
| | |
| |

+ + +
+ +
, 1 2 6 , , 1
2 7 , , 1 2 8 , , 1 2 9 , , 1 3 0 , , 1 ,
*
* * * * - -
i t i t i t
i t i t i t i t i t i t i t i t i t
o l l a t e r a l v a l u e o f a s s e t M u l t R i s k
M u l t P r o f i t a b i l i t y M u l t S i z e M u l t A g e M u l t M a r k e t t o b o o k v a l u e
|
| | | | c


+
+ + + + +


The Probit regression is conducted using full sample of 2749 of which 973 are MCs and the remaining being MCs (1776). The dependent variable Payer is identified as 1 in year t if a firm pays dividends, 0
otherwise. The independent variables are: Multinationality - this effect is measured where it takes a value of 1 when a corporation is a multinational otherwise it is 0. It takes a place of unity (1) if a firm has
foreign sales, foreign assets and at least two number countries involvement at any given year, otherwise it is coded Zero (0) to represent domestic corporations. Political risk is the sum of all the MCs
subsidiaries countries political risk ratings exposed to the proportion of each sale that a subsidiary makes overseas. Foreign exchange risk FX is proxied by regression coefficient of trade weighted index. The
regression is performed on every firms weekly (52 observations per year) against all ordinaries index and trade weighted index. Geographical diversification is measured as ln(Foreign sales proportion times
by total number of subsidiaries across countries). Industry level diversification is measured as 1 minus the Harfindahl index and this procedure is followed for both two digit GICS code industry level
diversification and four digit GICS codes industry level diversification. Effective tax rate is measured as tax paid scaled by pretax income. Leverage is measured as the total debt to total debt and market value
of equity. Leverage is measured as the total debt to total debt and market value of equity. Cash is estimated as proportion of cash to total assets. Collateral value of asset is measured as fixed asset to total
assets. Risk is measured as standard deviation of firms stock return over a year using weekly observations. Profitability is measured as net income over total assets. Size is calculated as ln(total asset).
Firms age is the natural logarithm of the age of the firm in years from date of incorporation. Market-to-book is sum of market value of equity and book value of equity scaled by book
value of total assets. Mult* indicates slope variables for multinational corporations for each independent variables. Note: a, b and c represents significance level of 1%, 5% and 10% for two tailed test.















41
Cash
Dividends
Off Market
Dividends
On Market
Dividends
Special
Dividends
Total
Dividends
Net
Dividends

Coeff z-stat Coeff z-stat Coeff z-stat Coeff z-stat Coeff z-stat Coeff z-stat Coeff z-stat Coeff z-stat Coeff z-stat Coeff z-stat Coeff z-stat Coeff z-stat
C 0.03 0.30 -0.19 -0.98 -0.081 -1.11 -0.04 -1.28 -0.73 -1.76
c
-0.44 -2.23
b
-0.11 -1.01 0.36 1.62 -0.20 -1.37 -0.84 -1.75
b
-0.23 -1.70
c
-0.07 -1.13
MULT -0.47 -3.12
a
2.10 1.02 0.06 0.19 -0.39 -1.08 0.02 0.04 3.96 0.84 -0.45 -1.58 -0.31 -1.13 -0.83 -4.42
b
1.70 0.73 -0.62 -3.35
a
2.12 0.86
PR 0.01 2.33
b
0.02 2.61
b
0.00 0.29 0.00 -0.06 0.01 0.65 0.00 0.03 -0.01 -0.78 0.00 0.13 0.02 3.83
a
0.02 3.16
a
0.01 2.94
a
0.01 2.00
b

FX -0.20 -1.11 -0.07 -0.21 -0.14 -0.28 -0.51 -0.73 -0.02 -0.04 0.44 0.40 -0.59 -1.64 -0.02 -1.32 0.14 0.62 0.38 0.99 0.05 0.22 0.12 0.37
G_DIVER 0.03 0.48 0.99 1.40 0.11 1.45 0.46 1.42 0.19 1.67 0.19 0.68 0.00 0.05 -0.03 -3.02
a
0.26 3.08
a
2.00 1.51 0.14 1.65
c
1.07 1.17
I_2_DIGIT 0.36 0.31 1.26 0.61 1.42 1.23 1.00 0.29 -1.39 -2.92
a
-0.80 -0.31 -3.55 -1.51 -0.39 -1.73
c
2.97 2.04
b
5.14 3.27
a
3.01 2.30
a
4.64 2.87
b

I_4_DIGIT -0.24 -0.33 0.11 0.07 0.31 0.13 1.81 0.54 0.76 2.08
b
0.24 0.08 2.60 1.10 0.01 0.15 -0.79 -1.04 -0.91 -0.93 -1.18 -1.91
b
-0.74 -0.81
ETR 0.01 0.32 -0.02 -0.18 -0.06 -0.93 0.15 0.97 -0.02 -0.49 0.29 1.10 0.02 0.99 0.01 1.49 -0.01 -0.49 0.11 0.75 -0.01 -0.59 0.08 0.58
LTD -0.35 -2.60
a
-0.33 -1.42 -0.22 -0.35 0.46 1.16 0.00 0.00 0.46 0.97 -0.24 -0.31 0.02 0.89 -0.18 -1.35 -0.20 -1.02 -0.05 -0.32 -0.22 -0.99
CASH -3.69 -6.73
a
-3.92 -4.62
a
0.59 0.48 0.08 1.11 -0.44 -0.18 -6.96 -0.64 -0.28 -0.23 0.02 0.30 -5.75 -8.40
a
-2.10 -5.66
a
-2.08 -8.06
a
-5.18 -5.13
a

CVA -2.56 -6.99
a
-2.94 -4.85
a
-0.88 -1.29 -0.28 -0.30 -0.45 -0.42 3.21 0.84 -2.10 -3.05
a
-0.07 -1.73
c
-3.71 -8.03
a
-4.09 -5.00
a
-3.32 -7.44
a
-3.58 -4.54
a

RISK -3.42 -11.75
a
-3.07 -7.29
a
-2.20 -3.44
a
-1.24 -1.76
c
-1.13 -1.96
c
-2.52 -1.23 -1.85 -1.33 -0.25 -1.37 -3.82 -3.34a -1.53 -6.26
a
-3.07 -1.14
a
-3.08 -7.33
a

PROF 0.00 -0.09 0.11 1.00 0.00 -2.57
b
0.00 -1.24 0.00 -1.66
c
-0.01 -1.20 0.00 -2.92
a
0.00 -1.53 0.00 2.39
b
0.01 1.06 0.00 1.13 0.01 1.04
SIZE 0.42 7.64
a
0.44 4.90
a
0.26 2.80
a
0.10 0.53 0.40 2.69
b
0.46 1.40 0.20 2.09
b
0.00 0.37 0.78 11.10
a
0.72 6.72
a
0.63 8.38
a
0.64 5.70
a

AGE 0.37 5.22
a
0.36 2.84
a
0.11 0.85 0.13 0.62 -0.24 -1.49 0.10 0.29 0.49 3.49
a
0.02 2.70
b
0.47 5.51
a
0.50 3.59
a
0.50 6.07
a
0.52 3.56
a

MB 0.14 3.61
a
0.14 2.45
b
0.08 1.19 0.20 1.93
c
-0.01 -0.07 -0.03 -0.12 0.15 1.89
c
0.01 2.11
b
0.09 2.05
b
0.07 1.05 0.14 3.30
a
0.13 2.01
b

M*PR -0.01 -1.32 0.00 0.23 0.01 0.41 0.00 -0.83 -0.01 -0.64 0.00 -0.03
M*FX -0.15 -0.36 0.56 0.57 -0.56 -0.43 0.01 0.60 -0.35 -2.75
a
-0.10 -2.25
b

M*G_DIVER -0.99 -1.39 -0.35 -1.04 0.03 0.09 0.02 2.57
b
-1.78 -1.34 -0.93 -1.02
M*I_2_DIGIT -1.21 -0.51 0.72 1.30 -0.07 -1.65
c
0.27 0.91 -3.77 -1.64 -2.52 -1.08
M*I_4_DIGIT -0.39 -0.21 -2.70 -0.64 0.80 1.74
c
0.07 0.62 0.53 0.36 -0.58 -0.48
M*ETR 0.03 0.25 -0.23 -1.29 -0.39 -1.36 -0.01 -1.45 -0.13 -1.91
c
-0.11 -2.75
b

M*LTD -0.04 -0.16 -1.96 -2.75
a
-1.21 -1.43 -0.05 -1.86
c
0.00 0.01 0.31 0.99
M*CASH 0.40 0.36 -0.52 -1.02 1.72 0.61 -0.05 -0.51 0.54 0.37 0.14 0.10
M*CVA 0.53 0.69 -0.78 -0.59 -1.76 -1.19 0.01 0.19 0.63 0.63 0.49 0.51
M*RISK -1.49 -0.38 -1.46 -0.76 1.05 0.21 0.28 1.12 0.12 0.70 0.53 0.52
M*PROF -0.12 -1.00 0.00 0.75 0.01 1.08 0.00 0.88 -0.01 -0.68 -0.01 -0.67
M*SIZE -0.02 -0.21 0.22 1.01 -0.09 -0.23 0.01 1.17 0.13 0.91 -0.01 -0.10
M*AGE 0.00 -0.02 0.02 0.07 -0.35 -0.89 -0.01 -0.53 -0.08 -0.43 -0.06 -0.34
M*MB 0.01 0.09 -0.24 -1.88
a
-0.02 -0.08 -0.01 -1.57 0.03 0.28 0.01 0.09
Industry effect Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Time effect Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
R-square 0.32 0.33 0.29 0.30 0.31 0.31 0.28 0.29 0.26 0.27 0.29 0.30
No. of obs 2749 2749 2749 2749 2749 2749 2749 2749 2749 2749 2749 2749
5. Conclusion

We demonstrate that international factors, for example multinationality, geographical diversification, political
risk and foreign exchange risks are essential to incorporate in determining dividend payout ratios. Particularly it
is evidenced that Australian MCs pay significantly less regular cash dividends, special dividends, total dividends
and net dividends relative to their counterpart DCs. After controlling for the multinationality effect, the political
risk factor is found to be extremely important in explaining regular cash dividends, total dividends and net
dividend payments. This result implies that firms tend to increase dividend payments when earnings are received
from safe overseas subsidiary countries. Foreign risk exposure is also found significant in explaining regular
cash dividends, on-market share repurchase and total dividends. This outcome indicates that Australian firms
operations are affected imperfectly by exchange rate movements which in turn shock profit figures and lead to
pay less dividend payouts. The other most common determining factors that are statistically significant in
explaining various forms of dividends payments are cash in hand, collateral value of assets, risks and size.
These results support dividend related agency cost theory of dividend payments.

The determinants that explain the slope difference in MCs and DCs across various dividend payout modes are
political risk, geographical diversification, 2-digit industry code diversification, effective tax rates, profitability
and size. Among, these variables, effective tax rates and profitability are two main dominant factors which
became consistently significant in explaining the difference of Australian MCs paying less dividends than their
domestic counterparts. The negative significant interaction slope variable of effective tax rates indicates that
Australian MCs shareholders are not in as good a position as DCs shareholders to utilise the benefit from the
dividend imputation tax credit. The resident shareholders of Australian MCs become inferior in receiving
dividends since they miss out in claiming tax credit on the tax payments made in overseas countries. This result
is consistent with the argument that Australian MCs tax expense payment in the overseas countries cannot be
part of the tax credit.

The negative significant interaction variable of profitability suggests that the Australian MCs receiving higher
profits than DCs has a significantly negative impact on regular cash dividends, special cash dividends, total
43
dividends and net dividends. This finding is consistent with the effective tax rate arguments. This result
indicates that receiving higher profits from overseas subsidiaries does not add any additional benefit to attract
shareholders because the tax that MCs subsidiaries pay in overseas countries cannot be claimed as a tax credit by
its resident shareholders. As a result, Australian MCs pay significantly lower dividends to their shareholders
relative to their DCs counterparts.

A further investigation of the degree of Australian firms foreign involvement on various forms of dividend
payments shows that holding assets in foreign countries and geographical expansion matters in determining
special cash dividends and net dividends only. In dividend increasing activities, Australian MCs are
comparatively more active than DCs and the factors motivating the likelihood of MCs increasing dividend
payments are political risk, cash in hand and firm size. Lastly, it is found that Australian MCs are significantly
less likely to be a dividend payer relative to DCs especially in paying regular cash dividends, total dividend and
net dividends. This could be due to the tax and profitability arguments discussed above which argues that
dividend payment is more costly for Australian MCs since the majority of its subsidiaries are located under a
classical tax regime and Australian Tax law does not permit MCs to offer their shareholders the tax credit on
dividends that are distributed from after-tax foreign income. As a result Australian MCs are relatively
disadvantaged as opposed to DCs whose income is predominantly from Australia under an imputation tax
system.
Appendix of A. Variable definitions

Dependent variables

:

i,t
i,t
i,t
Regular cash dividends
1. Cash dividends
Net Income


2. - :
i,t
i,t
i,t
Off market share repurchase
Off Market
Net Income



3. - :
i,t
i,t
i,t
On market share repurchase
On Market
Net Income


4. :
i,t
i,t
i,t
Special Cash Dividends
Special Cash
Net Income


:
i,t i,t i,t i,t
i,t i,t
i,t
i,t
Regular cash div ,regular script div ,bonus share plan ,special cash div ,
special script div ,off - market and on market share repurchase
5. Total Dividends
Net Income
| |
|

\ .


6.
:
i,t
i,t
Total Dividends - Newequity issues (via dividend reinvestment plans, right issues, public issues or private placements)
Net Dividends
Net Income

Independent variables
1. Multinationality:
1 ,

0 .
M u l t i n a t i o n a l c o r p o r a t i o n i f a c o r p o r a t i o n h a s f o r e i g n s a l e s
f o r e i g n a s s e t s a n d a t l e a s t t w o n u m b e r s o f c o u n t r i e s i n t i m e t ; a n d
D o m e s t i c c o r p o r a t i o n o t h e r w i s e
=
=

2. Political Risk:

e
e
e
= =
R i
i c
R i
i c i
R i
i c i c
I
I
P
,
,
,


where: C is the sample of companies;
R is the set of different countries from which the companies in the sample operate;
I
c,r
be the sales revenue of company c coming from a particular country, r;

i
denotes political risk rating for a given country in a given year; and
P
c,r
is the proportion of sales from a particular country relative to the total sales of company c:

e
=
R i
i c
r c
r c
I
I
P
,
,
,

3. Foreign Exchange Risk:
0 1 2 it mt xt it
R R TWI | | | c = + + +
Where:
it
R = continuously compounded return on firm ith corporations on week t;
45

0
| = regression constant;

xt
TWI
27
= continuously compounded return for Reserve Bank of Australias trade weighted index
(TWI) measured as the dollar price of the foreign currency and
2
| , the slope coefficient of the
regression is the exchange rate exposure;
mt
R = continuously compounded return on the market portfolio (Australian All Ordinary Index)
on week t;

it
c = random error term.
4. Diversification:
a. Product diversification:
2
10
1
2
22
1
2 _ 1- ( 10, 2- )
: ' 2- .
4 _ 1- (
i i
i
j
j
PROD CC s There are a total of digit industries in GICS
where s is the proportion of a firm s sales in each digit GICS industry i
PROD CC s The
=
=
=
=

22, 4- )
: ' 4- .
j
re are a total of digit industries in GICS
where s is the proportion of a firm s sales in each digit GICS industry j

a. International diversification:
,
,
,

*

i t
i t
i t
Foreign Sales
ln Total numbers of subsidiaries
Total Sales
| |
|
|
\ .

5. Effective Tax:
,
,


i t
i t
Tax Paid
Pre Tax Income

6. :
i,t
i,t
Cash
Cash
Total Assets

7.

:
i,t
i,t
Fixed Assets
Colletral value of assets
Total Assets

8.
i,t
RISK Standard deviation of weekly stock return =
,
,

:
i t
i t
Total Debt
Long term debt
Market Value of Equity

9.
,
,


i t
i t
Net Income
Profitability :
Capital Expenditure

10. : ln( ) SIZE Total Assets
11. AGE
i,t
= ln (age of firm i, in years from date of incorporation)

27
The trade weighted exchange rate is derived from the Datastream computed by Reserve Bank of Australia. The
Bank has revised the weights used for currencies in the trade-weighted index (TWI) for the Australian dollar, to allow
for changes in the country mix of Australia's trade during 1998/99. The revisions take effect from 1 October 1999. The
composition of the TWI is determined by Australia's two-way trade with its major trading partners. Currencies
sufficient to account for at least 90 per cent of aggregate trade are included.
http://www.rba.gov.au/MediaReleases/1999/mr_99_09.html

46
12.
, ,
,
,
- - :

i t i t
i t
i t
Market Value of Equity Book Value of Liabilities
Market to book
Book Value of Total Assets
+

13. Time: In order to capture year effect (e.g. business cycle shocks or economic downturn, tax law changes
and relaxation of share repurchase rules, etc), a dichotomous one and zero variable will be used for each year.
14. Industry: A zero one dummy variable will be used in the proposed models to capture the effect of industry
in both domestic and multinational corporations dividend payout policy.
Reference
Adler M, Dumas B. Exposure to currency risk: Definition and measurement. Financial
Management; 1984 13(2); 41-50.
Akhtar S. The determinants of capital Structure for Australian multinational and domestic
corporations. Australian Journal of Management 2005; 30(2); 1-21.
Akhtar S, Oliver B. Capital structure for Japanese multinational and domestic corporations.
International Review of Finance 2009; 9(1-2); 1-26.
Allen L, Pantzalis C. Valuation of the operating flexibility of multinational corporations. Journal
of International Business Studies 1996; 27; 633653.
Alli KL, Khan AQ, Ramirez GG. Determinants of corporate dividend policy: A factorial analysis.
The Financial Review 1993; 28(4); 523-547.
Asquith P, Mullins DW Jr. The impact of initiating dividend payments on shareholders wealth.
Journal of Business 1983; 77-96.
Bae CS, Noh S. Multinational corporations versus domestic corporations: A comparative study of
R&D investment activities. Journal of Financial Management 2001; 11; 89-104.
Bailey W, Chung YP. Exchange rate fluctuations, political risk and stock returns: Some evidence
from an emerging market. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 1995; 30(4); 541-
561.
Baker HK. Relationship between industry classification and dividend policy. Southern Business
Review 1988; 14; 1-8.
Baker HK, Powell GE. Determinants of corporate dividend policy: A survey of NYSE firms,
financial practice and education 2000; 10(1); 29-40.
Baker HK, Veit ET, Powell GE. Factors influencing dividend policy decisions of Nasdaq firms.
The Financial Review 2001; 38; 19-38.
Barlett CA, Ghoshal S. Managing across borders: The transnationals solution. Harvard Business
School Press, Cambridge, Machaschussets; 1989.
Bartov E, Bodnar GM, Kaul A.1996 Exchange rate variability and the riskiness of U.S.
multinational firms: Evidence from the breakdown of Bretton Woods. Journal of Financial
Economics 1996; 42; 105-132.
Beaver W, Kettler P, Scholes M. The association between market determined and accounting
determined Risk Measures, Accounting Review 1970; 45; 645-682.
Black F, Equilibrium exchange rate hedging. Journal of Finance 1990; 45; 899-907.
Braun M, Larrain B. Finance and the business cycle: International, industry evidence. Journal of
Finance 2005; 60; 1097-1128.
Brav A., Graham JR, Harvey CR, Michaely R. Payout policy in the 21
st
century. Journal of
Financial Economics 2005; 77; 483-527.
Brealey A. and Stewart C. Myers, Principles of Corporate Finance, 5th edition, Irwin-McGraw-
Hill; 1996.
Brown C. The announcement effects of off-market share repurchases in Australia. Australian
Journal of Management 2007; 32(2); 369-386.
Buckley P, Casson M. Models of the multinational enterprise. Journal of International Business
Studies 1998; 29; 21-44.
Burgman TA. An empirical examination of multinational corporate capital structure. Journal of
International Business Studies 1996; 27(3); 553-557.
Berger PG, Ofek E. Diversifications effect on firm value. Journal of Financial Economics 1995;
37; 39-65.
Callen, T, Steven M, Pleban J. Dividends and taxation: A preliminary investigation Economic
Group Reserve Bank of Australia Research Discussion Paper 9211; 1992; 1-26.
Cannavan D, Finn F, Gray S. The value of dividend imputation tax credits in Australia. Journal of
Financial Economics 2004; 73 (1); 167-197.
48
Chkir IE, Cosset JC. Diversification strategy and capital structure of multinational corporations.
Journal of Multinational Financial Management 2001; 11; 17-37.
Cornell B, Shapiro AC. Corporate stakeholders and corporate finance. Financial Management
1987; 16(1); 5-14.
Kogut B, Zander U. Knowledge of the firm and the evolutionary theory of the multinational
corporation. Journal of International Business Studies 1993; 24; 625-645.
DeAngelo H, DeAngelo L. Dividend policy and financial distress: An empirical investigation of
troubled NYSE firms. Journal of Finance 1990; 45, 1415-1431.
DeAngelo H, Masulis RW. Leverage and dividend irrelevancy under corporate and personal
taxation. Journal of Finance 1980; 35(2); 453-464.
DeAngelo H, DeAngelo L. The irrelevance of the MM dividend irrelevance theorem. Journal of
Financial Economics 2006; 79; 293-315.
Dempsey SJ, Laber G, Rozeff MS. Dividend policies in practice: Is there an industry effect?.
Quarterly Journal of Business and Economics 1993; 32; 3-13
Easterbrook FH. The agency - Cost explanations of dividends. American Economic Review 1984;
74; 650-709.
Errunza VR, Senbet LW. International corporate diversification, market valuation, and size-
adjusted evidence. Journal of Finance 1984; 39(3); 727-743.
Eun CS, Resnick BG. Exchange rate uncertainty, forward contracts, and international portfolio
selection. Journal of Finance 1988; 43; 197-215.
Eun CS, Kolodny R, and Resnick BG. U.S.-based international mutual funds: A performance
evaluation. The Journal of Portfolio Management 1991; Spring; 88-94.
Fama EF, French KR. Disappearing dividends: Changing firm characteristics or lower propensity
pay?. Journal of Financial Economics 2001; 60(1); 3-43.
Fama EF, French KR. Testing trade-off and pecking order predictions about dividends and debt.
Review of Financial Studies 2002; 15; 1-33.
Fatemi AM. The effect of international diversification. Journal of Business Research 1988; 16;
17-30.
Gaver JJ, Gaver KM. Additional evidence on the association between the investment opportunity
set and corporate financing, dividends, and compensation policies. Journal of Accounting
and Economics 1993; 16; 125-160.
Geyikdagi YM. The cost of equity capital and risk of 28 U.S. multinational corporations vs. 38
U.S. domestic corporations: 1965-1978. Management International Review 1981; 21; 89-
94.
Glen JD, KarmokoliasY, Miller RR, Shah S. Dividend policy and behavior in emerging markets:
To pay or not to pay. International Financial Corporation Discussion Paper 1995; 26; 322-
354.
Grossman. SJ, Hart OD. Corporate Financial Structure and Managerial Incentives in J. McCall
(ed.): The Economics of Information and Uncertainty, Chicago, University of Chicago
Press. USA; 1982.
Grullon G, Michaely R. Dividends, share repurchases, and the substitution hypothesis. Journal of
Finance 2002; 57 (4); 1649-1684.
Grullon G., Michaely R, Swaminathan B. Are dividend changes a sign of firm maturity?. The
Journal of Business 2002; 75; 387-424.
Hines, JR Jr. Dividends and profits: Some unsubtle foreign influences. Journal of Finance 1996;
51(2); 661-689.
Holder M, Langrehr F, Hexter L. Dividend policy determinants - An investigation of the
influences of stakeholder theory. Financial Management 1998; 27 (3); 73-82.
Homaifar G, Zietz J, Benkato O. Determinants of capital structure in multinational and domestic
corporations. Economia Internazionale 1998; 51(2); 189-210.
49
Hymer SH. The international operations of national firms: A study of foreign direct investment,
MIT Press, Cambridge: Machaschussets; 1976.
Jensen GH, Solberg DP, Zorn TS. Simultaneous determination of insider ownership, debt and
dividend policies. Journal of Financial Quantitative Analysis 1992; 27; 247- 261.
Jensen MC, Meckling WH. Theory of the firm: Managerial behaviour, agency costs and
ownership structure. Journal of Financial Economics 1976; 3; 305-360.
Jensen MC. Agency costs of free cash flow, corporate finance and take-overs. American
Economic Review 1986; 76; 323- 339.
Jodice D. Political risk assessment: An annotated biography, Greenwood Press: Westport; 1995.
Jorion, P., 1990, The Exchange Rate Exposure of Multinationals, Journal of Business 1990; 63;
331-342.
Kalay A.The ex-devidend day behavior of stock prices: A re-examination of the clientele effect,
Journal of Finance 1982; 37; 1059-1131.
Keller 2008,
Kim H, Mei J. Political risk and stock returns: The case of Hong Kong. Working Paper; New
York University Salomon Brothers 1994; 94-130.
Kim WS Lyn EO. Excess market value, the multinational corporation, and the Tobins Q-Ratio,
Journal of International Business Studies 1986; 19(2); 195-217.
Kim CF, Margetis S, Pantzalis C. Financial sector diversification and MNC valuation. Journal of
Multinational Financial Management 2009; 19 (5); 343-354.
Kogut B. Designing global strategies: Profiting from operational flexibility, Sloan Management
Review 1985a; 26; 27-38.
Kogut, B. The Multinational Corporations in 1980s, MIT, Press, Cambridge, Machaschussets;
1985b.
La Porta RF, Lopez-de-Silanes F, Shleifer A, Vishny R. Agency problems and dividend policies
around the world. Journal of Finance 2000; 55(1); 1-33.
Lang HP, Stulz RM. Tobins q, Corporate diversification, and firm performance. Journal of
Political Economy 1994; 12; 1248-1280.
Lease R, John K, Kalay A, Loewenstein U, Sarig OH. Dividend Policy Its impact on firm value.
Harvard Business School Press; 2005.
Lee K, Kwok Y. Multinational corporations vs. domestic corporations: International
environmental factors and determinants of capital structure. Journal of International
Business Studies 1988; 19; 195-217.
Lintner J. The determinant of corporate savings, in savings in the modern economy, ed. W.
Heller (Minneapolis: University of Minnesota Press) 1953; 230-255.
Lintner J. Distribution of Incomes of corporations among dividends, retained earnings, and taxes.
American Economic Review 1956; 46(2); 97-113.
Litzenberger RH, Ramaswamy K. The effect of personal taxes and dividend on capital asset
prices: Theory and empirical evidence. Journal of Financial Economics 1979; 7(2); 163-
195.
Long MS, Malitz IB, Sefcik SE. An empirical examination of dividend policy. Journal of
Financial and Quantitative Analysis 1994; 29; 131-144.
Lloyd WP, Jahera JS Jr., Page DE. Agency costs and dividend payout ratios. Quarterly Journal of
Business and Economics 1985; 24; 19-29.
Mahajan A. Pricing expropriation risk. Financial Management 1990; 19; 77-86.
Michael I. Contagion effects of dividend reduction or omission announcement in the electricity
utility industry. The Financial Review 1979; 35; 121-136.
Michel, A. and Shaked, A., 1986, Multinational Corporations vs. Domestic Corporations
Financial Performance and Characteristics, Journal of International Business Studies 1986;
16; 89-106.
50
Miller MH, Modigliani F. Dividend policy, growth and the valuation of shares. Journal of
Business 1961; 34; 411-33.
Miller MH, Rock K. Dividend policy under asymmetric information. Journal of Finance 1985;
1031-1052.
Morck R, Yeung B.Why investors value multinationality. The Journal of Business 1991; 64; 165-
187.
Morck R. and B. Yeung, Internalization: an event study test, Journal of International Economics
1992; 33; 41-56.
Myers SC. The capital structure puzzle. Journal of Finance 1984; 39; 575-592.
Officer RR. A note on the cost of capital and investment evaluation for companies under the
imputation tax. Accounting and Finance 1988; 28(2); 65-71.
Pantzalis C., Does location matter? An empirical analysis of geographic scope and MNC market
valuation. Journal of International Business Studies 2001; 32; 133-155.
Pattenden K, Twite G. Taxes and dividend policy under alternative tax regimes. Journal of
Corporate Finance 2008; 14; 1-16.
Pettit RR. Dividend announcements, security performance, and capital market efficiency. Journal
of Finance 1972; 27(5); 993-1007.
Reeb M, Sattar AM, Allee JM. Firm internationalization and the cost of debt financing: Evidence
from non-provisional publicly traded debt david abstract. The Journal of Financial and
Quantitative Analysis 2001; 36(3); 395-414.
Richardson SA,Tuna AI, Wysocki PD. Accounting for taste: Board member preferences and
corporate policy choices, MIT Sloan Working Paper No. 4307-03; 2003.
Rozeff M. Growth, beta and agency costs as determinants of dividend payout ratios. Journal of
Financial Research 1982; 5; 249-259.
Schooley D, Barney LD. Using dividend policy and managerial ownership to reduce agency
costs. Journal of Financial Research 1994; 17; 363-373.
Shaked I. Are Multinational corporations safer?. Journal of International Business Studies 1986;
16; 83-106.
Shapiro AC. Financial structure and the cost of capital in the multinational corporation. Journal of
Financial and Quantitative Analysis 1978; 2; 211-266.
Shapiro, A.C., 1990, Modern corporate finance, New York, NY, Macmillan Publishing Co.
Smith CW. Watts R. The investment opportunity set and corporate financing, dividend and
compensation policies. Journal of Financial Economics 1992; 32; 263-292.
Solnik BH. Why not diversify internationally?. Financial Analyst Journal 1974; 30(4); 48-54.
Stultz RM. The Effect of capital structure on a firms liquidation decision. Journal of Financial
Economics 1990; 26; 3-28.
Tallman S, Li JT. Effects of international diversity and product diversity on the performance of
multinational firms. Academy of Management Journal 1996; 39(1); 179-196.
Vogt SC. The cash flow/investment relationship: Evidence from U.S. manufacturing firms.
Financial Management 1994; 23; 3-20.
Wright FW, Madura J, Wiant KJ. The differential effects of agency costs on
multinational corporations, Florida Atlantic University Working Paper; 1997.

You might also like