You are on page 1of 8

Strategic Management Journal

Strat. Mgmt. J., 26: 873–880 (2005)


Published online in Wiley InterScience (www.interscience.wiley.com). DOI: 10.1002/smj.480

RESEARCH NOTES AND COMMENTARIES

COMMENT ON ‘INDUSTRY, CORPORATE AND


BUSINESS-SEGMENT EFFECTS AND BUSINESS
PERFORMANCE: A NON-PARAMETRIC APPROACH’
BY RUEFLI AND WIGGINS
ANITA M. McGAHAN1 * and MICHAEL E. PORTER2
1
School of Management, Boston University, and Institute for Strategy and Competi-
tiveness, Harvard University, Boston, Massachusetts, U.S.A.
2
Graduate School of Business Administration, Harvard University, Boston, Mas-
sachusetts, U.S.A.

The Strategic Management Journal has published a series of articles on variation in business-
segment performance. This comment addresses the insights and potential sources of confusion in
the decomposition literature, with a particular focus on Ruefli and Wiggins (2003). We review the
basic purpose of descriptive decomposition techniques and argue that they offer no information
about the drivers of business performance or the mechanisms by which performance is generated.
The techniques in the literature do not rely on ceteris paribus assumptions or a mapping between
managerial influence and corporate effects. The estimated effects of industry, business segments,
and corporate parents need not be independent to be modeled using variance decomposition.
The comment also focuses on the distortions in estimates that can arise when the underlying
sample of data does not represent the population accurately. Copyright  2005 John Wiley &
Sons, Ltd.

The Strategic Management Journal has published by the decomposition literature on the variation
a series of articles on variation in business-segment in business performance. This comment addresses
performance, including Rumelt (1991), Roquebert, these potential sources of confusion not only to put
Philips, and Westfall (1996), McGahan and Porter Ruefli and Wiggins (2003) in perspective, but also
(1997), Brush and Bromiley (1997), Brush, Bromi- to clarify our understanding of the entire line of
ley, and Hendrickx (1999), Bowman and Helfat literature.
(2001), and Hawawini, Subramanian, and Verdin At the root of many of the problems is a mis-
(2003). The most recent is Ruefli and Wiggins understanding of the nature of variance decom-
(2003). position itself. The technique has been used to
Ruefli and Wiggins (2003) contains assertions describe industry, corporate-parent and business-
and methods that may lead to unfortunate con- specific influences on performance. It offers no
fusion in the field regarding the insights offered information about the drivers of business perfor-
mance or about the mechanisms by which per-
Keywords: corporate performance; sustainability; prof- formance is generated. In particular, the tech-
itability; industry structure; business strategy nique offers no information about how managerial
*Correspondence to: Anita M. McGahan, School of Manage-
ment, Boston University, 595 Commonwealth Ave., Boston, MA action affects the influence of industry, corporate-
02215, U.S.A. E-mail: amcgahan@bu.edu parent, or business-specific effects on performance.

Copyright  2005 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Received 20 April 2004
Final revision received 15 March 2005
874 A. M. McGahan and M. E. Porter

Overlooking this point leads to a series of unfortu- the researcher to explore a theoretical relationship
nate and fundamental problems of interpretation. between an explanatory variable and performance
We offer the following comments in response outcomes without modeling the entirety of the
to specific points that have been made in the system. In no article of which we are aware in this
literature. body of research is the ceteris paribus assumption
evoked. The purpose of this literature is simply
1. The mutatis mutandis vs. ceteris paribus to describe the variance in performance without
assumptions are not relevant to the decompo- any claim about underlying causal relationships
sition of variance. between the effects.
The variance-components analysis (VCA)
A central argument in Ruefli and Wiggins (2003) is method (discussed further below and called ‘com-
that the results of studies on the decomposition of ponents of variance’ and ‘COV’ in McGahan and
variance were designed in a ceteris paribus (i.e., Porter, 1997) relies on an assumption of ‘random
‘all else equal’) context. Their principal point is effects,’ which has a specific technical meaning
that the research in this line does not account for that is often misconstrued. The technical assump-
responses to the emergence of particular effects. tion is that the processes that relate various effects
For example, they suggest that rivals may be able are not systematically tied to the levels of the
to elevate their own performance and hence the effects. As we argue below, this assumption is
industry average by imitating the strategic action of not unreasonable even in context of the Ruefli and
a high-performing firm. This process of imitation Wiggins critique since imitation and other compet-
induces a positive relationship between a firm- itive action may either raise or lower performance.
specific effect and an industry effect. Similarly, The VCA method was adopted only because of
efforts to diminish commitment to a poorly per- computational constraints that were broken by the
forming industry could induce a negative relation- mid 1990s. As a result, the VCA method has
ship between a firm-specific effect and an industry not been used by most current researchers, who
effect. have relied instead on other methods that do not
Ruefli and Wiggins (2003) use mutatis mutandis assume random effects (see McGahan and Porter,
nomenclature to motivate their analysis. Mutatis 2002). Furthermore, the assumption of random
mutandis (i.e., ‘the necessary changes having been effects under the VCA method is so specialized
made’) evokes the notion of a system response to that it should not be confounded with the broader
the variable in question. Ruefli and Wiggins (2003) agenda of the literature as a whole, which is sim-
suggest that their results account for managerial ply to report on variation in performance among
responses that influence the performance of rivals the population of businesses. This agenda requires
over time via improvements in performance rank- no restrictive assumptions about the processes that
ing of firms or industries. They argue that changes give rise to variance in performance.
in the performance rankings of industries, corpo- Thus, the distinction between the ceteris paribus
rations, and business units may be influenced by and mutatis mutandis assumptions, while relevant
managerial action, and that this action should be to theoretical models and normative empirics, has
modeled explicitly because it carries the poten- nothing to do with the descriptive empirical anal-
tial to dampen differences between firms. Vari- ysis at hand, even when variance is estimated
ance decomposition is inferior, according to Ruefli using VCA.
and Wiggins, because it rests on the assumptions
of ceteris paribus: ‘managerial activities . . . [rep- 2. Many factors other than managerial influence
resent] a possible deviation from an assumption can give rise to industry, corporate, or business-
of ceteris paribus, and thus a compromise of the specific effects.
conditions required for valid application and inter-
pretation of variance decomposition techniques’ Ruefli and Wiggins correctly suggest on pages
(Ruefli and Wiggins, 2003: 865). 864 and 865 of their article that managerial action
This criticism by Ruefli and Wiggins (2003) is may give rise to corporate, industry, or business-
not valid because the ceteris paribus assumption is specific effects. With this suggestion they depart
not evoked in the literature on the decomposition from prior authors, including Schmalensee (1985),
of variance. A ceteris paribus assumption allows who incorrectly associated only corporate effects
Copyright  2005 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Strat. Mgmt. J., 26: 873–880 (2005)
Research Notes and Commentaries 875

with the influence of managers. Ruefli and Wig- governmental regulation, and managerial action
gins (2003) are not entirely consistent, however. In all contributed to a low industry effect for the
their abstract and conclusion they associate man- property and casualty insurance industry in the
agerial influence exclusively with corporate effects wake of Hurricane Andrew. Creativity and a disci-
and claim that their findings on corporate effects plined research program—both of which may be
‘provide . . . evidence that managers can have a the direct result of management policy—can give
strategic influence on business performance’ (Rue- rise to a high corporate effect as in the pharma-
fli and Wiggins, 2003: 861). While management ceutical industry of the 1990s. Thus, managerial
certainly influences performance, the influence of intervention (as well as other forces) can give rise
management is not exclusively reflected in corpo- to either high or low effects.
rate effects. In sum, managerial action may be associated
Managerial action can influence any class of with high effects, low effects, high variation in
effects in a decomposition of variance. For exam- a class, or low variation in a class. Hence, no
ple, Bill Gates has influenced the structure of information can be gleaned from variation in
the operating systems software industry and Jef- performance—or from the estimated levels of
frey Katzenberg created a business-specific effect effects—about the influence of management.
by leading Disney’s film division to new heights
between 1984 and 1994. Of course, manage- 3. Assessing changes in performance cannot gen-
rial action can also generate a corporate effect erate information about the causes of the effects.
(Jack Welch was instrumental to GE’s performance
while he was CEO). Conversely, corporate effects On page 865 of their article, Ruefli and Wig-
may arise from forces other than managerial influ- gins note that ‘this area of strategic management
ence: macroeconomic fluctuations, governmental research would be better served by stepping back,
decisions, competitor action, and many others. For selecting fresh methodologies to employ, and then
example, a general increase in interest rates could if necessary, attempting to revisit the relationships
lead to capital-budgeting restrictions within a cor- between levels of organization and performance.’
poration that affect all divisions (and thus generate We agree entirely with this claim (and made a
a corporate-parent effect for the corporation). similar call for new research in McGahan and
Ruefli and Wiggins (2003) go a step further to Porter, 2002). Our work on the persistence of
suggest, incorrectly, that the findings of prior stud- profits (McGahan and Porter, 1997, 2003; McGa-
ies on corporate, industry, and business-specific han, 1999a; Furman and McGahan, 2002) offers
effects should be re-evaluated because the low complementary insights into many of the conclu-
importance of a class of effects (such as corporate sions in Ruefli and Wiggins (2003). The concep-
effects) may be related to successful managerial tual, technical, and methodological challenges are
intervention. Their argument is that managers may considerable and yet we agree that the study of
be so effective at competing that they may perva- persistence carries great potential for delivering
sively dampen variation within the class; in other important stylized facts about profitability patterns.
words, the capabilities of managers to influence a Ruefli and Wiggins (2003) claim to make pro-
class of effects may not be revealed in variation gress on this new research agenda through their
within the class. investigation of relationships between changes in
The problem with this logic is that there are the relative ranking of business-segment profitabil-
many other influences besides managerial interven- ity and the ranking in prior years of industry, cor-
tion that can give rise to effects of each type. Just porate, and business-specific effects. They argue
as managerial intervention may cause a particu- that changes in rankings motivate managers to
lar effect (or variation in a class of effects) to be act in ways that would subsequently influence the
low, other forces such as governmental regulation, organization’s performance ranking. Hence they
buyer behavior, natural catastrophes, macroeco- interpret consistency in the rankings as evidence
nomic events, and competitive dynamics also may that managers have successfully controlled their
cause an effect (or variation in a class) to be low. businesses and no longer seek to disrupt the sta-
Furthermore, managerial intervention (and these tus quo.
other forces) also may cause the effects or varia- This claim and interpretation are problematic. It
tion in a class of effects to be high. Bad weather, is impossible to infer the cause of persistence in
Copyright  2005 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Strat. Mgmt. J., 26: 873–880 (2005)
876 A. M. McGahan and M. E. Porter

performance from the fact that persistence occurs. In sum, there is no connection between the
(Later, we will also argue that persistence is not extent of managerial influence, the degree of vari-
properly modeled by rank in the first place.) Per- ance, and the rate of persistence in the effects. The
sistence may be due to fixed resources, consistent ordinal methodology in Ruefli and Wiggins (2003)
industry structure, financial anomalies, price con- does not yield information about whether manage-
trols, or many other influences that endure. In rial or non-managerial explanations are valid for
short, many factors other than managerial inter- why the performance occurs and/or persists.
vention can generate persistence in rankings.
Furthermore, managerial control does not neces- 5. Variance is an attractive and appropriate
sarily cause persistence. Through creativity, entre- method of measuring performance differences.
preneurial insight, process innovation, and many
other actions managers can induce new effects,
The decomposition of variance to identify industry,
cause rankings to change, and enhance overall
corporate, and business-specific effects is attractive
variation (this point is discussed further below).
because it is simple and statistically robust. The
In sum, reliable inferences about the causes of
use of variance has been criticized, particularly
persistence cannot be generated from an analysis
by Brush and Bromiley (1997), because it gives
that only documents whether or not persistence
weight to observations that are far from the mean.
occurred.
Brush and Bromiley (1997) are concerned that
an analysis of variance on a sample from the
4. An increase in managerial influence does not population can lead to incorrect inferences about
necessarily dampen variation in performance, the population’s characteristics, particularly when
and may increase variation in performance. the population’s characteristics are systemically
determined.
Ruefli and Wiggins (2003) make the related argu- In McGahan and Porter (1997, 1999, 2002,
ment that managerial control leads to (a) dimin- 2003) and McGahan (1999a, 1999b), we strive to
ished levels of poor performance and/or (b) dimin- represent the population of firms rather than a sam-
ished variability in performance. They argue that ple to mitigate this concern. In no sense are we
a manager’s incentive is to enhance positive influ- simulating the population’s characteristics through
ences and dampen negative influences. Yet it is repeated inferences from a sample as in the exam-
incorrect that the presence of this incentive dimin- ple from genetics cited in Brush and Bromiley
ishes poor performance or diminishes variability (1997). When the decomposition of variance is
in performance. Poor management can exacerbate run on the population, far-flung observations are
poor performance just as good management can actual data points that are of inherent interest. Our
enhance good performance. When investment is purpose is to describe variation in the population
required to generate future return, even good man- without imputing causality on why any of the par-
agers may have an incentive to take actions that ticular effects arise.
temporarily depress profitability, and thus good Ruefli and Wiggins (2003: 865) go further to
management can lead to poor performance. assert that variance analysis is inappropriate for
Even when managers enhance high performance describing the performance characteristics of the
and neutralize low performance, it is ambiguous population of firms because of the importance of
whether this success would dampen the difference learning and feedback: ‘Recognizing the context in
between the best and worst performer. Further- which industry and corporate-level factors affect
more, managerial success in improving the tra- performance as one in which learning and feed-
jectory of performance could either increase or back loops are important renders discussion of the
decrease variability around the trajectory. (Real operational details of the use of techniques such as
options theory suggests that improvements in the VCA analysis, as historically applied, moot.’ We
trajectory are likely to be associated with increased agree that no inferences about managerial action
variation.) As a result, success by managers at can be drawn from a study of the variance of the
enhancing the positive contributions of an effect effects. Ironically, Ruefli and Wiggins later make
may increase the explanatory power of the effect incorrect inferences about the influence of man-
rather than dampen it. agerial action on changes in performance ranking.
Copyright  2005 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Strat. Mgmt. J., 26: 873–880 (2005)
Research Notes and Commentaries 877

We disagree that learning and feedback make 6. The decomposition of variance does not involve
variance decomposition (and its operational detail) any per se assumptions about the independence
moot. The purpose of variance decomposition is to of the effects, and the non-parametric method
describe the system, which may incorporate learn- does not involve fewer assumptions than vari-
ing, feedback, inertia, managerial action, and many ance decomposition.
other influences, mechanisms and processes. While
a study of variance decomposition yields no infor- Ruefli and Wiggins (2003) assert that their ‘non-
mation about the processes of learning and of feed- parametric’ method for analyzing performance dif-
back within the system, it does generate descriptive ferences is superior to other methods that have
information about the system as a whole that is been used in this literature because it contains
valuable. fewer restrictive assumptions than a decomposi-
We also disagree that VCA is an inappropriate tion of variance. The ordinal technique and focus
method for decomposing variance. This technique, on persistence in their paper are designed to gen-
which was originally motivated to lower computa- erate information on the relationships between the
tional requirements, was adapted by Schmalensee estimated effects. In particular, Ruefli and Wiggins
(1985) and incorporates an assumption that the (2003) explore how changes in the ranking of the
observed effects are each randomly generated. This performance of a business segment are related to
means that there is no relationship between (i) the its prior rank and the prior rank of its industry and
sizes of the industry, corporate, and business- corporate parent.
specific effects on an observation and (ii) the fre- Ruefli and Wiggins (2003) criticize previous
quency with which effects are generated and their studies by arguing that they involve restrictive
sizes. For example, a business segment with a assumptions. They are most concerned with
high industry effect is equally likely to have a the assumption of random effects under VCA,
high or low corporate effect; and furthermore, any which we have already discussed, but they
particular business segment is just as likely to fail to acknowledge the important contributions
have a high industry effect as any other business of Rumelt (1991) and McGahan and Porter
segment. Brush and Bromiley’s (1997) criticism, (1997, 1999, 2002, 2003), which report on
which is incorporated by reference in Ruefli and results obtained through ANOVA under the non-
Wiggins (2003), is that the effects are not randomly restrictive assumptions of ordinary-least squares.
conferred and that relationships among them may In particular, McGahan and Porter (2002)
arise. This is indeed a valid concern that has been implements an ANOVA that does not assume,
tested directly by McGahan and Porter (2002) constrain, or rule out any form of relationship
and that has been discussed extensively by prior between the estimated effects.
authors such as Bowman and Helfat (2001). Ruefli and Wiggins (2003) are incorrect in sug-
It is worthwhile to reflect on the fact that the gesting that their approach involves fewer assump-
original VCA (or ‘COV’) by Schmalensee (1985) tions than variance decomposition techniques. The
did not depart from historical precedent and was ordinal approach in Ruefli and Wiggins (2003)
entirely appropriate for this context. The tech- does not incorporate the same assumption as VCA
nique of VCA identifies the first-order influence about random effects, but it does incorporate many
of the classes of effects and apportions vari- assumptions about competitive processes. The fol-
ance between them. Without additional informa- lowing is a partial list of them:
tion, it is not unreasonable to make a first-order
approximation of the decomposition of variance • Relative ranking in the performance of organi-
under the assumption that the relationships are zations, industries, and corporations stimulates
randomly conferred. In particular, purposeful man- processes that affect the subsequent rank of
agerial action can lead to either improvements or organizations.
deterioration in any of the estimated effects. There • The processes that influence rank do not arise
is nothing about the application of the VCA tech- randomly, but rather are systematically related
nique to the population of firms that departs from to prior ranking.
historical precedent or that makes variance decom- • The processes that influence rank take effect
position moot because of learning or feedback. quickly (i.e., within the time span of this study).
Copyright  2005 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Strat. Mgmt. J., 26: 873–880 (2005)
878 A. M. McGahan and M. E. Porter

• The processes are dominated by managerial investor valuations than businesses with better per-
influence. formance, but are less likely to improve their per-
• Managerial control leads to a dampening of formance than businesses with better ex ante per-
variability in performance ranking over time. formance.
• Managers do not intentionally take actions that Ruefli and Wiggins (2003) emphasize that there
could diminish short-run performance ranking. are significant differences in the mean performance
of the firms in their categories. There are also sig-
nificant differences in the mean performance of
Thus, Ruefli and Wiggins’ (2003) methodology
organizations classified using other categorization
does not incorporate fewer restrictive assumptions
schemes. Thus, there is nothing about the Rue-
than the prior variance decomposition studies. The fli and Wiggins (2003) approach that leads to a
decomposition of variance does not impose any unique, superior classification.
functional form on the relationships between the Ruefli and Wiggins (2003) criticize prior clas-
estimated effects, but simply describes the pop- sification schemes for failing to assure that sta-
ulation statistically. Studying variance is analo- tistical differences arise between the performance
gous to calculating the mean or even counting characteristics of firms that are near the border-
the number of members of a population. There line between the categories. In other words, they
is no stipulation about the relationships between argue that similar organizations are arbitrarily clas-
the members of the population in simply count- sified into the top half or bottom half of per-
ing them, in calculating their mean characteris- formers based on only small differences between
tics, or in calculating the variance around the their characteristics and the median. Yet the Rue-
mean. In fact, there are no ‘restrictive assump- fli and Wiggins (2003) schema raises the same
tions’ at all associated with the calculation of vari- issue except when ‘modal’ firms are excluded
ance. from the analysis. The cost of this exclusion
is high because excluding these firms from the
7. There is no statistically valid reason to focus on analysis makes the results unintuitive and means
three categories of performance instead of two, that the sample does not represent the popula-
four, or any other number; the ‘non-parametric’ tion.
approach in Ruefli and Wiggins (2003) omits a The ordinal ranking of data based on per-
significant amount of information and does not formance is necessary in the Ruefli and Wig-
represent the persistence of effects accurately. gins (2003) analysis to categorize observations as
‘superior,’ ‘modal,’ or ‘inferior.’ Ruefli and Wig-
gins (2003) then examine whether particular busi-
Ruefli and Wiggins (2003) assert that prior studies ness segments are classified in the same category
on persistence such as McGahan and Porter (1999, over time to support their conclusions about the
2003) and Mueller (1986) arbitrarily impose a dis- persistence of industry and corporate effects. This
tinction between high and low performers by cate- approach is fundamentally inaccurate because an
gorizing observations into just two groups, which observation with exactly the same level of prof-
is inferior to their choice of three categories. Our itability year after year may be categorized differ-
view is that either approach is justifiable. How- ently in each year. For example, an industry with
ever, it is misleading to suggest that three cat- exactly the same performance level in 2 years can
egories are somehow better than two categories. be classified in different categories just because
The choice to stratify the population by category of differences in the other industries. Thus, the
can generate descriptive statistics that yield impor- approach can lead to the inaccurate conclusion that
tant insights about how competition operates. For performance is not persistent when in truth it stays
example, McGahan (1999b) uses four categories exactly the same.
of performance to show how ex ante differences In sum, we endorse the use of multiple cate-
in the levels of industry, corporate, and business- gories of performance to investigate intertemporal
specific effects are related to ex post performance. relationships. Yet Ruefli and Wiggins (2003) mis-
Furman and McGahan (2002) break the popula- lead the reader by reporting that their own catego-
tion into 10 categories and show that businesses rization is more robust than others. The approach
that rank in the bottom 10 percent carry greater in the prior literature on the persistence of effects
Copyright  2005 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Strat. Mgmt. J., 26: 873–880 (2005)
Research Notes and Commentaries 879

(i.e., by Mueller, 1986, Waring, 1996, and McGa- because diversified firms tend to perform close
han and Porter, 1999, 2003) uses detailed infor- to the overall mean. Including only diversified
mation on actual levels of performance rather than firms lowers total variation and makes it appear
only rankings, and therefore has advantages over that the diversified firms account for a larger por-
the ordinal ranking. By examining the rate by tion.
which performance persists (regardless of whether
ordinal ranking changes), this prior literature yields
intuitive information about substantive changes ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS
over time.
Thanks to Juan Alcacer, Nick Argyres, Jay Bar-
8. The more aggregated the industry definitions ney, David Hoopes, Jill Hough, Brian Silverman,
(i.e., 3- or 4-digit industry effects), the more and Robert Wiggins for comments. The views
likely that industry effects are obscured. expressed here should not be construed as theirs.
McGahan thanks BUILDE, the SRC, and the
Ruefli and Wiggins aggregate their data to the 3- Dean’s Office at Boston University for financial
digit level despite the availability of Compustat support.
data at the 4-digit level ‘. . .to yield a sample size
comparable to prior studies. . .’ (Ruefli and Wig-
gins, 2003: 867). Aggregation of this type obscures REFERENCES
the true industry effects in the population by sys-
tematically enhancing intra-industry variation and Bowman EH, Helfat CE. 2001. Does corporate strat-
thus driving estimated industry effects toward the egy matter? Strategic Management Journal 22(1):
sample mean. As a result, the variance of esti- 1–23.
Brush TH, Bromiley P. 1997. What does a small
mated industry effects is artificially low, and the corporate effect mean? A variance-components
contribution of industry effects to total variation simulation of corporate and business effects. Strategic
is underestimated. Furthermore, this distortion of Management Journal 18(10): 825–835.
the estimated industry effects also may inflate the Brush TM, Bromiley P, Hendrickx M. 1999. The relative
estimated rate of industry persistence because of influence of industry and corporation on business seg-
ment performance: an alternative estimate. Strategic
artificially dampened intertemporal variation in the Management Journal 20(6): 519–547.
estimated industry effects. Furman JL, McGahan AM. 2002. Turnarounds. Man-
agerial and Decision Economics 23: (June–August):
9. Using only diversified firms distorts industry 283–300.
effects significantly and inflates corporate Hawawini G, Subramanian V, Verdin P. 2003. Is perfor-
effects. mance driven by industry or firm-specific factors? A
new look at the evidence. Strategic Management Jour-
nal 24(1): 1–16.
Our final comment is not specifically applicable McGahan AM. 1999a. The performance of U.S.
to Ruefli and Wiggins (2003), although it is fun- corporations: 1981–1994. Journal of Industrial
damentally important to a correct interpretation Economics 47(4): 373–398.
of the results in this literature. Roquebert et al. McGahan AM. 1999b. Competition, strategy, and busi-
ness performance: 1981–1997. California Manage-
(1996) introduced a practice into the literature that ment Review 41(3): 74–101.
has been endorsed by Bowman and Helfat (2002): McGahan AM, Porter ME. 1997. How much does
they reported results on a sample of diversified industry matter really? Strategic Management Journal ,
firms rather than on the entire population of all Summer Special Issue 18: 15–30.
publicly traded firms. This restriction significantly McGahan AM, Porter ME. 1999. The persistence of
shocks to profitability. Review of Economics and
distorts the influence of each class of effects. To Statistics 81(1): 143–153.
see this, it is essential to understand that firms with McGahan AM, Porter ME. 2002. What do we know
performance far from the mean tend to be single- about variance in accounting profitability. Manage-
segment businesses, and that the industries that ment Science 48(7): 834–851.
host single-segment businesses also tend to host McGahan AM, Porter ME. 2003. The emergence and sus-
tainability of abnormal profits. Strategic Organization
diversified firms. By excluding the single-business 1(1): 79–108.
firms, total variance is diminished significantly and Mueller DC. 1986. Profits in the Long Run. Cambridge
estimated corporate effects are artificially inflated University Press: Cambridge, U.K.
Copyright  2005 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Strat. Mgmt. J., 26: 873–880 (2005)
880 A. M. McGahan and M. E. Porter

Roquebert JA, Philips RL, Westfall PA. 1996. Markets Rumelt R. 1991. How much does industry matter? Strate-
versus management: what ‘drives’ profitability. gic Management Journal 12(3): 167–185.
Strategic Management Journal 17(8): 653–664. Schmalensee R. 1985. Do markets differ much?.
Ruefli TW, Wiggins RR. 2003. Industry, corporate and American Economic Review 75: 341–351.
business-segment effects and business performance: Waring G. 1996. Industry differences in the persistence
a non-parametric approach. Strategic Management of firm-specific returns. American Economic Review
Journal 24(9): 861–879. 86(5): 1253–1265.

Copyright  2005 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Strat. Mgmt. J., 26: 873–880 (2005)

You might also like