You are on page 1of 57

Incarceration, Unemployment, and Eurosclerosis!

Felix Elwert Harvard University

First Version: March 2000 This Version: August 2002

Direct correspondence to Felix Elwert, Department of Sociology, 622 William James Hall, Harvard University, Cambridge, MA 02138 (elwert@fas.harvard.edu). Part of this research was previously presented at the Bureau of Labor Statistics, Washington D.C., March 1999, and circulated as a research report (2000) for Understanding Unemployment and Working Time: A Cross-Country Comparative Study,! funded by the Ford and Rockefeller Foundations. I thank Christopher Winship, Stephen Morgan, Mariko Chang, Lawrence Bobo, David Howell, Orlando Patterson, Barry Bluestone, Constance Sorrentino, David Harding, Tobias Linzert, and Jay Gabler for discussions and advice. Laura Silverberg provided splendid editing assistance.

Abstract This paper contradicts the current consensus about the role of incarceration in U.S.-European labor market performance differentials. Theoretically, I develop a more general model for the causal interrelationship between incarceration and unemployment that integrates admission, release, and employment effects. Empirically, I show that the causal effect of incarceration on unemployment is (1) considerably smaller than previously reported; (2) not large enough to noticeably impact U.S.-European performance differentials; and (3) potentially increasing, rather than decreasing the official U.S. unemployment rate. I further demonstrate that the forced inactivity of the U.S. incarcerated population does not question the reality of U.S.-European labor market performance differentials, even when prisoners are included in labor market measurement.

Word count: 12,498.

INTRODUCTION Measurement and explanation of labor market performance continue to pose significant challenges for social research. Nowhere do these analytical difficulties surface more acutely than in the international comparison of labor market regimes where sociologically enlightened investigations must engage considerable variation across institutional frameworks. The debate on high unemployment in Europe, and the role of U.S. incarceration therein, is a case in point. European unemployment rates have exceeded U.S. rates since the early 1980s. Between 1984 and 2000, standardized unemployment rates in the fifteen European Union member states hovered between eight and eleven percent, surpassing U.S. rates by four percentage points on average (Figure 1). Earlier attempts to explain this disparity have focused on a collection of institutional conditions, popularly known as Eurosclerosis.! This summary diagnosis attributes the European predicament to labor market rigidities, misaligned incentive structures, excessive workers' rights, and redistributive welfare state policies, while the United States is thought to have escaped high unemployment through labor market deregulation and wage flexibility (for reviews, see Krugman 1994; Howell 2000). Much empirical research contradicts this account (e.g. Blank 1994; Freeman 1995; Buchele and Christiansen 1998; Marshall 1999; Howell 2000), yet politically it has become a veritable article of faith that continues to inspire deregulatory European labor market legislation. Public policy requires theory for guidance and legitimacy. Conceivably, it is the absence of an alternative theory as simple and persuasive as Eurosclerosis! that has allowed political pressures on the European welfare states to linger. Recent years have witnessed the emergence of an alternative research agenda, which maintains the institutional focus but concentrates on a surprising new candidate, incarceration. The U.S. incarcerated population has quadrupled to two million inmates since 1980. Meanwhile,

European incarceration grew at a slower pace and today remains at significantly lower levels. The timing of the U.S. prison boom thus roughly coincides with the emergence of the U.S.European unemployment rate differential. If, as Jancovic (1977) first investigated, the United States hides part of its unemployment problem behind bars, or, alternatively, if incarceration is to be viewed as forced unemployment (Freeman 1995), then official labor force statistics, which exclude the incarcerated population from consideration, understate U.S. unemployment and overstate the EU-U.S. unemployment gap. This paper assesses the evidence for incarceration-based accounts of the U.S.-European unemployment rate differential. Analytically, the literature divides into two approaches, causal and accounting (Western and Beckett 1999). The causal approach is an explanatory one, asking how the labor market would have performed had the prison system evolved differently, given current definitions of labor market performance (Jancovic 1977; Western and Beckett 1998, 1999; Katz and Krueger 1999). Its main contention is that rising incarceration has lowered the official unemployment rate because many inmates were unemployed prior to their incarceration. The accounting approach, by contrast, deals with measurement and asks how our perception of labor market performance would change if we used different lenses # definitions, measures, and conventions # to view a given reality of labor market and incarceration (Jencks 1992; Freeman 1995; Faux 1997; Buchele and Christiansen 1998; Western and Beckett 1998, 1999; Western, Beckett and Harding 1998; Western and Pettit 2000). Its main concern is whether apparent unemployment rate differentials from the official statistics are robust to alternative measures of labor market inactivity that include the incarcerated population in the unemployment count. Empirical results differ in magnitude but agree in direction. From a causal perspective, Western and Beckett (1999) conclude that incarceration lowered the official male U.S.

unemployment rate by 0.6 percentage points in 1995. At zero incarceration male unemployment would have been at 6.2 rather than officially 5.6 percent (Western and Beckett 1999, p.1039). Using a similar methodology, Katz and Krueger (1999, p.42-44) estimate that the increase in incarceration between 1985 and 1998 caused the official male unemployment rate to decrease by 0.3 percentage points. Notwithstanding effects in the opposite direction due to increased

unemployment among released former inmates, rising incarceration is asserted to cause an overall decrease of unemployment in the labor market (Western and Beckett 1999, p.1053). Results from the accounting perspective are even stronger. In their analysis of the four largest European countries, E-4, Buchele and Christiansen (1998, p.121) find that "the large 1988-95 prime-age male unemployment gap in favor of the US $ shrinks to an insignificant non-employment gap $ and reverses itself for 1992/93 in favour of the [E-4] $ when the nonemployment rates are adjusted to include the incarcerated population." Similarly, Western and Beckett (1999, p.1032) show that including inmates in the unemployment count raises the male U.S. unemployment rate by a full third, or two percentage points, from 5.6 to 7.5 percent (1999, p.1041). Their modified unemployment rate indicates that the U.S. has outperformed

unemployment in Europe only from the early 1990s, rather than from the early 1980s as suggested by the official rates. According to these results, On account of their theoretical and political importance, these results have received considerable attention and distribution in the academic world and the public press (e.g. Wacquant 1998; Justice Policy Institute 2000; Petersilia 2000; Mauer 2001; Downes 2001; Wray 2001). Methodologically, this new research agenda highlights the limitations of truncated Theoretically, it demonstrates the importance of non-

sampling in labor market research.1

For example, Mare and Winship (1984) show that a substantial portion of the relative decline in African American youth employment in the 1960s and 70s can be explained through increased school enrollment and military service.

economic institutions in the determination of market! outcomes, thus confirming a central tenet of economic sociology. Incarceration appears to both contribute to a new explanation of existing unemployment rate differentials and to cast doubt on their very reality. For that reason,

incarceration may furnish double ammunition against popular notions of Eurosclerosis and their policy implications. To wit, it seems as if incarceration contributes to a new etiology for the disease of high unemployment in Europe while simultaneously questioning its symptoms. This paper questions the current consensus about the impact of incarceration on labor market inactivity.2 In the main part of this paper I extend the theoretical agenda through a more complete model for the causal interrelationship between incarceration and unemployment that distinguishes between admission, release, and employment effects of incarceration. I note that prior work has unduly focused on admission effects to the neglect of total causal effects. Empirically, I show that the causal (admission) effect of incarceration on aggregate unemployment is considerably lower than previously thought. Performing a sensitivity analysis for the total causal effect, I argue that incarceration may quite possibly have increased, rather than decreased unemployment in the labor market. Next, I critically engage the accounting approach and show that it is unclear whether current measurement protocols hide or exaggerate inactivity. Drawing on detailed U.S. and European data I show that incarceration does not qualitatively change comparisons between U.S. and EU labor market performance from either the causal or accounting perspectives. The results presented in this paper do not furnish support

Chandra (2001) shows that past research systematically overstates the decline in the racial wage gap by neglecting the increased institutionalization and incarceration of African American men. 2 Dissenting voices are rare. In a commentary, Greenberg recently concluded that the main reason unemployment dropped was not that the number of [inmates] rose $ it was because the economy was expanding! (2001, p. 72). The present paper goes beyond Greenberg (2001) by formally engaging both causal and accounting perspectives, incorporating European data, and extending the theoretical agenda of incarceration effects through a revised model of causal interrelationships.

for popular notions of Eurosclerosis, but they indicate that incarceration does not provide evidence against them either. Next, I briefly detail the relevant trends in incarceration in the United States and Europe and review the concepts underlying OECD labor market measurement.

TRENDS IN INCARCERATION U.S. incarceration rates are high in international comparison. In 1999, more than one fifth, or 1.9 million, of the 8.6 million people held in penal institutions worldwide were incarcerated in U.S. prisons and jails (Walmsley, 2000). Table 1 shows the size of the incarcerated population and incarceration rates per 100,000 residents for twenty-two countries of the western world, Russia, and China. Incarceration rates in OECD countries ranged between 60 and 130. The U.S., by contrast, imprisoned 680 out of every 100,000 adult residents, more than seven times the European Union average, and second only to Russia. Due to a Russian mass amnesty in 2000 the U.S. today has the highest known incarceration rate in the world (Sentencing Project, 2001). When parolees and probationers are added to the count of prison and jail inmates, the total number of individuals under the supervision of the U.S. criminal justice system in 1999 sums to 6.3 million, roughly 3 percent of the adult population and 5 percent of the total labor force. Nationally, one percent of white men and close to seven percent of African American men are incarcerated (Bureau of Justice Statistics [BJS], 2000a). U.S. % leadership&in incarceration is a relatively recent development. Figure 2 shows time series for the size of the incarcerated populations in the U.S. and the 15 member countries of the European Union (EU-15). The number of inmates in U.S. prisons grew relatively slowly during much of the twentieth century, doubling from about 92,000 to 196,000 between 1925 and 1970.

The prison boom started only in the late 1970s. Between 1980 # the first year for which reliable data on the size of the jail population are available # and 2000, the incarcerated population quadrupled from one half to 2 million (BJS 2000a; Sentencing Project 2001). Over the same period, European incarceration did not even double, rising from 212,000 to 366,000 (Council of Europe 1984-2000). A juxtaposition of the trends in Figures 1 and 2 shows that the sharp rise in U.S. incarceration since the late 1970s correlates with a decrease in the U.S. unemployment rate.3

INDICATORS OF LABOR MARKET PERFORMANCE This section discusses several measures of labor market performance used in the subsequent theoretical and empirical discussions. Labor market performance is a multidimensional construct that cannot be captured by any single indicator. Choosing between indicators depends on the purpose of measurement. This is unproblematic as long as choices are carefully reasoned and properly disclosed. The measures and arguments described in this section are those used in official U.S. labor market statistics. They closely resemble European measurement standards, as both are based on the same set of international guidelines proposed by the International Labor Office and endorsed by OECD member countries (ILO 1982; OECD 1985). The unemployment rate, UROfficial, is the most widely used among these statistics. It is defined as the ratio of unemployment, U, to the labor force, LF, which equals the sum of unemployment and employment, E.

UROfficial =
3

U U *100 = *100 U+E LF

(1)

The zero-order correlation between the U.S. unemployment rate and incarceration is r = #.71 for men and r = #.76 for both sexes.

The Current Population Survey (CPS), which collects the official U.S. labor market data, defines employment as doing any work for pay or profit during the survey& s reference week. Payment may be monetary, or in kind, such as meals, living quarters, room and board, or supplies received in place of cash wages! (U.S. Bureau of the Census 1998, section B1). The official definition of employment is not tied to any minimum standards of decency, such as earning above minimum wage, working under safe conditions, or even legality. The definition is broad; literally, any work! for pay or profit qualifies (U.S. Bureau of the Census 1998, p. C4-2). Individuals not employed are classified as non-employed. Unemployment, by contrast, is a considerably more restrictive concept than employment or non-employment. According to U.S. concepts, unemployment is defined by the triple criteria of (1) not working, yet (2) being available for work during the reference week, and (3) having actively looked for work over the past four weeks. Of these requirements, the active search criterion is the strongest. Contacting an employment agency or prospective employer or placing an ad in the newspaper count as active search, whereas reading ads or participating in job training programs do not (U.S. Bureau of the Census 1988, p. B2-2). The unemployment rate is meant to measure the degree to which labor supply is met by demand. Labor supply is equated with the labor force. Unmet labor supply is equated with unemployment. If labor market performance means market clearance, then the unemployment rate is a direct measure for market failure.4

The unemployment rate has several oft-neglected siblings, U-1 through U-7 (Shiskin 1976), which differ from the standard unemployment rate in the degree to which they consider part-time employed individuals as unemployed.! For example, U-1 considers only persons who have been unemployed for thirteen or more weeks. U-7 includes the usual unemployed, persons working part-time for economic reasons (i.e. involuntarily), and discouraged workers (Sorrentino 1993). U-1 through U-7 thus differ in their underlying concept of labor supply.

It is important to emphasize that unemployment, conceptually, is not the same as nonemployment, joblessness, or labor market inactivity. Unemployment is intended to capture unmet labor supply and is therefore (per OECD definitions) limited to individuals that demonstrate their willingness and availability for market work through active job search behavior. A large fraction of those non-employed, jobless, or inactive does not fit this

description (e.g. full-time college students, homemakers, and retirees). The extent to which a population is not employed therefore is better measured by the employment to population ratio, EPR, (which divides the number of employed persons by the total, civilian, non-institutional population), or its complement, the non-employment to population rate, NEPR. The (non)employment to population ratio separates the population into those that do any work for pay or profit and those that don& t. All of these measures (UR, EPR, NEPR, U-1/U-7) in one way or another capture labor utilization. The unemployment rate captures the fraction of persons willing and available for market work who are not taken up on their offer, while the employment to population ratio measures what fraction of the population is contributing to GDP through paid work. As

indicators of labor utilization, these measures are evidently imperfect. Better indicators would consider hours worked and hours desired to work. However, such more detailed statistics are hard to measure and are rarely attempted.

The Exclusion of Inmates from Official Labor Market Measurement Official labor market statistics in the United States and Europe are defined on the civilian non-institutional population, rather than the total resident population. Excluded are members of the armed forces and residents of non-institutional households, such as students living in dorms,

residents of homes for the elderly, and inmates of mental institutions.5

Important for our

purposes, the entire incarcerated population # inmates of prisons and jails # is excluded from official labor market measurement. The literature challenges the exclusion of prison and jail inmates (e.g. Downes 2001, p.62), but never discusses its rationale. I therefore review the official rationale before analyzing its effect on labor market statistics. The OECD, building on the international standards of labor market measurement set by the International Labor Office (ILO 1982), justifies the exclusion of the incarcerated population with technical arguments regarding the primacy of the employment concept (OECD 1985, p.12). On the most basic level, ILO and OECD define employment as direct contribution to GDP as defined by the UN-OECD system of national accounts (SNA). Individuals contributing to GDP are to be counted as employed (OECD 1985, p.13). But whereas OECD guidelines explicitly acknowledge that inmates may receive monetary wages or payment in kind from jobs in the prison industries, farm work, food preparation or prison maintenance, they are nonetheless not to be counted as employed because the SNA regards expenses for feeding, housing, and paying prisoners part of government intermediate consumption, which does not factor into GDP. In short, because paid inmate labor, in a technical sense, does not contribute to GDP, inmates are not counted as employed, even though they would fulfill the CPS criteria of employment. Consequently, inmates may not be counted as unemployed either because unemployment requires the possibility of employment (OECD 1985, p.15). Compare the treatment of prisoners to that of monks in conventional labor market measurement. The OECD acknowledges that members of contemplative religious orders (e.g.
5

A small number of OECD countries include the military in their labor market statistics (Sorrentino, 2000). The U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics included the military for a few years until the early 1990s, but discontinued the practice for three reasons: (1) Data on the number of military personnel stationed in the U.S. (not overseas) proved unreliable; (2) their inclusion made little difference; and (3) the BLS perceived little demand for the inclusive series (Phil Rones, BLS, personal communication, March 1999).

Trappist or Buddhist monks) may spend most of their time in prayer or meditation! rather than gainful employment. But even if the inmates [of monasteries] receive no cash payment of any kind, so long as they are housed and fed they are considered to receive an income in kind which is to be recorded in the GDP. Members of religious orders are therefore included in

employment! (OECD 1985, p.14). In other words, prisoners that work for pay may not be counted as employed, but monks that receive nothing beside room and board in return for meditation must be counted. # Obviously, these rules concern the outer limits of the OECD& s GDP-based definitions, and they exhibit a certain degree of arbitrariness. It is this arbitrariness that provides a good argument for exploring alternative measures of labor market performance that do not exclude the incarcerated population wholesale. I will return to this point in the analysis of accounting effects below. In addition to this technical argument, several theoretical and practical reasons could be considered to justify the exclusion of the incarcerated population from labor market measurement. First, working or not, prisoners are not free participants in the labor market. As such, their work may be regarded akin to slave labor (cf. Wacquant 2000; Buck 1994), which could warrant their exclusion from official labor statistics on technical as well as moral grounds.6 Second, economists and governments routinely use the unemployment rate as an indicator of inflationary tendencies. Low unemployment proxies wage pressures, which may lead to an increase in the nominal wage level and thus inflation. If the incarcerated population were counted with the unemployed, then the unemployment rate would signal an excess of labor supply beyond the actual number of laborers still available in the market. An inclusion of the

The debate on counting slave labor as free labor in the literature on the economics of slavery (cf. Fogel and Engerman 1974, pp.207-209; David and Temin 1976, pp. 209-214, 223-230) parallels the contemporary discourse on prison labor in many ways. Note that the BLS originally excluded military personnel from the employment count because military service was not voluntary under the draft (National Commission 1979, p.49).

incarcerated population in UROfficial would thus mask inflationary potential. Third, although the unemployment rate is neither intended nor particularly well suited to measure social and economic hardship (Cain 1979, p.11; National Commission 1979, p.66-68), it is nonetheless often used one. Conflating inadvertent hardship from unemployment in the market with socially intended hardship in prison would further obscure the value of the unemployment rate as a measure of misfortune. Finally, including the incarcerated population into UROfficial would

impair its international comparability. If nations differed significantly in incarceration rates, then differences in national unemployment rates could no longer be interpreted as corresponding to differences in the degree of labor market clearance because the unemployment! associated with people in prison is beyond the means of the labor market to eradicate. To be sure, these arguments refer to the stated purpose of the official statistics. They do not imply that the incarcerated population should never be considered in labor market measurement. The design of any statistical measure has to be judged in light of the purpose of measurement, and purposes may change. Next, we turn to investigating the questions following from the exclusion of the incarcerated population from measures of labor market performance.

THE CAUSAL EFFECT OF INCARCERATION ON UNEMPLOYMENT This section investigates the causal effect of incarceration on unemployment. In order to avoid a confusion of causal and accounting-type questions, I take the official concepts of employment and unemployment as given in this section. Throughout, I adopt the standard counterfactual notion of causality (Rubin 1978; Holland 1986; Sobel 1996; Winship and Morgan 1999) and ask what the size of the official unemployment rate would be had there been no

changes in incarceration.

I focus on the unemployment rate for two reasons.

First, the

unemployment rate is the key measure of labor market performance and also the measure with regard to which most of the debate on incarceration and labor market performance is led in the U.S. Second, the unemployment rate serves as the reference point for the debate on weak labor market performance in Europe. In order to contribute to both debates, I must relate to the same outcome of interest. I first delineate three theoretical mechanisms that causally link incarceration to unemployment and derive a formal model for the total causal effect of incarceration. Empirically, I present direct estimates for what I term the net admission effect of incarceration, and a sensitivity analysis for the total causal effect. The results suggest that previously published results overstate the effect on the U.S. unemployment rate by a wide margin. Repeating the analysis with European data shows that incarceration fails to provide a new causal explanation for the U.S.-European unemployment rate differential.

Theory: Admission, Release, and Employment Effects The unemployment rate is linked to changes in incarceration via three mechanisms: admission, release, and employment effects. In reality, these three mechanisms will occur

simultaneously and jointly produce the overall causal effect. In theory, each mechanism can be described ceteris paribus. Admission effects occur when new inmates, which, as a group, had a different unemployment rate from the rest of the population, enter prison or jail. If newly admitted inmates suffered from a higher level of unemployment prior to their incarceration than the civilian, non-institutional population that remains behind, then UROfficial will fall because official

labor force statistics exclude the institutionalized population from consideration. Admission effects are plausible because the unemployed, poor, and educationally or otherwise disadvantaged # not to mention traditionally disadvantaged young minority males # face both higher unemployment and greater odds of incarceration. The literature to date on the causal effect of incarceration on unemployment exclusively considers admission effects.7 Release effects occur when released inmates, as a group, face a different unemployment rate than the rest of the population. If newly released inmates suffer from a level of unemployment higher than the rest of the civilian, non-institutional population, then UROfficial will rise. Release effects are plausible mainly because ex-convicts suffer severe stigmatization. Much

ethnographic and quantitative research documents the disadvantage, prejudice, and suspicion that former inmates face in the labor market (e.g. Dale 1976; Davinedas 1983; Hagan 1993; Freeman 1992; Miller 1996; Holzer 1996; Western, Beckett, and Harding 1998; Kling 1999). Furthermore, prisoners experience a deterioration of existing job skills, human capital, and social capital8 while in prison, and forego the acquisition of new work experience and schooling. To a degree, the existence of release effects is even inscribed in the statues, as many states bar exinmates from public employment (Travis et al 2001, p.31). Even short spells in jail may produce measurable release effects if employers treat unexcused absences or the embarrassment of imprisonment as grounds for dismissal (Miller 1996). Release effects will occur even if the net growth of the prison population is zero, due to the constant replacement of current prisoners. Since incarceration represents a large-scale social intervention, it has macro-level effects beyond inmates&own past and future employment status, i.e. beyond admission and release
7

Katz and Krueger (1999) and Western and Beckett (1999) acknowledge the existence of release effects, but do not provide aggregate level estimates. 8 To be precise, inmates often face not only deterioration but also a transformation of their social capital. Tie s to the legal world are undermined, while ties to crime are formed or cemented. Prisons are important recruiting venues for gangs and organized crime.

effects.

One macro-level, or general equilibrium, effect relates to the construction boom

generated by the demand for new correctional facilities (Hallinan 2001). Another concerns the expansion in prison related employment, such as in security and maintenance (BJS 1997e, p.15). If these macro-level implications of mass incarceration provide jobs for workers whom would otherwise have remained unemployed, then the growth of the prison sector creates an employment effect that lowers the official unemployment rate. The total causal effect of incarceration on unemployment, understood as the tradeoff between admission, release, and employment effects, is thus determined not simply by the level of incarceration at any given point in time, but crucially by the volume of inmates moving into and out of prison and jail over time, as well as by their macro societal ramifications.

A Model for the Total Causal Effect of Incarceration on Unemployment We can formalize these mechanisms and derive a simple yet general measure for the total effect of incarceration. The measure relates the official unemployment rate to the hypothetical unemployment rate that would have been obtained had prisons and jails not admitted or released any inmates (i.e. had there been no changes in incarceration). The difference between the official and the hypothetical rate identifies the causal effect. For clarity of exposition, I first consider only changes occurring during a single year. First, note that incarceration will cause the official annual unemployment count to change if the number of unemployed people admitted to prison differs from the number of inmates released into unemployment in a given year. The official level of unemployment, UOfficial, thus equals the hypothetical level, UHypo, that would have prevailed in the absence of changes in incarceration, minus the number of unemployed people admitted, plus the number released into

unemployment. To allow for employment effects, further subtract the number of newly created prison-related jobs that offer employment to workers that would otherwise be unemployed,

U Official = U Hypo xA + zR w( G) ,

(2)

where A stands for the total number of admissions, and R is the total number of releases that year, of which the fractions x and z are unemployed respectively.9 G is the change in the number of jobs for prison guards, administrators, maintenance workers, etc, and w is the fraction of these jobs filled with otherwise unemployed workers. Similarly, the official size of the labor force, LFOfficial, equals a hypothetical level, LFHypo, minus those removed from the labor force through admission to prison, qA, plus those added to the labor force after being released, sR. Additionally, add the number of workers otherwise not in the labor force who are now employed in new prison related jobs, t(G).

LFOfficial = LFHypo qA + sR + t ( G) .

(3)

Solving (2) and (3) for the hypothetical quantities and dividing one by the other yields

URHypo =

U Hypo LFHypo

U Official + xA zR + w( G) LFOfficial + qA sR t ( G)

*100.

(4)

For now I neglect that the same individual may be admitted to and released from prison or jail more than once in a given year. I take up the issue of reincarceration in the sensitivity analysis below.

URHypo is the hypothetical unemployment rate that would have been obtained in the absence of changes in incarceration. We can rewrite equation 4 in order to facilitate comparison with the measure used by other authors (e.g. Western and Beckett 1999; Katz and Krueger 1999). Without making additional assumptions, rewrite A = R + I, where I stands for to the change in the size of the incarcerated population during the reference year. Write z = x + e, which highlights that inmates released from prison may face a different risk of unemployment than those newly admitted. Similarly, write q = s + d, where d is the difference between the labor force participation rates of those that are admitted and those that are released from incarceration. Now assume that newly admitted inmates suffered from unemployment to the same extent as did current inmates overall, x = upi, where upi is the fraction of all current inmates that were unemployed prior to their incarceration. Likewise, assume that q = lfpi, where lfpi stands for the fraction of current inmates that participated in the labor force prior to their incarceration. (We can justify these assumptions with reference to the high turnover in the inmate population # a large proportion of current inmates is newly admitted, see below.) Substituting into (4) yields

URHypo =

U Official eR + upi ( I ) + w( G) LFOfficial + dR + lfpi ( I ) t ( G)

*100 .

(5)

(No additional assumptions are made about size or sign of d, e, w, t, upi, or, lfpi. Note, that, plausibly, d,e > 0 would imply that inmates released from prison and jail have a higher risk of unemployment and a lower labor force participation rate than those admitted.) In the formulation of equation 5, interpretation is straightforward. The first terms in

numerator and denominator describe the official unemployment rate. The second terms, eR and

dR, determine the release effect: UOfficial grows to the extent that more inmates are released into unemployment than are admitted when unemployed. The third terms, upi(I) and lfpi(I), determine what can be called the % net admission effect&of a change in the size of the incarcerated population: UOfficial drops if the incarcerated population grows and currently incarcerated inmates had a higher risk of unemployment prior to their incarceration than the non-incarcerated rest of the population. The fourth terms, w(G) and t(G), give the employment effect of prison-related job creation. Subtracting UROfficial from URHypo thus identifies the overall causal effect of

changes in incarceration on the official unemployment rate in the year under consideration. The measure derived in equation 4 is considerably more general than the measures used in the literature. Rewritten as equation 5, the relationship between these measures is easy to appreciate. For example, Western and Beckett (1999) use a measure for the causal effect of incarceration on unemployment that adds inmates that had been unemployed prior to their incarceration to the numerator of UOfficial, and all inmates to the denominator.

URZero =

U Official + upi * I LFOfficial + I

*100 .

(6)

Western and Beckett use URZero as a measure for a hypothetical unemployment rate at zero incarceration and interpret the difference to the official unemployment rate as the causal effect of incarceration. Their measure thus differs from the one developed here in three respects. First, it omits release and employment effects. Therefore it captures only net admission effects and is biased for the total effect of incarceration on unemployment. Second, it assumes that prior to

incarceration all inmates had been in the labor force. Third, it implies an extreme long-run perspective, since incarceration was never fully zero at any time during the twentieth century. Katz and Krueger (1999) use an approach very similar to Western and Beckett (1999), but focus on more realistically circumscribed time horizons.10 Allowing that part of the current incarcerated population was not in the labor force prior to incarceration, Katz and Krueger use a version of equation 6 to build a simple difference-in-difference-type estimator that identifies the effect of a net change in the size of the incarcerated population between two points in time while subtracting out the changes in unemployment that would have occurred concurrently regardless of changes in incarceration

t2 t2 t1 t1 (UROfficial URZero ) (UROfficial URZero ),

(7)

where t2 is a point in time after t1. As with Western and Beckett& s method, Katz and Krueger& s method from equation 7 corresponds to equation 5 only if release and employment effects cancel each other out. The methods used in the literature thus at best identify partial (i.e. net admission) effects and are biased with respect to the total effect of incarceration on unemployment. Western and Beckett argue that rising incarceration in the United States has concealed a significant amount of unemployment and caused the official unemployment rate to be lower than it would have been in the absence of prison growth. Due to their shorter time horizon Katz and Krueger estimate smaller effects, but also conclude that the prison boom has lowered unemployment.
10

The

Recall that the assumption needed to go from equation 4 to equation 5 was that current inmates would have the same labor market status today as the one occupied at the time of their incarceration, had they not been incarcerated. This assumption is implicit in the causal interpretation of Western and Beckett& s and Katz and Krueger& s methods. Since this assumption is more credible the shorter the duration of incarceration, it seems advisable to prefer short time horizons that track the causal effect of changes in incarceration over a limited number of years.

theoretical point made in equation 5 is that if releases add more people to the official unemployment count than are removed from it by the growth of the incarcerated population and the concomitant employment effect, then incarceration would increase official unemployment, rather than diminish it.11 Next I attempt first to replicate the literature& s estimates for the net admission effect empirically, and supplement these results with a sensitivity analysis for the total effect of incarceration on the U.S. unemployment rate. I then revisit the causal role of incarceration in the U.S.-European unemployment rate differential.

Data
The data used in this paper are time series from 1976 to 1999, unless noted otherwise. This period encompasses both the takeoff of U.S. prison growth and the time frame for the debate on high unemployment in Europe. United States. The Bureau of Labor Statistics provides labor market data on average annual levels of employment and unemployment from the Current Population Survey (OECD 2001). All data refer to the civilian non-institutional population aged 16 and above.12 Time series on the composition and size of the incarcerated population since 1976 were compiled from various Bureau of Justice Statistics (BJS) publications (see footnotes to Tables

11

This informal statement neglects changes in the labor force level caused by incarceration. Note, however, that UOfficial is much smaller than LFOfficial, so that changes to the numerator will dominate changes to the denominator. Since d*R and n*G are probably small relative to the size of the official labor force, I assume here that they approximately cancel to zero. If there are no significant changes in the denominator of the measure beside those associated with the net increase in incarceration then it is obvious that equation 7 overstates the decreasing effect of incarceration on the unemployment rate if, approximately, eR > upi(I) + w(G). The empirical part of this paper takes into account changes to both the numerator and denominator. 12 Since most prisoners are adults I repeated all analyses with labor market series for individuals aged 20 and above. Differences in results are negligible (not shown).

A.1 and A.2).13 In order to avoid double counting, inmate data refer to custody counts (of inmates actually held in a given facility), rather than jurisdiction counts, wherever possible. Due to some irredeemable double-counting owed to problems with racial categorizing, prison and jail inmate-counts by sex and race do not always exactly sum to incarceration totals. But remaining discrepancies do not appear to affect results. Data on size and composition of the jail population before 1979 are not available and had to be estimated. appendix Tables A.1 and A.2. I construct detailed time series variables on inmates& labor market status prior to incarceration and current work activities while imprisoned from several large representative BJS surveys of inmates of federal and state prisons and local jails, listed in appendix Table A.3. Missing values between survey years are interpolated linearly. Data on the flow of admissions and releases are taken from various editions of the Sourcebook of Criminal Justice Statistics and the Correctional Populations in the United States series published by the BJS. Unfortunately, detailed national time series on admissions and releases by sex and race are not currently available. Europe. When comparing the U.S. to Europe, an agreement has to be reached about which European countries to include. The debate on high unemployment in Europe typically refers to all fifteen member-countries of the European Union, EU-15. Some authors omit select weak economies from the comparison. For example, Western and Beckett (1999) omit some highunemployment Southern European nations and add a few economically strong nations from central/western Europe, yielding thirteen countries, E-13. Buchele and Christiansen (1998) Incarceration series are shown in

compare the U.S. to the four strongest European economies, E-4. This paper produces estimates
13

This paper restricts attention to inmates of prisons and jails. Additionally, a small number of inmates are detained in drunk tanks, police lock-ups, etc. Due to the short duration of their incarceration, they are excluded from this analysis, as are approximately 3000 prisoners in military confinement facilities (BJS, 1998, p.511).

for both the EU-15 and the E-13 (but does not usually show both sets of results). Additionally I compute adjustments for the EU-6, which is a group of economically strong Western European nations for which the most thoroughly internationally standardized labor market series are available. The countries comprising EU-15, E-13, and EU-6 are listed in appendix Table A.4. Since the impact of incarceration on measures of labor market performance is small relative to their absolute level, it is crucial to use comparable baseline labor statistics for the U.S. and Europe. While labor market measurement is highly standardized in OECD countries, important differences remain (for an excellent discussion, see Sorrentino 1993, 2000). Currently, neither Eurostat, ILO, nor OECD provide fully standardized time series on the levels of employment and unemployment in the U.S. and the E-13/Eu-15 reaching back to the 1970s.14 For this paper, I resort to time series on absolute levels by sex published in the OECD& s Labour Force Statistics, which are provided by Eurostat and the BLS to comply with standardized OECD definitions.15 To guard against spurious results due to incomplete standardization, I repeat analyses for both sexes on more fully standardized time series for the EU-6 that were recently produced by the BLS for the entire period of interest (BLS, 2001).16 Time series on the size of the incarcerated population in Europe by sex from 1976 were compiled from Council of Europe (1984-2000). Values missing before 1983 for Switzerland, Finland, The Netherlands, and Austria were imputed. Inmate surveys with information on

inmates& labor market status prior to incarceration and work activities while imprisoned
14

The EU did not adopt a common labor force survey questionnaire for all member countries before the ea rly 1980s. Therefore, nicely comparable labor force data for Europe are generally unavailable before 1983. Comparable data for Austria and Denmark do not become available until several years later. 15 Official U.S. definitions are very close to OECD concepts. Therefore, the OECD makes no additional adjustments to U.S. labor force data, even for its series of Standardized Unemployment Rates (SUR). Note that OECD SURs are not useful for the current project because they do not allow for the derivation of standardized data on levels. 16 The BLS has adjusted its EU-6 series to U.S. concepts. They represent the most fully internationally standardized series of labor market statistics available today. However, they are not available by sex or race (Sorrent ino 2000; BLS 2001).

comparable to the U.S. surveys listed in Table A.3 are not available for Europe. U.S. estimates are used in their place.

Results for the Causal Effect of Incarceration on Unemployment


Net Admission Effects To estimate the net admission effect in isolation, i.e. without consideration of release and employment effects, I use a version of equation 6 (instead of assuming perfect labor force participation prior to incarceration I estimate actual participation rates empirically). I identify the causal net admission effect of changes in the size of the incarcerated population over time by contrasting the difference between official and zero-incarceration unemployment rates at different points in time according to equation 7. To maintain comparability with the results from the literature I at first restrict attention to males. Crucial for the unbiased estimation of the net admission effect is the parameter upi, the percentage of inmates unemployed prior to their incarceration,17 and to a lesser degree lfpi, their labor force participation rate. Applying the official definition of unemployment reviewed above as best possible to data from ten nationally representative inmate surveys (listed in Table A.3),18 I produce yearly estimates for both parameters for several demographic groups. Table 4 shows the estimates for U.S. males between 1978 and 1997. On average, 18 percent of male inmates were unemployed and 86 percent were in the labor force prior to incarceration. Inmates of local

17

Upi is not to be confused with inmates& unemployment rate prior to incarceration. The denominator of the latter includes only inmates that participated in the labor force prior to their incarceration. Upi, on the other hand, is defined relative to all inmates. 18 Perfect adherence to official definitions is impossible because the questions asked in the CPS and inmate surveys are not identical. A comparison of exact wordings suggests, however, that the items are sufficiently close. The main difference concerns the reference periods for the questions on employment and on job search. The reference periods used in the inmate surveys are generally longer (see Table A.3). Thus, inmate surveys are likely to overestimate employment among all prisoners, and to overestimate unemployment among non-employed prisoners.

jails were more likely to be unemployed prior to incarceration than were inmates of state prisons; African American men reported higher unemployment than white men (appendix Table A.5). These rates are quite stable over time, but have decreased in recent years, perhaps reflecting both a trickle-down of improvements in the economy at large and a more indiscriminate use of imprisonment in the wake of mass-incarceration. Not surprisingly, these estimates for upi and lfpi differ considerably from the corresponding unemployment and labor force participation rates in the general population; this just confirms that incarceration is highly selective.19 Using these estimates for the auxiliary parameters upi and lfpi, I produce new estimates for URZero. Per equation 7, the difference over time in the differences between UROfficial and URZero identifies the causal net admission effect of changes in the size of the incarcerated population on the official unemployment rate. Table 5 contrasts UROfficial and URZero for various demographics. Over the twenty-year period from 1980 to 1999, which witnessed the nearly fourfold increase in incarceration from one half to 2 million inmates, my estimates suggest that the net admission effect of incarceration reduced the male UROfficial by 0.13 percentage points, which accounts for 5 percent of the official decline in unemployment over this period.20 The net admission effect on the unemployment rate for both sexes was 0.08 percentage points, or less than 3 percent of the official decline. Time series for the size of the incarcerated population by race are available only

19

At the same time, my estimates also differ importantly from the parameters used in the literature. For example, Western and Beckett (1999, p.1039) find that in 1995 36 perc ent of current inmates had been unemployed prior to their incarceration. Similarly, Katz and Krueger (1999, p.42), following Kling (1999), assume upi = .35 throughout the 1980s and 90s. By contrast, the present paper, using much of the same data as Western and Beckett plus some additional inmate surveys, estimates upi at 16 percent for 1995. It appears that Western and Beckett conflate unemployment and non-employment (confirmed by Western, electronic communication, December 1998). Katz and Krueger& s estimate comes from a highly selective demographic (inmates sentenced to one to two years for federal crimes in California), which is not representative of the national inmate population. These discrepancies explain a large part of the differences between their results and those in the causal section of this paper. My estimates for upi confirm doubts about Western and Beckett & s causal results voiced by Greenberg. Using older data, Greenberg points out that at most, 17 percent of the inmates would be counted as unemployed [prior to their incarceration] under Department of Labor criteria ! in 1974 (2001, p. 71). 20 The difference between UROfficial and URZero was 0.1 percentage points in 1980s and 0.23 in 1999. The difference in differences is 0.23 # 0.1 = 0.13.

for a more limited range of years. I find that the decreasing effect of rising incarceration on the unemployment rates of white and African American men between 1983 and 1997 was 0.03 and 0.48 percentage points respectively, which translates into less than 1 percent and 5 percent of the official decline over this period. These results contrast sharply with claims that prison and jail has lowered male

unemployment by between a half and one percentage point since the late 1980s! (Western and Beckett, 1999, p.1041). Rather, according to my estimates, the growth of the incarcerated population between 1989 and 1999 has lowered the official U.S. unemployment rate for males by 0.05, or one twentieth of a percentage point. Thus, while adding 1.5 million inmates to the incarcerated population over the past twenty years did indeed have a measurable impact on the official unemployment rate via net admission effects, this decreasing effect is considerably smaller than previously believed. Less than 0.1 percentage points of the 3 percentage point drop in the unemployment rate of both sexes over the past twenty years can be attributed to the expansion of the criminal justice system. And these estimates still exclude release and

employment effects, which on balance can be expected to yield even smaller estimates for the total causal effect. The issue of total causal effects is taken up next.

Sensitivity Analysis for the Total Causal Effect: Adding Employment and Release Effects The total causal effect of incarceration on unemployment is determined by the balance of net admission, release, and employment effects. To the best of my knowledge it has not yet been estimated. The total causal effect is considerably more difficult to estimate than net admission effects, for two reasons. First, employment effects are best understood as general equilibrium effects and are thus near impossible to grasp in their entirety, short of modeling the full range of

interactions between economy and prison system. For this reason, I settle for a more limited conceptualization of employment effects that permits direct estimation. Second, release effects cannot be estimated directly, as suitable national data are not available for all necessary parameters. Therefore, I supplement partial estimates for the release effect with a sensitivity analysis for one remaining parameter. This permits the assessment of reasonable bounds for the total effect of incarceration. The point of reference throughout is UROfficial for both sexes in 1997. Eventually, this analysis will suggest that the total effect of incarceration is to increase rather than decrease the official unemployment rate. As this finding contradicts published results that are based solely on net admission effects, I aim to produce high estimates for the employment effect and low estimates for the release effect. Doing so strengthens the challenged results and renders my estimates for the total causal effect conservative, i.e. more credible. Consider employment effects first. As it would exceed the scope of this paper to consider the full range of interactions between the prison system and the overall economy, I restrict attention to job creation within the corrections sector (which presumably represents the lion& s share of incarceration-induced employment effects). Per equation 5, the size of the employment effect depends on the annual change in the number of jobs associated with the prison system, G, the fraction of such jobs occupied by otherwise unemployed workers, w, and the fraction occupied by workers that would otherwise not be in the labor force, t. To obtain G, note that between 1983 and 1999 the employment count for correctional institution officers nationwide rose twofold from 146,000 to 315,000 (Statistical Abstract of the United States 2000, tables 511

and 669),21 and that correctional officers and related security staff account for 63 percent of all employees of correctional facilities (BJS 1997e, p.15).22 Thus, the average increase in prison and jail related employment in the 1980s and 1990s can be estimated at approximately 16,000 new jobs per year. Although in reality not all of these jobs would be occupied by otherwise unemployed workers, we can set w = 1 and thus use G for the upper bound of the annual

employment effect of incarceration during the prison boom.23 Next, consider the release effect. Per equation 5, it depends upon the number of people released from prison and jail, R, and the difference in the risk of unemployment between those entering and leaving incarceration in a given year, e. R is relatively straightforward to calculate, although exact national release counts suitable for the present purpose are not available. Turnover in prisons and jails is high. Between 1996 and 1997 prisons and jails grew by 96,000 inmates. Over the same period, 515,000 prisoners sentenced to more than one year were released from state and federal prisons (BJS 2001, table 6.34).24 These ' million former inmates are those most likely to suffer adverse treatment in the labor market because their long sentences will prove hard to conceal from prospective employers.25 Additionally, approximately 10 million

This estimate of an approximately twofold increase in incarceration related employment is corroborated by parallel developments in expenditure. Between 1980 and 1998 state expenditure for corrections increased from $4.5 to $30.6 billion ($20 to $113 per capita), at nearly double the growth rate of overall state expenditure. 22 Besides correctional officers employed as guards and security staff, prisons provide employment to administrators, clerical workers, educators, maintenance, and food workers (BJS 1997e, table 19). 23 Note that w=1 implies t=0. If all new prison related jobs are occupied by otherwise unemployed workers ( w=1), then all of them would be in the labor force had they not found a job ( t=0). Setting w=1 thus implies the largest possible employment effect, given G. The problem of determining an upper bound for the employment effect consequently reduces to estimating G. Here, I focus on prison related employment # arguably the most important aspect of employment effects. This conceptualization neglects job creation in the (prison building) construction sector, in (non-prison based) law enforcement, and support services for releasees (for the growing number of former convicts). This paper does not test whether these omissions would offset the impact of asserting w = 1. 24 This number underestimates the number of inmates released from prisons because the BJS excludes prisoners sentenced to less than one year and unsentenced prisoners (e.g. awaiting trial) from the release count. I additionally exclude intrasystem transfers, escapees, and deaths. 25 The mean time served until release by federal prisoners was 18.7 months in 1999 (BJS 2001, table 6.53). Twenty percent of releasees in 1997 completed their maximum sentence (BJS 2001, table 6.60).

21

inmates are released from local jails every year (BJS 1993a, table 6.35).26 Generously adjusting their number for intrasystem transfers and repeat-jailing, we can set a lower bound for the number of inmates released from jail at 2 million inmates annually.27 Adding releases from prisons and jails together yields R = 2.5 million for 1997. National data for the direct estimation of e (the difference in the risk of unemployment between those entering and leaving incarceration) are not available.28 Therefore, direct estimates for the total effect of changes in incarceration on unemployment cannot be provided. However, we have estimates for a sufficient number of parameters (neglecting changes to the denominator of equation 5 for now), to enable a sensitivity analysis which calculates critical values for e and assesses a probable range for the overall causal effect of incarceration. Plugging the results obtained above into equation 5,29 one finds that if those released in 1997 suffered from only a 0.64 percentage point higher risk of unemployment than those admitted (i.e. if e=0.0064), then the release effect would exactly offset the employment effect. Under this scenario, the total causal effect of incarceration on unemployment would equal the net admission effect calculated above. If e>0.012, (i.e. if those released suffered from more than a one

Data on the number of inmates released from local jails in 1997 are unavailable. The BJS reports between 8 and 10 million releases from local jails per year between 1983 and 1991 (BJS 1993a, table 6.35). On June 30, 1993, alone U.S. local jails released 18,591 adults (BJS 1995, table 2.4). 27 U.S. jails record at least 10 million releases per year. Let half of those be intrasystem transfers, and further allow that the average remaining inmates are released 2.5 times per year. This leaves 2 million individuals to be released from jail and placed into the civilian non-institutional population. Clearly, these adjustments are exaggerations that underestimate the number of releasees affected each year, which serves to render my estimates conservative. These adjustments further guarantee that the average former jail inmate considered in this analysis has spent more than a few days time in jail over the course of the year. This is an important point because about 60 percent of inmates released from jail in a given week have spent less than five days behind bars (BJS 1990, table 11) and are thus less likely to suffer negative repercussions (Zagorsky 1996). 28 The use of social science survey data for the estimation of e is problematic because the number of self-identified ex-convicts is too small, and likely to suffer from severe response bias (Harding 2001). National administrative data for the estimation of e are unavailable. 29 From above, recall that in 1997 admissions removed 14,400 unemployed persons from the labor market (net admission effect = upi(I) = 0.15*96,000=14,400). The upper bound of the employment effect ( w(G)=1*(G)), leaves an additional 16,000 persons unemployment. For the lower bound of the number of releasees, use R=2.5 million.

26

percentage point higher risk of unemployment than those admitted), then changes in incarceration have increased, rather than decreased the official unemployment rate. This possibility stands in sharp contradiction to previously published results. While I stress that there are no data to measure e directly, there are at least two strong reasons to expect that e exceeds these critical values. First, a one percentage point increase in the risk of unemployment for inmates released over inmates admitted seems modest, particularly given the strong empirical evidence for discrimination against ex-convicts. Consider for example evidence from California where in 1991, only 21 percent of the state& s parolees had full-time jobs. Seventy percent were not employed, and an additional 9 percent had % casual&employment! (Austin and Irwin 2001, p. 148).30 Second, my model neglects that release effects from previous years carry over into the present, as inmates released in the past continue to be negatively affected by their history of incarceration (Kling 1999, Western and Beckett 1999). This will further lower the critical value of e. On the other hand, if release effects do not replenish the labor force beyond its depletion through admissions (i.e. if d>0 in equation 5) then the labor force count will decrease and thus raise the critical value of e. It seems improbable, however, that the latter argument should outweigh the former two (the labor force is large compared to the unemployment count # changes in the denominator therefore matter comparatively less). On balance, these considerations suggest that incarceration has caused more unemployment in the civilian non-institutional population than it has concealed.

Did Incarceration Cause the U.S.-European Unemployment Differential?

30

What is more, one can expect parolees to fare better on the labor market than other releasees because parole authorities often require parolees to maintain gainful employment (Rhine et al 1991). Job placement programs exist for all types of ex-convicts (Travis et al 2001, 31-34), but Austin and Irwin (2001, p.147) cite research that most prison systems are unable or unwilling to assist inmates! with their economic reintegration.

If incarceration has indeed increased U.S. unemployment rates beyond the level they would have reached without the U.S. prison boom, as is suggested by the preceding sensitivity analysis, then the question whether incarceration has amplified the U.S.-European unemployment gap is moot. If anything, the performance differential would be even larger. However, since a

sensitivity analysis cannot provide the same degree of confidence as direct estimation, let us revisit the issue of net admission effects for which direct estimates exist. Since the net admission effect of incarceration on the U.S. unemployment rate is smaller than previously thought, it follows that the effect on the U.S.-European unemployment gap should be smaller, too. Using the level of incarceration in 1976 as a point of reference, we can ask how large the difference between U.S. and European unemployment rates for both sexes would have been had incarceration remained at 1976 levels.31 To this end, Figure 3 contrasts the official unemployment rate gap (Europe minus U.S., solid line) with the gap obtained when considering rates adjusted for the net admission effect of incarceration (broken line).32 The upshot is that incarceration did not change the width or timing of the unemployment rate differential. The official EU-15 unemployment rate for both sexes surpassed the official U.S. rate consistently from 1983, as does the unemployment rate adjusted for net admission effects. The official unemployment rates of the E-13 and EU-6 consistently exceed U.S. rates from 1984, and, again, adjusting for the net admission effect of incarceration does not change the timing or affect the size of the unemployment differential noticeably. The same result holds for male unemployment rates. Figure 4 shows that the male unemployment rate in EU-15 and E-13 has
31

The year 1976 approximately marks the start of the prison boom and also the point in time when incarceration trends in Europe and the U.S. began to diverge. Whether one chooses 1976 or zero incarceration! as point of reference in this case makes no qualitative difference (not shown). 32 I compute net-admission-adjusted unemployment series for Europe analogously to the U.S. series above. Since European inmate surveys are unavailable, I use the U.S. estimates for upi and lfpi. The European net admission effect is almost zero because European incarceration rates are much lower, and increased more slowly (results not shown).

surpassed U.S. unemployment from 1984, whether or not we adjust for growing incarceration. The difference in the gaps between official and adjusted rates is negligible compared to the size of the gap (but, predictably, it is larger for men than for both sexes). In other words, the dramatic increase in U.S. incarceration cannot explain, let alone explain away,! the marked divergence between U.S. and European unemployment rates for males or both sexes. To sum up the causal part of this paper, thus far I have demonstrated that the causal effect of incarceration on UROfficial is (1) considerably smaller than previously reported if we follow the literature in looking at net admission effects in isolation; (2) not large enough to have caused a noticeable difference in U.S.-European unemployment rate differentials; and (3) potentially increasing, rather than decreasing the official U.S. unemployment rate if we further consider employment and release effects. The American penal system is not concealing the surplus population! that so burdens European labor markets.

The Robustness of the U.S.-European Unemployment Rate Gap to Changes in Definition


The accounting perspective deals with the robustness of existing measures of labor market performance to changes in definition. As regards the incarcerated population, the prevailing notion is that including prisoners in the count would increase the official unemployment rate because, presumably, prisoners are inactive. For example, Western and Beckett (1999), in a widely cited analysis, propose a modified measure of unemployment, which adds all inmates of prisons and jails to both numerator and denominator of the official unemployment rate. They consider their measure a better indicator of labor market inactivity! and labor

underutilization,! because it captures the hidden unemployment! and inactivity among able-

bodied, working-age men! imposed by incarceration (Western and Beckett 1999, p.1039). According to their modified measure, the male unemployment rate was 1.9 percentage points higher in 1995 than officially stated, and European unemployment significantly overtakes U.S. unemployment only from 1993! (pp.1042-43) rather than from 1983. Low unemployment in the U.S. and high unemployment in Europe are thus thought to be an artifact of the exclusion of the incarcerated population from official labor market measurement. Similar ideas can be found in numerous places (e.g. Jencks 1992; Chiricos and Delone 1992; Freeman 1995; Faux 1997; Buchele and Christiansen 1998; Beckett and Western 1997; Western and Beckett 1998; Western, Beckett and Harding 1998; Western and Pettit 2000). This paper agrees that the exploration of alternatives to the official standards of labor market measurement is important. Labor market performance is a multidimensional construct and basic trends should be robust to alternative operationalizations. But not all operationalizations are equally valid. In the following, I question the particular practice of including the incarcerated population wholesale in modified measures of unemployment and explore alternatives. The core of my critique is that the inclusion of all inmates in the unemployment count produces internally inconsistent indicators. Counting all inmates as unemployed means to

modify current concepts selectively, by applying a broad definition of unemployment to inmates in prison and jail (including, for example, inmates that work for money), while applying the narrow official definition of unemployment to the non-institutional population. This

inconsistency results in larger than appropriate differences between official and modified statistics. To arrive at internally consistent alternatives to official statistics, conceive of any modification as a two-step procedure. First, broaden the survey universe to include prisons and

jails (currently CPS, and with it the Bureau of Labor Statistics, simply do not count the incarcerated population). Secondly, decide what definitions to apply to this new, broader, survey population in a uniform and consistent manner.33 The first step, for our purposes, is

uncontroversial. Whereas above I reviewed arguments that rationalize the exclusion of the incarcerated population from official labor market statistics for the purpose of measuring short term labor supply, my intention in this section is not to propose a new official measure, but to explore its robustness to the exclusion of the inmate population. It is the second step that engenders some surprising results.

Modified Unemployment Rates First, consider modified measures of unemployment. If inmates were included in the CPS universe, and if the official definitions of employment and unemployment were applied to the incarcerated population (disregarding the OECD& s SNA-based exclusion of inmates reviewed above), then nearly half of all male inmates would have to be considered employed because they work for money or payment in kind, as shown in Table 6. (Table 6 also shows that in 1996, 57 percent of male inmates worked in or outside of their confinement facility, and 34 percent worked for money, slightly down from previous years.)34 Whether the remaining non-working inmates ought to be counted as unemployed or non-employed is unclear because it is not known

33

Questions regarding the post-release labor market fortunes of former inmates are tied to causal considerations and are irrelevant for the accounting perspective. The accounting perspective simply asks how a given state of the world would be portrayed by different ways to measure it, whereas the causal perspective asks how that reality would change under different trends in incarceration. 34 Several authors acknowledge inmate work in principle, but underestimate its prevalence. For example, Western and Beckett (1999, p. 1040) assert that only 10 percent of prisoners engage in paid and therefore do not incorporate working inmates in their calculations employment. The numbers in Table 6 contradict this assertion. The numbers for all inmates, male and female, are near identical to those presented in Table 6, due to the small number of female inmates (not shown).

whether they would (or could) fulfill the availability and search criteria that are at the heart of the concept of unemployment.35 Table 7 demonstrates how adjustments would play out under different assumptions regarding the treatment of non-working inmates. If paid working male inmates are included in the employment count, but all other inmates are regarded non-employed, then the resulting modified male unemployment rate would be lower than the official rate (if only marginally so, by less than 0.1 percentage points in 1999). This is shown in column 2. If working inmates are counted as employed, and all remaining inmates as unemployed, then the new rate would be about one percentage point higher than the official rate, as shown in column 3. The treatment of non-working inmates thus determines whether a modified measure of unemployment # one that considers the incarcerated population but also takes account of paid employment among prisoners # would show that the U.S. labor market performs better or worse than indicated by the official statistics. In any case, the results in Table 7 are at best half the 1.9 percentage point difference for 1995, found by Western and Beckett (1999) (approximately reproduced in column 4). Adjustments of the unemployment rate for both sexes, predictably, are smaller by about half (not shown).

The point here is not to reify official definitions, but to apply them consistently. Recall that employment is defined as doing any work for (either) pay (or profit) ! over the past week (U.S. Bureau of the Census 1998, p. C42). Contrary to widespread belief (e.g. Western and Pettit 2000, p. 6), the official definition of employment is not tied to hours worked, or any minimum standards of decency, such as minimum wage, fair labor standards etc. Literally, any work! for pay or profit qualifies, and is duly counted in the non-institutional population. The same standard should be applied to the inmate population, if the CPS universe were to be extended to include prisons and jails. None of this is to say that inmate work compares seamlessly to typical employment situations in the free labor market. It doesn& t. (For an at times polemical discussion see Featherstone 2000; Buck 1994; Marks and Vining 1986.) Yet paid prison work compares sufficiently to certain types of (mainly low prestige, low income) work, so that it would still fall within the scope of the official employment definition. Note, for example, that inmate compensation follows a different logic, as most income is in kind.! An important source of non-monetary remuneration specific to prison labor is so-called good time,! which refers to time deducted from a sentence in exchange for work (BJS 1995, p.3). Inmate surveys indicate that a majority of working inmates work for good time! as well as other forms of in kind benefits such as cigarettes and food (calculations not shown). Average monetary wages for working state prisoners were only 56 cents per hour in 1991 (BJS 1993c, p.27).

35

Modified Non-Employment-to-Population Ratios Non-employment and the non-employment-to-population-ratio (NEPR) provide a more suitable basis for an incarceration-adjusted measure of inactivity than does the unemployment rate. While the concept of unemployment is too restrictive to allow for the inclusion of nonworking inmates without compromising the internal consistency of the adjusted measures, nonemployment naturally permits their inclusion.36 Using the NEPR as a basis for a modified measure of inactivity thus avoids conflating inactivity (in prison and jail) with unemployment (in the non-institutional population). Table 8 shows results for incarceration-modified NEPRs for U.S. males. The official male NEPR is reproduced in the first column. Between 1976 and 1999 it remained relatively stable at around twenty-nine percent. Adding all male inmates not working for money or payment in kind to the numerator of the official NEPR, and all inmates to its denominator, increases the official NEPR by between 0.1 and 0.5 percentage points, as shown in column 3. If, again, one chooses to disregard paid employment among inmates and adds all inmates to the NEPR, the official NEPR would increase by between 0.3 and 1.2 percentage points, as shown in column 4.37 These adjusted series arguably yield a more encompassing and appropriate measures of overall labor resource utilization, inactivity, and joblessness than the official NEPR. A comparison with correspondingly modified European NEPRs tests whether official statistics overstate the U.S.-European difference in resource utilization. Figure 5 shows the difference between European (EU-6) and U.S. NEPRs for both sexes.38 The solid and broken lines

36

In the non-institutional population non-employment is the broadest concept of inactivity # most students, homemakers, retirees, discouraged workers and the chronically ill count as non-employed but not as unemployed. 37 When similar adjustments are performed on the NEPR for both sexes, the difference is roughly halved (not shown). 38 The EU-6 comprise Western Europe & s strongest economies. Comparing the U.S. to the EU-6 results in a conservative test for the strength of performance differentials because it omits economies such as Portugal, Greece,

represent the trend of this difference according to official and modified definitions, respectively. For good measure, the modified measure charted in Figure 5 includes all inmates, working or not, with non-employment. Positive values indicate that European non-employment exceeded the U.S. NEPR. Figure 5 shows that EU-6 non-employment exceeded U.S. non-employment over the entire period under consideration regardless of the forced inactivity of two million inmates in U.S. prisons and jails. Due to mass incarceration in the U.S., the U.S.-European incarceration-adjusted difference in non-employment is somewhat smaller (by about .5 percentage points) than the official difference. But this does not alter the qualitative conclusion that the U.S. has maintained lower levels of labor market inactivity than Europe over at least the past twenty-five years. In sum, this analysis rejects the proposition that the U.S.-European unemployment rate gap between 1983 and 1994 is an artifact of the exclusion of the incarcerated population from official labor market statistics. Due to extensive (and oft underestimated) paid work among inmates, incorporating the incarcerated population into the unemployment count might well point to an even larger U.S.-European unemployment differential than indicated by the official rates, as was shown in Table 7. Alternatively including the incarcerated population into a modified measure of inactivity based on non-employment shows that the overall difference in inactivity between the U.S. and Europe is somewhat smaller than indicated by the official NEPR, but still large and growing, as was shown in Figure 5. This analysis does not support the notion that, in

contradistinction to conventional statistics, inactivity was higher in the U.S. than in Europe until the mid 1990s due to the forced inactivity generated by sky-high American incarceration

and Spain, which suffer from the highest rates of unemployment and non-employment in Europe. Performance differences between the U.S. and the EU-15 or E-13 are even larger.

Conclusion
Over the past years, incarceration has received considerable attention in the field of comparative institutional labor market analysis (e.g. Faux 1997; Buchele and Christiansen 1998; Western and Beckett 1998, 1999; Katz and Krueger 1999) and successfully challenged received notions of the nature of labor market institutions (particularly Western and Beckett 1998, 1999). Whereas standard analyses of aggregate labor market performance often confine their attention to explicitly wage-setting institutions, such as trade unions, labor legislation, or the education sector, the new research agenda highlights the importance of seemingly unrelated social institutions, such as the criminal justice system, in the determination of market outcomes. Empirical research on the relationship between incarceration and labor market performance has produced several dramatic findings that challenge the conventional wisdom about the causes of low unemployment in the United States and about origin and reality of U.S-European labor market performance differentials. Specifically, the literature attacks conventional notions of Eurosclerosis from two fronts, causal and accounting: first by contributing to an alternative, incarceration-based causal explanation of existing U.S.-European unemployment rate differentials; second by questioning the very reality of these differentials with reference to the large fraction of the American population that is forced into labor market inactivity ( hidden unemployment! ) through incarceration. This paper extends the theoretical agenda by proposing a more general model of the causal interaction between incarceration and unemployment, and on that basis engages previous empirical results in a critical dialogue. From a causal perspective, I find that the fourfold increase of incarceration in the United States over the past twenty five years has caused the official unemployment rate to decrease by 0.08 percentage points through net admission effects,

which amounts to only 3 percent of the overall decline in unemployment. I find that net admission effects decreased the male unemployment rate over the same period by 0.13 percentage points, which amounts to 5 percent of the official decline. Previous research put the impact of incarceration at multiples of these estimates. I further argue that even my small net admission effect estimates overstate the total causal effect of incarceration on unemployment because they do not capture concomitant release and employment effects. I concede that the total causal effect of incarceration currently eludes direct estimation because the full extent of macro societal implications of the prison boom (the employment effect) has yet to be theorized, and because data requirements for a satisfactory estimation of release effects are not fully met. However, I show that the formal model for the total causal effect developed in this paper enables a sensitivity analysis, which suggests that incarceration likely has increased, rather than decreased the official unemployment rate in the 1990s. In other words, the U.S. labor market might have performed even better (as measured by the official unemployment rate) in the absence of the U.S. prison boom. Surprisingly, instead of providing an alternative explanation for existing U.S.-European unemployment rate differentials, incarceration might therefore better be seen as a factor preventing such differentials from being even more pronounced. This paper also challenges previous results from the accounting perspective, which investigates the robustness of official labor market indicators to changes in definition. Using detailed data on the work activities of the U.S. incarcerated population, I show that almost half of all inmates would count as employed if they were included in the official unemployment count. Modified unemployment rates designed to capture the forced inactivity among inmates of prisons and jails would count working inmates as employed, but would not necessarily count nonworking prisoners as unemployed. Therefore, it is not clear whether the exclusion of the

incarcerated population from the CPS understates or overstates unemployment in the United States. Abandoning the unemployment rate as a measure of inactivity, I argue that the nonemployment to population ratio provides a less controversial basis for measuring the forced inactivity of the incarcerated population and show that the inactivity differentials between the U.S. and Europe are present and large whether or not the incarcerated population is included. I stress that this paper does not provide support for popular theories of Eurosclerosis. I do, however, argue that the labor market implications of the U.S. prison boom, somewhat surprisingly, cannot supply ammunition against such claims either. Incarceration at best

contributed marginally to the decline in the official U.S. unemployment rate, it did not cause the U.S.-European unemployment rate gap to a meaningful extent, and the forced inactivity of the incarcerated population is not large enough to question the reality of U.S.-European activity differentials.

References
Austin, James and John Irwin. 2001. It!s About Time: America!s Imprisonment Binge. 3rd ed. Belmont, CA: Wadsworth. Barclay, Gordon, Cynthia Tavares, and Arsalaan Siddique. 2001. International Comparisons of Criminal Justice Statistics 1999.! Home Office Statistical Bulletin 6/01. Beckett, Katherine and Bruce Western. 1997. The penal system as labor market institution: jobs and jails 1980-1995.! Overcrowded Times 8,6. BJS [Bureau of Justice Statistics]. 1993a. Sourcebook of Criminal Justice Statistics " 1992. Washington, D.C.: Bureau of Justice Statistics. ---. 1993b. Survey of Inmates of State Correctional Facilities, 1991. ICPSR. Ann Arbor, Mich.: Inter-University Consortium for Political and Social Research. ---. 1994a. Survey of Inmates of State Correctional Facilities, 1986. ICPSR. Ann Arbor, Mich.: Inter-University Consortium for Political and Social Research.

---. 1994b. Survey of Inmates of Federal Correctional Facilities, 1991. ICPSR. Ann Arbor, Mich.: Inter-University Consortium for Political and Social Research. ---. 1995. Correctional Populations in the United States, 1993. Washington, D.C.: Bureau of Justice Statistics. ---. 1997a. Survey of Jails Inmates, 1978. ICPSR. Ann Arbor, Mich.: Inter-University Consortium for Political and Social Research. ---. 1997b. Survey of Inmates of Local Jails, 1983. ICPSR. Ann Arbor, Mich.: InterUniversity Consortium for Political and Social Research. ---. 1997c. Survey of Inmates of Local Jails, 1989. ICPSR. Ann Arbor, Mich.: Inter-University Consortium for Political and Social Research. ---. 1997d. Survey of Inmates of State Correctional Facilities, 1979. ICPSR. Ann Arbor, Mich.: Inter-University Consortium for Political and Social Research. ---. 1999. Survey of Inmates of Local Jails, 1996. ICPSR. Ann Arbor, Mich.: Inter-University Consortium for Political and Social Research. ---. 2000a. Sourcebook of Criminal Justice Statistics " 1999. Washington, D.C.: Bureau of Justice Statistics. [2000 updates online at http://www.albany.edu/sourcebook/1995/] ----. 2000b. Correctional Populations in the United States, 1997. Washington, D.C.: Bureau of Justice Statistics. ---. 2000c. Survey of State and Federal Correctional Facilities, 1997. ICPSR. Ann Arbor, Mich.: Inter-University Consortium for Political and Social Research. ---. 2001. Sourcebook of Criminal Justice Statistics " 2000. Washington, D.C.: Bureau of Justice Statistics. [2001 updates online at http://www.albany.edu/sourcebook/1995/] Blank, Rebecca M. (ed.). 1994. Social Protection versus Economic Reality: Is there a trade-off? Chicago: Chicago University Press. BLS [Bureau of Labor Statistics]. 2001. Comparative Civilian Labor Force Statistics: Ten Countries 1959-2000. Washington, D.C.: Bureau of Labor Statistics. Buchele, Robert, and Jens Christiansen. 1998. Do Employment and Income Security Cause Unemployment? A Comparative Study of the U.S. and the E-4.! Cambridge Journal of Economics 22:117-136. Buck, Pem D. 1994. % Arbeit macht Frei& : Racism and Bound, Concentrated Labor in U.S. Prisons.! Urban Anthropology 23:331-372.

Cain, Glen C. 1979. Labor Force Concepts and Definitions in View of Their Purposes.! In National Commission on Employment and Unemployment Statistics (ed.). Concepts and Data Needs. pp.3-45. Chandra, Amitabh. 2001. Is the Convergence in the Racial Wage Gap Illusory? New Estimates of the Butler-Heckman Hypothesis.! Unpublished Manuscript. Dartmouth College. Chiricos, Theodore G., and Miriam A. Delone. 1992. Labor Surplus and Punishment: A Review and Assessment of Theory and Evidence.! Social Problems 39:421-446. Council of Europe. 1984-2000. Prison Information Bulletin. Various issues. Dale, Mitchell W. 1976. Barriers to the Rehabilitation of Ex-Offenders.! Crime and Delinquency 22:322-377. David, Paul A., and Peter Temin. 1976. Slavery: The Progressive Institution?! In Paul A. David, Herbert G. Gutman, Richard Sutch, Peter Temin, Gavin Wright (eds.). Reckoning with Slavery. New York: Oxford University Press: 165-230. Davinedas, Joseph. 1983. The Professional License: An Ex-Offender& s Illusion?! Criminal Justice Journal 7:61-96. Downes, David. 2001. The macho penal economy: Mass incarceration in the United Sates # a European perspective.! In David Garland (ed.), Mass Imprisonment: Social Causes and Consequences. London: Sage Publications: 70-81. Faux, Jeff. 1997. The % American Model&Exposed.! The Nation. 27 October 1997: 18. Featherstone, Liza. 2000. Prison Labor.! Dissent 47:71-74. Fogel, Robert W., and Stanley L. Engerman. 1974. Time on the cross; the economics of American Negro slavery. Boston: Little, Brown. Freeman, Richard B. 1992. Crime and the Employment of Disadvantaged Youth.! In Peterson, George and Wayne Vroman (eds.), Urban Labor Markets and Job Opportunity. Washington, D.C.: Urban Institute:201-237. ---. 1995. The Limits of Wage Flexibility to Curing Unemployment.! Oxford Review of Economic Policy 11:63-72. Greenberg, David F. 2001. Novus ordo saeclorum: A commentary on Downes, and on Beckett and Western.! In David Garland (ed.), Mass Imprisonment: Social Causes and Consequences. London: Sage Publications: 70-81. Hagan, John. 1993. The Social Embeddedness of Crime and Unemployment.! Criminology 31:465-491

Hallinan, Joseph T. 2001. Going Up the River: Travels in a Prison Nation. New York: Random House. Harding, David. 2001. "Will the True Causal Effect of Incarceration Please Stand Up: Matching Estimates of the Effect of Incarceration on Employment and Wages." Unpublished manuscript. Department of Sociology: Harvard University. Holland, Paul W. 1986. Statistics and Causal Inference.! Journal of the American Statistical Association 81:945-970. Holzer, Harry J. 1996. What Employers Want: Job Prospects for Less-Educated Workers. New York: Russel Sage Foundation. Howell, David R. 2000. Increasing Earnings Inequality and Unemployment in Developed Countries: A Critical Assessment of the # Unified Theory.$ CEPA working paper 2000-20. New School University. ILO [International Labour Office]. 1982. Resolution Concerning Statistics of the Economically Active Population, Employment, Unemployment and Underemployment, adopted by the Thirteenth International Conference of Labour Statisticians (October 1982). Geneva: International Labour Office. Online at http://www.ilo.org/public/english/ bureau/stat/res/ecacpop.htm Jancovic, Ivan. 1977. Labor Markets and Imprisonment.! Crime and Social Justice 8:17-31. Jencks, Christopher. 1992. Rethinking Social Policy: Race, Poverty, and the Underclass. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. Justice Policy Institute. 2000. The Punishing Decade: Prison and Jail Estimates at the Millennium. Washington, D.C.: Justice Policy Institute. Katz, Lawrence F., and Alan B. Krueger. 1999. The High-Pressure U.S. Labor Market of the 1990s.! With discussion. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity1:1-88 Kling, Jeffrey. 1999. The Effects of Prison Sentence Length on the Subsequent Employment and Earnings of Criminal Defendants.! Woodrow Wilson School Economics Discussion Paper 208. Princeton University. Krugman, Paul. 1994. Past and Prospective Causes of High Unemployment.! Economic Review (Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City) 79 (4):23-43. Langan, Patrick A., and David Levin. 1999. Assessing the Accuracy of State Prisoner Statistics. Technical Report. Washington, D.C.: Bureau of Justice Statistics.

Mare, Robert D, and Christopher Winship. 1984. The Paradox of Lessening racial Inequality and Joblessness Among Black Youth: Enrollment, Enlistment, and Employment, 1964-1981.! American Sociological Review 49:39-55. Marks, Denton, and Aidan Vining. 1986. Prison Labor Markets: The Supply Issue.! Policy Sciences 19:83-111. Miller, Jerome G. 1996. Search and Destroy: African-American Males in the Criminal Justice System. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Mauer, Marc. 1997. Americans Behind Bars: U.S. and International Use of Incarceration, 1995. Washington, D.C.: Sentencing Project. ---. 2001. The Causes and Consequences of Prison Growth in the United States.! In David Garland (ed.), Mass Imprisonment: Social Causes and Consequences. London: Sage Publications:4-14. National Commission [National Commission on Employment and Unemployment Statistics]. 1979. Counting the Labor Force. Washington, D.C.: U.S. Department of Labor. OECD. 1985. Standardized Unemployment Rates. Quarterly Labour Force Statistics Sources and Methods. Paris: OECD. OECD. 2001. Labour Force Statistics. Paris: OECD. Petersilia, Joan. 2000. When Prisoners Return to the Community: Political, Economic, and Social Consequences.! Sentencing and Corrections, Issue 9. Rhine, Edward E., William R Smith, and Donald W. Jackson 1991. Paroling Authorities: Recent History and Current Practice. Laurie, MD: American Correctional Association. Rubin, Donald B. 1978. Bayesian Inference for Causal Effects: The Role of Randomization.! Annals of Statistics, 6:34--58. Sentencing Project. 2001. Slowing of Prison Growth Likely Linked to Both Crime and Criminal Justice Policy. News Release. Washington, D.C.: Sentencing Project Shiskin, Julius. 1976. Employment and Unemployment: The Doughnut or the Hole?! Monthly Labor Review 99 (2):3-10. Sobel, Michael. 1995. Causal Inference in the Social and Behavioral Sciences.! Handbook of Statistical Modeling for the Social and Behavioral Sciences, ed G. Arminger, C.C. Clogg, M.E. Sobel, pp.1-38. New York: Plenum. Sorrentino, Constance. 1993. International Comparisons of Unemployment Indicators.! Monthly Labor Review 116 (3):3-24.

---. 1995. International Unemployment Indicators, 1983-1993.! Monthly Labor Review 118 (8):31-50. ---. 2000. International Unemployment Rates: How Comparable Are They?! Monthly Labor Review 123 (6):3-20. Travis, Jeremy, Amy L. Solomon, and Michelle Waul. 2001. From Prison to Home: The Dimensions and Consequences of Prisoner Reentry. Washington, D.C.: The Urban Institute. U.S. Bureau of the Census. 1998. Current Population Survey Interviewing Manual, February 1998. Washington, D.C.: Bureau of the Census. Wacquant, Loic. 1998. From Welfare State to Prison State: Imprisoning the American Poor.! LeMonde Diplomatique: July 1998. ---. 2000. The New % Peculiar Institution& : On the Prison as Surrogate Ghetto.! Theoretical Criminology 4:377-389. Walmsley, Roy. 2000. World Prison Population List (second edition).! Research Findings No. 116.: London. Home Office Research, Development and Statistics Directorate. Western, Bruce, and Katherine Beckett. 1998. Der Mythos des freien Marktes. Das Strafrecht als Institution des amerikanischen Arbeitsmarktes.! Berliner Journal f% r Soziologie 8:159-180. ---. 1999. How Unregulated Is the U.S. Labor Market? The Penal System as a Labor Market Institution.! American Journal of Sociology 104:1030-1060. Western, Bruce, Katherine Beckett, and David Harding. 1998. Syst( me P+nal et March+ du Travail Aux - tats-Unis.! Actes de la Recherche en Sciences Sociales 124:27-35. Western, Bruce, and Becky Pettit. 2000. Incarceration an Racial Inequality in Men& s Employment.! Industrial and Labor Relations Review 54:3-16 Winship, Christopher, and Stephen L. Morgan. 1999. The Estimation of Causal Effects From Observational Data.! Annual Review of Sociology 25:659-707. Wray, L. Randall. 2001. Did the Rising Tide Eliminate Our % Surplus&Population?! Journal of Economic Issues 35:525-531. Zagorsky, Jay. 1996. Can Prison Explain the U.S. Canadian Unemployment Rate Gap?! Unpublished manuscript. Department of Human resource Planning: Ohio State University.

Table 1 Incarceration and Incarceration Rates per 100,000 Residents Both sexes, 1999. INCARCERATED POPULATION INCARCERATION RATE

COUNTRY Europe Austria 6,877 85 Belgium 8,143 80 Denmark 3,496 65 Finland 2,389 45 France 53,948 90 Germany 79,666 95 Greece 7,525 70 Iceland* 103 35 Ireland 2,741 80 Italy 51,427 90 Luxembourg 386 90 Netherlands 13,231 90 Norway* 2,466 60 Portugal 13,086 130 Spain 44,197 110 Sweden 5,270 60 Switzerland 5,818 85 United Kingdom 73,195 125 North. America Canada 37,384 110 United States 1,860,520 680 - White Men** 806,300 990 - Black Men** 753,600 6,838 Other Australia 20,416 110 China 1,408,860 110 Japan 54,811 40 Russia 1,060,085 730 Notes: * 1998, ** 197. Sources: Barclay, Tavares, Siddique (2001); Walmsley (2000); Bureau of Justice Statistics (2000).

Table A.1 Inmates of Federal and State Prisons, and Local Jails U.S., both sexes, 1980-1999 PRISON JAIL % CHANGE 319,598 182,288 .. 360,029 195,085 10.6 402,914 207,853 10.0 423,898 221,815 5.7 448,264 233,018 5.5 487,593 254,986 9.0 526,436 272,735 7.6 562,814 294,092 7.2 606,810 341,893 10.7 683,382 393,303 13.5 743,382 403,019 6.5 792,535 424,129 6.1 850,566 441,781 6.2 909,381 455,500 5.6 990,147 479,800 7.7 1,078,542 499,300 7.3 1,127,528 510,400 3.8 1,176,564 557,974 5.9 1,224,469 584,372 4.3 1,284,894 596,485 4.0 Avrg. ann. increase 7.2 Note: Data refer to custody counts. Source: BJS 2000a. YEAR 1980 1981 1982 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 TOTAL 501,886 555,114 610,767 645,713 681,282 742,579 799,171 856,906 948,703 1,076,685 1,146,401 1,216,664 1,292,347 1,364,881 1,469,947 1,577,842 1,637,928 1,734,538 1,808,841 1,881,379

Table A.2 Male Inmates of Federal and State Prisons U.S, males, by race, 1980-1999 YEAR TOTAL WHITE BLACK 1980 303,643 159,500 140,600 1981 338,940 178,200 156,100 1982 378,045 199,400 174,900 1983 405,634 210,700 185,900 1984 428,491 223,500 194,600 1985 465,488 242,700 210,500 1986 501,194 258,900 232,000 1987 535,013 277,200 249,700 1988 575,670 292,200 274,300 1989 645,189 322,100 313,700 1990 702,077 350,700 340,300 1991 747,862 369,200 366,500 1992 803,558 394,500 393,700 1993 858,092 428,700 434,900 1994 933,256 465,300 474,800 1995 1,014,540 487,400 509,800 1996 1,057,755 511,300 528,600 1997 1,102,978 541,300 548,500 1998 1,144,569 .. .. 1999 1,196,498 .. .. Note: Data refer to jurisdiction counts, except totals 1983-1998 which refer to custody counts. Data for Blacks exclude Hispanics. Totals include Hispanics and other/unknown races. Totals in 1993/94 may be below sum of White and Black due to jurisdiction/custody classification problems. Sources: BJS, 1995, 2000a, 2000b, National Prison Statistics Series - NP1, 2001, online.

Table A.3 Inmate Surveys Used to Derive upi, lfpi, and Work In Confinment Variables. Reference period for "had job or business" and "search for work" prior to incarceration variables ? "at time of your arrest" "at time of arrest (or admission)" "month before admission (arrest)" "month before current offense" ? "month before arrest" "month before arrest" "month before" "month before arrest"

Sample Size Sample Universe Year Citation Institutions Individuals 1 Local Jails 1978 BJS 1997a ~400 5,247 2 1983 BJS 1997 b 407 5,785 3 1989 BJS 1997c 424 6,258 4 1996 BJS 1999 431 6,133 5 State Prisons 1979 BJS1997 d ~300 11,397 6 1986 BJS 1994a 275 14,649 7 1991 BJS 1993b 272 13,986 8 1997 BJS 2000 c 280 14,285 9 Federal Prisons 1991 BJS 1994b 6,572 10 1997 BJS 2000 c 32 4,041 Note: Items 8 and 10 are jointly administered but separate surveys.

Table A.4 European Country Groups COUNTRY Eu-15 E-13 Eu-6 Austria X X .. Belgium X X .. Denmark X X .. Finland X X .. France X X X Germany X X X Greece X .. .. Ireland X X .. Italy X X X Luxembourg X .. .. Netherlands X X X Norway .. X .. Portugal X .. .. Spain X .. .. Sweden X X X Switzerland .. X .. United Kingdom X X X Eu-15: Member countries of the European Union E-13: Used by Western and Beckett (1999) EU-6: Highly standardized labor market data available (BLS 2001)

Table 4 Inmate's Labour Force Participation and Unemployment Rates Prior to Incarceration. U.S. males, 1978-1997 Fractions YEAR LF pi UE pi 1978 0.85 0.17 1979 0.85 0.18 1980 0.86 0.20 1981 0.86 0.20 1982 0.87 0.21 1983 0.87 0.22 1984 0.87 0.21 1985 0.88 0.21 1986 0.88 0.21 1987 0.88 0.20 1988 0.87 0.19 1989 0.87 0.18 1990 0.86 0.18 1991 0.86 0.17 1992 0.85 0.17 1993 0.85 0.16 1994 0.85 0.16 1995 0.85 0.16 1996 0.84 0.15 1997 0.84 0.15 Notes: Table shows wieghted averages for inmates of federal prisons, state prisons, and local jails. Author's calculations from surveys listed in Table A.3, using appropriate sample weights.

Table A.5 Inmate's Unemployment Rates Prior to Incarceration U.S., males, State Prison and Local Jail Inmates, 1985, 1995. Fractions STATE LOCAL YEAR Total White Black Total White Black 1985 0.17 0.14 0.20 0.28 0.26 0.33 1986 0.18 0.15 0.21 0.26 0.23 0.31 1987 0.17 0.14 0.21 0.24 0.21 0.28 1988 0.17 0.14 0.20 0.22 0.19 0.26 1989 0.17 0.13 0.20 0.20 0.17 0.24 1990 0.16 0.13 0.20 0.20 0.16 0.24 1991 0.16 0.12 0.20 0.20 0.16 0.24 1992 0.16 0.12 0.19 0.19 0.15 0.24 1993 0.15 0.12 0.19 0.19 0.15 0.24 1994 0.15 0.11 0.18 0.19 0.15 0.24 1995 0.14 0.11 0.18 0.19 0.14 0.24 Notes: Author's calculations from surveys listed in Table A.3., using appropriate sample weights. Piecewise interpolation between survey years.

Table 5 U.S. Unemployment Rates, Official and at Zero Incarceration By sex and race, 1976-1999. Percentages UNEMPLOYMENT RATE TOTAL MEN WHITE MEN BLACK MEN YEAR Official Zero Inc Official Zero Inc Official Zero Inc Official Zero Inc 1976 7.70 7.73 7.06 7.11 6.38 .. 12.68 .. 1977 7.06 7.10 6.28 6.35 5.54 .. 12.32 .. 1978 6.07 6.12 5.27 5.36 4.55 .. 10.96 .. 1979 5.85 5.90 5.14 5.23 4.47 .. 10.39 .. 1980 7.14 7.20 6.94 7.04 6.14 .. 13.21 .. 1981 7.61 7.68 7.39 7.50 6.52 .. 14.08 .. 1982 9.69 9.76 9.89 10.00 8.79 .. 18.23 .. 1983 9.61 9.68 9.93 10.05 8.76 8.81 18.51 18.75 1984 7.52 7.61 7.43 7.57 6.42 6.50 14.72 15.08 1985 7.20 7.29 7.02 7.17 6.07 6.15 13.79 14.21 1986 6.99 7.08 6.92 7.08 6.00 6.09 13.37 13.82 1987 6.19 6.29 6.19 6.36 5.42 5.51 11.50 11.98 1988 5.51 5.61 5.46 5.63 4.74 4.83 10.31 10.88 1989 5.27 5.38 5.20 5.38 4.47 4.56 10.04 10.65 1990 5.60 5.71 5.66 5.84 4.92 5.00 10.36 10.96 1991 6.83 6.93 7.15 7.32 6.47 6.54 11.43 12.00 1992 7.50 7.60 7.89 8.05 7.00 7.06 13.41 13.90 1993 6.92 7.03 7.18 7.35 6.33 6.40 12.37 12.90 1994 6.10 6.22 6.17 6.36 5.39 5.47 10.82 11.45 1995 5.60 5.72 5.58 5.79 4.90 4.99 9.63 10.32 1996 5.40 5.53 5.38 5.59 4.69 4.77 9.55 10.22 1997 4.94 5.08 4.88 5.10 4.22 4.31 8.80 9.51 1998 4.51 4.65 4.42 4.64 3.86 .. 7.64 .. 1999 4.22 4.36 4.11 4.34 3.59 .. 7.14 .. Notes: Labor market data from BLS series compiled in OECD (2001). Incarceration data from BJS (1995, 2000a, 2000b) and parameter estimates from surveys listed in Table A.3. Estimates by race missing for some years, due to lacking incarceration counts.

Table 6 Fraction of Inmates Working and Receiving Compensation in Prison and Jail U.S. males, 1983-1996 Fractions YEAR Working in- or outside of facility 1983 1991 1996 AVERAGE* PRISONS FEDERAL STATE LOCAL JAIL

0.60 0.58 0.57

.. 0.91 0.90

0.73 0.69 0.69

0.36 0.32 0.27

Working for money 1983 0.37 .. 0.50 0.10 1991 0.34 0.88 0.47 0.03 1996 0.34 0.88 0.41 0.08 Working for money or payment in kind (= employed per CPS definition) 1983 0.48 .. 0.63 0.20 1991 0.46 0.89 0.61 0.14 1996 0.45 0.89 0.54 0.15 Notes: Authors calculations from surveys listed in Table A.3, using appropriate sample weights. Piecewise interpolation between survey years. * Averages weighted by relative sizes of inmate population in prisons and jail.

Table 7 Alternative Measures of Unemployment Under Various Inmate-Inclusion Scenarios U.S., males, 1976-1999 Percentages (1) (2) (3) (4) Official Working Inmates: All Inmates Unemployment employed employed, counted as Rate unemployed Non-Working Inmates: YEAR non-employed unemployed 1976 7.06 7.04 7.31 7.59 1977 6.28 6.26 6.56 6.86 1978 5.27 5.25 5.59 5.91 1979 5.14 5.12 5.46 5.79 1980 6.94 6.92 7.30 7.62 1981 7.39 7.36 7.76 8.12 1982 9.89 9.85 10.28 10.67 1983 9.93 9.88 10.33 10.75 1984 7.43 7.40 7.87 8.31 1985 7.02 6.98 7.49 7.97 1986 6.92 6.89 7.42 7.93 1987 6.19 6.16 6.74 7.26 1988 5.46 5.43 6.09 6.63 1989 5.20 5.16 5.92 6.50 1990 5.66 5.62 6.41 7.02 1991 7.15 7.10 7.90 8.56 1992 7.89 7.83 8.68 9.36 1993 7.18 7.12 8.01 8.72 1994 6.17 6.11 7.08 7.83 1995 5.58 5.53 6.57 7.36 1996 5.38 5.33 6.41 7.21 1997 4.88 4.84 5.99 6.79 1998 4.42 4.37 5.58 6.38 1999 4.11 4.07 5.32 6.14 Note: Same sources as in Table 5.

Table 8 Non-Employment to Population Ratio, Adjusted for Non-Working Inmates U.S., males, 1976-1999. Percentages (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) Official Adding non-employed Adding all Inmates NEPR Inmates to NEPR to NEPR YEAR New Ratio Difference New Ratio Difference 1976 27.96 28.06 0.10 28.28 0.32 1977 27.22 27.33 0.12 27.56 0.35 1978 26.24 26.38 0.14 26.64 0.39 1979 26.16 26.30 0.14 26.56 0.40 1980 27.98 28.13 0.15 28.40 0.43 1981 28.71 28.86 0.15 29.17 0.46 1982 30.98 31.12 0.15 31.46 0.48 1983 31.19 31.34 0.15 31.70 0.51 1984 29.32 29.49 0.17 29.86 0.54 1985 29.10 29.28 0.18 29.68 0.58 1986 29.03 29.21 0.19 29.65 0.62 1987 28.53 28.74 0.21 29.19 0.66 1988 27.98 28.24 0.26 28.70 0.72 1989 27.54 27.85 0.31 28.35 0.81 1990 27.96 28.28 0.32 28.81 0.84 1991 29.64 29.94 0.30 30.50 0.86 1992 30.16 30.47 0.31 31.06 0.90 1993 29.98 30.31 0.33 30.92 0.94 1994 29.57 29.93 0.36 30.58 1.00 1995 29.21 29.60 0.39 30.28 1.07 1996 29.10 29.51 0.41 30.20 1.10 1997 28.69 29.13 0.45 29.84 1.15 1998 28.42 28.89 0.47 29.60 1.19 1999 28.35 28.85 0.49 29.57 1.22 Note: Same sources as in Table 5.

Figure 1

Unemployment Rates, United States - EU-15


12.00
Percent of labor force

10.00 8.00 6.00 4.00 2.00 0.00 1976 1978 1980 1982 1984 1986 1988 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998
1989 1993

Notes: Standardized unemployment rates for both sexes from OECD (2001). Solid line: U.S.; broken line: 15 EU member countries.

Figure 2

Incarcerated Population, United States and EU-15. 1925-1999


2000000 1800000 1600000 1400000 Inmates 1200000 1000000 800000 600000 400000 200000 0 1925 1929 1933 1937 1941 1945 1949 1953 1957 1961 1965 1969 1973 1977 1981 1985 1997

U.S. Prisons and Jails

U.S. Prisons

EU-15

Sources: U.S., BJS (1995, 2000a, 2000b); EU-15, Council of Europe (various years)

2000

Figure 3

European Unemployment Rates Relative to the U.S.: Official and Incarceration-Adjusted Differences (both sexes)
8.00 6.00 Percentage Point Difference 4.00 EU-15 EU-13 EU-6 2.00 0.00 1976 1978 1980 1982 1984 1986 1988 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 -2.00 -4.00 2000 incEU-15 incEU-13 incEU-6

Sources: Labor force data: OECD (2001), BLS (2001). Incarceration adjusted differences computed from BJS (1995, 2000a, 2000b), Council of Europe (various years), BJS inmate surveys listed in Table A.3.

Figure 4

European Unemployment Rates Relative to the U.S.: Official and Incarceration-Adjusted Differences (males)
8.00 6.00 4.00 2.00 0.00 1977 1979 1981 1983 1985 1987 1989 1991 1993 1995 1997 -2.00 -4.00 Sources: Labor force data: OECD (2001), BLS (2001). Incarceration adjusted differences computed from BJS (1995, 2000a, 2000b), Council of Europe (various years), BJS inmate surveys listed in Table A.3. 1999 year

Percentage point differences

EU-15 EU-13 incEU-15 incEU-13

Figure 5
Eu-6 NEPR Relative to the U.S.: Official and Incarceration-Adjusted Differences (both sexes)
14.00 Percentage point differences 12.00 10.00 8.00 6.00 4.00 2.00 0.00 1976 1978 1980 1982 1984 1986 1988 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 Official Inc. included

Sources: Labor force data: OECD (2001), BLS (2001). Incarceration adjusted differences computed from BJS (1995, 2000a, 2000b), Council of Europe (various years), BJS inmate surveys listed in Table A.3.

You might also like