You are on page 1of 3

COMMENTARY

Rescue Package for Power Discoms


Continuing with Mismanagement
Surya P Sethi

A mismanaged energy sector is at the heart of Indias scal woes. The 2012 package for nancial restructuring of power sector losses exemplies such mismanagement and merely recycles a 2002 package that did not solve any problem.

Surya P Sethi (spsethi09@yahoo.com) is former principal advisor, power and energy, Planning Commission, New Delhi.
Economic & Political Weekly EPW

bout 75% of Indians either lack access to any form of commercial energy for household use or have limited access to the same, well below levels in several low-income comparators. We continue to subsidise food, health, education, and shelter and fund programmes aimed at empowering the deprived, especially women and the girl child. The need for these subsidies and empowerment schemes would have greatly reduced if we had succeeded in providing modern commercial energy to all Indian households. Adequate access to affordable modern cooking energy and electricity would have improved health and education, especially among women and girls (by relieving them from the daily drudgery of collecting biomass and exposure to unhealthy chullahs); improved and developed skills; raised productivity; and provided alternate livelihoods. Most importantly it would have improved the efcacy of some of the subsidy programmes, thereby empowering the deprived and reducing their dependence on subsidies. One does not have to be a high-ying economist to comprehend the positive impact on human development and consequent scal stability both at the state and central levels through a lowering of multiple subsidy burdens. The complete bankruptcy of our energy sectors brain trust is evident from the fact that the same bunch of experts who had designed the failed 2002 onetime settlement of state electricity board dues amounting to some Rs 40,000 crore are behind the 2012 Financial Restructuring of State Distribution Company Dues totalling roughly Rs 2 lakh crore! I hope that these much acclaimed economists will at least now realise that merely naming a loss restructuring scheme one-time settlement does not stop the losses from recurring.
vol xlix no 4

I had exposed the shortcomings of the 2002 one-time settlement scheme to its creators and predicted that it will strike back with much greater ferocity in less than 10 years. And I predict, again, that the proposed nancial restructuring of state discoms will buy breathing space through dressing up of the balance sheets of the banks who have funded the current losses; but it will come back to haunt us as an even bigger problem within ve years. The proposed nancial restructuring of state discoms suffers from all of the shortcomings of its predecessor as it (a) simply converts half of the bank loans to interest bearing tax-free bonds guaranteed by the same scally strained governments that own the bankrupt state utilities while paying lip service to scal prudence; (b) reschedules the balance debt of the discoms and attempts to incentivise compliance through an inadequate trickle of new funds attached to a zillion impractical and unenforceable conditions; and, most importantly, (c) demonstrates little understanding of the underlying malaise thereby leaving the real problems unaddressed. As in 2002, a serious nancial restructuring exercise is thus transformed once again into the favourite bureaucratic sport of kicking the can down the road. Attaching conditionalities that are unenforceable and impractical in the prevailing political economy to key elements of the scheme merely provides a camouage of due diligence to the reality of bureaucratic ignorance and incompetence. Mismatched Risk and Reward Structure The rst thing that should strike any serious power sector professional is that all central public sector units (CPSUs) that are primarily engaged in generation and high voltage transmission are highly protable, as are the CPSUs and private sector companies that provide fuel, equipment and services to the power sector. Similarly, transporting fuel for the power sector is also a highly protable enterprise. The Power Finance Corporation and Rural Electrication Corporation, the dedicated lenders to the power sector, are AAA rated nancial institutions. The private sector bulk power producers
17

january 25, 2014

COMMENTARY

and private distributors (that serve a few cities) are, by and large, also doing well. The sector is thus rich for all stakeholders except for the loss-making state discoms that are mandated to service the end users and actually generate bulk of the cash ow that delivers the returns to all the other participants in the sector detailed in the previous paragraph. Another anomaly, explained in greater detail in the following section, that should strike those at the helm is that the generation and transmission companies owned by the state governments do not enjoy the guaranteed regulated returns enjoyed by CPSUs and private players active in these elds and are just permitted to keep their heads above water by the state regulatory agencies. This siphoning of cash from the state-owned utilities that were once held as models for the developing world by the World Bank has left them sick and incapable of delivering their respective mandates. The scally strapped state governments who are answerable to the end-consumers are left holding the baby. Truth is that every central scheme or central government-driven bailout package merely attempts to preserve this unsustainable risk and reward structure. Uncompetitive Bulk Tariffs and Uninformed Regulation The Electricity Act 2003 sought to create a competitive power market with transparent competition in every element of its value chain, operating under an independent and informed regulatory regime. This has not happened. A measure of this failure is the fact that average bulk power prices at the nine major US electricity hubs ranged between 2.3 and 4.7 cents/kilowatt-hour (kWh) in 2012 whereas the price of bulk power in India averaged 6.5 cents/kWh in 2012. Now, even if the distribution sector in India was as efcient as that in the US with large paying loads at the end of each line, average retail tariffs in India would need to be 25% to 30% higher, in the very least, because of higher bulk tariffs all else being the same. Thus, Indian consumers with average per capita income of less than 8% of their US counterparts, in purchasing parity terms, must pay up to 30% more for their electricity to ensure viability of the
18

power sector in India! Truth is that the Indian distribution sector cannot be as efcient as the US system given our low level of consumption and the prole of our loads. So, if we want a sustainable power sector with the currently prevailing bulk power prices, Indias average retail tariffs would need to be even higher. This is clearly unsustainable. The above state of affairs has come to pass despite the fact that coal, which accounts for over 70% of our power generation, is sold at a discount to its true economic value at the pithead. This low realisation not only results in lower royalties for the coal-bearing states but also encourages mining practices that are actually destroying our most abundant though limited domestic energy resource. The sad truth is that the prevailing policy and regulatory regime governing various elements of the electricity value chain encourages uncompetitive bulk power tariffs that are continuing to rise to even higher levels of unsustainability. We have failed to create an efcient and well-regulated power sector built upon a foundation of transparent competitive markets for all inputs and outputs across each element of the electricity value chain. Unlike their compatriots worldwide who regulate markets, Indian regulators are primarily attempting to regulate the government and government-owned corporations. The Indian power sector regulatory framework grants the worlds highest level of post-tax returns to the shareholders of power sector utilities. These high equity returns are currently guaranteed for the CPSUs who were covered by the tripartite agreement that served as the backbone of the 2002 one-time settlement scheme. These returns primarily support highly inefcient CPSUs and a non-competitive private sector under a cost plus regime that allows mandated recovery of all approved costs. The regulatory regime enforced by the Central Electricity Regulatory Commission (CERC) for these select entities also applies legally to the state generation and transmission utilities. However, given the pressures that state regulatory agencies face in keeping consumer tariffs within reasonable limits they, at best, allow full recovery costs to the state-owned generation and transmission

companies and permit the state distribution utilities to book huge losses. Raising tariffs to levels that allow identical high returns promised under the prevailing regulatory regime even to the state-owned utilities is all the more difcult under the prevailing tariff regime that is riddled with cross-subsidies. The customers that fund the cross-subsidies are already paying among the highest tariffs in the world. Raising their currently unsustainable tariffs further will only raise the reward for theft of electricity, thus boosting this free enterprise while driving electricity even further beyond the reach of the bottom half of my fellow Indians. Even where power generation projects are awarded on a competitive basis, the concessions signed are, knowingly or unknowingly, saddled with so many inrmities that they are often renegotiated or exceptions are made, resulting in effective burdens on the sector that go way beyond the tariffs bid out by the competitors. Such poorly structured concessions/contracts considerably increase the scope for crony capitalism and rent extraction. Misdirected Resources The facts highlighted here have, over the years, resulted in disproportionately high investments in generation, less than the technically required level of matching investment in transmission and an almost complete neglect of essential investments in distribution beyond the simple expansion of the system. Any power sector expert should know that in India, the power distribution segment requires more than the normative level of investment typical of a more industrialised society. This is so because: (a) the combined load of all households in a typical Indian village is less than the load of a single middle-class home in the suburban US; (b) even the paying industrial and commercial loads are relatively much smaller than similar loads in more advanced countries; (c) the tariff regime is riddled with cross-subsidies requiring separation of feeders and metering for effective management and control; and (d) there is an overall shortage of power and peculiar pressures of load management given the realities of our political economy. However, even normative
vol xlix no 4
EPW Economic & Political Weekly

january 25, 2014

COMMENTARY

levels of distribution investment have gone missing since independence. The distribution sub-sector that, today, needs the maximum attention is totally unable to support such investments. A few states have made such investments despite their scal pressures but even they need to do more. However, they are unable to generate the required surpluses. The tariff increases and efciency gains at the state utilities primarily guarantee the protected returns of bloated CPSUs and the private sector both of whom have gradually raised their stake in the sector and are, today, the dominant force because of being rewarded selectively with the highest regulated returns in the world. All this is at the cost of the state utilities charged with the primary responsibility for servicing end users of electricity but progressively rendered unable to do so because of a misguided policy and regulatory regime. All of the above is further compounded by the poor governance that aficts both the central and the state public sector units engaged in the power sector with the state-owned units being relatively worse. Poor vision, poor planning and procurement practices, high degree of political interference in all commercial

decisions and human resource management, and, above all, the lucrative arbitrage offered by a tariff regime that ranges from free power to power priced at rates not charged anywhere else in the world has led to a grossly inefcient and distorted sector wherein available data is completely unreliable and doctored to obfuscate massive corruption, poor productivity and a culture of mediocrity. In Conclusion I have primarily highlighted the power sector issues here within the context of the proposed nancial restructuring of the dues of the state discoms and the broader concerns of scal stability both at the centre and the state levels. The distortions in the oil and gas sector and the coal sector are no less potent in threatening Indias scal stability and undermine our attempts to provide even basic levels of energy access to our people. A fact that might come as a surprise to our elitist planners, but best reects our loss of touch with the reality of India, is that traditional biomass together with the animal and human draught energy constitutes the single largest source of energy in India by far. We put out an erroneous guestimate

of how much traditional biomass we use as a nation year after year in our Plan documents and we are blissfully ignorant about the extent of animal and human draught energy that powers the worlds third or fourth largest economy. Those who tell us that nuclear energy is the answer to Indias energy woes are simply fooling themselves and the people of this country. I can safely say that at least till 2050 and possibly till even later, that is not even remotely likely. The Indian electricity and energy sectors are simply unsustainable in their current form. Schemes that tinker around the edges while preserving the current policy and regulatory superstructure provide limited policy space. Fiscal stability and our promise of basic energy access to our people demands a more comprehensive and a more serious rethink. The rst step in that direction is to get rid of the vested interests that are advising the government on key policy initiatives. These are the same people who have brought us to the current abyss. They benet from preserving the status quo. The honorable young and articulate power minister and the Fourteenth Finance Commission will do well to take note.

Climate Change in Himachal


Evidence from Kullu Region
Mohit Kapoor, Abdul Shaban

Temperatures are rising in Kullu in Himachal Pradesh where farmers are dependent on the rains for agriculture. This article uses meteorological data to provide evidence of gradual climate change in the region that might affect livelihoods.
Mohit Kapoor (kapoormohit4@gmail.com) is at the School of Development Studies, Tata Institute of Social Sciences, Mumbai. Abdul Shaban is with the School of Development Studies, Tata Institute of Social Sciences, Mumbai.
Economic & Political Weekly EPW

number of studies provide evidence of changes in local climate and the effects these changes have on people and economies across the world. Studies on the Himalayan region (Ranbir et al 2009) and perception of people in these regions also show a change in climatic variables (Vedwan and Rohodes 2001). It has been observed that a change in climatic variables in various parts of the Himalayan belt has affected agricultural activities in the region as well as livelihoods. An attempt has been made in this article to look into the local-level climate change by analysing climatic variables in the Kullu district
vol xlix no 4

of Himachal Pradesh, a small district in the western Himalayan region. The district is situated between 310 20-320 25 N latitude and 760 56-770 52 E longitude and topographically is rugged mountain and a transitional zone between the Lower and Greater Himalayas. The altitude of the district varies between 1,000m and 6,000m. The general climate of Kullu is cold, dry with average rainfall around 800 mm. It receives its major rainfall from July to September. Kullu is one of the most rural districts of India as about 90% of the population of the district lives in villages (Census of India 2011) and more than 75% of the population depends on primary activities and the majority of farmers are marginal farmers. Only 6% to 7% of the total cultivable area is under irrigation (Government of Himachal Pradesh 2012). Thus any change in climate can affect the economy as people largely depend on nature for their livelihood.
19

january 25, 2014

You might also like