You are on page 1of 16

No.

517 June 29, 2004

Deficits, Interest Rates, and Taxes


Myths and Realities
by Alan Reynolds

Executive Summary

The federal government’s swing from budget these hypotheses. Also, several of the hypotheses
surpluses to budget deficits has raised concerns are inconsistent with each other. In reality, nei-
about possible negative economic effects. Some ther actual nor projected budget deficits raise
economists have argued that deficits will raise real or nominal interest rates, steepen the yield
interest rates, reduce economic growth, increase curve, reduce national savings, cause trade
trade deficits, and possibly create a financial crisis. deficits, or make the dollar go down or up. The
This paper examines those claims and finds logic behind such speculations is flawed and the
that they are not supported by the evidence. In evidence is missing.
particular, the arguments of a recent study by for- These issues are important because numer-
mer Treasury secretary Robert Rubin, Brookings ous pundits and policymakers are arguing that
Institution scholar Peter Orszag, and economist taxes should be raised to reduce deficits. Indeed,
Allen Sinai are examined in detail. That study a theme of Rubin, Orszag, and Sinai is that high-
proposed four hypotheses about the effects of er tax rates can improve economic growth, but
sustained budget deficits: First, projected future that runs directly counter to serious research on
deficits affect current interest rates. Second, the causes of economic growth. Research on eco-
smaller budget deficits produce more domestic nomic growth assigns importance to the tax
private investment. Third, budget deficits cause structure, marginal tax rates, and the level and
trade deficits. Fourth, budget deficits cause fiscal composition of government spending, but not to
disarray and require tax increases to maintain whether spending is financed by taxes or deficits.
confidence. Deficits are a sign that federal spending is too
Empirical evidence—U.S. time series data and high, but deficits do not cause many of the eco-
international comparisons—do not support nomic harms that some analysts are claiming.

_____________________________________________________________________________________________________
Alan Reynolds is a senior fellow at the Cato Institute.
Rubin, Orszag, Introduction The external borrowing that helps to
and Sinai argue finance the budget deficit is reflected
A January 2004 study by former Treasury in a larger current account deficit . . .
that estimated secretary Robert Rubin, Brookings Institution The reduction in domestic investment
future budget scholar Peter Orszag, and economist Allen (which lowers productivity growth)
Sinai proposed four hypotheses about the and the increase in the current account
deficits increase effects of sustained federal budget deficits.1 deficit (which requires that more of the
real interest rates. The first hypothesis describes a link returns from the domestic capital
between budget deficits and interest rates. stock accrue to foreigners) both reduce
Some economists used to argue that current future national income.3
budget deficits increased long-term interest
rates. Rubin, Orszag, and Sinai have proposed The authors augment the conventional
two new variations on this theory. They argue view with another hypothesis that is sup-
that estimated future budget deficits increase posed to be novel and unconventional. This
real interest rates, or alternatively change the fourth hypothesis is what used to be called
spread between short- and long-term interest the “hard landing scenario” simply relabeled
rates. as the “risk of financial and fiscal disarray.”
The second hypthesis is that smaller budg- Specifically, the authors claim that sustained
et deficits will automatically produce more budget deficits may cause “depreciation of
domestic private investment, regardless of the exchange rate and decline in confidence
whether they are attained by higher tax rates [which] can reduce stock prices.”4 The
or restrained spending. authors advocate a preemptive strike against
The third hypothesis is that larger budget estimated future budget deficits in the form
deficits cause larger trade or current account of higher taxes on investors and others,
deficits. This echoes the “twin deficits” theory ostensibly to improve investor confidence.
of the 1980s, except that deficits are now said These are not new ideas. The first two
to make the dollar go down rather than up. hypotheses (about deficits reducing savings
The fourth hypothesis is that market par- and raising interest rates) were associated with
ticipants may fail to notice budget deficits for proponents of high tax rates in the 1950s, par-
years yet experience an unsettling loss of con- ticularly President Dwight D. Eisenhower. The
fidence because of unnoticed fiscal problems. third (twin deficits) was forcefully articulated
This “risk of financial and fiscal disarray” in the 1980s and mid-1990s by Harvard
bears a strong resemblance to the endless University’s Martin Feldstein and former
“hard landing” scares of the 1980s.2 The Treasury secretary Lawrence Summers. The
authors’ proposed solution is also the same fourth (higher taxes to restore investor confi-
as in the 1980s—an increase in taxes as a “pre- dence) was embraced in 1931 under President
emptive strike” to maintain confidence. Herbert Hoover.
Rubin, Orszag, and Sinai refer to the first
three hypotheses as the “conventional view”:
First Hypothesis: Deficits
Under the conventional view, ongoing and Interest Rates
budget deficits decrease national sav-
ing, which reduces domestic invest- The original version of the first hypothesis
ment and increases borrowing from predicted that actual deficits would raise actu-
abroad. Interest rates play a key role in al long-term interest rates. The new version of
how the economy adjusts. The reduc- this theory is presented in the recent paper by
tion in national saving raises domestic Rubin, Orszag, and Sinai, and in a 2003 study
interest rates, which dampens invest- by Anne-Marie Brook of the Organisation for
ment and attracts capital from abroad. Economic Co-operation and Development.5

2
The Rubin, Orszag, and Sinai paper redefines increasing marginal tax rates on individuals
the supposed link between deficits and inter- by increasing statutory rates and phasing-out
est rates in three ways. deductions for higher-income taxpayers.
First, it argues that interest rates are In the fall of 1994, after tax rates had been
affected by estimated future deficits rather than increased, the Congressional Budget Office
actual present deficits. One cited study, by continued to overestimate the deficit in the
Thomas Laubach of the Federal Reserve year 2000 by 5.3 percent of gross domestic
Board, assumes “deficits projected several product—a $520 billion exaggeration for a
years into the future may be informative single year. Higher tax rates in 1993 had
about the longer-run fiscal position, and may nothing to do with the exaggerated 1994
therefore approximate investors’ expecta- deficit projections. The two new tax brackets
tions.”6 Yet it is difficult to see how estimated of 36 and 39.6 percent were projected to raise
deficits could have effects that actual deficits only $22.5 billion in 1995 (much smaller
do not have, since past estimates have been than typical estimating errors one year
wildly inaccurate. ahead) and the long-term 1994 budget pro-
Budget forecasting errors follow a cyclical jections already incorporated such static rev-
pattern, becoming too optimistic near eco- enue estimates.10
nomic peaks but too pessimistic in the early At the recent business cycle peak in early
Debt service
stages of recovery, as in 1984, 1994, and prob- 2001, the CBO erred in the opposite direc- is the true
ably 2004. As the economy expands, so does tion, as it routinely does at cyclical peaks, by burden of deficit
the budget. As the actual budget gets better, overestimating future surpluses by trillions
so do estimated future budgets. of dollars. If interest rates actually depended financing, but
The fiscal year 1984 federal budget esti- on such unreliable estimates (as Rubin, currently it is
mated that the deficit would reach $308 bil- Orszag, and Sinai contend), bond yields
lion by 1987. But the deficit actually fell to would have been extremely low in early 2001
unusually low.
$150 billion that year, with few major policy and would be much higher today. Instead,
changes except lower tax rates. In early 1986, interest rates were substantially higher in
the CBO quickly slashed projected deficits that period of estimated future surpluses and
for the following three years by $411 billion fell to record lows after those estimates had
over a five-month period.7 Deficit estimates been revised to show large future deficits.
are eventually adjusted to conform to reality. That theory had already failed before it was
In President Bill Clinton’s first budget published.
address in 1993, he said, “Ten years from now In a separate paper, Orszag and William
. . . when Members of Congress come here, Gale, of the Brookings Institution, respond to
they’ll be devoting over 20 cents on the dollar this recent turn of events by arguing, “The fact
to interest payments.”8 Yet actual interest that long-term nominal interest rates are low
expense turned out to be only 7.1 cents on the does not mean they would not have been
dollar in 2003—down from 12.5 in 2000 when lower.”11 But that amounts to turning this
the budget was in surplus.9 Debt service is the into a nonfalsifiable hypothesis—what Karl
true burden of deficit financing, but currently Popper called a metaphysical statement.
it is unusually low. Just as homeowners have “Those among us who are unwilling to expose
refinanced their mortgages, so has the U.S. their ideas to the hazard of refutation,” wrote
Treasury. Popper, “do not take part in the scientific
Interest expense was not the only spending game.”12
estimate that turned out to be grossly exag- Rubin, Orszag, and Sinai’s variation on the
gerated in the 1993 projections. In response first hypothesis is to downplay the obviously
to such erroneous forecasts, Congress enacted invisible effect of deficits on nominal interest
the second tax increase in three years. Both rates by saying, “The overall level of nominal
the 1990 and 1993 federal tax laws focused on interest rates is affected by many factors

3
[emphasis in the original].”13 That suggests when the economy is expanding briskly (e.g.,
that although deficits may not raise nominal 1983–84 and 1996–2000) and lowest when
interest rates, they do not raise real interest the economy is stagnant or declining (e.g.,
rates either. One reason for switching from Japan in recent years).
nominal to real rates, as Anne-Marie Brook
notes, is that “most empirical work conducted Yield Curves
in the past ten years estimates the impact on Rubin, Orszag, and Sinai prefer to change
U.S. real long-term interest rates.”14 Gale and the subject from long-term rates, whether real
Orszag cite Laubach, for example, but neglect or nominal, to the yield curve, which shows
to mention that his study tried to estimate interest rates on bonds of different maturi-
what real interest rates are expected to be five ties. They note: “For purposes of assessing the
years in the future. effects of future budget surpluses or deficits,
Expectations aside, changing the subject it may be more insightful to examine the
from nominal to real interest rates is not a spread between long-term and short-term
trivial distinction. If estimated deficits raised real interest rates. That spread is currently rela-
interest rates but not nominal interest rates, that tively high . . . and has increased substantially
must mean bigger deficits cause inflation to fall. As since the 2001 tax cut.” Anne-Marie Brook
a matter of historical fact, there actually was also views the interest rate spread as an alter-
a connection between bigger deficits and native to claiming that deficits raise real inter-
lower inflation in the United States. It is not est rates. “The most common approach is to
that rising deficits caused inflation to fall in use some measure of the level of real interest
the 1980s, but that falling inflation after rates as the dependent variable,” she writes. “A
1981 caused deficits to rise. Lower inflation related approach is to model the interest rate
ended the previous revenue windfalls from spread (long minus short).”16
bracket creep and overtaxation of inflated However, the interest rate spread is not at
inventory profits and capital gains. Also, the all related to real interest rates, either in the-
Federal Reserve’s decision to hold the federal ory or fact. Real interest rates were extremely
funds interest rate at between 9 and 16 per- high in 1979–81, for example, but the yield
cent from 1981 to 1984 (far above the infla- curve was inverted at the time. Real interest
tion rate) greatly increased federal interest rates were unusually low in 1992–93 and
expense and caused profits and employment 2002–03, but the yield curve was steep.
to contract until 1983–84 when tax rate Changing the dependent variable from
reductions were phased in. Laubach ac- long-term interest rates to the gap between
knowledges: “Both deficits and interest rates long- and short-term rates is even more trou-
rose sharply, with the latter arguably driven blesome than changing from nominal to real
at least in part by the Volcker disinflation.” yields. If estimated future deficits only affect the
He does not seem to realize that the former— spread between short-term and long-term interest
deficits—were “driven at least in part by the rates, then larger projected deficits must cause short-
The hypothesis Volcker disinflation.” term rates to fall. Projected future budget sur-
The hypothesis that budget projections pluses would likewise be associated with high-
that budget affect real interest rates has the additional er short-term rates. This is not what Rubin,
projections affect handicap of being inconsistent with the Orszag, and Sinai say, but it is what their
real interest rates facts. As Rik Hafer, a professor at Southern hypothesis says.
Illinois University at Edwardsville, demon- The yield curve hypothesis is logically
has the additional strated graphically, “During the late 1990s obligated to thank rising budget deficits for
handicap of being when the projected budget surplus was the dramatic drop in both real and nominal
increasing steadily, the 10-year real interest short-term interest rates since the 2001 tax
inconsistent with rate was rising.”15 This should have been no cut, and, therefore, the wider spread between
the facts. surprise. Real interest rates are always highest long-term and short-term rates.

4
In reality, any observed connection rise at all if the yield curve merely became As long as the
between yield curves and deficit projections is steeper (and therefore more optimistic) or if yield curve is not
simply due to the fact that both are cyclical.17 the mortgage rate increased only in real
Long-term interest rates always fall when terms (because inflation fell). inverted, interest
short-term rates fall, but never by nearly as It is hard to avoid the conclusion that this rates are high in
much—causing the yield curve to become debate is not about facts but about theory.
steeper when the Fed eases. The Fed eases dur- Stubborn convictions about an invisible link
real terms only
ing and shortly after recessions, which is also between deficits and bond yields rest on “the when the pace of
when the CBO and the White House usually quantity theory of bonds”: Treasury bonds economic growth
revise their deficit projections upwards. are thought to be valued for their scarcity,
The yield curve is a component of the like rare stamps or antiques, making their is also high.
index of leading indicators. A steep yield market value vary inversely with the volume
curve—which Rubin, Orszag, and Sinai of bonds marketed. This theory is never
depict as an ominous sign of future deficits— applied to other debt instruments. Those
is universally viewed as an excellent leading who advance the quantity theory of Treasury
indicator of future prosperity. A flat or bonds do not claim that the huge volume of
inverted yield curve—which the authors asso- mortgages issued in the year 2002 must have
ciate with surpluses—“significantly outper- pushed mortgage rates higher.
forms other financial and macroeconomic In reality, people do not buy a country’s
indicators in predicting recession.”18 The bonds because of their scarcity (unless
authors surely do not intend to claim that default risk is involved) but because they
budget surpluses cause recessions nor that expect the return—including coupon and
deficits cause prosperity, but that is what capital gains—to at least match the risk-
their yield curve hypothesis implies. adjusted return of alternative investments.
The hypothesis that projected deficits Those alternative investments include all of
steepen the yield curve and the contradictory the world’s stocks, bonds, bills, commodities,
hypothesis that they raise real interest rates and real estate. Governments do not borrow
both undermine the authors’ central claim from the current flow of national savings, as
that projected deficits reduce economic the authors assume, but from the world’s
growth. Steep yield curves forecast strong stock of assets.
economic growth, not weakness. As long as Interest rates are also reduced rather than
the yield curve is not inverted (indicating increased by lower marginal tax rates, for the
unsustainably tight monetary policy), inter- same reason that tax-exempt money market
est rates are high in real terms only when the funds pay a lower interest rate than taxable
pace of economic growth (and therefore the bonds. Rubin, Orszag, and Sinai’s “financial
real return on capital) is also high.19 disarray” analysis promotes concern that
“depreciation of the dollar . . . would almost
Interest Rates on Government Bonds surely reduce stock prices.” (That would have
Despite all these strained efforts to link been terrible investment advice in 2003).
unreliable deficit projections to yield curves Ostensibly to help keep stock prices higher,
or real interest rates, efforts to demonize they propose to raise investors’ marginal tax
deficits still rely on their alleged effect on rates. But stock prices only increased after
actual interest rates. Brookings Institution marginal tax rates (including those on divi-
scholars Alice Rivlin and Isabel Sawhill, for dends and capital gains) came down. Rajnish
example, illustrate the burden of deficits by Mehra and Edward Prescott find that much
noting, “monthly payments on a thirty-year of their famous “equity premium puzzle”
fixed-rate mortgage will rise from $1,500 to was because “reductions in marginal tax rates
$1,663 when interest rates rise from 6 to 7 account for the high return on corporate
percent.”20 But monthly payments would not equity in the [1960–2000] period.”21

5
Long-term nominal interest rates have ration of national savings to GDP. Second,
been very closely linked to inflation, but infla- such a decline must reduce domestic invest-
tion has not been linked to budget deficits ment or make U.S. citizens more indebted to
(except inversely in the 1980s). To shore up foreigners. The central thesis dates back to
their fourth “financial disarray” hypothesis, the late 1950s.
Rubin, Orszag, and Sinai favorably quote a In President Eisenhower’s budget address
CBO speculation that “consumer prices could of January 1960, he defended keeping punitive
shoot up” because of deficits. This quaint Korean War tax rates in place because “sound
notion that deficits are inherently inflationary fiscal and economic policy requires a budget
arose in the 1950s from traditional Keynesian surplus . . . to increase the supply of savings
analysis, which treated deficits as an equiva- available for the productive investment so
lent “stimulus” to Fed easing, thus blurring a essential to continued economic growth.”24
vital distinction between the Treasury selling His comments came three months before the
bonds and the Federal Reserve buying bonds. third recession in six years. Republicans were
The U.S. public debt is less than 40 percent of harshly punished in the 1960 elections. Paul
GDP; Japan’s debt is three times that large. Samuelson, President Kennedy’s top econom-
But few people are worrying about hyperinfla- ic adviser, called Eisenhower’s fiscal policy an
Financial tion in Japan. “investment in sadism.”25
markets are Sustained changes in real interest rates are Eisenhower’s hypothesis that budget sur-
global and driven by the real return on invested capital, pluses raise savings and private investment
which makes promises to boost growth with has been reborn in the Rubin, Orszag, and
are not driven lower real interest rates illogical and incon- Sinai paper. Similarly, Gale and Orszag sug-
by the national sistent with experience.22 gest that the effect of deficits on interest rates
International arbitrage ensures that nation- is “at least partially a red herring” because
government’s al interest rates are not determined by domes- what matters is that savings and investment
portion of tic fiscal conditions, except to the extent that must fall “regardless of whether interest rates
domestic those conditions might imply greater risks of are affected.”26 But that evasion begs all the
default or of future exchange rate losses. The questions, since higher interest rates were
borrowing. first table in Brook’s study shows that long- supposed to be the mechanism that discour-
term U.S. interest rates rose by an average of 2.4 ages investment and (in all previous “twin
percentage points in three recent cycles of cen- deficits” theories) drives the dollar higher.27
tral bank tightening. But long-term interest Gale and Orszag offer no direct evidence as
rates also rose by 2.4 percentage points in to whether or not national savings rates actu-
Canada, Japan, and the U.K. (there were slight ally rose in any country at any point after
differences between Germany, France, and deficits were replaced by surpluses. “For the
Italy, but only before they joined a common most part, we summarize findings obtained in
currency). Financial markets are global and are earlier surveys . . . [and] focus on a few key
not driven by the national government’s por- highlights from the literature.”28 But there are
tion of domestic borrowing.23 notable omissions from their summary, such
The quantity theory of bonds is clearly as Robert Eisner’s 1994 study in The Review of
irrelevant for major countries—even those Economics and Statistics, which found no effect
with large accumulated debts, such as Japan. of deficits on savings.29 John Seater’s 1993 sur-
vey is mentioned, but not the fact that it found
the evidence “inconsistent with the view that
Second Hypothesis: government debt is positively related to inter-
Deficits and Savings est rates.”30

The second hypothesis has two parts. Foreign Experience


First, budget deficits must reduce the overall Those earlier surveys (mostly from 1987–

6
93) did not have the benefit of three ideal Japan’s long series of huge budget deficits
natural experiments in recent years: the was eventually followed by a reduction in pri-
United States, the United Kingdom, and vate savings in recent years. But that was
Australia all moving from large and pro- because Japanese households have been
longed deficits to several years of surplus. offered a near-zero return on stocks, bonds
The swing from deficit to surplus was sizable and banks deposits. Corporate profits (there-
in each case, about 4 to 5 percent of GDP. If fore retained earnings) have also been quite
the second hypothesis were correct, the weak. Casey Mulligan of the University of
national savings rate should have increased Chicago shows that savings is sensitive to after-
by 4 to 5 percentage points following the tax returns on investments in general, but that
swing from deficit to surplus. Instead, the such returns are not captured by the interest
national savings rate rose briefly for only one rate on Treasury bonds.33 The prolonged
year in the U.K. and declined slightly in the absence of profitable investment opportuni-
U.S. and Australia. ties undoubtedly contributed to Japan’s bud-
From 1981 to 1989, when U.S. budget get deficits, but it is implausible that it was
deficits averaged 3.8 percent of GDP, the caused by those deficits.
national savings rate was 18.2 percent of GDP. A key point to note is that Japan’s huge,
From 1998 to 2001, while the U.S. budget was sustained budget deficits, which have aver-
in surplus, the national savings rate was 18 aged 7 percent of GDP in recent years, did not
percent of GDP.31 result in high interest rates, a steep yield
The U.K. national savings rate averaged 17.8 curve, a collapsing yen, or a big current
percent from 1984 to 1987, when the budget account deficit, as the Rubin-Orszag-Sinai
was in deficit, but dipped to 17.2 percent in theory predicts.
1988–89, when the budget moved into surplus. The Rubin-Orszag-Sinai “taxes equal sav-
British budget deficits subsequently averaged ings” doctrine was popular in development
4.7 percent of GDP from 1990 to 1997, fol- economics in the early sixties, when it was
lowed by surpluses averaging 1.5 percent of called “forced savings.” A popular textbook of
GDP from 1998 to 2001. The savings rate was that era, Economic Development by Gerald Meier
15.4 percent during the eight years of chronic and Robert Baldwin, explained: “Increased tax-
deficits and 16 percent during the period of ation . . . allows the government to force savings
surpluses, but all of the latter gain was in a sin- and reduce disposable incomes. A difficulty
gle year, 1998. Savings during 1999–2001 with this method, however, is that while invol-
dropped back to 15.4 percent. untary saving is increased, voluntary saving
Australia had an unbroken string of may be diminished.”34 Meier and Baldwin’s
deficits that averaged 2.9 percent of GDP simple explanation of why more taxes do not
from 1986 to 1997. The deficits were fol- equal more savings did not require “Ricardian
lowed by surpluses averaging 1.1 percent of Equivalence,” which is the theory that people
GDP from 1998 to 2001. The savings rate have perfect foresight about future tax obliga- Japan’s huge,
during the period of deficits was 19 percent. tions to service the added debt. To the extent sustained budget
The savings rate during the period of sur- that taxes reduce household’s after-tax income,
pluses was 18.9 percent. 32 their savings must fall unless they can somehow deficits, which
It should not be surprising that taking save a higher percentage of their shrunken have averaged 7
more money from the private sector and giv- incomes. Taxpayers cannot save money they no percent of GDP
ing it to the government does not improve longer have.
the budgets of both the private and govern- Even if deficits did reduce savings, would in recent years,
ment sectors at the same time. After all, domestic investment be reduced? The authors did not result in
income taxes fall heavily on the main sources contradict themselves on this point, because if
of saving—corporations and high-income investment was closely tied to domestic sav-
high interest
households. ings then there would be no need for external rates.

7
The twin deficits finances and no impact on the current However, like the notion that more taxes
hypothesis has account deficit. equal more saving and investment, the twin
Some economists have theorized that each deficits hypothesis has rarely been presented
been thoroughly billion dollars of government borrowing is as a theory whose veracity depended on any
tested and proven drained from a supposedly fixed “savings facts. The twin deficits hypothesis has,
pool,” which reduces the amount left over for instead, been presented as an unquestionable
thoroughly private investment.35 Others have theorized accounting identity. This has been conve-
incorrect. that domestic investment would instead have nient, because the sharp cyclical reduction in
to be financed by a net inflow of foreign direct budget deficits from 1991 to 2000 provided
and portfolio investment. But these two theo- an excellent time to test the theory, if facts
retical conjectures contradict each other. mattered at all.
The belief that a high savings rate ensured In 1991, the budget deficit was 4.7 percent
rapid economic growth is the main reason of GDP, up from 3.9 percent in 1989. The
many U.S. economists in the sixties predicted current account, however, had moved from a
that the Soviet Union would out-produce the deficit of 1.8 percent in 1989 to a small sur-
United States by 1980 or 1990.36 The high sav- plus in 1991. In each subsequent year, the
ings rate in Japan is also why others in the budget deficit fell and the current account
eighties predicted that the Japanese economy rose. By 1998, the budget surplus equaled 0.8
would be larger than the U.S. economy by now. percent of GDP but the current account
Economic growth is not as simple as that. deficit was 2.5 percent. By 2000, the budget
surplus equaled 2.4 percent of GDP but the
current account deficit was 4.4 percent.
Third Hypothesis: Budget It would be difficult to discover any
Deficits and Trade Deficits hypothesis that produced worse predictions
than the twin deficits theory. A possible
Rubin, Orszag, and Sinai attempt to revive exception is the prediction of recent years
the 1980s specters of “twin deficits” and an that moving from budget surpluses to
economic “hard landing.” In the twin deficits deficits between 2000 and 2003 threatened
theory, budget deficits are linked to trade to make mortgage interest rates rise.
deficits. A hard landing is now called “finan- The twin deficits hypothesis fares no bet-
cial disarray” by the authors. ter in cross-country comparisons than it does
Before the federal budget moved into sur- in the U.S. time series data. The February 7,
plus in 1998, the same accounting model 2004, edition of The Economist estimated that
now being recycled by Rubin, Orszag, and Australia had a budget surplus of 0.8 in 2003
Sinai was used by Martin Feldstein, Larry but a current account deficit of 6.2 percent of
Summers, and others to make three very GDP. Japan had a budget deficit of 7.4 percent
explicit and unconditional predictions. They of GDP but a current account surplus of 3 per-
predicted that moving from deficits to sur- cent of GDP. Australia’s government bond
pluses would increase the national savings yield was 5.69 percent, while Japan’s was 1.28
rate, reduce long-term interest rates, and percent.
eliminate the current account deficit. Not
one of those predictions came true.37 The Bogey of Foreign Debt
In 1995, Martin Feldstein, a former advis- The twin deficits hypothesis has been thor-
er to President Reagan, argued: “With a lower oughly tested and proven thoroughly incor-
level of current and expected future govern- rect. The United States has had a current
ment borrowing, real interest rates would account deficit in most recent years, and Japan
decline and the dollar would come down has had a current account surplus, but both of
with them . . . A lower budget deficit would those developments were correlated with the
thus reduce our trade deficit.”38 relative pace of U.S. economic growth rather

8
than budget deficits. When the U.S. grows The U.S. current account deficit means
faster than other major economies, such as that foreign exporters are choosing to sue
Japan, U.S. imports grow faster than exports. some of their export earning s to invest in the
If and when growth elsewhere speeds up, so United States rather than purchase U.S. goods
does their demand for U.S. exports. and services immediately. As Matthew Higgins
Even if there was some invisible connec- and Thomas Klitgaard of the New York
tion between budget deficits and current Federal Reserve Bank point out, such extra
account deficits, the related claims of Rubin, investment from the current account deficit
Orszag, and Sinai that a net inflow of foreign produces long-term U.S. income gains “from
investment reduces future U.S. assets and the indirect effects of higher investment
income would still be invalid. The authors spending on economy-wide employment.”41
say that “the increase in the current account
deficit (which requires that more of the
returns from the domestic capital stock The Fourth Hypothesis:
accrue to foreigners) [will] reduce future Raising Taxes to Restore
national income.”39 Similarly, Gale and
Orszag note that if foreigners invest in the
Confidence
U.S., “the capital owned by Americans The last idea of Rubin, Orszag, and Sinai
In a preemptive
declines.”40 is that raising taxes will restore confidence. strike designed
This reasoning appears to take the This myth has been around for decades. It to restore
amount of capital invested in the U.S. as was prominently articulated by Peter G.
fixed, so that foreigners could buy claims to Peterson in an October 1987 cover feature in confidence,
that fixed stock of capital only at the expense the Atlantic Monthly arguing that the stock marginal tax
of Americans. But physical capital financed market had crashed because investors sud-
by selling equity or bonds to foreigners is not denly noticed that there was a budget deficit.
rates were raised
a zero-sum transfer of ownership of claims to The myth did its greatest damage when it in June 1932 from
a fixed capital stock but a means of financing was put into practice by President Herbert 1–25 percent to
additions to that capital stock. Hoover. At the end of 1931, a year after signing
One obvious problem with alluding to all a disastrous increase in tariffs, President 4–63 percent.
foreign investment as U.S. debt to foreigners Hoover asked Congress for a “temporary”
is that much of the net capital inflow is real- income tax increase, raising tax rates to levels
ly equity—direct investment and purchases of not seen since the depression of 1920–21.
shares in the U.S. firms. When Nissan built a Hoover proclaimed repeatedly that “nothing
factory in Tennessee, it certainly did not is more necessary at this time than balancing
reduce “the capital owned by Americans.” If the budget.”42 It was, he said, “indispensable to
that investment is profitable, earnings from the restoration of confidence and to the very
the U.S. plant will accrue to Nissan stock- start of economic recovery . . . We cannot
holders as dividends or capital gains. maintain public confidence nor stability of
Americans can and do own shares in Nissan, the Federal Government without undertaking
just as Americans own more shares in the some temporary tax increases.”43
French drug company Aventis than the In a preemptive strike designed to restore
French do, and many Americans work at fac- confidence, marginal tax rates were raised in
tories and offices with foreign names on June 1932 from rates of 1–25 percent to rates
them. It makes little sense to say Americans of 4–63 percent. Yet revenue from the individ-
would be even better off if they had built all ual income tax dropped from $834 million in
the foreign factories in America with their 1931 to $427 million in 1932 and to $353 mil-
own savings. Americans cannot produce lion in 1933. Consistent with his theory,
Nissans, BMWs, and foreign-brand drugs Hoover also asked Congress to create a new
without foreign help and permission. national sales tax. He said, “To assure a bal-

9
anced budget . . . excise taxes should be extend- national income. First, the tax cut will
ed to cover practically all manufacturers at a affect [increase] labor supply, human
uniform rate, except necessary food.”44 That capital accumulation, saving, invest-
time Congress did not go along, and neither ment, entrepreneurship and so on.
did the electorate. Second, the reduction in revenues will
As the experience of the early 1930s raise the deficit and reduce national
shows, the old “confidence” game is a dam- saving . . . For the tax cut to have a net
aging myth that should not be revived. positive effect on economic growth,
Renaming it a “preemptive strike” does not the effects on labor supply, savings,
improve the theory’s chances of success. etc., not only must be positive, they
must be larger than the drag created by
the increased deficit. Similar findings
Taxes: Microeconomic apply to deficits created by spending
Effects Matter increases.45

Those who cling to various hypotheses These “two effects” are inherently incon-
about how budget deficits are supposed to sistent with each other. To the extent that
affect interest rates, savings, exchange rates, and reductions in marginal rates have beneficial
the current account tend to dismiss criticism by effects on economic growth, as the authors
claiming that economists who disagree with acknowledge, those reductions will result in a
them are just saying that “deficits don’t mat- larger tax base. “A fair assessment [of the evi-
ter.” Deficits do matter, but not in any of the dence],” wrote Gale, “would conclude that
ways Rubin, Orszag, Sinai, and Gale imagine. well-designed tax policies can raise growth.”46
Federal debt service is not a free lunch, The tax base would therefore be enlarged,
although it now amounts to only 1.4 percent even aside from reduced avoidance, and tax
of GDP, down from 2.3 percent in 2000. revenues might also be enlarged. If a larger
Government borrowing is much like any other tax base is taxed at a lower average (not mar-
borrowing, such as mortgages or corporate ginal) rate, the net effect on revenue is
bonds: The debt service cost of government ambiguous. That ambiguity makes it incor-
borrowing has to be compared with the alter- rect for Gale and Orszag to assume a long-
natives (e.g., the alternative to a young family term “reduction in revenues.” For the same
taking out a mortgage is to keep paying rent). reason, the authors’ key assumption that
For the federal government, the alterna- lower taxes today must be fully offset by
tives to borrowing are restraining spending higher taxes tomorrow is also invalid, as are
or attempting to collect more taxes. (The lat- their cited simulations from a nonmarginal
Congress ter is difficult because the income tax share model that depends on that assumption (the
of GDP has been stubbornly immune to such 1987 Auerbach-Kotlikoff model).
increased the attempts). It is pointless to say that U.S. tax- Congress increased the highest federal
highest federal payers would be better off raising current marginal income tax rates in 1990 (effective
taxes on the basis of projected future bor- for 1991) and 1993 by raising statutory tax
marginal income rowing without comparing all costs to tax- rates and phasing out deductions and
tax rates in payers of increasing marginal tax rates, exemptions for high-income earners. Despite
1990 and 1993. including potential damage to the economy those rate increases, tax revenues were not
(and therefore to actual tax receipts). visibly increased. Receipts from the individ-
Despite those rate Writing in Tax Notes last year, Gale and ual income tax averaged 8.2 percent of GDP
increases, tax Orszag said: from 1988 to 1990 when the top tax rate was
revenues were not 28 percent, and 7.8 percent in 1991–92 after
A cut in marginal tax rates will general- the Bush tax increase. The economy was in
visibly increased. ly have two sets of effects on future recession for the first two quarters of FY91,

10
so we should have expected that tax receipts after the deep and broad Kennedy tax cuts, Federal
would recover by 1993, regardless of the tax and 18.3 percent in 1989 after two rounds of revenues from
increase. Yet revenues were only 7.7 percent of major tax rate reductions under President
GDP in 1993, 7.8 percent in 1994, and 8.1 Reagan. the individual
percent in 1995—less than in 1989 (8.3 per- Sustained, noncyclical variations in the income tax have
cent) prior to the two tax rate increases. tax share of GDP have not been associated
Revenues did surge in 1997–2000, but much with legislated tax cuts or increases except to
been a nearly
of that revenue gain was from capital gains the extent that tax policy affected the denom- constant share
taxed at the reduced rate of 20 percent. inator of that ratio (by helping or hurting the of GDP since
Federal revenues from the individual real GDP growth). Aside from the stock mar-
income tax have been a nearly constant share ket boom of 1997–2000, the only time the 1952 (I call this
of GDP (and of personal income) since 1952, federal share of GDP exceeded 19 percent was “Reynolds’ Law”).
regardless of whether the top tax rate was 91 just before and during recessions, when GDP
percent or 28 percent and regardless of slowed or fell in real terms—in particular
whether loopholes were opened or closed. The 1952, 1969–70 and 1980–82. The tax share
individual income tax varies cyclically between declined for a while after every recession,
about 7.5 and 9 percent of GDP, largely reflect- partly because taxes are paid on income
ing swings in the stock market, but it shows earned in the prior year. Yet the overall tax
no significant connection to how high or low share of GDP was back above 18 percent in
the highest tax rate is on upper-income filers (I 1977–79 and 1987–89 without any tax rate
call this “Reynolds’ Law”). Since taxes on indi- increase.
vidual income are a nearly constant share of Why have past changes in the highest
GDP, and taxes on corporate income vary with marginal tax rates—ranging from 28 to 91
profits, it follows that the only way to achieve percent—had no discernible effect in raising
a sustained increase in real federal revenue is or lowering the share of taxes to personal
by adopting policies conducive to sustained income or GDP? The only possible answers
increases in real GDP. are that higher tax rates either discourage the
The absence of any relationship between affected people from earning as much
top tax rates and revenues is most revealing income or that higher tax rates encourage
when focusing on individual income taxes, taxpayers to receive income in ways not
and excluding the many increases in the reported to the IRS or seeking higher deduc-
Social Security and Medicare tax rates and tions (e.g., by switching from salary to perks
base. Yet there is also no apparent relation- or by taking out a larger mortgage).
ship between income tax changes and the Studies by Daniel Feenberg and James
ratio of all taxes to GDP. Rudolph Penner and Poterba, Martin Feldstein, and Lawrence
Eugene Steuerle remark that “the federal tax Lindsey have shown that the amount of tax-
burden has seldom been allowed to exceed 19 able income reported is extremely sensitive to
percent. Every time that level has been the highest marginal tax rates. Their critics
breached, taxes have been cut significantly.”47 merely debate the source of that sensitivity
The implication that the ratio of taxes to (the extent to which it represents tax avoid-
GDP would have risen well above 19 percent ance or reduced effort) and its duration (the
were it not for reductions in tax rates is extent to which it reflects deferring or avoid-
extremely misleading. After all, taxes reached ing taxation). One of those critics, Emmanuel
20 percent in 1944 and 1945 when tax rates Saez, examined behavioral responses, mainly
were almost confiscatory (94 percent) and for 1996–2000, “such as labor supply deci-
compliance was high due to patriotism and sions, career choices and savings decisions.”
rationing. Federal taxes were 16.2 percent of He finds that “behavioral responses to
GDP in 1959 when Eisenhower was defend- changes in marginal tax rates [were] concen-
ing 91 percent tax rates, 18.4 percent in 1967 trated at the top of the income distribution.”48

11
But that is the crucial part of the income dis- would not have to do nearly as much damage
tribution, since the top 1 percent of taxpayers to the economy and stock market as I believe
earned 17.5 percent of all income in 2001 and they would to end up raising little or no rev-
paid 33.9 percent of all federal income tax.49 enue at all over time.
And it is at the top of the income distribution
where leading politicians claim it would be
possible to raise substantially more revenues Taxes, Spending, and
by raising tax rates. Economic Growth
Saez concludes that the rapid rise of top
incomes in the 1990s “appears too large to The central theme of Rubin, Orszag, and
have been solely the direct consequence of . . . Sinai—that higher tax rates can improve
supply-side effects.”50 Yet nobody ever said growth by raising saving and investment—
that income growth depends “solely” on tax might be “conventional” at the International
policy. There were unanticipated windfalls Monetary Fund or in some elementary text-
from exercised stock options during the tech- books, but it is quite unconventional when it
nology stock boom, for example, although comes to serious research on the causes of
that was partly an indirect consequence of the economic growth. Such research assigns
Research on lower tax on capital gains. Saez finds it “par- importance to marginal tax rates and the
the causes of ticularly surprising” that high incomes grew structure of taxation and to the level and
economic while stocks soared, since the top tax on ordi- composition of government spending but
nary income was higher in 1996–2000 than it not to whether spending is financed by taxes
growth assigns had been in 1988–92. But the tax on capital or debt.
importance to gains was lower than it had been over the pre- Cross-country empirical studies, such as
vious 10 years. In any case, the existence of Economic Growth by Robert Barro and Xavier
marginal tax rates stock market windfalls in 1996–2000 is Sala-i-Martin and the Global Competitiveness
and the structure entirely irrelevant to the question of whether Report from the World Economic Forum,
of taxation but or not high marginal tax rates encourage rev- find no significance of budget deficits per
enue-losing behavioral responses, such as se.52 In contrast with Rubin, Orszag, and
not to whether premature retirement or aggressive tax avoid- Sinai, economists looking at the sources of
spending is ance. In fact, any effect of high tax rates on economic growth do not treat tax and spend-
financed by tax avoidance is virtually ruled out by the way ing policy as two equally viable devices for
Saez measures income—before tax deductions changing budget deficits. They treat increas-
taxes or debt. and adjustments. es in distortive taxation as a negative influence
Brookings Institution scholars Henry on economic growth and reduction in gov-
Aaron, Gale, and Orszag propose the option ernment purchases and transfers as a positive
of repealing the 2001 income tax changes influence.
that benefit “high-income filers.”51 It turns Consider a recent study of 18 countries by
out that “high-income” means the top four Alberto Alesina of Harvard University, Silvia
marginal tax rates—including putting the 25 Ardagna of Wellesley College, Robert Perotti
percent rate back up to 28 percent. For single of the European University Institute, and
people, “high income” starts at a taxable Fabio Schiantarelli of Boston College.53 They
income of $29,050 in 2004. Despite the conclude the following:
broad reach of this proposed tax increase,
their static revenue estimate from raising all First, increases in public spending
of the top four tax rates is just 0.4 percent of increase labor costs and reduce profits.
GDP in 2014. Their estimate from taxing div- As a result, investment declines as well
idends and capital gains at the tax rates before . . . . Second, increases in taxes reduce
2001 is only 0.2 percent of GDP. On a profits and investment. . . . Labor taxes
dynamic basis, such increased tax rates have the largest impact on profits and

12
investment. Third, . . . fiscal stabiliza- case of Social Security. Such programs are a
tions that have led to an increase in disincentive for those who receive them and
growth consist mainly of spending also for taxpayers who fund them. These dis-
cuts, particularly in government wages incentive effects are not reduced by funding
and transfers, while those associated transfers with taxes rather than borrowing.
with a downturn in the economy are Demographic projections imply that
characterized by tax increases.54 unfunded promises of Social Security had
Medicare benefits could impose such a heavy
The old myth that growth depends on tax burden on younger workers in the future
balanced budgets is nowhere to be found in that their incentives to work, attend college,
the recent 248-page OECD study, The Sources and save for their own retirement will be
of Economic Growth in OECD Countries.55 The severely impaired. This threat of demoraliz-
marketing blurb for that study notes: ingly high tax rates on workers and savers is
“Growth patterns through the 1990s and the essence of the “aging crisis.” Converting
into this decade have turned received wisdom that threat into a reality by speeding up the
on its head . . . with the United States notably taxation of workers cannot solve this problem.
drawing further ahead of the field.” The CBO’s long-term budget outlook projects
OECD’s chief economist, Ignazio Visco, individual tax receipts rising to about 15 per-
writes that “one of the most important cent of GDP by the year 2050, up from about
lessons to emerge from this work is that . . . 8 percent today, assuming that progressive
excessive tax burdens distort proper resource taxes on labor and savings can and will be
allocation.”56 In particular, the OECD study tapped to fund programs heretofore financed
goes on, “high personal income tax rates can by flat-rate payroll taxes.58 There is nothing in
discourage entrepreneurship.”57 U.S. experience to suggest it would be remote-
Such microeconomic effects of tax and ly feasible to double the share of GDP collect-
spending policy can be seriously misunder- ed by taxes on individual incomes. Trying to
stood by placing undue emphasis on the gap do so would severely depress the denominator
between planned or realized tax receipts and of the ratio (GDP). Looking ahead, it is not
expenditures, that is, estimated or actual future deficits that are unsustainable, it is
budget deficits. future transfer payments from unreformed
Government purchases of real resources entitlement programs.
reduce the availability of labor, equipment,
and real property, and raise their costs to pri-
vate businesses. That is why Alesina and his Conclusions
colleagues find that countries that cut gov-
ernment spending, such as Ireland, have had Rubin, Orszag, and Sinai have offered
much faster economic growth than countries four hypotheses that purport to predict the
that pursued costly public works schemes, effects of estimated future budget deficits on
such as Japan. This “crowding out” is real, not yield curves, real interest rates, national sav- It is not future
financial. It cannot be reduced by funding ings, the current account deficit, and investor deficits that are
government consumption with taxes rather confidence. If these were not intended to
than borrowing. yield testable predictions, they would be only unsustainable, it
Government transfer payments are gener- metaphysical speculations. is future transfer
ally given only on the condition that recipi- Several of these hypotheses depend on a
ents do not work too much, save too much, highly unusual chain of casuality, such as
payments from
or plant too many crops. If productive effort requiring that deficits cause inflation to fall unreformed
or saving is even allowed by recipients of in order to raise the real interest rates, or entitlement
transfer payments, the payments are typically requiring that deficits cause short-term inter-
reduced or taxed at a higher rate, as in the est rates to fall in order to steepen the yield programs.

13
Neither actual curve. Several hypotheses are inconsistent 9. Budget of the United States Government, Fiscal Year
2005, Historical Tables (Washington: Government
nor projected with each other, or with previous versions of Printing Office, February 2004), Table 6.1,
this whole exercise in conventionality (twin www.whitehouse.gov/omb/budget/fy2005/pdf/h
budget deficits deficits theorists such as Larry Summers ist.pdf.
raise real or used to postulate that deficits made the dol-
10. Alan Reynolds, “Where the Surplus Came
lar rise, not fall). All four hypotheses are com-
nominal interest pletely inconsistent with all direct evidence
From,” Wall Street Journal, July 9, 1999, p. A14.

rates. from U.S. time series data and with evidence 11. William G. Gale and Peter R. Orszag, “The
from international comparisons. Economic Effects of Long-Term Fiscal Discipline,”
Urban-Brookings Tax Policy Center Discussion
In reality, neither actual nor projected Paper, December 17, 2002, p. 12.
budget deficits raise real or nominal interest
rates, steepen the yield curve, reduce national 12. Karl R. Popper, The Logic of Scientific Discovery
savings, cause “twin deficits,” or make the (New York: Science Editions, 1961), p. 280. See
also my comments on the epistemological short-
dollar go down or up. The logic behind such comings of the Gale-Orszag “evidence,” such as
speculations is flawed and contradictory and quoting famous people, textbooks, and the
the evidence is nonexistent. assumptions (rather than predictive value) of
econometric models, in The International Economy
symposium on this topic (Summer 2003), www.
findarticles.com/cf_dls/m2633/3_17/106423903
Notes /p1/article.jhtml.
1. Robert E. Rubin, Peter R. Orszag, and Allen
Sinai, “Sustained Budget Deficits: Longer-Run 13. Rubin, Orszag, and Sinai, p. 13.
U.S. Economic Performance and the Risk of
Financial and Fiscal Disarray,” presented at the 14. Brook, pp. 17–18.
AEA-NAEFA Joint Sessions, San Diego, January 4,
15. Rik Hafer, “The Deficit Debate,” Wall Street
2004, www.brookings.org/dybdocroot/views/pap
Journal, January 14, 2003, p. A14.
ers/orszag/20040105.pdf.
16. Brook, p. 17.
2. Lester Thurow and Laura D’Andrea Tyson,
“The Economic Black Hole,” Foreign Policy 67 17. Stephen Entin and Paul Evans, “Deficits, Tax
(Summer 1987). Cuts, Interest Rates and Investment (Part I): Do
Large Deficits Raise Interest Rates?” Institute for
3. Rubin, Orszag, and Sinai, p. 1.
Research on the Economics of Taxation, Con-
4. Rubin, Orszag, and Sinai, p. 2. gressional Advisory no.139, October 23, 2002,
ftp://ftp.iret.org/pub/ADVS-139.PDF. See also
5. Anne-Marie Brook, “Recent and Prospective Entin and Evans, “Deficits, Tax Cuts, Interest
Trends in Real Long-Term Interest Rates: Fiscal Rates and Investment (Part II): Would Financial
Policy and Other Drivers,” Organisation for Market Consequences of Tax Reduction Negate
Economic Co-operation and Development, Positive Effects on Growth?” IRET, Congressional
Economics Department Working Paper no. 367, Advisory no.140, November 8, 2002, ftp://ftp.iret.
September 29, 2003, www.olis.oecd.org/olis/2003 org/pub/ADVS-140.PDF.
doc.nsf.
18. Arturo Estrella and Frederic S. Mishkin, “The
6. Thomas Laubach, “New Evidence on the Yield Curve as a Predictor of U.S. Recessions,” in
Interest Rate Effects of Budget Deficits and Debt,” Federal Reserve Bank of New York, Current Issues
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, in Economics and Finance 2, no. 7, June 1996,
Working Papers, May 2003, p. 2, www.federalre www.lynixco.com/yield.pdf.
serve.gov/pubs/feds/200312/200312pap.pdf.
19. Alan Reynolds, “Monetary Policy by Trial and
7. Alan Reynolds, “Who Really Understands Error,” in The Supply-Side Revolution 20 Years Later,
What’s Going On With Budget Numbers?” Wall U.S. Senate, Joint Economic Committee, March
Street Journal, March 27, 1986. 2000, Figure 4, p. 17.

8. Quoted in Francis X. Cavanaugh, The Truth About 20. Alice M. Rivlin and Isabel Sawhill, “Growing
the National Debt: Five Myths and One Reality, (Boston: Deficits and Why They Matter,” in Restoring Fiscal
Harvard Business School Press, 1996), p. 14. Sanity: How to Balance the Budget, ed. Rivlin and

14
Sawhill (Washington: Brookings Institution 31. Council of Economic Advisers, Economic
Press, 2004), p. 25. Report of the President (Washington: Government
Printing Office, February 2003), Table B-32, p.
21. Rajnish Mehra and Edward C. Prescott, “The 315. The figures are for gross savings as a per-
Equity Premium Puzzle in Retrospect,” National centage of GDP.
Bureau of Economic Research, Working Paper no.
9525, February 2003, p. 52. 32. Organisation for Economic Co-operation and
Development, OECD Economic Outlook (Paris:
22. Alan Reynolds, “Do Budget Deficits Raise OECD, December 2003). See the budget and sav-
Long-Term Interest Rates?” Cato Tax and Budget ings data at www.oecd.org/dataoecd/5/51/2483
Bulletin no. 1, February 2002, www.cato.org/pubs/ 816.xls and www.oecd.org/dataoecd/5/48/24838
tbb/tbb-0202-1.pdf. 58.xls.

23. Some economists have estimated a miniscule 33. Casey B. Mulligan, “Capital, Interest and
effect of national deficits on worldwide interest Aggregate Intertemporal Substitution,” NBER
rates, which acknowledges the integrated market Working Paper no. 9373, December 2002. Some
for financial assets (though not their substitutabil- studies purporting to find no link between sav-
ity at the margin for real assets). Such estimates ings and interest rates do not even account for the
depend on the model’s assumptions. Two British fact that a rising interest rate creates a capital loss
theoreticians devised a neoclassical model in which for bondholders, making the interest rate a total-
“lower taxes and larger deficits early on result in a ly inaccurate measure of even the pretax return.
lower global rate of interest.” See Willem H. Buiter
and Anne C. Sibert, “Cross-Border Tax Externali- 34. Gerald M. Meier and Robert E. Baldwin,
ties: Are Budget Deficits Too Small?” NBER Economic Development (New York: John Wiley and
Working Paper no. 10110, November 2003. Sons, 1962), p. 340.

24. Dwight D. Eisenhower, “Annual Budget 35. “Let us suppose that the pool of savings is
Message to the Congress: Fiscal Year 1961,” fixed in size. It follows that, because more money
January 18, 1960. has to be diverted from this pool to the govern-
ment, less is available to companies for invest-
25. Herbert Stein, The Fiscal Revolution in America ment.” Tim Congdon, The Debt Threat (New York:
(Washington: American Enterprise Institute, Basil Blackwell, 1988), p. 84. This empty
1996), pp. 350, 369. metaphor of a savings “pool” suggests a stock of
something (dollar bills?); but savings is a flow. If
26. William G. Gale and Peter R. Orszag, “The the savings rate is unchanged but income rises
Economic Effects of Long-Term Fiscal Discipline,” then savings also rise.
p. 27.
36. “Soviet industrial output will match ours
27. C. Fred Bergsten, for example, presented a within three decades. And if one takes a less opti-
paper “Can the United States Afford the Tax Cuts mistic view of the relative rates of growth . . . the
of 2001?” at the American Economics Association catching-up period is shortened to two decades.”
meetings in Atlanta, January 5, 2002, www.iiee. Robert W. Campbell, Soviet Economic Power (New
com/publications/papers/bergsten0102-2.pdf. York: Houghton Mifflin, 1960), p. 194. Other
On page 10, he said: One major risk of the tax cut prominent economists in the 1960s and 1970s
legislation of 2001 is, of course, that by inducing who argued that forced savings through steep
higher long-term interest rates, it will reduce taxes and/or central planning created economic
investment.” If interest rates are now to be dis- growth included Robert Heilbroner, Lester
missed as a “red herring,” then so should such Thurow and James Tobin. They are quoted in
unsupported claims about investment being so Alan Reynolds, “International Comparisons of
sensitive to interest rates. Taxes and Government Spending,” in Rating
Global Economic Freedom, ed. S. T. Easton and M. A.
28. William G. Gale and Peter R. Orszag, “Economic Walker (Vancouver: The Fraser Institute, 1992),
Effects of Sustained Budget Deficits,” National Tax pp. 360–86.
Journal 56, no. 3 (September 2003): p. 473.
37. Alan Reynolds, “The Fiscal-Monetary Policy
29. Robert Eisner, “National Saving and Budget Mix,” Cato Journal 21, no. 2 (Fall 2001), www.
Deficits,” The Review of Economics and Statistics 76, cato.org/pubs/journal/cj21n2-11.pdf.
no. 1 (September 1994): pp. 181–86.
38. Quoted in Alan Reynolds, “So Who’s Afraid of
30. John Seater, “Ricardian Equivalence,” Journal of a Deficit?” National Review, May 14, 2001,
Economic Literature 31, no. 1 (March 1993): p. 176. www.findarticles.com/cf_0/m1282/9_53/736408

15
72/p1/article.jhtml. Budget Crisis at the Door (Washington: Urban
Institute Press, 2004), p. 24.
39. Rubin, Orszag, and Sinai, p. 1.
48. Emmanuel Saez, “Reported Incomes and
40. William G. Gale and Peter R. Orszag, “Economic Marginal Tax Rates, 1996–2000: Evidence and
Effects of Sustained Budget Deficits.” Policy Conclusions,” Tax Policy and the Economy 18
(Cambridge: MIT Press, forthcoming 2004), www.
41. Matthew Higgins and Thomas Klitgaard, nber.org/books/tpel18/saez12-2-03.pdf.
“Viewing the Current Account Deficit as a Capital
Inflow,” Federal Reserve Bank of New York, 49. Tax Foundation, “New Income Tax Data
Current Issues in Economics and Finance, December Show Greater Progressivity,” February 6, 2004,
1998, www.newyorkfed.org/research/current_ www.taxfoundation.org/prtopincome.html.
issues/ci4-13.pdf.
50. Saez, p. 38.
42. Herbert Hoover, “Message to Congress,” May
5, 1932, in State Papers and Other Public Writings of 51. Henry J. Aaron, William G. Gale and Peter R.
Herbert Hoover (New York: Doubleday, Doran & Orszag, “Meeting the Revenue Challenge,” in
Company, 1934). Restoring Fiscal Sanity: How to Balance the Budget, ed.
Rivlin and Sawhill, p. 114.
43. Quoted in Alan Reynolds, “Balanced Budget
Amendment, R.I.P.” Reason, June 1995, http://rea 52. See Robert Barro and Xavier Sala-i-Martin,
son.com/9506/reynolds.jun.shtml. Economic Growth (Cambridge: MIT Press, 2003).
For the Global Competitiveness Report, see the World
44. Ibid. Economic Forum website at www.weforum.org.

45. William G. Gale and Peter R. Orszag, “Fiscal 53. Alberto Alesina et al., “Fiscal Policy, Profits
Policy and Economic Growth: A Simple and Investment,” American Economic Review 92,
Framework,” Tax Notes, February 3, 2003, p. 759. no. 3 (June 2002).

46. William G. Gale, “Notes on Taxes, Growth, 54. Ibid., p. 572.


and Dynamic Analysis,” in The Future of American
Taxation: Tax Notes 30th Anniversary, 2003, p. 32. 55. OECD, The Sources of Economic Growth in OECD
Countries (Paris: OECD, 2003), www1.oecd.org/
47. Rudolph G. Penner and Eugene Steuerle, publications/e-book/1103011E.PDF.

Published by the Cato Institute, Policy Analysis is a regular Additional copies of Policy Analysis are $6.00 each ($3.00
series evaluating government policies and offering proposals each for five or more). To order, or for a complete listing of
for reform. Nothing in Policy Analysis should be construed as available studies, write the Cato Institute, 1000 Massachusetts
necessarily reflecting the views of the Cato Institute or as an Ave., N.W., Washington, D.C. 20001 or call toll
attempt to aid or hinder the passage of any bill before Con- free 1-800-767-1241 (8:30 a.m.-4:30 p.m. eastern
gress. Contact the Cato Institute for reprint permission. time). Fax (202) 842-3490 • www.cato.org

You might also like