You are on page 1of 15

No.

354 October 6, 1999

The Community Reinvestment Act


Looking for Discrimination That Isn’t There
by George J. Benston

Executive Summary
Congressional attempts to enact banking to consumers. Researchers using the best avail-
and financial services reform in recent years able data find very little discernible home-
have stumbled over the Community Reinvest- mortgage lending discrimination based on area,
ment Act. That act originally was meant to deal race, sex, or ethnic origin. Furthermore, inter-
with “redlining,” the alleged refusal of banks to state banking; wider branching; and improved
lend to residents of poorer urban, often racial- technology, which has engendered nation-
minority areas. But critics maintain that quali- wide—indeed, global—competition, have meant
fied applicants do not, in fact, suffer unwar- greater availability of mortgage loans. Today
ranted discrimination and that CRA simply there is no indication that qualified borrowers
adds to the costs of banking, in the end often are turned down.
harming the very consumers the act was meant Further, many large banks “cream skim,”
to protect. that is, make loans to the better credit risks in
CRA, enacted in 1977, and its 1975 prede- central cities and to minorities to meet CRA
cessor, the Home Mortgage Disclosure Act, requirements. This practice takes business
were initially intended simply to collect data from smaller, often minority-owned banks
on where banks lend money. However, over the that have traditionally served those communi-
years HMDA and CRA reporting costs have ties and clients.
increased. Further, CRA is used to delay or pre- The Clinton administration wants an even
vent banks’ acquiring or merging with other stricter CRA. But more than two decades of its
banks, closing branches, and the like when no operation suggest that repealing rather than
illegal acts are involved. tightening the act would be the economically
HMDA and CRA have yielded few benefits and socially responsible thing to do.

___________________________________________________________________________________

George J. Benston is the John H. Harland Professor of Finance, Accounting, and Economics, Goizueta Business School,
Emory University, and a member of the Shadow Financial Regulatory Committee.
The Home incur high costs if they found it necessary to
Mortgage A Brief History of the Acts foreclose on defaulting mortgage borrowers.
Lenders applied those stringent criteria to
Disclosure Act of Racial and gender discrimination by conventional (not government-guaranteed)
1975 did not lenders generally has been illegal since 1968, mortgages to weed out borrowers who might
when the Equal Credit Opportunity Act was default.
grow out of a passed. It was followed by the Home Many African-Americans who were able to
desire to prevent Mortgage Disclosure Act of 1975. Although secure FHA-insured mortgages moved into
racial discrimi- often seen as the predecessor of the somewhat more prosperous, often white eth-
Community Reinvestment Act of 1977, nic neighborhoods in Chicago. But sloppy
nation in mort- HMDA did not grow out of a desire to pre- FHA underwriting and fraudulent practices
gage lending. vent racial discrimination in mortgage lend- by some real estate firms often forced those
ing. Ironically, it was enacted in part as a borrowers to overpay for houses that were in
result of the desire of white homeowners, poor condition and that they could not
particularly in Chicago, in the 1970s to keep afford to maintain. The result was aban-
African-Americans from moving into their doned houses and neighborhood deteriora-
neighborhoods.1 tion. That is the source of the pejorative term
To understand this, it is necessary to recall “FHAing a neighborhood.” White residents
that African-Americans who had moved of deteriorating neighborhoods in Chicago
from the rural South to northern cities in the as well as other cities believed that if banks
1940s and 1950s faced housing discrimina- and thrifts were forced to make conventional
tion that confined them to badly maintained loans in their neighborhoods, then only buy-
and overcrowded inner-city neighborhoods. ers who were unlikely to default (people like
But by the 1960s the economic conditions of them) would purchase local property.
many African-Americans had improved, and Residents of other cities experienced similar
they wanted better housing. situations as houses bought by poorer people
In 1968 Martin Luther King was assassi- with almost-no-down-payment FHA-guaran-
nated and riots followed in cities across the teed mortgages were abandoned when the
country. Many concerned policymakers owners could not meet payments or repair
believed that people would not burn down and maintenance costs.
homes if they and their neighbors owned Furthermore, studies by community
them. President Lyndon Johnson instructed activists in the early 1970s revealed that
the Federal Housing Administration to dis- banks and thrifts made many more mort-
criminate in favor of minorities, rather than gages on suburban properties than on hous-
against them as the agency had been doing es in the cities.2 The authors of those studies
since its inception in 1934. The FHA claimed that the lending patterns they found
designed and guaranteed very-low-down-pay- were the result of banks’ and thrifts’ refusing
ment, interest-rate-subsidized mortgages, for to make mortgages or home improvement
which urban properties were eligible. Lenders loans on central-city properties, thereby caus-
were encouraged to and did make those loans ing those areas to deteriorate.
to minorities and poorer people generally. In HMDA, enacted in 1975, was designed to
Chicago, had only conventional loans been make banks’ and thrifts’ mortgage lending
available, relatively few African-Americans practices more transparent, presumably to
could have come up with the required 20 per- pressure or shame them into making more
cent down payment or met the stringent central-city mortgages. The act simply
credit standards for home purchases. Those required lenders to report the number and
strict borrowing criteria were the result of a amount, but not the terms, of mortgages
Depression-era law in Illinois that forced made (and, since 1990, applied for but
lenders to wait about two years or longer and denied) by census tract. Those data were sup-

2
posed to allow banking supervisors and the were not too upset. They were not required to
public to determine the extent to which indi- allocate funds to particular areas of cities or
vidual lenders were serving their communities. to particular borrowers, nor were they forced
But the Indianapolis, Brooklyn, and other to make unsound loans. Rather, banks and
studies on which HMDA was based did not thrifts were simply subject to criticism if they
take account of loans made by mortgage did not appear to adequately serve their mar-
bankers or privately funded mortgages, nei- ket areas, as defined by banking supervisors.
ther of which was covered by the act at that But normally those banks suffered few penal-
time, and both of which were more common ties in the early years of CRA.
in the central cities than in the suburbs. The A bank would face a serious potential
studies also did not consider that differences problem, though, if it had to get approval
in lending might reflect greater demand for from regulators for some change in its status,
mortgages in the suburbs, or other relevant such as merging with or acquiring another
factors. bank. In that case, complaints might be
Supplementing HMDA was the Com- lodged against the bank and regulators
munity Reinvestment Act of 1977. That law might refuse to honor the bank’s request,
was based on an incorrect belief that banks even if the bank previously had received a sat-
and thrifts actually “redlined” communities. isfactory CRA rating. However, at that time,
Like HMDA, CRA
Then-senator William Proxmire (D-Wisc.), restraints on branching and the prohibition was directed only
principal sponsor of CRA, expressed the on interstate banking limited banks’ de- at banks and
accepted view at that time: mands for regulatory approval.
thrifts; other
By redlining . . . I am talking mortgage lenders
about the fact that banks and savings Evidence of Geographic
and loans will take their deposits
were excluded.
from a community and instead of Redlining
reinvesting them in that community,
they will invest them elsewhere, and Academic researchers have studied the
they will actually or figuratively draw redlining allegation and found it wanting.4
a red line on a map around the areas Those studies did not rely on HMDA data
of their city, sometimes the inner alone, because those data did not provide
city, sometimes in older neighbor- information on mortgage terms, borrowers’
hoods, sometimes ethnic and some- financial situations and credit histories, the
times black, but often encompassing supply of mortgages from lenders other
a great area of their neighborhood.3 than banks and thrifts, and, of great impor-
tance, the demand for mortgages in central-
Like HMDA, CRA was directed only at city compared with suburban areas. Indeed,
banks and thrifts; other mortgage lenders many studies did not use the HMDA data
were excluded. (Unlike HMDA, CRA still cov- at all.
ers only banking organizations.) Banks’ lend- Two such studies compared the demand
ing practices with respect to neighborhoods for and supply of home mortgages in four
and poorer people are separately examined by cities—Rochester, New York; Cincinnati,
special supervisory staffs of several federal Ohio; Indianapolis, Indiana; and Nashville,
regulatory agencies, and those evaluations Tennessee.5 My colleagues and I chose those
are made public. From the politician’s point cities because community groups claimed
of view, this is an inexpensive way to address that their central areas were redlined. We
an alleged problem, since it does not require gathered data on mortgages made in the
major expenditures of government funds. allegedly redlined central areas and roughly
At the time CRA was enacted, bankers comparable suburbs of those cities; our data

3
included interest rates, maturities, and down Journal-Constitution published a series in May
payments, as well as house prices and charac- 1988 that was awarded a Pulitzer Prize. A
teristics of properties. We included loans Detroit Free Press series ran in June 1988, and
made by mortgage bankers and other the Washington Post series was published in
lenders. Buyers of homes in the older, central- June 1993. Those articles included maps and
city neighborhoods and buyers of homes in charts showing the racial composition of cen-
suburban areas of the same cities were inter- sus tracts together with the number of mort-
viewed to learn of their mortgage-related gages made by reporting banks and thrifts.
problems. Neither group experienced much Those data, which still did not include loans
difficulty in obtaining the mortgages (FHA made by mortgage bankers and privately
or conventional) they wanted. In particular, funded mortgages, gave the impression that
buyers of suburban homes said they were not banks and thrifts were making fewer loans
kept from buying homes in the central cities than were demanded in predominantly black
because of problems in obtaining mortgages. areas.
We estimated unmet demand for mortgages
by interviewing central-city homeowners
who had tried to sell their houses. Those peo- More Denials of Black Applicants
ple, we reasoned, would know whether or not In 1989 HMDA was amended as part of
potential buyers had problems getting mort- the Financial Institutions Reform, Recovery,
gages, perhaps because of redlining. Almost and Enforcement Act. That amendment
none said that a sale had not been made for required all mortgage lenders, not just banks
that reason (and those few who complained and thrifts but mortgage banks as well, to
said that only blacks could get loans). Nor report the race or ethnic origin, gender, and
did homeowners in the central cities com- annual gross income of loan applicants. A
plain that they were unable to obtain home Federal Reserve Board analysis of those 1990
improvement loans. Other well-structured data, covered widely in the press, revealed
studies also found no evidence of redlining or that African-Americans were more likely than
unwarranted geographic discrimination.6 other racial groups to use Federal Housing
Thus, the claim that lenders redlined or Authority or Veterans Administration loans,
were biased in making loans for the purchase 52 percent compared to 25 percent of white
of homes in central cities is not supported. borrowers.7 Further, two-thirds of lower-
Nor did the studies find that financial insti- income black homebuyers purchased homes
tutions discriminated against actual or in the inner city, compared to two-fifths of
The claim that potential borrowers on the basis of the racial whites. In addition, acceptances of loan
or ethnic composition of neighborhoods. applications were considerably lower in large-
lenders redlined ly minority census tracts, 57 percent com-
or were biased in pared to 76 percent. Press reports especially
making loans for Charges of Racial focused on figures that seemed to show high-
er rates of denials of African-American and
the purchase of Discrimination Hispanic applicants who had about the same
homes in central reported income as whites. Federal Reserve
Renewed concerns that loans were being Board economists tried to explain that the
cities is not denied to potential homeowners, in this HMDA data did not take account of differ-
supported. instance on the basis of race, were themselves ences in the mortgage applicants’ wealth as
based on several factors. A number of news- well as liabilities, employment history, and
papers published exposés beginning in 1988 credit record, among other relevant variables
that analyzed the HMDA data that were read- that lenders should and do consider. But
ily available from the Federal Reserve Board reporters downplayed or ignored those
in computer-readable form. The Atlanta points.

4
In 1992 researchers at the Federal Reserve in loans to minorities have high denial rates. HMDA data did
Bank of Boston attempted to deal with the Those banks are likely to get a large number not take account
limitations of the HMDA data by collecting of marginal applicants and, hence, will have a
information on some 30 variables that they relatively large percentage of denials. On the of differences in
believed were related to lending decisions.8 other hand, a bank that discriminated the mortgage
They found that much, but not all, of the dif- against African-Americans would have had a applicants’
ference between minority and nonminority very low denial rate for those borrowers, if
denial rates was explained by those variables. that bank let realtors know that it would con- wealth as well as
Their finding of an average remaining black sider applications only from financially “very liabilities,
denial rate of 17 percent compared to a well qualified” individuals and that it would
denial rate of 11 percent for whites was wide- “very carefully” scrutinize applications by
employment his-
ly publicized. “certain” individuals. tory, and credit
Subsequently, David Horne, an economist record.
at the Federal Deposit Insurance Corpora-
tion, analyzed the 70 FDIC-supervised banks Defaults by Black Mortgagors
studied by the Boston Fed. As reported in his Data on defaults might seem to be a good
1997 study, Horne found some important way of learning whether lenders discriminate
mistakes in the data.9 For example, 69 appli- against African-Americans. If lenders dis-
cants were recorded as having negative net criminated by accepting only the most credit-
worth (57 of them were approved for mort- worthy black applicants while accepting mar-
gages), and 116 applications were for loans ginally qualified white applicants, whites
that were supposed to have been excluded would default proportionately more than
from the study (e.g., refinancings and invest- blacks. In fact, there are no studies that
ments). He found that including more rele- report this finding, and several that report
vant measures of the borrowers’ credit histo- the contrary.11
ry, such as past delinquencies and whether However, the fact that the available data
the borrower met the lenders’ credit stan- show higher average default rates for black
dards, the lenders’ inability to verify the data than for white mortgagors should not be
submitted by the applicant, and information interpreted as demonstrating that lenders
about the borrowers’ ability to cover closing discriminate against whites, that is, accept
costs, explained the divergence in denial rates only the best-qualified white borrowers but
of black and white applicants. Furthermore, marginally qualified black borrowers. Higher
49 of the 70 banks (70 percent) did not reject default rates for blacks compared to whites
any minority loan applications; 2 of the need not be racially determined any more
remaining 21 banks were responsible for over than a higher rate of denial is racially deter-
half the denials of black applicants. Both of mined. Rather, both statistics could be due to
those banks, one of which was minority other factors that happen to be associated
owned, had conducted extensive minority with the borrowers’ race.
outreach programs and participated actively A 1996 analysis by Robert Avery and col-
in affordable-housing programs. In addition, leagues examined factors related to defaults
Harold Black applied the Boston Fed model on mortgages made through special “afford-
to black- and white-owned banks operating able-housing” programs to low- and moder-
in the same standard metropolitan statistical ate-income households.12 That inquiry
area.10 He found that black applicants were found that the Federal Home Loan Mortgage
denied loans at significantly higher rates by Corporation’s (Freddie Mac’s) “Affordable
the black-owned than by the white-owned Gold” loans, which go to poorer applicants,
banks. had a 60-day delinquency rate that was about
It is neither surprising nor evidence of 50 percent higher than that of a control
racial discrimination that banks specializing group of traditionally underwritten mort-

5
gages with similar loan-to-value ratios and to buy homes in poor neighborhoods should
dates of origination for similar types of prop- be examined: (1) the risks and profitability of
erty in similar regions of the country. The such lending; (2) the effect of CRA and
most important reason for the higher delin- HMDA on loans made to and in presumably
quencies was a shortfall of mortgagors’ funds discriminated-against people and areas; and
to make down payments and other outlays. (3) the effect of this lending on neighbor-
Indeed, Affordable Gold mortgagors who hood revitalization.
were allowed to meet part of the minimum Risks and Profitability. Evidence on the first
down-payment requirement with funds pro- aspect is provided in the Report to Congress on
vided by a third party had delinquency rates Community Development Lending by Depository
four times higher than the control group. In Institutions, submitted by the Board of
those cases loans were made to individuals Governors of the Federal Reserve System.15
with marginal qualifications, exemplified by Section 910 of the Housing and Community
the fact that they could not meet down pay- Development Act of 1992 required this
ment requirements. The mortgagors’ race report to compare “the risks and returns to
was not the relevant factor. insured depository institutions of residential,
Three private mortgage insurance compa- small business, and commercial lending in
There is very lit- nies, Mortgage Guarantee Insurance Corpo- low-income, minority, and distressed neigh-
tle evidence of ration, GE Capital Mortgage Insurance borhoods with the risks and returns of such
racial discrimina- Corporation, and United Guarantee Corp., lending in other communities.” That detailed
also analyzed delinquencies among their report contains a wealth of data comparing
tion by any banks “affordable-housing” mortgagors.13 They profits, defaults, and nonperforming loans
or thrifts also found much higher delinquency rates on according to various personal factors.
loans for which the borrower received much Included are data on race and income, type
of the down payment from the seller or and amount of loan, and type of property
another third party. Further, they found being sold. Overall, the report found no con-
much higher delinquency rates among mort- sistent relationship between risk to lenders
gagors with no or adverse credit histories, and the profitability of loans and the average
higher ratios of debt payments to income income level of the residents of a neighbor-
than the traditional guideline levels, and less hood or a neighborhood’s racial or ethnic
than one or two months of cash reserves at composition. The study also found that
closing. banks that made loans to minorities and on
Recall that, to reanalyze the Boston properties located in distressed areas were
Fed’s data, FDIC researcher David Horne not more profitable than other banks.
used measures of credit risk similar to those These relationships were examined fur-
found to be related to defaults. With those ther in a 1997 study by Federal Reserve
variables included, there was no evidence of Board economists Glenn B. Canner and
racial discrimination. Thus, it appears that Wayne Passmore. They extended and con-
there is reason to doubt that Boston banks firmed their earlier (1995) finding that
denied mortgages to African-Americans banks that made relatively more loans to
because of their race. Indeed, there is very people living in poorer areas and minority
little evidence of racial discrimination by areas were as profitable as banks that did
any banks or thrifts.14 almost no or only a moderate amount of
such lending.16
Thus, it appears that banking organiza-
CRA and Mortgage Lending to tions and other institutions make loans to
Minorities and in Poor Neighborhoods minority and lower-income borrowers for
Three aspects of bank lending (or failure the same reason that businesses in general
to lend) to minorities and people who want serve the public—to generate profits with

6
an acceptable level of risk. Not surprisingly, earlier.18 Those economists took into
then, research finds that banks making account the variables usually associated with
mortgages to minorities and poorer bor- the number of new mortgage loans, such as
rowers are not adversely affected. the number of house sales. Poor neighbor-
Perhaps of greatest importance, the prof- hoods did experience greater growth in mort-
itability/risk findings are inconsistent with gages relative to richer neighborhoods in the
the claim that potential minority borrowers 1990s, but the rates of increase were about
or distressed neighborhoods suffer unfair equal before and after 1992. Approvals of
discrimination. If such discrimination were applications from low-income homebuyers
taking place, banks that served minorities increased more than approvals of applica-
and poor neighborhoods would tend to be tions from the other groups in 1991 and
more profitable and incur less risk. This 1993 but not in the other years through
would be because they could charge higher 1995. New mortgages on homes in poorer
rates and cream skim in those neighbor- neighborhoods grew at rates similar to those
hoods, that is, make only the most profitable, for homes in richer neighborhoods. New
least-risky loans. mortgages for blacks and other minorities
Effect of CRA on Additional Loans. The sec- increased proportionately more than those
ond aspect to consider is whether the CRA for whites in the period 1993 through 1995.
examinations and reports and the newspaper Denial rates for blacks and other minorities
articles using HMDA data actually pressure appear to have declined somewhat over the
or encourage banks to make additional loans 1990s.
to low- and moderate-income homebuyers. Additional evidence is provided in a 1999
Federal Reserve economists studied changes study by Federal Reserve Board researchers of
in home purchase loans made to lower- home-purchase mortgages made by banking
income and minority households and on organizations (banks and thrifts), to which
properties located in lower-income and CRA applies, and other mortgage lenders
minority neighborhoods during 1992–93 (mortgage bankers and credit unions), which
and 1993–97. 17 They found that these mort- are not subjected to CRA but must report
gages increased by a much higher percentage data as required by HMDA. Avery et al. mea-
than did similar loans made to high-income sured home-purchase lending in 1993 and
and white homebuyers. The percentage 1997 in counties that had and did not have
increase was greatest for minority homebuy- branch offices of banks.19 They reported the
ers. For example, between 1993 and 1997, numbers for all, minority, and low-income
Banking organi-
mortgages made to all borrowers increased borrowers and for loans made on properties zations and other
by 30 percent, while mortgages made to in minority and low-income neighborhoods. institutions make
minority borrowers increased by 63 percent. In 1993 and 1997, institutions not subject
However, when the data are examined to and subject to CRA made about the same loans to minority
closely, the possible relationship between percentage of mortgages to lower-income and lower-income
increased CRA enforcement or awareness borrowers and neighborhoods as they did to borrowers for the
and a relatively greater increase in mortgages all borrowers; about 60 percent of those
to low-income black and other minority mortgages were made by banking organiza- same reason that
homebuyers in low-income neighborhoods is tions and 40 percent were made by other businesses in gen-
not clear. Douglas D. Evanoff and Lewis M. institutions. However, lenders not subject to
Segal, economists at the Federal Reserve CRA made a somewhat higher percentage of
eral serve the
Bank of Chicago, examined data through the mortgages obtained by minority borrow- public—to gener-
1995 and found that the growth in mortgage ers and neighborhoods than did banking ate profits with
lending during the early 1990s, when CRA organizations—about 55 percent compared
reporting and enforcement accelerated, was to 45 percent.20 Furthermore, banking orga- an acceptable
not much different from that experienced nizations made a substantial number of level of risk.

7
The profitabili- mortgages in counties in which they did not evidence that banks fail to meet the credit
ty/risk findings have branch offices, an extension that is not needs of low-income neighborhoods per
required (indeed, that might be discouraged) se.”21 Even if there are some lenders who are
are inconsistent by CRA, which encourages banking organiza- racially biased, are not competent to deal
with the claim tions to serve their local communities. In with minorities, or misperceive the risks and
1997 those lenders made about the same misestimate the costs of dealing with people
that potential number of loans to lower-income and minor- who are different from themselves, it is very
minority borrow- ity borrowers and in lower-income and likely that other profit-seeking lenders would
ers or distressed minority neighborhoods in counties where gladly take the business.
they did and did not have branch offices.
neighborhoods Thus, market forces rather than CRA seem to
suffer unfair dis- be driving the provision of mortgages. Extension of CRA
crimination. Neighborhood Revitalization. The evidence
on the first and second aspects of lending by In 1989 the scope of CRA examinations
banks (profitability/risk and mortgages and reports to the public was expanded.
made) bears on the third aspect—the effect of Banks and thrifts were rated by examiners
CRA and HMDA on neighborhood revital- on 12 “assessment factors.” Two factors
ization. Although CRA may (or may not) evaluated how well the institution dealt
have encouraged banks to make mortgage with community groups, three with the
loans to poorer and minority homebuyers, institution’s marketing efforts, two with
there is no evidence, one way or the other, the geographic distribution and record of
that it has fulfilled its mandate to aid com- opening and closing offices, three with
munities. community development, and only two
Perhaps there have been no studies of the with overt discrimination. With the excep-
effect of CRA on neighborhoods because the tion of a few quantitative measures, the
answer is obvious. The market for mortgage evaluations necessarily were subjectively
lending has been very competitive. Stan- determined by the examiners.
dardization of mortgages and the expansion Despite the evidence that banks were
of Freddie Mac and Fannie Mae (originally lending profitably but not overprofitably to
the Federal National Mortgage Association), minorities and in poor and distressed com-
together with and partially driven by munities and despite the absence of any
improvements in technology, have resulted study showing that potential borrowers in
in a national, indeed, an international, mar- those areas were not well served, in 1993
ket for home mortgages. There are no barri- federal banking regulators proposed greatly
ers to the entry of mortgage bankers. In most extended and much more detailed and cost-
communities, potential homebuyers and real ly CRA reporting requirements. If those
estate brokers can place mortgages with requirements had been adopted, banks and
dozens, often hundreds, of lenders. News- thrifts with more than $250 million in
papers carry comparative rates. Information assets would have had to report greater
and applications can be obtained by tele- amounts of data on the number and
phone inquiry, and mortgage bankers often amount of loan applications, denials,
will come to the applicant’s home. Mortgages approvals, and purchases by census tract
also can be made through the Internet. for 10 kinds of loans—those to consumers,
Consequently, it is very likely that all prof- small farms, four sizes of small businesses,
itable demand for mortgages is met. Indeed, and for four types of residential real estate.
in 1996 Federal Reserve of Richmond econo- Smaller banks would have been subject to
mist Jeffrey M. Lacker reviewed much of the somewhat simpler, but still considerable,
evidence on redlining and racial discrimina- reporting requirements. The Shadow
tion. He concluded, “There is little conclusive Financial Regulatory Committee, a private

8
group of academic economists and lawyers nity development banks, other than loans;
who specialize in financial services, re- purchases of securitized mortgages on mul-
viewed and opposed this proposed change. tifamily houses located in low- and moder-
In Statement 105, February 14, 1994, the ate-income areas; and contributions to
SFRC said: community groups. The service measure
reflected primarily the placement of
There is little evidence that CRA branches in low-income communities.
has had an appreciable impact on Although the distribution of loans mea-
credit flows to disadvantaged com- sured by the new tests was somewhat more
munities and persons. Rather, it has quantitative than that measured by the 12
evolved into a costly and ineffective assessment factors used before 1995, the
credit allocation scheme that tends evaluation by examiners was still subjective.
to benefit primarily those vocal spe- The General Accounting Office reviewed the
cial-interest groups capable of new guidelines, found that they presented
extracting concessions from lenders. problems similar to the ones presented by
Past experience has shown credit the previous regulations, and recommended
allocation programs to be expensive that significant efforts be made to improve
to administer, difficult to target, vir- examiner training and the quality of data
In 1993 and 1997,
tually impossible to monitor, and used in evaluating performance.23 institutions not
ineffective in helping targeted bor- CRA reports are supposed to help deter- subject to and
rowers.22 mine the extent to which all banks taken
together make loans to borrowers in low- and subject to CRA
The regulatory agencies partially with- moderate-income areas and to small busi- made about the
drew the proposed change. In May 1995 new nesses. There is no guarantee that such
CRA regulations to be phased in over two potential borrowers receive particular per-
same percentage
years were issued by the federal banking reg- centages of mortgage loans. An analysis of of mortgages to
ulatory agencies. The first data-reporting 1993 HMDA data by Canner and Passmore lower-income
requirements took effect in 1996. CRA exam- shows that relatively few loans are made to or,
inations under the new rules started in July apparently, demanded by individuals in low- borrowers and
1997. The new regulations exempted smaller income areas. Canner and Passmore point neighborhoods as
banks, those with assets under $250 million out that there are likely to be economies of they did to all
that were not affiliates of a $1 billion or larg- scale in serving that market, and they find
er holding company, from the reporting that some banks and thrifts specialize in borrowers.
requirements. Those smaller banks, neverthe- making loans to such potential borrowers.
less, were still subject to CRA requirements, Those banks are as profitable as are other
but with less well-defined factors being mea- banks, which indicates that low-income bor-
sured and, perhaps as a consequence, even rowers and areas are well served.24 Direct
greater exposure to subjectivity on the part of measures of possible unmet demand, in any
examiners. event, cannot be obtained from HMDA data
The 12 assessment factors against which or CRA reports.
banks had been evaluated were replaced
with 3 new tests: lending (the most impor-
tant), investment, and service. Data on Adverse Effects of CRA
loans made to residential homebuyers, as
per the HMDA reports, and loans under $1 CRA has been costly to banks and thrifts,
million made to small businesses and farms both directly and indirectly. A direct cost that
(those with revenues below $1 million) had affects all banks is preparing the required
to be reported by census tract. Investments HMDA and CRA reports. Other direct costs
to be measured include support of commu- include hiring compliance officers, dealing

9
with CRA examiners, and meeting with com- who could benefit from checking, savings,
munity groups. Indirect costs include delay consumer loans, and other banking services
in obtaining regulatory approval for mergers, will be denied the convenience and benefits
acquisitions, and branch changes; legal and of competition by additional institutions.
other costs incurred in replying to com- Third, some borrowers are likely to be
plaints, despite the banks’ having previously harmed by the CRA policy of requiring all
received satisfactory CRA reports; and “pay- banks to be involved in lending to members
ing off” community activists by making of specified groups. A bank might have exper-
unprofitable and loss loans to people and tise in lending to members of some other
groups they favor. group (such as Polish-Americans or Chinese-
Anjan V. Thakor and Jess C. Beltz found Americans) or to companies that happen to
that, in 1992, CRA cost the 445 relatively be owned by persons other than those con-
small banks that they surveyed 4.5 percent of sidered by CRA examiners to be disadvan-
their pretax income and 0.25 percent of their taged. If all banks must show that they seek
total assets, on average.25 They found that to serve a specified group, nonspecified
costs are higher for smaller banks and banks groups are likely to be served less well.
located in more highly populated areas. For
large banks the relative amounts probably are
considerably smaller than the percentages Discovering Lending
reported by Thakor and Beltz.
CRA also has had at least three important Discrimination
adverse effects on borrowers and distressed
neighborhoods. First, it appears that loans Given CRA’s and HMDA’s considerable
made by banks attempting to fulfill CRA cost and few discernible benefits, should
obligations have simply drawn customers those laws be repealed? Because racial dis-
from other lenders who otherwise would crimination has been an unfortunate part of
have served them, although perhaps on less American history, some might argue that it is
beneficial terms to the borrowers. In particu- not enough that minorities as a whole are
lar, minority-owned banks have complained being well served by the banking system as a
that they suffered from having to compete whole. Consequently, policymakers should
with subsidized lending by banks that are ensure that not even one bank is allowed to
willing to make unprofitable loans to obtain discriminate unfairly in lending or that not
regulatory approval of a merger or acquisi- even one individual suffers unfair discrimina-
It is very likely tion. There is reason for concern that future tion. To that end it might be argued that, if
minority borrowers will be poorly served, not for HMDA data and CRA reports, regula-
that all profitable because the banks that previously would tors and the public would not know whether
demand for mort- have served them will have been driven from or not a bank was discriminating unfairly
gages is met. the market and the banks that no longer against some members of certain groups.
need regulatory approval will no longer offer But more effective and less costly proce-
subsidized loans to minorities. dures are now being used by the federal bank-
Second, CRA makes it almost impossible ing agencies. For several years now, bank
for banks to close branches in distressed examiners have been applying statistical
neighborhoods. Although keeping such models to determine the extent to which
branches open might benefit some people, it individual banks might be discriminating
has the unintended adverse effect of discour- unfairly against minority and female mort-
aging other regulated institutions from gage applicants. Using a bank’s mortgage
entering minority neighborhoods and offer- application data, the models take into
ing banking services that might turn out to account the expected relationship between
be unprofitable. Consequently, individuals specified borrower and property characteris-

10
tics and predict whether a loan might be mortgagors. The percentage of minority In 1992 CRA cost
expected to be granted or denied. The Federal and female applicants for mortgages that, 445 relatively
Reserve has used general models, such as that upon detailed examination, appears to have
developed by the Federal Reserve Bank of been denied unfairly should be presented in small banks 4.5
Boston for its 1992 study. 26 The Office of the a report, much as the limited and potential- percent of their
Comptroller of the Currency has employed ly misleading HMDA denial data are now
models that take into account the situation reported.
pretax income
at individual banks. Some evidence, though, may be gleaned and 0.25 percent
Mitchell Stengel and Dennis Glennon, from actions taken by the Department of of their total
economists at the OCC, report that those Justice. The Federal Deposit Insurance
bank-specific models are much more reliable Corporation Improvement Act of 1991 assets, on average.
than general models. Indeed, they find that requires bank regulatory agencies to refer
general models (such as the Boston Fed to DOJ cases in which they have “reason to
model) indicate discrimination against believe” there is or they perceive to be a
minorities, while the OCC’s model, which “pattern or practice” of possibly illegal dis-
takes into account the actual procedures crimination. Of the some 8,000 banks and
used by individual banks, does not.27 thrifts that are examined annually for com-
Whether general or bank-specific models pliance with CRA and the anti-discrimina-
are used, loans that are granted or denied tion statutes, the banking agencies referred
contrary to expectation (as predicted by the 4 in 1992, 13 in 1993, 25 in 1994, and 10 in
model) are examined further to determine if 1995.28 Of those 48 referrals, legal action
the race, ethnicity, or gender of the applicant was taken in 6 cases (4 of which were settled
or borrower played a role. by consent agreements, with complaints
Unfortunately, the federal regulatory filed in 2), 23 were returned to the bank reg-
agencies have not made the data and results ulators for administrative action, and 9
of those examinations available to the pub- were dismissed because no cause was found
lic. From personal inquiries, I have learned or there was insufficient information. In
that they have found very few, if any, addition, on the basis of HMDA data, DOJ
instances in which there are not good busi- independently brought 10 actions, 9 of
ness or other explanations for mortgages which were settled with consent decrees.
not having been made to minorities or Even assuming that the DOJ complaints
women or that were, but should not have were valid, it appears that very few banks
been, made to majority or male applicants. are discriminating unfairly.
Among those explanations are additional In addition, the U.S. Department of
borrower-specific data that were not includ- Housing and Urban Development is charged
ed in the model (such as aspects of the with enforcing the Fair Housing Act and
applicant’s credit record), data corrections other civil rights laws. It makes referrals to
that were misrecorded (but not changed) in the DOJ, makes grants to private organiza-
the application (such as misstated employ- tions to investigate possible FHA viola-
ment and sources and amounts of income tions, and itself investigates complaints.
and sources of down payments), and loans From 1989 through 1995 HUD processed
that were miscoded as ordinary mortgages 2,356 fair lending complaints brought
(applicants were turned down because they against real-estate lenders and companies.
did not qualify for special programs). Of those, 896 cases, or 38 percent, were
However, the federal banking agencies “conciliated,” that is, HUD brokered a deal
should undertake a systematic study of the between bank and borrower. Another 720
examiners’ data. They should report cases, or 31 percent, were dismissed admin-
whether many, only a few, or no banks have istratively, apparently because HUD found
discriminated unfairly against potential them to be without merit. And in 717 cases,

11
or 30 percent, HUD investigated and found interest rate and fees on other loans are put
that no violation had occurred. In only 23 in and the program computes the required
cases, or 1 percent of the total, did HUD monthly payment, down payment, and
find lenders guilty of unfair discrimination. closing costs. If the person cannot qualify
HUD referred only 9 of those 23 cases to for a loan, the program indicates the
DOJ.29 changes that are required, such as improv-
ing the person’s credit standing, finding a
less expensive house, and increasing the
Helping Minority down payment. The program can construct
a budget showing how the person can save
Homebuyers enough for the down payment. Alternative-
ly, the counselor can advise such would-be
The fact that potential borrowers are borrowers that they cannot afford to buy
rarely denied loans because of economically and maintain a house. If the person does
irrelevant characteristics does not imply that qualify, the program completes a loan
the poor or minorities have an equal chance application and forwards it to lenders who
to obtain mortgage loans. Often they are have agreed to accept such applications. If
The Equal Credit inexperienced in the borrowing process. They the lender verifies or accepts the accuracy of
Opportunity Act often do not know whether or not they have the information, a loan is made.
constrains bank the financial assets to buy and maintain a It would be excessively costly for most
home, or what they must do to qualify for a banks to provide this service to many low-
employees’ ability loan. Some bankers have attempted to help income potential homebuyers. One reason
to communicate such borrowers understand the mortgage is that the Equal Credit Opportunity Act
lending process so they can decide whether constrains bank employees’ ability to com-
with potential they can become homeowners. However, the municate with potential borrowers. Bank
borrowers. exercise usually is costly and beyond most employees’ advice on what an applicant
bankers’ experience. Furthermore, many of must do to qualify for a loan triggers a for-
the individuals most in need of help are not mal application with the required docu-
comfortable asking bankers for that help or mentation and disclosures. This paperwork
receiving it from them. is fraught with potential for error, which
Fannie Mae has developed a means of could result in severe regulatory penalties.
helping poorer and inexperienced people get Hence, most banks permit only highly
through the borrowing maze. Its interactive trained employees to accept applications. In
computer program that is made available to addition, bank employees who advise
community counselors “walks” potential minorities not to buy houses or to look for
homeowners through a series of questions less expensive houses might be charged
about the location and price of a house they with discrimination. In either situation, the
want to buy and their ability to qualify for a potential homebuyer, as well as the bank,
mortgage and afford to own the house.30 would not be well served.
Information about the potential home-
owner’s credit record is downloaded from the
files of the principal credit information com- The Case for Repealing
panies, and the counselor puts in the appli-
cant’s salary, savings, and financial obliga- HMDA and CRA
tions. The program determines whether the
person qualifies for various supported lend- The rationale for both HMDA and CRA
ing programs and puts in the applicable is not valid today and probably was not
interest rate and down payment. valid when those laws were enacted.
If such loans cannot be obtained, the Nevertheless, those “disclosure” statutes

12
have been expanded to require ever more in which they bought houses. It is clear that Competition and
detailed and extensive reporting. The agen- competition and just good business sense just good busi-
cies charged with enforcing the statutes have been effective in encouraging most, if
and evaluating those reports have created not all, banks to offer loans to creditworthy ness sense have
bureaucratic structures involving extensive mortgagors without regard to their race, been effective in
costs in agency personnel, reporting costs gender, or other irrelevant personal attrib-
to regulated institutions, and even micro-
encouraging
utes. Thus there is no case for and every
management of financial institutions. case against retaining CRA and HMDA. most, if not all,
HDMA and CRA were predicated on the banks to offer
assumption that the banking and thrift
industry failed to deliver adequate credit Notes loans to credit-
services in some urban neighborhoods and worthy mort-
on the belief that significant improvement 1. George J. Benston, “Mortgage Redlining Re-
search: A Review and Critical Analysis,” Federal gagors without
could result from supervisory pressures. No Reserve Bank of Boston, Conference Series no. 21,
credible evidence has been published October 1979, pp. 144–46.
regard to their
demonstrating the validity of the assumed race, gender, or
credit failure. As scholars have looked deep- 2. Among those studies are “Why Do Neighbor-
er into mortgage lending, they have found
hoods Deteriorate? Red-Lining in Indianapolis,” other irrelevant
Coalition to End Neighborhood Deterioration,
little evidence of unfair discrimination 1975; and “Take the Money and Run! Redlining personal attrib-
against individuals on the basis of race or in Brooklyn,” New York Public Interest Research utes.
gender. Very few of the nation’s more than Group, Inc., 1976. Nine of these studies are
described and critiqued in George J. Benson, Dan
14,000 depositories have even been charged Horsky, and H. Martin Weingartner, An Empirical
with illegal discriminatory practices. Study of Mortgage Redlining, Monograph Series in
Further, the evolution of financial mar- Finance and Economics, no. 1978-5 (New York:
kets over the past 25 years has eroded mate- New York University Graduate School of Business
rially any market monopoly position that Administration, Salomon Brothers Center for the
Study of Financial Institutions, 1978), pp. 4–34.
banks and thrifts might once have enjoyed.
Other providers of credit, such as mortgage 3. Congressional Record, June 6, 1977, S. 8958.
companies, credit unions, and finance com-
4. Notable among these are Richard F. Muth,
panies, continue to increase their share of “Yields on Inner-City Mortgage Loans,” Federal
the market at the expense of banks and Home Loan Bank of San Francisco, 1979; and
thrifts. Indeed, Avery et al. report that the Andrew L. Holmes and Paul Horvitz, “Mortgage
nonbanks made about 38 percent of the Redliing: Race, Risk, and Demand,” Journal of
mortgages in the 1993–97 period (the total Finance 49 (1994): 81–99. Additional articles are
described, critiqued, and referenced in the fol-
does not include lenders who do not report lowing articles: Benston, “Mortgage Redlining
HMDA data).31 In addition, banking dereg- Research,” pp. 144–95; Anthony M. Yezer, ed.,
ulation that allowed interstate banking and Fair Lending Analysis: A Compendium of Essays on
encouraged intrastate branching has creat- the Use of Statistics (Washington: American
Bankers Association, 1995); George J. Benston,
ed even more competition and access to W. Curt Hunter, and George G. Kaufman, eds.,
loans. Lending via the Internet has further Discrimination in Financial Services (Boston:
expanded homebuyers’ access to mortgage Kluwer Academic Publishers, 1997), also pub-
loans. lished as a special double issue of Journal of
Financial Services Research 11 (February–April
HMDA and CRA may have forced some 1997).
banks and thrifts to serve some customers
whom they previously did not serve. It is 5. See Benston, “Mortgage Redlining Research,”
not clear, though, that those customers pp. 144–95; and George J. Benston and Dan
Horsky, “The Relationship between the Demand
would not have been well served by other and Supply of Home Financing and Neighbor-
lenders or that the loans made actually ben- hood Characteristics,” Journal of Financial Services
efited the borrowers or the neighborhoods Research 5 (1992): 72–87.

13
6. See Benston, “Mortgage Redlining Research,” of the other cases, which are described briefly in
for a review and critique of these studies; the U.S. General Accounting Office, “Fair Lending:
papers presented in Yezer for critiques of Federal Oversight and Enforcement Improved
research on redlining that use HMDA and other but Some Challenges Remain,” Report
data; and the papers presented in Benston, GAO/GGD-96-145, August 1996.
Hunter, and Kaufman for recent studies. Also,
for a review of other studies and bibliographic 15. Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve
references, see Douglas D. Evanoff and Lewis M. System, Report to Congress on Community Develop-
Segal, “CRA and Fair Lending Regulations: ment Lending by Depository Institutions (Washing-
Resulting Trends in Mortgage Lending,” Federal ton: Federal Reserve Board, October 1993).
Reserve Bank of Chicago Economic Perspectives,
November–December 1996, pp. 19–46. 16. Glenn B. Canner and Wayne Passmore,
“Home Purchase Lending to Low-Income
7. Glenn B. Canner and Delores S. Smith, “Home Neighborhoods and to Low-Income Borrow-
Mortgage Disclosure Act: Expanded Data on ers,” Federal Reserve Bulletin, February 1995, pp.
Residential Lending,” Federal Reserve Bulletin 77 71–103; and Glenn B. Canner and Wayne
(November 1991): 859–81. Passmore, “The Community Reinvestment Act
and the Profitability of Mortgage-Oriented
8. Alicia H. Munnell et al., “Mortgage Lending in Banks,” Federal Reserve Board Finance and
Boston: Interpreting HMDA Data,” American Economics Discussion Series, no. 7, 1997.
Economic Review 86 (March 1996): 25–53.
17. Avery et al., “Credit Risk, Credit Scoring, and
9. David K. Horne, “Mortgage Lending, Race, and the Performance of Home Mortgages,” Table 8;
Model Specification,” Journal of Financial Services and Robert B. Avery et al., “Trends in Home
Research 11, nos. 1–2 (1997): 43–68. Purchase Lending: Consolidation and the Com-
munity Investment Act,” Federal Reserve Bulletin,
10. Harold Black, “Discrimination in Financial February 1999, pp. 81–102 and Table 4, p. 92.
Services,” Journal of Financial Services Research 11,
nos. 1–2 (1997): 189–204. 18. Evanoff and Segal.

11. James A. Berkovic et al., “Mortgage Discrimi- 19. Avery et al., “Trends in Home Purchase
nation and FHA Loan Performance,” Cityscape: A Lending.” The research examined the hypothe-
Journal of Policy Development and Research 2 sis that bank consolidations (which were exten-
(1992): 9–24. sive during these years and which resulted in
branch office closings) reduced the number of
12. Robert B. Avery et al., “Credit Risk, Credit mortgages made to minorities and lower-
Scoring, and the Performance of Home Mortgages,” income homebuyers. The paper concludes that
Federal Reserve Bulletin, July 1996, pp. 621–48. this did not occur.
13. Ibid., pp. 644–45. 20. Derived from ibid., Table 4.
14. Through 1995 the Department of Justice had 21. Jeffrey M. Lacker, “Neighborhoods and
issued 10 complaints against financial institu- Banking,” Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond
tions for alleged violations of the Fair Lending Economic Quarterly (Spring 1995): 14.
Acts. In all but one of those, DOJ obtained con-
sent decrees with the accused institution. None 22. Shadow Financial Regulatory Committee,
has gone to court. In particular, Decatur Federal “Proposed Revisions to Community Reinvest-
(Georgia) was charged with discrimination on the ment Regulations,” Statement 105, February
basis of the findings from a statistical model, sim- 14, 1994, Journal of Financial Services Research 8
ilar to that used by the Boston Fed. That analysis, (1994): 233–34.
however, is subject to the same shortcomings as
the Boston Fed’s analysis; in addition, the DOJ 23. U.S. General Accounting Office, Community
misused the model. See Harold A. Black, “HMDA Reinvestment Act: Challenges Remain to Successfully
Data and Regulatory Inquiries Regarding Implement CRA (Washington: Government
Discrimination,” and Andrew L. Sandler and Printing Office, 1995).
Jonathan Biran, “The Improper Use of Statistics
in Mortgage Lending Discrimination Actions,” in 24. Canner and Passmore, “The Community
Yezer, pp. 147–62. The action brought against Reinvestment Act and the Profitability of
Chevy Chase (Maryland) alleged only that the Mortgage-Oriented Banks.”
bank did not open offices in predominantly
African-American areas. I have not seen analyses 25. Anjan V. Thakor and Jess C. Beltz, “An

14
Empirical Analysis of the Costs of Regulatory 27. A summary of the study is given in Yezer, pp.
Compliance,” in Proceedings: The 29th Annual 57–64.
Conference on Bank Structure and Competition
(Chicago: Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, May 28. U.S. General Accounting Office, “Fair
1993), pp. 549–68. The data were obtained from a Lending: Federal Oversight and Enforcement Im-
mail survey. Only 4 percent of the responding proved but Some Challenges Remain,” p. 39 ff.
banks had assets of more than $500 million.
29. Ibid., pp. 48–51.
26. The procedure employed is described by
Robert B. Avery et al., “Using HMDA Data as a 30. See Fannie Mae, Desktop Home Counselor.
Regulatory Screen for Fair Lending Compli-
ance,” Journal of Financial Services Research 11 31 Avery et al., “Trends in Home Purchase
(1997): 9–42. Lending.”

Published by the Cato Institute, Policy Analysis is a regular series evaluating government policies and offer-
ing proposals for reform. Nothing in Policy Analysis should be construed as necessarily reflecting the views
of the Cato Institute or as an attempt to aid or hinder the passage of any bill before congress. Contact the
Cato Institute for reprint permission. Additional copies of Policy Analysis are $6.00 each ($3.00 each for five
or more). To order, or for a complete listing of available studies, write the Cato Institute, 1000 Massachusetts
Ave., N.W., Washington, D.C. 20001, call toll free 1-800-767-1241 (noon - 9 p.m. eastern time), fax (202) 842-
3490, or visit our website at www.cato.org.

15

You might also like