You are on page 1of 51

Transferring tacit know-how through licensing or joint venture: Is opportunism really redundant?

Alex Eapen The University of Sydney Business School Discipline of International Business NSW 2006, Australia Tel: + 61-2-903 66435 Email: alex.eapen@sydney.edu.au

Rekha Krishnan Simon Fraser University Department of International Business 8888 University Drive Burnaby, BC V5A 1S6, Canada Tel: +1-604-291-3047 Email: rekhak@sfu.ca

Version: Mar, 2012

We thank Aks Zaheer, Anand Nandkumar, Anita McGahan, Anoop Madhok, Harbir Singh, Kannan Srikanth, Klaus Meyer, Peter Liesch, Rajiv Krishnan, Sarah Kaplan, and seminar participants at the Indian School of Business and the University of Sydney, for helpful comments on earlier drafts of this paper.

Transferring tacit know-how through licensing or joint venture: Is opportunism really redundant?

Abstract Transaction cost economics scholars argue that firms exist due to failure of markets, a main stimulus of which is opportunism. On the contrary, proponents of the knowledge based view claim that the opportunism assumption is redundant in explaining why firms exist. A key feature of this debate, however, is that despite competing causal mechanisms, predictions of both theories are identical. We see this lack of predictive uniqueness as the prime bottleneck in resolving the question of whether opportunism matters, and contribute to the debate in two ways: (1) we exploit the contingency logics inherent in knowledge based and transaction cost approaches to build distinctive predictions from both theories, and (2) we empirically test their competing logics, bringing empirical evidence to the debate which has this far been largely on conceptual turf. Our results, based on an analysis of tacit know-how transfer in strategic alliances between foreign and local firms in India, and subject to certain caveats we discuss in the paper, indicate that opportunism matters. (165 words)

INTRODUCTION A key debate in the theory of the firm is on the role of opportunism. Some scholars, primarily from a transaction cost economics (TCE) standpoint, argue that firms exist due to market failure, a main stimulus of which is opportunism (Hennart, 1982; McFetridge, 1995; Williamson, 1985; 1991; 1993). Others maintain that the opportunism assumption is redundant, that is, the existence of the firm can be explained without the notion of opportunism (Conner & Prahalad, 1996; Ghoshal & Moran, 1996; Kogut & Zander, 1993; Madhok, 2006). Yet another group suggests that opportunism may be relevant, but not to the encompassing extent that TCE portrays (Madhok, 2006), nor always directed by guileful selfinterest seeking (Verbeke & Greidanus, 2009). Conceptual disagreement aside, empirical evidence on whether opportunism is critical to explaining the boundaries of the firm is also very scant. Even within the huge body of empirical research on TCE (David & Han, 2004; Macher & Richman, 2008), scholars usually assume but omit testing the underlying opportunism assumption (Tsang, 2006; Verbeke & Griedanus, 2009). A specific context in which this debate has gained significant play in recent years is the international strategy literature on the implications of ownership advantages of firms on their boundaries. Examining how firms transfer their knowledge-based advantage into new countries, Kogut & Zander (1993) suggest that firms, as social communities with superior cooperation and coordination mechanisms, are simply better vehicles to transfer know-how. Transferring knowledge across borders, particularly when it is tacit, is hence more likely to occur within the firm than on the market. This is a key prediction of the knowledge-based view (KBV) of the multinational enterprise. Transaction cost theorists agree that tacit knowledge is more efficiently transferred within the firm, but emphasize that this is because contracting for tacit knowledge on the market is rendered inefficient by opportunism-related hurdles (McFetridge, 1995; Hennart, 1982). Within firms, on the other hand, members have

fewer incentives to behave opportunistically (Williamson, 1985). Thus, unlike KBV, the transaction cost theory of the multinational enterprise turns on the notion of opportunism. This debate in the international strategy literature has witnessed passionate arguments from all sides (Kogut & Zander, 1993; McFetridge, 1995; Love, 1995; Verbeke, 2003) and little sign of being settled (e.g., Fransson, Hakanson, & Liesch, 2011). We seek to advance the literature surrounding the opportunism debate in both conceptual and empirical ways. Our starting point is the observation that despite fundamentally different views from KBV and TCE on the relevance of opportunism, both sides arrive at the same prediction that tacit know-how is more efficiently transferred internally than on the market. In other words, while the causal mechanisms differ, predictions from transaction cost and knowledge-based views are identical. This lack of predictive uniqueness poses a key conceptual bottleneck in this debate 1. A second critical gap, given that the debate has been largely on conceptual turf (e.g., Conner & Prahalad, 1996; Foss, 1996a; 1996b; Kogut & Zander, 1992; Fransson et al., 2011), is the lack of empirical evidence on whether or not opportunism matters. There is indeed abundant empirical research on KBV and TCE, but as Verbeke & Greidanus (2009) rightly say, very few studies assess directly whetheropportunism is actually instrumental [or not] to governance choices (p.1476). The question of whether opportunism is critical to understanding the boundaries of the firm, yet, is ultimately an empirical one (Tsang, 2006). We seek to get around these conceptual and empirical issues in this paper. Conceptually, we exploit the contingency logics inherent in KBV and TCE to build distinctive predictions from both theories. Contingency propositions also better represent the causal mechanisms underpinning both theories (cf. Rajan & Zingales, 1998). Our theoretical strategy involves identifying situations where opportunism is likely to be a concern, and then
1 The predictive similarity of TCE and KBV in spite of their different theoretical mechanisms has been highlighted by scholars in other contexts as well (e.g., Poppo & Zenger, 1998; Sampson, 2004).

examining whether the likelihood of internal transfer of tacit know-how increases in those circumstances. In other words, we test whether the potential for opportunism makes any difference to how tacit know-how is transferred. We expect tacit know-how, in general, to be transferred internally, but if the effect of tacitness on transfer through hierarchical means increases with the level of opportunism faced by transferor and recipient, this could be the smoking gun to suggest that opportunism matters. On the contrary, if the effect of tacitness on the mode of transfer is insensitive to the potential for opportunism, then perhaps as KBV suggests, opportunism is not so crucial for the theory. So the difference in the magnitude of the effect of tacitness under conditions of low and high opportunism serves as our litmus test for whether opportunism matters. To obtain a complete picture, we also frame a contingency argument for KBV. We argue that while the likelihood of internal transfer increases with the tacitness of know-how, this effect is weaker when the transferor and unaffiliated recipient have similar routines. That is, when routines are similar, transferring tacit know-how should be easier, even to unaffiliated firms. Any evidence for this would corroborate the KBV view that ease of transfer (and not opportunism) is what drives firms proclivity to internal transfer. Empirically, we test these notions using unique data from a survey of technology transfer arrangements between foreign and domestic firms in India. We surveyed licensing contracts, which are closer to a market transaction, as well as joint ventures, which have overtones of hierarchy or internal transfer (Gulati & Singh, 1998; Hennart, 1988; Osborn & Baughn, 1990; Oxley, 1997; Phene & Tallman, 2012). We collected detailed micro-level data on the nature of know-how transferred such as its tacitness, importance to the recipient, and the extent of specific investments required to be made by the recipient for its implementation. As we argue below, the latter two variables are reasonably good indicators of potential opportunism. We also measured the similarity between transferor and recipient in this case, between foreign and domestic partners in their routines and culture. Employing logistic

regression analyses, we find that tacit know-how is more likely transferred through joint venture than through licensing. This is consistent with prior literature. However, we also find that the effect of tacitness on the choice of joint venture is stronger under conditions of high potential opportunism, i.e., when the know-how being transferred is central to the recipient, or when the recipient needs to make specific investments. But we do not find the effect of tacitness varying with whether or not the recipient has routines similar to that of the transferor. Subject to certain caveats we discuss later on, we interpret these results to mean two things firstly, that opportunism is relevant to understanding the boundaries of the firm, and secondly, that opportunism is the likely causal mechanism behind the often observed empirical link between tacitness of know-how and its internal transfer. These conceptual and empirical observations, as we discuss later on in the paper, have fairly significant implications for the debate over opportunism and the theory of the firm, and for issues related to the question of what firms really do (cf. Kogut & Zander, 1992). BACKGROUND The assumption of opportunism has received a significant amount of attention and commentary in the organization, strategy, and international business literatures. Not all of it has been positive. While there is seldom any disagreement over the need to carefully identify the nature of human beings that underlies their behavior (Simon, 1985; Verbeke & Greidanus, 2009; Williamson, 1993), scholars have attacked opportunism, inter alia, as being an undersocialized and narrow view of human behavior (Donaldson, 1990; Granovetter, 1985), of little normative value (Ghoshal & Moran, 1996), and irrelevant to understanding why firms exist (Conner & Prahalad, 1996; Hodgson, 1998; Kogut & Zander, 1992; 1996; Love, 1995). This critical commentary has been reciprocated in equal measure with extensions (Rugman & Verbeke, 2003), elaboration (Wathne & Heide, 2000), and reconceptualization of the opportunism construct (e.g., Verbeke & Greidanus, 2009).

In the international strategy literature, the study of how tacitness of know-how influences the boundaries of the MNE has turned out to be a duelling ground for this debate. By questioning the need for the opportunism assumption, Kogut and Zander (1993) reshaped the way scholars understood the MNE and its boundaries (Tallman, 2003; Verbeke, 2003). Until Kogut and Zander (1993), the existence of the MNE was largely attributed to the failure of markets for critical intermediates such as knowledge, raw materials, and distribution (Hennart, 2001). According to proponents of this approach, whether the cross-border transfer of a firm's ownership advantage, e.g., its proprietary knowledge, occurs on the market or through hierarchical modes such as joint ventures or wholly-owned subsidiaries depends on whether or not there is a viable market for that advantage (Buckley & Casson, 1976; Hennart, 1982; Rugman, 1981). In some instances, markets fail for reasons related to opportunism (Williamson, 1985), necessitating the internalization of that transfer. Kogut and Zander (1993) took issue with this explanation and argued that it is overdetermined with its reliance on opportunism. In building their case, they introduced the concept of tacitness of knowledge to the literature which until then considered knowledge as a public good that is easy to transfer but hard to protect. By bringing tacitness of knowledge into the picture, they established that the transfer of tacit knowledge, due to the difficulty in describing and teaching it, may not be easy even among willing parties. However, because routines, values, and assumptions are shared within the firm, it turns out less costly to transfer tacit knowledge internally. Hence, according to Kogut and Zander (1993), the existence of the MNE, or more precisely, the transfer of tacit knowledge across borders through hierarchical modes can be attributed simply to the efficiency of firms in transferring knowledge internally. The notion of opportunism is redundant. Kogut and Zanders thesis received a lot of support (e.g. Love, 1995; Tallman, 2003), but also provoked a series of critiques (Foss, 1996a; 1996b; McFetridge, 1995), rebuttals

(Kogut & Zander, 1995), and reflections (Kogut & Zander, 2003). Like Kogut and Zander, Love (1995) too asserts that opportunism is not necessary to explain the existence of the firm. But unlike them, Love (1995) maintains that firms exist because of market failure, but a different class of it that comes not from opportunism but from genuine unbridgeable differences in routines. Madhoks (1996) argument is similar and largely consistent with Kogut & Zanders. From a transaction cost perspective, on the other hand, McFetridge (1995) argued that the reason firms transfer tacit knowledge internally is because the potential for opportunism is subdued when transactions are organized through hierarchical modes. Kogut and Zanders finding that MNEs transfer tacit knowledge internally rather than externally, thus, is entirely consistent with transaction cost reasoning that is based on opportunism (McFetridge, 1995). Several other scholars too have weighed in on this issue of whether opportunism matters (e.g., Foss, 1996a; 1996b; Ghoshal & Moran, 1996), and the debate continues (e.g., Fransson et al., 2011), but largely on conceptual terrain. Empirical evidence for whether or not opportunism matters is rare, not only in the TCE literature that rests on the notion of opportunism (Tsang, 2006), but also in the KBV literature that refutes it. THEORY Theoretical Strategy As we have indicated, a key bottleneck in the opportunism debate as it has played out in the international strategy literature is that predictions from TCE and KBV regarding the transfer of tacit know-how are identical. Hence, what would help make progress, in our view, is a way to draw and empirically test distinctive predictions based on the 'with opportunism' and 'without opportunism' logics of both theories. As we demonstrate below, this can be done by means of contingency arguments. Furthermore, contingency arguments are native to the key logics of both KBV and TCE, so portraying them as such is really just more precise articulation.

Take the KBV for example. Kogut and Zander (1993) argue that firms are social communities that specialize in the creation and internal transfer of knowledge. Firms are simply better at transferring tacit knowledge. And this is largely because they are a ...repository of social knowledge that structures cooperative action... (p.627). In other words, firms naturally beget the cooperation and coordination necessary to transfer tacit knowledge. The reverse argument then is also true; the key hurdle in transferring knowledge to unaffiliated firms is that transferor and recipient lack a common social fabric. When unaffiliated firms lack the same routines, structures, and identity as the transferor, extra effort needs to go into teaching the recipient, and transfer becomes costly. Herein lies the key contingency in the knowledge based view. Tacitness of know-how, per se, is not the real barrier to its transfer. Tacit knowledge can be transferred (it is transferred within the firm, after all), but less easily so, when the recipient lacks similar routines. Kogut and Zander do emphasize that differential routines between transferor and recipient are what matter (p.630), a point that Love (1995) too nicely summarizes: ...the boundaries of the firm are determined...by differential 'embedded capabilities' that exist between creators of knowledge and its users (p.400). By embedded capabilities, Love essentially means routines. Although there is a bit of confusion over which side of the debate Teece (1986) stands (cf., Love, 1995: 402), his statement that trying to transact tacit knowledge may ...fail if it must take place between unaffiliated enterprises with different internal cultures (and) codes of

communication... (Teece, 1986: 29) also attests to the point we are making. Transferring tacit knowledge is problematic only to the extent that the recipient lacks the appropriate routines. This contingency argument is inherent in the knowledge based view of the firm. Let us move on to TCE. An important rebuttal from TCE to Kogut and Zander's thesis is that the relationship between tacitness and internal transfer can easily be explained by transaction cost theory (McFetridge, 1995). Firms are indeed relatively efficient in

transferring tacit knowledge but this is because the market for tacit knowledge fails. And according to TCE theorists, opportunism is what drives this failure. The key implication of this argument is that contracting for tacit knowledge on the market becomes a problem only to the extent that conditions of opportunism exist. One such condition, for example, is when transaction specific investments are needed. Transaction specific investments and the resulting lock-in problems are a breeding ground for opportunism related contractual problems (Williamson, 1985). So tacitness could pose a problem to contractual exchange, but more so in the presence of transaction specific investments. McFetridge (1995: 410) clarifies this and says: if there were no transaction-specific investments and hence no lock-in, (tacitness) need not burden market and unified governance differentially. It is also widely acknowledged in the TCE literature that uncertainty coupled with asset specificity begets contractual problems (Leiblein & Miller, 2003; Williamson, 1985). In our context of know-how transfer, uncertainty arises from the difficulty in defining and specifying tacit knowledge. And whenever assets are specific in nontrivial degree, [an increased] degree of uncertainty makes it more imperative that the parties devise a machinery to 'work things out' (Williamson, 1985: 60). In other words, the combination of uncertainty and asset specificity is what necessitates hierarchical solutions. So the kernel of transaction cost theory too is a contingency argument. Tacitness matters only to the extent that transferor and recipient face circumstances that beget opportunism concerns. Phrasing our KBV and TCE predictions as contingency statements, thus, is consistent with the conceptual core of both theories. There are also empirical benefits of employing contingency arguments in the KBV-TCE debate. They bring sharper focus to the terms of disagreement by better capturing the underlying causal mechanisms of both theories (cf. Rajan & Zingales, 1998), and in turn, allow us to test the competing logics. The first set of contingency arguments we propose below are on how the effect of tacitness varies with the

potential for opportunism, and the second, on how it varies with similarity of routines and culture between transferor and recipient. Hypotheses Development As a baseline, and as TCE and KBV scholars in the international strategy field have suggested, we maintain that tacit know-how is more likely to be transferred through hierarchical modes than on the market (Kogut & Zander, 1993; McFetridge, 1995). So our baseline hypothesis is that the more tacit the know-how, the more likely it will be transferred through hierarchical modes than on the market. However, in order to accurately portray and test TCE and KBV predictions relating to how tacit know-how is transferred, in the following sections we frame propositions as contingency statements. Tacitness, opportunism, and internal transfer. Contracting on the market works well when the buyer and seller have a fairly good understanding of what is being exchanged (Arrow, 1962; Barzel, 1989; Mayer & Nickerson, 2005). And for this reason, transacting any kind of knowledge on the market is inherently difficult because the buyer does not completely know what he is buying (Arrow, 1962; Hennart, 1982) and the seller cannot describe it to the buyer because in doing so he reveals it free of charge. This problem only gets compounded when the knowledge is tacit as well. This information asymmetry between buyer and seller is the first contributor to market failure for knowledge. The second, is opportunism. When it is difficult to clearly specify the details of the knowledge being transferred, the seller has sufficient room to behave opportunistically. And so, the buyer maybe concerned, ex-ante, that the seller is exploiting the information asymmetry and quoting a higher price, or that, ex-post, the seller will not deliver what was promised. With room for such opportunistic manoeuvres, it is unlikely that the buyer will consent to a market-based contractual transfer of the knowledge. The safeguards and opportunism-mitigation inherent in hierarchy (Hennart, 1988; Oxley, 1997; Sampson, 2004) become necessary. The seller too may have similar opportunism

10

concerns, but mainly around whether or not he/she will be able to fully appropriate rents on the knowledge (Oxley, 1997). If the buyer uses the knowledge ex-post in ways not covered by the contract, the seller may lose access to rents that are legally due to him/her. Tacit knowledge, by definition, is not patentable, and so the ability to prevent such misappropriation is weak. The market for tacit know-how thus fails under conditions of opportunism. And given the opportunism-mitigating properties of hierarchy (Hennart, 1988; Oxley, 1997; Sampson, 2004), such know-how is likely to be transferred through hierarchical modes. However, the threat of opportunism is not uniform across all transactions. Some conditions beget greater opportunism concerns than others. We focus on two such conditions when the know-how is of central importance to the recipient, and when it requires specific investments by the recipient. When the know-how being transferred is central to the recipient, this raises the sceptre of opportunism for both the transferor and recipient. Recall that from the recipient's perspective, the key concern is that the transferor may misrepresent the value of the knowhow, or not deliver as promised. These are always concerns for the recipient when contracting for know-how, but arguably, more of a concern when the know-how being purchased is critical to its operations. The stakes are higher since the recipient has more to lose from the poor performance of know-how related to its core operations. Consequently, he/she will be particularly wary about the transferor being opportunistic and misrepresenting the value or defaulting on the delivery of the know-how. From the transferor's side too, the stakes are high. Everything else constant, the potential for the recipient to misappropriate know-how that is central to its operations is higher because the recipient may have better ability and incentive to do so. It is likely that recipients are more capable of misusing technologies in the areas of operation they are most familiar with. And the gains from doing so are higher. Thus from both

11

the recipient's and transferor's perspectives, concerns over opportunism are likely to be higher when the know-how is central to the recipient. Putting these arguments together, it becomes clear that transferring tacit know-how on the market is likely to fail, but more so when it is central to the recipient. In such cases, both parties are likely to take recourse to transfer through more hierarchical modes, where the incentives to act opportunistically are drastically reduced (Hennart, 1993; McFetridge, 1995; Williamson, 1985). It is perhaps useful to reiterate our key point that from the TCE point of view, the market failure for tacit know-how, and the need to replace markets with internal transfer, is not due to tacitness per se, but because of associated opportunism concerns. By specifying the following contingency hypothesis we directly capture this underlying causal mechanism. Hypothesis 1: Tacit know-how is more likely to be transferred through hierarchical modes (e.g., through joint ventures) than on the market (e.g., through licensing), but more so when the know-how is central to the recipient's operations. As we briefly alluded to earlier, another situation likely to give rise to opportunism concerns is when the recipient is required to make specific investments to implement the know-how (Shelanski & Klein, 1995). The problems associated with asset specificity and how it yields room for opportunism concerns have received a lot of commentary in the TCE literature (for the sake of brevity we do not repeat them here). And as mentioned earlier, the combination of asset specificity with uncertainty raises significant transaction costs (Williamson, 1985). Again, as discussed above, a key concern for the recipient in attempting to contract for tacit know-how is that the transferor may change terms of the contract ex-post and not deliver as promised. This is always a concern but a greater one when the recipient has invested heavily in specific investments. The cost to the recipient of the transferor opportunistically reneging on the contract is immensely higher. Thus:

12

Hypothesis 2: Tacit know-how is more likely to be transferred through hierarchical modes (e.g., through joint ventures) than on the market (e.g., through licensing), but more so when the recipient needs to make specific investments to implement the know-how. Tacitness, similarity of routines and culture, and internal transfer. The knowledgebased view of the MNE contends that it is not opportunism but the difficulty in effectively coordinating with third parties that prevents firms from transferring tacit knowledge on the market. If that is indeed the case, then firms should be more likely to transfer tacit knowledge externally when routines and organizational culture of the recipient are similar to their own2. Culture is typically considered a set of cognitions shared by members of a social unit [such as an organization] (OReilly et al., 1991:491; Scott, 2001; Smircich, 1983). Such shared cognition, which involves translating events consistently and developing shared meanings and conceptual schemes (Daft & Weick, 1984; Klimoski & Mohammed, 1994), guide the behavior of organizational members (Rousseau, 1990; Schein, 1985) and allows them to develop common interpretations (Klimoski & Mohammed, 1994). Scholars argue that shared mental models held by organizational members result in effective coordination (Klimoski & Mohammed, 1994; Srikanth & Puranam, 2011). Tacit knowledge is not easy to describe and makes systematic transfer cumbersome (Nonaka, 1994). Codifying tacit knowledge in order to make it teachable requires extensive communication and coordination between source and recipient. In the context of knowledge transfer, prior research suggests that similarity in management styles between the source and recipient results in similarity of work expectations, operating procedures and interpretation of strategic issues (Olk, 1997; Park & Ungson, 1997; 2001; Simonin, 1999). Compared to their culturally distant counterparts, organizations that share similar expectations and

The need for articulating the knowledge based view as a contingency argument is evident in commentary by Fransson et al. (2011: 430) that ...it cannot be assumed that firms are always better at transferring...knowledge in house than through market transactions,...there may be conditions, as yet unspecified, when this might be the case. The only disagreement we have is that the conditions are not unspecified. The key condition under which firms are better at transferring knowledge, as we argue, is when potential recipients have a culture and routines dissimilar routines to those of the transferor.

13

interpretations need to expend less effort and energy in devising compatible interorganizational routines. This in turn facilitates better communication between them (Park & Ungson, 1997; 2001) and reduces knowledge exchange costs (Jensen & Szulanski, 2004). Therefore, when an unaffiliated knowledge recipient shares similar values and cognitions with the transferor, that similarity facilitates better communication and effective coordination. In turn, this should encourage the transfer of tacit knowledge on the market rather than through a more hierarchical mode, such as joint venture. Second, because tacit knowledge is firmly embedded in context, it is important to understand the context in which knowledge is stored and retrieved (Nonaka, 1994). In knowledge-exchange, scholars have argued that an organizations culture represents its history and is therefore considered one of the facilities where the organizations memory is retained for future reference (Klimoski & Mohammed, 1994; Walsh & Ungson, 1991). Thus, an organizations culture, besides providing a framework for information processing, enables it to store knowledge (Brief & Downey, 1983; Busenitz & Lau, 1996; Gray, Bougen, & Donnellon, 1985; Harris, 1994; Shaw, 1990). Accordingly, organizations that are culturally similar tend to organize and store knowledge in a mutually understandable manner (Schneider & Angelmar, 1993) as well as retrieve knowledge from their memory in similar ways (Klimoski & Mohammed, 1994). Their framework for decision-making, problem-solving, information and knowledge processing tends to be comparable as well (Mitchell et al., 2000). Thus, a recipient that is similar to the transferor in terms of organizational culture is more likely to understand the context in which the transferors knowledge is embedded, which makes the transfer of tacit knowledge easier. Taken together, these arguments suggest that the relative efficiency of internal transfer of tacit knowledge reduces when the knowledge recipient shares the same (or similar) routine and culture as the transferor. Hence:

14

Hypothesis 3: Tacit know-how is more likely to be transferred through hierarchical modes (e.g., through joint ventures) than on the market (e.g., through licensing), but less so when the transferor and recipient are similar in their organizational routines and culture.

METHODS Empirical Context We test these hypotheses using data from a survey of technology recipients in joint ventures and technology licensing arrangements between foreign and domestic firms in India. Our choice of the survey method and the target population of licensing and joint ventures (as opposed to, say, wholly-owned subsidiaries), as well as our decision to survey the recipient and not the transferor were deliberate. Scholars in the past have relied on secondary data to study licensing and joint ventures (Gulati, 1995; Oxley, 1997). But with secondary data, as those very scholars admit, ...it is very difficult to obtain data on aspects of technology transferred...such as tacitness or age... (Oxley, 1997: 394). Hence, to get at the attributes and details of the technology transferred, a survey is more appropriate. Our decision to survey the technology recipient is rather unique but necessary in our case for two reasons. First, some of the moderating variables we propose in our hypotheses, e.g., centrality of know-how to the recipient and the extent of specific investments it needed to make, are obviously best measured by surveying the recipient. Secondly, and perhaps more importantly, it seems to us appropriate to measure tacitness of the technology being transferred through the eyes of the recipient. Whether a technology is perceived as tacit or not, depends on the experience and repertoire of capabilities of the recipient. What might seem simple or codifiable technology to the transferor may appear complex and unclear to a recipient who lacks the relevant experience or capabilities. So the recipient's perception of tacitness is at least equally (and perhaps even more) relevant to the choice of mode of transfer. Surveying the recipient automatically precludes foreign wholly-owned subsidiaries from our sampling frame because in wholly-owned operations there is no unaffiliated recipient. Our empirical focus is thus on 15

licensing and joint ventures and on the choice between them, considering licensing closer to a market contract and joint ventures closer to a hierarchical solution to knowledge transfer (Gulati & Singh, 1998; Hennart, 1988; Oxley, 1997; Phene & Tallman, 2012). Surveying only licensing and joint ventures, if anything, makes our empirical tests more conservative. Compared to the differences between licensing and wholly-owned subsidiaries, the differences between licensing and joint venture are less distinctive. They do for sure differ in transaction cost mitigating and knowledge transfer properties (Oxley, 1997), but these differences are not as stark as between licensing and wholly-owned subsidiaries. Also, given that most tacit know-how is perhaps transferred through wholly-owned subsidiaries, which we do not observe, the variation in tacitness in our dataset is likely to be limited. All these factors militate against us in finding any significant results. Focussing on the choice between licensing and joint ventures thus only raises the bar for us, making it even harder to find any significant results. Data We used Capitaline, a secondary database, and member lists of various international chambers of commerce in India to identify a sample of 700 international licensing and joint venture agreements operating in India. Following Parkhe (1993) and Simonin (1999), we aimed to target respondents highly knowledgeable about the relationships. In our case these were mainly managing directors and chief executive officers. We obtained the names of these target respondents from Capitaline and chambers of commerce data. We designed our questionnaire and implemented our survey according to Dillmans (2000) 'Tailored Design Method', which suggests several ways to encourage response. Our measurement items were generated through a review of prior literature. We used university faculty and doctoral students to assess the content of the items and to ascertain whether the items tapped into the conceptual domain of the focal construct (DeVellis, 1991). This yielded 16

a set of fine-tuned questionnaire items that were used in personal interviews and early pretests with managing directors of Indian firms involved in international licensing and joint venture agreements. These steps allowed us to check for any item ambiguity. The first wave of questionnaires was sent to managing directors and senior executives of the 700 Indian firms we identified that had licensing and joint venture agreements with foreign firms. This was followed, four weeks later, by a second wave of survey mailings. Of the 700 managing directors and senior executives that received questionnaires, 126 responded, yielding an 18% response rate. This is comparable to surveys of such relationships in other emerging economies: e.g., 14.4% for China (Isobe, Makino & Montgomery, 2000), and 19% for Mexico (Robins, Tallman & Lindquist, 2002). All the responses to our survey came from individuals directly responsible for the relationships: 80 came from chairpersons and managing directors of the alliances, 30 from presidents, vice presidents and general managers, and 16 from full-time directors. Nearly 75% of the respondents had been with the firm for more than five years, and of these almost 25% for more than 20 years. The foreign partners of Indian firms we surveyed were spread over 21 countries. All relationships in our sample are dyadic, and belong to industries in the manufacturing sector where licensing and joint ventures are more prevalent (e.g., Parkhe, 1993; Simonin, 1999). Tests of proportions show that the distribution of our responses according to their two-digit manufacturing SIC is not statistically different from that reported in two landmark studies by Harrigan (1988) and Ghemawat, Porter & Rawlison (1986). The top four industries in our sample rank in the same order as in these studies, and as others have also found (e.g. Parkhe, 1993), are relatively high-tech (industrial machinery and equipment, chemicals and allied products, electrical and electronic equipment, and transportation equipment). Some of our key measures were collected using the same survey instrument and from 17

a single respondent. Hence we undertook multiple procedural and statistical remedies to address the potential concern of common method bias and single informant bias. Specifically, we undertook procedural remedies such as protecting respondent anonymity, scale reordering, and reducing item ambiguity, as well as statistical remedies like Harmans (1967) one factor test. Based on these, we are confident that common method or single respondent bias is not a serious problem in our study. We checked the potential for non-response bias by comparing the characteristics of our respondents to those of the targeted population sample. T-tests for the size of the firms (p = 0.284) and age of the Indian firm (p = 0.344) revealed no significant differences between respondent and non-respondent groups. In line with Mohr & Spekman (1994) and Poppo & Zenger (2002), we also tested for non-response bias by comparing early and late respondents. Armstrong & Overton (1977) argue that late respondents are more representative of nonrespondents. We found no significant difference between early and late respondents on characteristics such as number of employees of the Indian partner (p = 0.18) and relationship duration (p = 0.29). Dependent Variable We used a dummy variable to represent the mode of know-how transfer. This variable, JV, took the value 1 when know-how was transferred via joint venture, and 0 when it was through a licensing agreement. We carefully considered using on a more nuanced version of this variable based on the fact that an ideal test of transaction cost theory requires a dependent variable that captures finer aspects of safeguards built into the contract (Malhotra & Lumineau, 2011; Mesquita & Brush, 2008). Hierarchy is not the only solution to transaction costs; other safeguards such as contracts of longer duration (Crocker & Masten, 1988; Joskow, 1985; 1987), exclusivity (Gallick, 1984), or even relational assets (Madhok, 2006) could meet the same opportunism-mitigation purposes. So ideally, the extent of contractual 18

safeguards, irrespective of it source, should be our dependent variable. However, we stuck with the more conventional market hierarchy dichotomy measure for three reasons. Firstly, we needed our measure to be relevant to the debate we are contributing to. In other words, we needed a dependent variable that would be flexible enough to reflect both KBV and TCE mechanisms and thus appeal to both camps. While finer details of the contract would help in better capturing opportunism-mitigation elements of the governance structure, it is unclear how it would better represent the commonality of social fabric that, according to KBV, eases the cost of transfer. Secondly, the debate at the center of our work has primarily been around why firms are more efficient carriers of tacit know-how, or alternatively, why tacit know-how is transferred internally as opposed to on the market. For the sake of relevance to this question, we persisted with our dichotomous variable; it picks up whether the know-how transfer was within-firm or to an unaffiliated party. Thirdly, despite recent advances, the terrain of contract research where scholars micro-analyze contracts to capture their finer transaction cost mitigation characteristics still has teething problems. These include issues like which clauses of the contract to look at, whether sets of clauses still serve opportunism mitigation when they interact with each other, and indeed the definition of a contractual safeguard (Mayer, 2009). As a simple example, while Mesquita & Brush (2008) measure contract completeness with the number of contingency clauses included in the contract, Crocker & Reynolds (1993) consider those with fewer contingency clauses more complete because such contracts potentially cover broader areas of dispute. As TCE scholars duly acknowledge, contract research is an area where the enterprise as a whole needs to improve (Mayer, 2009). Without specific guidance from the literature on specific contractbased measures, and not to distract from the main goal of the paper, we decided to stick with our parsimonious measure. Our measure is not without precedent, though. Several other scholars both from KBV and TCE approaches have dichotomized the governance choice

19

into market or hierarchy (Colombo, 2003; Kogut & Zander, 1993; Mayer & Salomon, 2006; Nickerson & Silverman, 2003; Osborn & Baughn, 1990; Phene & Tallman, 2012; Sampson, 2004) Independent Variables Our main independent variable is tacitness, and our moderator variables fall under two groups: the potential for opportunism and the commonality of social fabric across transferor and recipient. As we explain below, we conceptualized tacitness as tacitness of the know-how package being transferred. We also used two indicators of potential opportunism - centrality of know-how to the recipient (for hypothesis 1) and size of specific investment (for hypothesis 2). We captured the commonality in social fabric across transferor and recipient using a variable similarity of routines and culture (hypothesis 3). Tacitness. In measuring tacitness, we focussed on the tacitness of the know-how package being transferred. The know-how package refers to the entire package being transferred, and includes not only the core technology, but also the surrounding supporting skills. The know-how package thus varies with the range of supporting skills needed from the foreign partner by the recipient. Capable recipients need fewer skills and vice-versa. So to measure tacitness of the know-how package, we used a five-item measure that captured the recipients need for supporting skills to implement the core technology. Specifically, based on prior conceptual descriptions (Baranson, 1969; Hall and Johnson, 1970; Odagiri, et al., 2010), we operationalized this variable by asking recipients whether or not the marketing and production skills they possessed matched those required to produce and sell the product for which know-how is being sourced, and whether they required production process, marketing, management, and other technical assistance to implement the technology contributed by the transferor. The key insight underpinning this measure is that as the need for tacit skills such as marketing and management increases, so does the overall tacitness of the know-how package.

20

This measure had satisfactory reliability. An important consideration when using binary items in a scale, as we do, is that the traditional Cronbach alpha can be negatively biased; an ordinal alpha, based on tetrachoric or polychoric correlations, is more appropriate (Zumbo, Gadermann, & Zeisser, 2007). For our five items, the ordinal alpha was 0.68. We also conducted factor analysis to assess construct validity. Following an orthogonal rotation, we extracted one factor that had an eigenvalue greater than 1 and accounted for 85% of total variance. The last three out of the five items loaded well onto this one factor with loadings greater than 0.65 and the 0.40 cut-off normally prescribed (Ford, MacCallum, & Tait, 1986). For our main analyses we therefore chose to retain only the last three items in the scale. Redoing factor analysis with only the last three items returned factor loadings that were higher than 0.71. Also, the ordinal reliability alpha improved significantly from 0.68 to 0.79. To be sure though, we ran our regressions with both the three-item and the five-item index and obtained substantially similar results. Moderators. In capturing the potential for opportunism, we resorted to unobtrusive measures (Webb & Weick, 1979). As research on personality traits has shown, using direct survey questions to capture negative constructs such as narcissm (Chatterjee & Hambrick, 2007), racism (Newman & Krzystofiak, 1979), or in our context, opportunism, is likely to elicit low response rates and social desirability bias. Hence, rather than trying to measure opportunism itself as some scholars have done (Anderson, 1988; Sako & Helper, 1998), we used unobtrusive indicators of opportunism (Gulati & Singh, 1998; Klein et al., 1978; Oxley, 1997). We measured centrality of know-how to the recipient using a dummy variable. We asked the respondent who in our case was also the recipient whether the know-how was central to its operations, and coded the variable 1 if the answer was in the affirmative, and 0 otherwise.

21

To measure size of specific investment, we asked the recipient to indicate the size of investment that had to be made specifically to implement the know-how, and was less relevant to other uses. This variable was coded in five bands: 1 for specific investments of less than US$10 million, 2 for investments between US$ 10 and 45 million, 3 for investments between US$45 and 110 million, 4 for investments between US$110 and 220 million, and 5 for those above US$ 220 million. Our contention is that higher values on this variable indicate greater levels of asset specificity (Dyer, 1996). This measure meets the three guidelines Mayer (2009) offers to increase construct validity of empirical measures of transaction-specific investments. That is, our item captures the specificity of the investment, the size (and not only the presence) of the investment, and we obtain this information from the firm making the investment and not from just any of the firms involved in the transaction. To measure similarity of routines and culture, we used a two-item measure to capture the extent to which there was overlap in the transferor's and recipient's organizational routines and culture. Specifically, we used five point likert type items to ask the respondents to what extent their business practices and operational mechanisms, and organizational culture and management style were similar to that of their foreign partner. This scale had an ordinal alpha of 0.80. Control Variables To control for alternative explanations for the relationship between our dependent and independent variables, we included controls for industry, age of the technology, cultural distance between home country of the foreign firm and India, and prior export experience of the foreign firm in India. Tacitness of a technology could be correlated with its age. As time wears on, details of the know-how become more established and well known. And it has been shown that older technologies are more likely to be transferred on the market (Davidson & McFetridge, 1985).

22

To rule out any correlation we observe between tacitness and choice of transfer mode being due to the common correlation with age of the technology, we specifically controlled for it. Age of technology was coded 1 when the respondent indicated that the core technology transferred (the technology stricto sensu) had been introduced in the transferors home country within the past year, 2 when it was two to three years old, 3 when it was three to five years old and 4 when its first introduction was more than five years ago. Cultural distance between the foreign and Indian firm could be correlated with both the latter's perception of tacitness and the mode of transfer. Whether a given technology appears tacit or not to a recipient could be partly a function of the cultural distance between the sender and recipient, and cultural distance has been shown to influence the choice between licensing and joint venture (Garca-Canal, Valds-Llaneza, & Snchez-Lorda, 2008). Hence we included cultural distance, measured using the Kogut & Singh (1988) index, as a control. A technology transferor who has been exporting to India in the past may be more willing to make greater resource commitments, i.e. to choose an EJV over a licensing agreement. To control for this, we included Prior Export, a dummy variable that was coded 1 if the foreign firm had exported its products to India prior to the present collaboration and 0 otherwise. Finally, to control for possible industry effects, we included industry dummies for chemicals, electronics, industrial machinery and transportation equipment industries. We are unable to include dummies for all industries in our data because the number of observations per industry is not large enough to justify that. RESULTS We report descriptive statistics and pair-wise correlations in table 1. Given the binary nature of our dependent variable, we used logistic regression to estimate the coefficients in our model. The results of our conventional logistic regression analyses are in table 2. To test our

23

hypotheses, we include in our models interaction terms between tacitness and each of our moderator variables. To attenuate problems related to multicollinearity, we mean-centered these variables before multiplying them to create the interaction terms. Model 1 includes only control variables, models 2 and 3 include the main independent variables, and models 4, 5, and 6 include interaction terms one at a time. Model 7 is the full model that includes all three sets of variables controls, independent variables, and the interaction terms. The main variables of interest, given our hypotheses, are the interaction terms. Looking at the coefficient estimates and their standard errors in model 7, we find support for hypotheses 1 and 2, but not for hypotheses 3. --------------Please insert tables 1 and 2 about here----------However, interpreting results in logistic regression models is notoriously difficult (Hoetkar, 2007). Unlike in linear regressions, estimates of coefficients in non-linear models, such as the logistic one, do not represent the actual marginal effect of independent variables. In the logistic case, the effect of each variable is non linear, and depends on its own values as well as on the values of other independent variables in the model. Interpreting interaction terms is even less straightforward. The coefficients of interaction terms are not equal to their marginal effect (Ai & Norton, 2003; Zelner, 2009) and conventional tests of statistical significance are wrong (Zelner, 2009). To make interpretation easy and to draw valid conclusions from logistic regressions, Zelner (2009) recommends computing differences in predicted probabilities () at different values of the independent variables. For example, we could calculate the predicted probability of joint venture () while holding tacitness at its minimum value and other independent variables at some theoretically interesting level. We could then repeat this, this time holding tacitness at its maximum value. The difference between these two predicted probabilities () i.e., at low and high levels of tacitness - indicates the 'effect' of tacitness on the probability

24

to joint venture. To get a sense of the magnitude of interaction effects, we could calculate at different values of the moderating variable. That is, we could calculate and compare the effect of tacitness () when the know-how is central to the recipient as well as when it is not. This double difference (), the difference in the effect of tacitness () when know-how is central to the recipient and when it is not, represents the interaction effect. If we find that the effect of tacitness is different when the know-how transferred is central to the recipient and when it is not, this suggests an interaction effect. And if we find that the effect of tacitness on joint venture is stronger when know-how is central to the recipient, this supports hypothesis 1. While examining differences in predicted probabilities () and double differences () gives us a sense of the magnitude of the effects we are interested in, we still do not know if these magnitudes are statistically significant. To calculate statistical significance, Zelner (2009) recommends a simulation-based method drawn from the political science discipline (King, Tomz, & Wittenberg, 2000). Essentially here, confidence intervals for coefficients, differences in predicted probabilities, and double differences are computed by drawing several values of these estimates from a simulated distribution. Using these confidence intervals, we can make inferences about statistical significance. We implemented this procedure by using the clarify suite of programs written for Stata (Tomz, Wittenberg, & King, 2001). The results of these analyses are in tables 3 and 4. ---------------Please insert tables 3 and 4 about here------------Table 3 shows the effect of tacitness () at minimum and maximum values of other variables. The predicted probability of joint venture at low levels of tacitness and when the know-how is central to the recipient is 0.30 (row 1(b), column 1 in table 3). This increases to 0.96 in cases where the know-how transferred is highly tacit (row 1(b), column 2 in table 3). The effect of tacitness, when know-how is central to the recipient, is thus 0.66. In a similar

25

way, tacitness increases the probability of joint venture by 0.15 when the size of specific investment variable is held at its minimum (row 2(a); column 3), and by 0.96 when the size of specific investment is very high (row 2(b); column 3). We also compute the confidence intervals for these effects. Essentially, if the confidence interval contains 0, is insignificant, and vice-versa. An interesting result that is not revealed in the conventional logistic regression results is that the effect of tacitness varies in magnitude across values of other variables. Also, the effect of tacitness is significant only at higher levels of the other variables. This is suggestive of interaction effects. Based on Zelners (2009) recommendation, we also plot these results in figures 1, 2, and 3. Figure 1 depicts the estimated effect of tacitness () along with its 95 percent confidence intervals at various (mean-centered) values of centrality of know-how to the recipient. The line in the plot that is bounded by confidence intervals represents the effect of tacitness () at various levels of centrality of know-how to the recipient. The narrow vertical rectangles denote the confidence intervals associated with these estimates. Figures 2 and 3 show the plots for size of specific investment and similar routines respectively. -----------Please insert figures 1, 2, and 3 about here----------The statistical test of the interaction hypotheses is essentially whether the effect of tacitness at low and high values of the moderator variables are significantly different. This is what we represent in table 4. As per Zelner's recommendation we compute double differences (). These are the differences between the effects of tacitness at lowest and highest values of the moderating variables. We also construct confidence intervals that allow us to run statistical significance tests. Table 4 shows that there are large differences in the effect of tacitness at various values of the moderator variables. We find that tacitness has a much stronger effect when know-how is central to the recipient and when the need for specific investment is high. These

26

two results are consistent with transaction cost theory. Contrary to the prediction from the knowledge based view though tacitness seems to lead to the choice of joint venture when transferor and recipient have similar routines. Sensitivity Analysis We tested if our results were sensitive to alternative measures of tacitness. We recoded tacitness of the know-how package as a count measure that took values from 1 to 5 depending on the number of types of supporting skills required. We also ran our analysis with another measure of tacitness tacitness of the core technology a set of three items that tapped into the extent to which the technology being transferred could be codified and taught, again measured from the recipient's perspective. Specifically, the five point likert type items captured the extent to which the technology transferred could be described in a manual, the extent to which the recipient can learn to manufacture the product or implement the manufacturing process by looking at a set of blueprints, and the extent to which manufacturing the product and/or implementing the process requires the on-site guidance of employees of the know-how transferring firm. The ordinal alpha for this measure was 0.75, and all three items loaded well onto one factor. Our results are robust to the use of these two different measures of tacitness. A possible threat to internal validity in our study lies in our use of single-item measures for centrality of know-how to the recipient and size of specific investment. One argument, based on the literature on (psychometric) measurement is that single-item measures are prone to measurement error. Measurement error in single-item scales could arise out of not being able to capture the multiple dimensions of a construct, and by leaving respondents with greater ambiguity to interpret the item in their own way. Moreover, one cannot compute a reliability statistic such as the cronbach or ordinal alpha in a single-item measure (Hoeppner et al., 2011). Using multiple items on the other hand generally allows for averaging out

27

random measurement error, and better means of capturing a complex construct. In our study, however, measurement error is unlikely to be a significant problem given that our single-item variables centrality of know-how to the recipient and size of specific investment capture objective and not perceptual data. We are indeed interested in the potential for opportunism in each transaction, but we do not directly measure the perception of opportunism (e.g., Anderson, 1988; Sako & Helper, 1998). Instead, for reasons mentioned before and as several others have done (e.g., Gulati & Singh, 1998; Klein et al., 1978; Oxley, 1997 etc.), we infer the potential for opportunism from certain objective characteristics of the transaction. And for such objective characteristics, single-item measures are usually sufficient (e.g., Sako & Helper, 1998: 396). Measurement error in our single-item measures, thus, is likely to be small. Nevertheless, we did some additional analysis to assess the resilience of our results to potential measurement error. Specifically, we employed regression calibration (Carroll & Stefanski, 1990; Hardin, Schmiediche, & Carroll, 2003) to check the sensitivity of our estimation to measurement error. Measurement error in independent variables generally poses two problems for regression estimates: (a) it reduces the power of the test, making it more difficult to detect significant effects (Anderson, 1988: 255; Carroll et al., 2006), and (b) induces bias in the coefficient estimates (Carroll, et al., 2006; Hardin et al., 2003). The first is likely not a problem for our study because for the interaction terms that include our two single-item variables centrality of know-how to the recipient and size of specific investment, we do find significant effects. In other words, we get significant effects even when measurement error should have made finding support for our TCE hypotheses more difficult. The latter problem of potentially biased coefficients, on the other hand, is something we would like to rule out. To do this, we estimated two sequences of regression calibration models, one for centrality of know-how to the recipient and the other for size of specific investment. In each sequence we progressively attributed a larger proportion of the total

28

variance in the (single-item) variable and its interaction term to measurement error. For example, in the sequence of regression calibration models for size of specific investment, we initially assumed that all the variance in size of specific investment and its interaction term is due to actual variance in the true measures (i.e., zero measurement error). In subsequent reruns of the model, we progressively increased the proportion of total variance due to measurement error to five, ten, fifteen, twenty, and twenty-five percent. Regression calibration modelling takes these estimates of error variance into account, and produces unbiased coefficients (Hardin & Carroll, 2003; Hardin, et al., 2003). We find that as we assume greater levels of measurement error, the unbiased coefficient estimate of the interaction terms are much larger than what we report in our main results table. In other words, if measurement error were present in our data, what we will have, more likely than not, is attenuation bias; in the other words, the coefficients we report here are smaller than what they ought to be. This obviously is not very disconcerting. It is perhaps useful to also note that the interaction term with size of specific investment remains significant in the regression calibration models. The interaction term with centrality of know-how to the recipient has the correct sign, but is significant only in a one-tailed test. This is not cause for excessive concern, however, given the inherent tendency in regression calibration models to trade off variability of the coefficient estimates in favour of unbiasedness (Carroll et al., 2006). Finally, while our results show that firms use structural solutions, such as equity joint ventures, to mitigate opportunism concerns in the transfer tacit knowledge, there is a rich line of research on how firms can handle opportunism but through informal solutions, such as trust-based governance (Madhok, 1995; Carson et al., 2003; Ghoshal & Moran, 1996). Gulati (1995) shows that partners formed non-equity alliances instead of equity alliances when they had prior ties, which he argued indicates the presence of prior trust between partners. We

29

tested if our results held even after controlling for prior familiarity between partners. We included in our regressions a dummy variable that indicated whether or not the recipient and transferor had a licensing or joint venture relationship before the focal one. And the results were not different from what we report here. DISCUSSION Our study seeks to contribute to the KBV-TCE debate on the relevance of opportunism for the theory of the firm. Both TCE and KBV predict that tacit know-how is more likely to be transferred through hierarchical modes than on the market, but TCE attributes this to market failure arising from opportunism concerns and KBV, to the difficulty in transferring tacit know-how owing to the absence of similar routines. We see this as the key bottleneck in the debate this far. While both theories disagree on the relevance of opportunism, they arrive at identical predictions for how tacit know-how is transferred. This lack of predictive uniqueness has also hindered empirical tests of the competing causal mechanisms. In this paper, we sought to move the KBV-TCE debate forward by crafting and testing contingency arguments from both theories. We examined whether opportunism matters to how tacit know-how is transferred. In testing contingency arguments from TCE, we predicted that the likelihood of tacit know-how being transferred through hierarchical modes will be stronger when opportunism inducing conditions are prevalenti.e., when know-how is core to the recipient firm in the host country and when the specific investments made by the recipient firm is high. Similarly, in testing contingency arguments from KBV, we predicted that the likelihood of tacit know-how being transferred through hierarchical modes will be weaker when the organizational culture and routines of the transferor and recipient are similar. Irrespective of our empirical findings, this theoretical approach confers several advantages. Framing arguments from KBV and TCE as contingency statements brings

30

distinctiveness to the predictions of both theories, and in the process, greater clarity to the debate. Contingency arguments also allowed us to tease out and isolate the different causal mechanisms in KBV and TCE and as a result, we conduct more direct tests of TCE and KBV positions (Tsang, 2006). We considered several candidate moderators of the relationship between tacitness and transfer mode to use in our study, but not all of them were useful for our purpose, viz., separating TCE and KBV predictions. On the one hand, many potential moderators that signal opportunism concerns can also be argued to signal transfer costs, but more importantly, the moderators that will do the job for us are those that deliver distinctive predictions for TCE and KBV. This is what has primarily guided our choice of moderators. From a TCE point of view we argue that when know-how is core to the recipient, it is likely to trigger opportunism concerns among both partieswith the transferor being concerned about potential knowledge leakage and the recipient, about misrepresentation of knowledge. Our second moderator, specific investment by the recipient, closely mirrors the TCE emphasis on asset specificity. These two, in our view, are distinctively TCE hypotheses. They are useful for our purpose because it is difficult to come up with knowledge-based explanations that result in the same predictions. Similarly, our third moderator similarity in routines and culture closely relates to the conceptual mechanisms of the knowledge-based view. It is difficult to draw an opportunism-based explanation for why similarity in routines should make the transfer of tacit know-how any easier. Besides the novelty of our theoretical approach that is based on contingency arguments, the fact that we bring some empirical evidence to bear on this debate is also valuable because the literature surrounding the debate has so far been largely on conceptual turf alone. Except for Kogut and Zanders (1993) article, all the other articles critiquing or defending their contention (e.g., McFetridge, 1995; Madhok, 1996; Love, 1995; Fransson et

31

al., 2011) have been conceptual. Even Kogut and Zanders (1993) article, although empirical in nature, was not able to partition out the causal mechanisms underlying KBV. As Kogut & Zander (1993: 633) themselves indicate, ...this test is by no means fully specified. In particular, we do not look at the capabilities of the recipient. Our paper has taken an empirical step forward in this direction. Implications The key implication of our study is that opportunism matters. Several aspects of our findings lend robust credence to this conclusion. Firstly, we set up two separate tests hypotheses 1 and 2 for whether opportunism matters, and across both, we find consistent results that it does. The likelihood of tacit know-how being transferred through hierarchy is significantly greater, both in terms of magnitude and statistical significance, when the knowhow is core to the recipient and when the recipient has made transaction specific investments. So opportunism necessitates recourse to hierarchy whenever the transferor seeks to transfer tacit know-how. Secondly, the robustness of this conclusion also comes from the fact that our results hold even when characteristics of our empirical test militate against finding any significant results. As discussed earlier, our test, based on only licensing and joint ventures, is very conservative. Thirdly, we do not find evidence that that transfers will be via licensing when transferor and recipient share the same routines and culture. In fact we find the opposite, although this result is not statistically significant. That is, we find that the likelihood of joint venture is higher when tacit know-how is transferred to recipients with similar routines and culture as the transferor. If we assume for a moment that similar routines reflect the ability of the recipient to compete back against the transferor, this result may also be considered additional support for TCE. When routines are similar, the transferor is likely to want better avenues for monitoring the use of know-how. And this is better afforded through JVs than licensing.

32

The second key implication of our results is that the causal mechanism underlying the often observed link between tacitness and hierarchical transfer modes is opportunism and not ease of transfer due to similar routines. As we have mentioned, an important point of contention in the KBV-TCE debate is that the link between tacitness and hierarchy is equally amenable to both KBV and TCE explanations. The way we set up our tests, we were able to directly test which of these two mechanisms is in play. There were three occasions in our empirical analysis for the KBV argument to receive support and show through. Had the effect of knowledge tacitness on transfer mode choice been insensitive to opportunism concerns (in hypotheses 1 and 2), that would have been sufficient to support the KBV contention. However, our results support the contention that opportunism matters. We also examined separate contingencies for KBV that transferring tacit knowledge hierarchically might be less likely if organizational culture and routines are similar. Finding this would have lent support to KBV that it is transfer costs and not opportunism that guides transfer mode choice. Our result for this prediction too was not significant. Across these three sets of results, we think it is fairly robust conclusion that, at least in our empirical context, opportunism and not similarity of routines is the relevant causal mechanism in play. A third important implication of our study is that it speaks to the question of what do firms do? This is a significant issue for the theory of the firm in general (Conner, 1991; Conner & Prahalad, 1996; Grant, 1996; Kogut & Zander, 1992; 1996; Foss, 1996a; 1996b), but also for the study of joint ventures (Gulati & Singh, 1998; Hennart, 1988). The dominant view until recent times has been that the raison d'etre for firms is their ability to curb opportunism. By virtue of better monitoring and incentive-alignment mechanisms, hierarchy reduces the payoffs from opportunism for the members of a firm (Kale & Puranam, 2004; Wathne & Heide, 2000; Williamson, 1985). To this end, Williamson (1985:66) says: ...market contracting would be ubiquitous in the face of nonopportunism. Departing from

33

this emphasis on opportunism and transaction cost mitigation, other scholars have suggested that what firms offer, over and above markets, is superior coordination abilities (Grant, 1996), the origins of which are in the social community of voluntaristic action inherent in firms (Kogut & Zander, 1992: 384). A similar opportunism-mitigation versus coordination argument has played out in the strategic alliance literature as well. One view in this literature is that joint ventures mainly serve an opportunism reduction purpose, i.e., since partners in a joint venture share from the gains of the venture, their incentives are aligned and they are less likely to act opportunistically (Hennart, 1988; Kale & Puranam, 2004). An alternative view is that joint ventures are chosen because they facilitate better coordination between partners (Gulati & Singh, 1998; Kogut & Zander, 1993; Madhok, 1995; 2006; Phene & Tallman, 2012). In recent times, however, scholars have converged on the notion that hierarchical governance mechanisms simultaneously serve both opportunism-mitigation and coordination functions (Kale & Puranam, 2004; Mesquita & Brush, 2008). In fact, TCE scholars in strategy and international business have not only highlighted the importance of coordination (Williamson, 1985; 1993), but even extended the transaction cost construct to include communication and coordination costs as well (Rugman & Verbeke, 2003; Phene & Tallman, 2012). What still distinguishes TCE and other perspectives on the question of what firms do, however, is its view on where the coordination benefits of hierarchy come from. To TCE proponents, coordination comes from reduced incentives of members of a firm to act opportunistically; ex-post maladaptation problems are less likely to arise in firms due to the absence of opportunism (Williamson, 1993: 97). The knowledge based view on the other hand ascribes coordination benefits to higher-order organizing principles (Kogut & Zander, 1992), a shared identity among members of a firm, and common procedural rules (Kogut & Zander, 1996). Somewhat similarly, Ghoshal & Moran (1996) suggest that coordination arises from a

34

sense of shared purpose. Contrasting the TCE view with theirs, they remark: the advantage of organizations over markets may not lie in overcoming human pathologies through hierarchy, but in leveraging the human ability to...cooperate (p. 42). So where do cooperation and coordination in firms really come from? Our view, which we think is reflected also in our empirical results, rests on the following three observations. Firstly, hierarchy need not automatically or always confer coordination benefits (Sako & Helper, 1998:391). Coordination, even within firms, is difficult unless specific mechanisms are in place (Bechky, 2003; Hansen, 1999; Mors, 2010). Hierarchy and superior coordination are thus not synonymous 3. Secondly, there is no reason why coordination, with some effort, cannot be effected on the market as well. If this statement is true, then hierarchy may not be essential to generating coordination benefits. Foss (1996a) makes this very point: ...the gains from...being embedded in higher order organizing principles could be realized over the market. In other words, agents could simply meet under the same factory roof, own their own pieces of physical capital equipment or rent it to each other, and develop valueenhancing organizing principles among themselves, or in other ways integrate their specialized knowledge. Firms would not be necessary (Foss & Klein, 2008; italics added). This view resonates well with Mesquita & Brush's (2008) empirical results that contracts, with some embellishments, can facilitate hierarchy-like coordination between alliance partners while at the same time, they do not adequately safeguard from opportunism (p.803). Srikanth & Puranam (2011) find similar results showing that fairly intensive coordination can be effected even in arms-length (offshoring) contracts. Moreover, investigating the kinds of coordination mechanisms within and across firms, Srikanth & Puranam (2010) conclude that there is no unique coordination mechanism within firms that cannot be implemented in

3 To be fair, Kogut & Zander do allude somewhat briefly to the difficulty in transferring knowhow between departments (1992: 389) and to the fact that firms differ in what they can do well (1996: 515). But their mainstream emphasis is on the coordination-enabling features of the firms through shared identities and higher order organizing principles.

35

contracts. Extrapolating from these results, one could argue that hierarchy is critical to curtailing opportunism but not to ensuring coordination. Thirdly, the argument that coordination arises from high-order organizing principles need not be inconsistent with an opportunism-based argument. Transaction cost theorists would suggest that ....the absence of opportunism that hierarchy may help to create stimulates the emergence of trust, cooperation, information exchange, and various sets of commitments, which is precisely what [is] packed into the concept of higher order organizing principles (Foss, 1996a: 473). Simply put, higher order coordination routines generally seen within firms could very well be because of the reduced payoffs from being opportunistic for members of the firm, and in that respect consistent with transaction cost theory. Taken together, these three observations suggest that the while the need for coordination is important in alliance governance, its role in driving the preference for hierarchy over market is not unequivocally clear. Coordination-benefits do not seem unique to hierarchy since firms can still suffer coordination problems, and effective coordination can occur on the market (Foss, 1996a; Srikanth & Puranam, 2011). What hierarchy really does is opportunism mitigation. And we think our results reflect this. In conditions were coordination is likely to be difficult, such as when routines and culture of partners are dissimilar, we do not find managers choosing joint venture over licensing. But on the other hand, the managers we surveyed chose joint ventures when opportunism concerns were high. So, what do firms do? They may very well facilitate coordination, but we think this is likely only because, as a first step, they mitigate opportunism. To be clear, we certainly do believe that coordination is crucial to transferring tacit knowledge (Nonaka, 1994), but not that this is what fundamentally distinguishes hierarchy and markets. There are, however, three important caveats to our story. Firstly, as we have said, our tests are very conservative. And despite that we find results supporting TCE. This strengthens

36

our confidence in the TCE results, but at the same time suggests that the insignificant findings for KBV do not indicate the theory is irrelevant or wrong. Our lack of support for KBV could simply be because our tests are too conservative to pick up those effects. Secondly, scholars have suggested that opportunism need not always be guileful. For example, Verbeke & Greidanus (2009) propose the concept of bounded reliability, taking into account that all failed commitments need not always be motivated by deceit. Our empirical analysis unfortunately does not distinguish between opportunism that is and isnt deceitful. And in that sense, Verbeke & Greidanuss (2009) concept of bounded reliability could very well be an alternative explanation to the conclusions we draw from our results. Thirdly, while we control for industry characteristics, we do not thoroughly explore whether our results are industrydependent. It is plausible that the relevance of opportunism could vary by industry. For example, in biotechnology alliances, knowledge transfer concerns rooted in coordination concerns and not opportunism could be more relevant (Phene & Tallman, 2012). Nevertheless, and despite these limitations, our study makes a worthwhile contribution to the opportunism debate. Conceptually, we derive distinctive predictions that capture the mechanisms underpinning KBV and TCE views, and empirically, we bring a set of results to bear on the question of whether or not opportunism matters. So, is opportunism really redundant in explaining the boundaries of the firm? Based on our research and subject to the caveats we have just mentioned, we think not. REFERENCES Ai, C.R., & Norton, E.C. 2003. Interaction terms in logit and probit models. Economics Letters, 80(1):123129. Anderson, E. 1988. Transaction costs as determinants of opportunism in integrated and independent sales forces. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 9(3): 247264. Armstrong, S.J., & Overton, T.S. 1977. Estimating non-response bias in mail surveys. Journal of Marketing Research, 14: 396-402. Arrow, K., 1962. Economic welfare and the allocation of resources for invention. In Arrow, K. (ed.) The rate and direction of economic activity. Princeton: Princeton University Press. Baranson, J. 1969. Industrial technologies for developing economies. NY: Praeger. 37

Barzel, Y. 1989. Economic analysis of property rights. NY: Cambridge University Press. Bechky, B.A. 2003. Sharing meaning across occupational communities: The transformation of understanding on a production floor. Organization Science, 14(3): 312- 330. Brief, A., & Downey, H.K. 1983. Cognitive and organizational structures: A conceptual analysis of implicit organizing theories. Human Relations. 36 (12): 1065-1090. Buckley, P., J & Casson, M., 1976. The future of the multinational enterprise, London: Macmillan. Busenitz, L.W., & Lau, C.M. 1996. A cross-cultural cognitive model of new venture creation. Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice. Summer: 25-39. Carroll, R.J., & Stefanski, L.A. 1990. Approximate quasilikelihood estimation in models with surrogate predictors. Journal of the American Statistical Association, 85: 652-663. Carroll, R.J., Ruppert, D., Stefanski, L.A., & Crainiceanu, C.M. 2006. Measurement error in nonlinear models: A modern perspective. London: Chapman & Hall. Carson, S.J., Madhok, A., Varman, R., & John, G. 2003. Information processing moderators of the effectiveness of trust-based governance in interfirm R&D collaboration. Organization Science, 14(1): 45-56. Chatterjee, A., & Hambrick, D.C. 2007. It's all about me: Narcissistic chief executive officers and their effects on company strategy and performance. Administrative Science Quarterly, 52(3): 351 386. Colombo, M.G. 2003. Alliance form: a test of the contractual and competence perspectives. Strategic Management Journal, 24: 1209-29. Conner, K.R. 1991. A historical comparison of resource-based theory and five schools of thought within industrial organization economics: Do we have a new theory of the firm? Journal of Management, 17(1): 121-154. Conner, K.R., & Prahalad, C.K. 1996. A resource-based theory of the firm: Knowledge versus opportunism. Organization Science, 7(5): 477-501. Crocker, K. J., & Masten, S.E. 1988. Mitigating contractual hazards: Unilateral options and contract length. RAND Journal of Economics, 24: 327-343. Crocker, K.J., & Reynolds, K.J. 1993. The efficiency of incomplete contracts: An empirical analysis of air force engine procurement. RAND Journal of Economics, 24(1): 126-146. Daft R.L., & Weick, K.E. 1984. Toward a model of organizations as interpretation systems. Academy of Management Review, 9(2): 284-295. David, R.J., & Han, S-K. 2004. A systematic assessment of the empirical support for transaction cost economics. Strategic Management Journal, 25: 39-58. Davidson, W.H., & McFetridge, D.G. 1985. Key characteristics in the choice of international technology transfer mode. Journal of International Business Studies, 16: 5-21. DeVellis, R.F. 1991. Scale development. Newbury Park, CA: Sage Publications. Dillman, D.A. 2000. Mail and internet surveys: The tailored design method. New York: Wiley. Donaldson, L. 1990. The ethereal hand: Organizational economics and management theory. Academy of Management Review, 15(3): 369-381. Dyer, J.H. 1996. Does governance matter? Keiretsu alliances and asset specificity as sources of Japanese competitive advantage. Organization Science, 7(6): 649-666. Ford, J.C., MacCallum, R.C., & Tait, M. 1986. The application of exploratory factor analysis in applied psychology: A critical review and analysis. Personnel Psychology, 39: 291-314. Foss, N.J. 1996a. Knowledge-based approaches to the theory of the firm: Some critical comments. Organization Science, 7(5): 470-476. Foss, N.J. 1996b. More critical comments on knowledge-based theories of the firm. Organization Science, 7(5): 519-523. Foss, N.J., & Klein, P. 2008. The theory of the firm and its critics: a stocktaking and 38

assessment. In Brousseau, E., & Glachant, J-M (eds) New Institutional Economics. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Fransson, A., Hkanson, L., & Liesch, P.W. 2011. The underdetermined knowledge-based theory of the MNC. Journal of International Business Studies, 42(3): 427-435. Gallick, E. C. 1984. Exclusive dealing and vertical integration: The efficiency of contracts in the tuna industry (Federal Trade Commission Bureau of Economics Staff Report). Washington D. C.: The Federal Trade Commission. Garca-Canal, E., Valds-Llaneza, A., & Snchez-Lorda, P. 2008. Technological flows and choice of joint ventures in technology alliances. Research Policy, 37 (1): 97-114. Ghemawat, P., Porter, M.E., & Rawlinson, R.A. 1986. Patterns of international coalition activity. In M.E. Porter (Ed.), Competition in global industries, Boston, MA: Harvard Business School Press. Ghoshal, S., & Moran, P. 1996. Bad for practice: A critique of the transaction cost theory. Academy of Management Review, 21(1): 13-47. Granovetter, M. 1985. Economic action and social structure: The problem of embeddedness. American Journal of Sociology, 91(3): 481-510. Grant, R. M. 1996. Toward a knowledge-based theory of the firm. Strategic Management Journal, 17(Winter special issue): 109-122. Gray, B., Bougon, M.G., & Donnellon, A. 1985. Organizations as constructions and destructions of meaning. Journal of Management, 11 (2): 83-98. Gulati, R. 1995. Does familiarity breed trust? The implications of repeated ties for contractual choice in alliances. Academy of Management Journal, 38(1): 85112. Gulati, R., & Singh, H., 1998. The architecture of cooperation: Managing coordination costs and appropriation concerns in strategic alliances. Administrative Science Quarterly, 43(4): 781814. Hall, G., & Johnson, R. 1970. Transfer of US aerospace technology to Japan. In: Vernon, R. (ed.) The technology factor in international trade. NY: Columbia University Press. Hansen, M.T. 1999. The search-transfer problem: The role of weak ties in sharing knowledge across organization subunits. Administrative Science Quarterly, 44(1): 82-111. Hardin, J.W., & Carroll, R.J. 2003. Measurement error, GLMs, and notational conventions. The Stata Journal, 3(4): 329-341. Hardin, J.W., Schmiediche, H., & Carroll, R.J. 2003. The regression-calibration method for fitting generalized linear models with additive measurement error. The Stata Journal, 3(4): 361-372. Harman, H.H. 1967. Modern factor analysis. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. Harrigan, K.R. 1988. Joint ventures and competitive strategy. Strategic Management Journal, 9: 141-158. Harris, S. G. 1994. Organizational culture and individual sensemaking: A schema-based perspective. Organization Science, 5(3): 309-321. Hennart, J-F. 1982. A theory of multinational enterprise. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press. Hennart, J-F. 1988. A transaction costs theory of equity joint ventures. Strategic Management Journal, 9(4): 361-374. Hennart, J-F. 1993. Explaining the swollen middle: Why most transactions are a mix of market and hierarchy. Organization Science, 4(4): 529-547. Hennart, J-F. 2001. Theories of the multinational enterprise. In Rugman, A. & Brewer, T. (eds.) The Oxford handbook of international business, Oxford: Oxford University Press: 127145. Hodgson, G.M. 1998. Competence and contract in the theory of the firm. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 35(2): 179-201. 39

Hoeppner, B.B., Kelly, J.F., Urbanoski, K.A., & Slaymaker, V. 2011. Comparative utility of a single-item versus multiple-item measure of self-efficacy in predicting relapse among young adults. Journal of Substance Abuse Treatment, 41(3): 305-312. Hoetker, G. 2007. The use of logit and probit models in strategic management research: Critical issues. Strategic Management Journal, 28(4): 331-343. Isobe, T., Makino, S., & Montgomery, D.B. 2000. Resource commitment, entry timing and market performance of foreign direct investments in emerging economies: The case of Japanese international joint ventures in China. Academy of Management Journal, 43(3): 468-484. Jensen, R., & Szulanski, G. 2004. Stickiness and the adaptation of organizational practices in cross-border knowledge transfers. Journal of International Business Studies, 35: 508523. Joskow, P. L. 1985. Vertical integration and long-term contracts: The case of coal-burning electric generating plants. Journal of Law, Economics, & Organization, 1: 33-80. Joskow, P. L. 1987. Contract duration and relationship specific investments: Empirical evidence from coal markets. American Economic Review, 77 168-185. Kale, P., & Puranam, P. 2004. Choosing equity stakes in technology sourcing relationships: An integrative framework. California Management Review, 46(3): 77-99. King, G., Tomz, M., & Wittenberg, J. 2000. Making the most of statistical analyses: improving interpretation and presentation. American Journal of Political Science, 44(2): 347361. Klein, B., Crawford, R.A., & Alchian, A.A., 1978. Vertical integration, appropriable rents, and the competitive contracting process. Journal of Law and Economics, 21(2): 297-326. Klimoski, R., & Mohammed, S. 1994. Team mental model: Construct or metaphor? Journal of Management, 20(2): 403-437. Kogut, B., & Singh, H. 1988. The effect of national culture on the choice of entry mode. Journal of International Business Studies, 19: 411-432. Kogut, B., & Zander, U. 1992. Knowledge of the firm, combinative capabilities, and the replication of technology. Organization Science, 3(3): 383397. Kogut, B., & Zander, U. 1993. Knowledge of the firm and the evolutionary theory of the multinational corporation. Journal of International Business Studies, 24(4): 625645. Kogut, B., & Zander, U. 1995. Knowledge, market failure and the multinational enterprise: A reply. Journal of International Business Studies, 26(2): 417426. Kogut, B., & Zander, U. 1996. What firms do? Coordination, identity, and learning. Organization Science, 7(5): 502-518. Kogut, B., & Zander, U. 2003. A memoir and reflection: Knowledge and an evolutionary theory of the multinational firm 10 years later. Journal of International Business Studies, 34(6): 505-515. Leiblein, M.J., & Miller, D.J. 2003. An empirical examination of transaction-and firm-level influences on the vertical boundaries of the firm. Strategic Management Journal, 24(9): 839859. Love, J.H. 1995. Knowledge, market failure and the multinational enterprise: A theoretical note. Journal of International Business Studies, 26(2): 399-407. Macher, J.T., & Richman, B.D. 2008. Transaction cost economics: An assessment of empirical research in the social sciences. Business and Politics, 10(1): 1-63. Madhok, A. 1995. Revisiting multinational firms' tolerance for joint ventures: A trust-based approach. Journal of International Business Studies, 26(1): 117-137. Madhok, A. 1996. The organization of economic activity: Transaction costs, firm capabilities, and the nature of governance. Organization Science, 7(5): 577-590. Madhok, A. 2006. How much does ownership really matter? Equity and trust relations in joint venture relationships. Journal of International Business Studies, 37(1): 4-11. 40

Malhotra, D., & Lumineau, F. 2011. Trust and collaboration in the aftermath of conflict: The effects of contract structure. Academy of Management Journal, 54(5): 981-998. Mayer, K. 2009. Construct validity and other issues in transaction cost economics empirical research. In Bergh, D., & Ketchen, D. (eds.) Research methodology in strategy and management (Volume 5). Mayer, K., & Nickerson, J.A. 2005. Antecedents and performance consequences of contracting for knowledge workers: Evidence from information technology services. Organization Science, 16: 225-242. Mayer, K., & Salomon, R. 2006. Capabilities, contractual hazards, and governance: Integrating resource-based and transaction cost perspectives. Academy of Management Journal, 49(5): 942-959. McFetridge, D.G. 1995. Knowledge, market failure and the multinational enterprise: A comment. Journal of International Business Studies, 26(2): 409-415. Mesquita, L.F., & Brush, T.H. 2008. Untangling safeguard and production coordination effects in long-term buyer-supplier relationships. Academy of Management Journal, 51(4): 785-807. Mitchell, R.K., Smith, B., Seawright, K.W., & Morse, E.A. 2000. Cross-cultural cognitions and the venture creation decision. Academy of Management Journal, 43(5): 974-993. Mohr, J., & Spekman, R. 1994. Characteristics of partnership success: Partnership attributes, communication behavior and conflict resolution techniques. Strategic Management Journal, 15: 135-152. Mors, M.L. 2010. Innovation in a global consulting firm: when the problem is too much diversity. Strategic Management Journal, 31(8): 841-872. Nickerson, J. and Silverman B. 2003. Why firms want to organize efficiently and what keeps them from doing so: Evidence from the for-hire trucking industry. Administrative Science Quarterly, 48: 433-65. Nonaka, I. 1994. A dynamic theory of organizational knowledge creation. Organization Science, 5(1): 14-37. Newman, J., & Krzystofiak, F. 1979. Self-reports versus unobtrusive measures: Balancing method variance and ethical concerns in employment discrimination research. Journal of Applied Psychology, 64(1): 82-85. Odagiri, H., Goto, A., Sunami, A., & Nelson, R. 2010. Conclusion. In: Odagiri, H., Goto, A., Sunami, A., Nelson, R. (eds), Intellectual property rights, development, and catch-up. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Olk, P. 1997. The effect of partner differences on the performance of R&D consortia. In P. Beamish & J. Killing (Eds.), Cooperative strategies, American perspectives. San Francisco: The New Lexington Press. OReilly III C, Chatman, J., & Caldwell, D.F. 1991. People and organizational culture: A profile comparison approach to assessing person-organization fit. Academy of Management Journal, 34(3): 487-516. Osborn, R., & Baughn, C. 1990. Forms of interorganizational governance for multinational alliances. Academy of Management Journal, 33(3): 503-519. Oxley, J.E. 1997. Appropriability hazards and governance in strategic alliances: A transaction cost approach. Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 13(2): 387-409. Park, S.H., & Ungson, G.R. 1997. The effect of national culture, organizational complementarity, and economic motivation on joint venture dissolution. Academy of Management Journal, 40(2): 279-307. Park, S.H., & Ungson, G.R. 2001. Interfirm rivalry and managerial complexity: A conceptual framework of alliance failure. Organization Science, 12 (1): 37-53. Parkhe, A. 1993. Strategic alliance structuring: A game theoretic and transaction cost 41

examination of interfirm cooperation. Academy of Management Journal, 36: 794-829. Phene, A., & Tallman, S. 2012. Complexity, context and governance in biotechnology alliances. Journal of International Business Studies, 43(1): 61-83. Poppo, L., & Zenger, T. 1998. Testing alternative theories of the firm: Transaction cost, knowledge-based, and measurement explanations for make-or-buy decisions in information services. Strategic Management Journal, 19(9): 853-877. Poppo, L., & Zenger, T. 2002. Do formal contracts and relational governance function as substitutes or complements? Strategic Management Journal, 23(8): 707-726. Rajan, R.G., & Zingales, L. 1998. Financial dependence and growth. American Economic Review, 88(3): 559-586. Robins, J.A., Tallman, S., & Lindquist, K.F. 2002. Autonomy and dependence of international cooperative ventures: An exploration of the strategic performance of U.S. ventures in Mexico. Strategic Management Journal, 23: 881-901. Rousseau, D. 1990. Quantitative assessment of organizational culture: The case for multiple measures. In B.Schneider (Ed.), Frontiers in industrial and organizational psychology, vol. 3: 153-192. San Francisco: Jossey-Bass. Rugman, A. 1981. Inside the multinationals: The economics of internal markets, New York: Columbia University Press. Rugman, A., & Verbeke, A. 2003. Extending the theory of the multinational enterprise: Internalization and strategic management perspectives. Journal of International Business Studies, 34(2): 125137. Sako, M., & Helper, S. 1998. Determinants of trust in supplier relations: Evidence from the automotive industry in Japan and the United States. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 34(3): 387-417. Sampson, R.C. 2004. Organizational choice in R&D alliances: Knowledge-based and transaction cost perspectives. Managerial and Decision Economics, 25(6-7): 421436. Schein, E.H. 1985. Organizational culture and leadership. San Francisco, Jossey-Bass. Schneider, S.C., & Angelmar, R. 1993. Cognition in organizational analysis: Whos minding the store? Organization Studies, 14(3): 347-374. Scott, W.R. 2001. Institutions and Organizations. Thousand Oaks, California: Sage Publications. Shaw, J.B. 1990. A cognitive categorization model for the study of intercultural management. Academy of Management Review, 15(4): 626-645. Shelanski, H.A., & Klein, P. 1995. Empirical research in transaction cost economics: A review and assessment. Journal of Law Economics and Organization, 11(2): 335-361. Simon, H.A. 1985. Human nature in politics: The dialogue of psychology with political science. American Political Science Review, 79(2): 293-304. Simonin, B.L. 1999. Ambiguity and the process of knowledge transfer in strategic alliances. Strategic Management Journal, 20: 595-624. Smircich, L. 1983. Concepts of culture and organizational analysis. Administrative Science Quarterly, 28: 339-359. Srikanth, K., & Puranam, P. 2010. Coordination within vs. across firm boundaries. Working paper (http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=1534632&download=yes). Srikanth, K., & Puranam, P. 2011. Integrating distributed work: comparing task design, communication, and tacit coordination mechanisms. Strategic Management Journal, 32(8): 849-875. Tallman, S. 2003. The significance of Bruce Koguts and Udo Zanders article,Knowledge of the firm and the evolutionary theory of the multinational corporation. Journal of International Business Studies, 34(6): 495497. Teece, D.J. 1986. Transactions cost economics and the multinational enterprise An 42

assessment. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 7(1): 2145. Tomz, M., Wittenberg, J., & King, G. 2001. CLARIFY: Software for interpreting and presenting statistical results, Version 2.0. http://gking.harvard.edu. Tsang, E.W.K. 2006. Behavioral assumptions and theory development: The case of transaction cost economics. Strategic Management Journal, 27(11): 999-1011. Verbeke, A. 2003. The evolutionary view of the MNE and the future of internalization theory. Journal of International Business Studies, 34(6): 498-504. Verbeke, A., & Greidanus, N.S. 2009. The end of the opportunism vs trust debate: Bounded reliability as a new envelope concept in research on MNE governance. Journal of International Business Studies, 40(9): 1471-1495. Walsh J.P., & Ungson, G.R. 1991. Organizational memory. Academy of Management Review, 16(1): 57-91. Wathne, K. H., & Heide, J.B. 2000. Opportunism in inter-firm relationships: Forms, outcomes, and solutions. Journal of Marketing, 64(4): 36-51. Webb, E., & Weick, K.E. 1979. Unobtrusive measures in organizational theory: A reminder. Administrative Science Quarterly, 24(4): 659-659. Williamson, O.E. 1985. The economic institutions of capitalism, New York: The Free Press. Williamson, O.E. 1991. Comparative economic organization: The analysis of discrete structural alternatives. Administrative Science Quarterly, 36(2): 269296. Williamson, O.E. 1993. Opportunism and its critics. Managerial and Decision Economics, 14(2): 97-107. Zelner, B. 2009. Using simulation to interpret results from logit, probit, and other nonlinear models. Strategic Management Journal, 30 (12): 1335-1348. Zumbo, B.D., Gaderman, A., & Zeisser, C., 2007. Ordinal versions of coefficients alpha and theta for Likert rating scales. Journal of Modern Applied Statistical Methods, 6: 21-29.

43

TABLE 1 Descriptive statistics and pair-wise correlations

Variable 1 JV 2 Tacitness of know-how package 3 Centrality of know-how to recipient 4 Size of specific investment 5 Similarity of routines and culture 6 Age of technology 7 Prior export 8 Cultural distance

Mean SD 0.58 0.38 0.79 1.44 2.92 3.74 0.22 7.25 0.5 0.33 0.41 0.96 0.92 0.71 0.42 1.62

Min Max 0 0 0 1 1 1 1 1 5 5

1 0.31 1 0.16 -0.03 0.16 0.23 0.04 -0.15 0.03 0.13 0.16 -0.06 -0.06 -0.05

1 -0.03 1 0.19 -0.09 1 0.07 0.11 -0.02 1 0.06 -0.01 0.05 -0.19 1 0.02 0.19 -0.14 -0.04 -0.01 1

1 4 0 1 2.63 12.16

44

TABLE 2 Results of logistic regression analysis: Choice of equity joint venture as dependent variable

Model 1

Model 2

Model 3

Model 4

Model 5

Model 6

Model 7

Tacitness of know-how package

2.412*** (0.720)

2.308*** (0.779) 0.945* (0.570)

2.361*** (0.812) 0.936* (0.557) 0.438 (0.325) 0.0607 (0.251) 2.832 (1.764)

2.920*** (0.925) 1.198** (0.609) 0.193 (0.402) 0.136 (0.256)

2.352*** (0.787) 0.870 (0.577) 0.297 (0.295) 0.121 (0.248)

3.351*** (1.046) 1.637** (0.702) 0.531 (0.467) 0.0798 (0.268) 5.891** (2.417)

Centrality of know-how to recipient

Size of specific investment

0.270 (0.296)

Similarity of routines and culture

0.114 (0.247)

Tacitness X Centrality of know-how to recipient Tacitness X Size of investment

3.670** (1.811)

5.920** (2.513) 0.505 (0.772) 0.435 (0.877) 0.239 (0.378) 1.558** (0.758) -0.160 (0.164) included 0.777 (1.956) 112

Tacitness X Similar routines

Age of technology

0.111 (0.290)

-0.02 (0.323) 1.005* (0.573) -0.127 (0.136) included 1.521 (1.635) 116

-0.07 (0.347) 0.941 (0.637) -0.194 (0.149) included 2.230 (1.781) 112

0 (0.350) 0.975 (0.647) -0.218 (0.152) included 2.204 (1.808) 112

0.04 (0.362) 1.277* (0.694) -0.118 (0.156) included 1.240 (1.876) 112

-0.06 (0.356) 0.992 (0.643) -0.191 (0.149) included 2.194 (1.812) 112

Prior export by transferor

0.787 (0.535)

Cultural distance

-0.112 (0.126)

Industry dummies Constant

included 0.800 (1.466)

Observations

116

*** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1 Standard errors in parentheses

45

TABLE 3 The effect of tacitness () at various levels of other independent variables

[1] Predicted probability of JV at low tacitness (low tacit)

[2] Predicted probability of JV at high tacitness (high tacit)

[3]

[4] 95 % CI of [4b] Upper bound

Effect of [4a] tacitness (), Lower i.e., change in bound predicted probability of JV, [2] [1]

1 Centrality of know- (a) Minimum value how to recipient held at its: (b) Maximum value 2 Size of specific investment held at its: (a) Minimum value (b) Maximum value

0.45 0.30 0.50 0.03

0.24 0.96 0.65 0.99

-0.21 0.66 0.15 0.96

-0.71 0.39 -0.27 0.58

0.42 0.86 0.49 0.99

3 Similarity of (a) Minimum value routines and culture (b) Maximum value held at its:

0.38 0.30

0.80 0.92

0.42 0.62

-0.29 0.05

0.85 0.93

** significant at p < 0.05

46

TABLE 4 Test of interaction effects: Difference in effect of tacitness at high and low values of moderator variables

Effect of tacitness () when moderator variable at its minimum value (moderator at min) Moderator variables: Centrality of know-how to the recipient -0.21

Effect of tacitness () when moderator variable at its maximum value (moderator at max)

Double difference: Difference in the effects of tacitness at low and high values of the moderator variable: = (moderator at max - moderator at min )

95 % CI of

Lower bound

Upper bound

0.66

0.87**

0.16

1.44

Size of specific investment

0.15

0.96

0.81**

0.26

1.27

Similarity of routines and culture **significant at p < .05

0.42

0.62

0.21

-0.66

1.15

47

FIGURE 1 Effect of tacitness at various values of centrality of know-how to recipient

48

FIGURE 2 Effect of tacitness at various values of size of specific investment

49

FIGURE 3 Effect of tacitness at various values of similar routines

50

You might also like