You are on page 1of 9

http://jtr.sagepub.

com/

Journal of Travel Research


http://jtr.sagepub.com/content/49/1/31
The online version of this article can be found at:

DOI: 10.1177/0047287509353192
2010 49: 31 originally published online 3 December 2009 Journal of Travel Research
Egon Smeral
Impacts of the World Recession and Economic Crisis on Tourism: Forecasts and Potential Risks

Published by:
http://www.sagepublications.com
On behalf of:

Travel and Tourism Research Association


can be found at: Journal of Travel Research Additional services and information for

http://jtr.sagepub.com/cgi/alerts Email Alerts:

http://jtr.sagepub.com/subscriptions Subscriptions:
http://www.sagepub.com/journalsReprints.nav Reprints:

http://www.sagepub.com/journalsPermissions.nav Permissions:

http://jtr.sagepub.com/content/49/1/31.refs.html Citations:

by Nita Valentin on October 15, 2010 jtr.sagepub.com Downloaded from


Journal of Travel Research
49(1) 31 38
2010 SAGE Publications
Reprints and permission: http://www.
sagepub.com/journalsPermissions.nav
DOI: 10.1177/0047287509353192
http://jtr.sagepub.com
Impacts of the World Recession
and Economic Crisis on Tourism: Forecasts
and Potential Risks
Egon Smeral
1
Abstract
In the face of the world recession, this article concentrates on analyzing and forecasting demand for outbound traveling
in Australia, Canada, United States, Japan, and the EU-15 countries in terms of tourism imports at constant prices and
exchange rates. Drawing on an analysis of the macroeconomic effects of the global recession and its impact on tourism
demand for outbound traveling, the article develops forecasts for the period from 2009 to 2010. For 2010, two scenarios
are created to project demand for foreign travel. The study is rounded off by a discussion of forecast uncertainties and
open questions.
Keywords
world recession, crisis, forecast models, tourism forecast for 2009 and 2010, slump of tourism demand
Introduction
In 2009 the world economy became mired in a deep reces-
sion, the worst since the Second World War. The sharp decline
in merchandise exports and industrial production, rising
unemployment, and rapidly eroding consumer confidence in
most of the major tourism source markets have had a severe
negative impact on the tourism industries. In 2009 the global
economy will shrink by 1.5% (IMF 2009) and world trade will
fall by about 15%.
By mid-2009 it appears that the free fall of production and
trade has come to an end and is about to bottom out (OECD
2009).
1
At the business level, such optimism is fueled by
observations that the massive destocking process seems to have
slowed down and may well come to a stop very soon. Still,
given the sheer vastness of current spare capacities, investment
will remain weak. On the consumer side, the outlook does not
yet promise a recovery: unemployment will continue to rise and
incomes will decline. Governmentsstill actively engaged in
stabilizing the economyhave not yet started to increase taxes
and cut public spending to reduce the debt burden (ETC 2009).
The BRIC countries (Brazil, Russia, India, and China)
already appear to be at the point of recovery. This is certainly
the case in China, which has taken substantial monetary and
especially fiscal measures. Brazil and India are also showing
signs of a recovery. Russia is suffering a severe recession,
but with commodity prices on the rebound and the effects of
government measures there should be a recovery on the hori-
zon in 2009-2010 (OECD 2009).
The downturn of the global economy is a result of a dra-
matic credit crunch and an economic slump (for an overview
of the causes of the financial and economic crisis, see Smeral
2009). The United States has been in recession since Decem-
ber 2007, the euro zone has seen its macroeconomic situation
deteriorate since the fourth quarter of 2008, and Eastern Cen-
tral Europe followed downhill at the start of 2009.
In contrast to former economic downturns, the current
crisis has a global and all-encompassing impact that has hit
tourism services (a non-necessary consumer good) with par-
ticular force. After a slight decline in the second half of 2008,
international arrivals plummeted by 8% worldwide between
January and April 2009 (UNWTO 2009a).
Broken down by regions, Europe (10% in terms of inter-
national arrivals) and the Middle East (18% in terms of
international arrivals) were the regions hardest hit in the period
from January to April 2009. The EU business survey for the
hotel and restaurant industry, based on seasonally adjusted
monthly balances of positive and negative responses (turnover
development during the past 3 months) in percentage of busi-
nesses polled, clearly reflects the negative assessment by the
industry in the course of 2008 and 2009 (Figure 1).
International arrivals in Asia and the Pacific decreased by
6% and in the Americas by 5%; the only exception was
Africa, which recorded an increase of 3% (UNWTO 2009a).
On the other hand, there is evidence that generally speak-
ing, domestic and near-foreign destinations (those within a
1
Austrian Institute of Economic Research, Vienna
Corresponding Author:
Egon Smeral, Austrian Institute of Economic Research,
P.O. Box 91, A-1103 Vienna, Austria
Email: Egon.Smeral@wifo.ac.at
by Nita Valentin on October 15, 2010 jtr.sagepub.com Downloaded from
32 Journal of Travel Research 49(1)
reasonable travel distance from populous source markets)
were suffering considerably less than long-distance destina-
tions since, in economically difficult times, tourists prefer
holiday places that are easy to reach by car. Staying closer to
their homes reduces the surprise factor because tourists can
minimize the risk in terms of product prices and quality. Fur-
thermore, tourists apparently economize on the duration of
their stay, scale back their expenditure per night, and tend to
sacrifice secondary holidays (mini-breaks, city trips) rather
than their main holidays (ETC 2009). Tourists also tend to
book at the last moment, partly because they are not confi-
dent of their future job situation and partly because they
hope to profit from last-minute bargains and cheaper deals
(ETC 2009).
In general, there is also evidence that the crisis hit business
travel harder than leisure travel. Moreover, overnight stays in
both luxury and budget accommodations showed lower rates
of decline than the average of all accommodations.
The International Air Transport Association (IATA) con-
firmed the slump in international tourism demand by finding
an 8% decline in worldwide passenger traffic from January
to May 2009. Hotel performance data from January to April
2009 show a similar drop in tourism demand (UNWTO
2009a): overall occupancy was down in all world regions.
Revenue per available room (RevPAR) fell by double-digit
rates, especially in Asia and the Pacific (30.3%) and in
Europe (32.7%).
To stop the tailspin and boost private consumption, almost
all advanced economies took massive fiscal and monetary
action: in the United States, the negative general government
balance as a percentage of the GDP rose from 6% (2008) to
10% (2009), and in the euro zone the increase was from
2% (2008) to 5.5% (2009).
Many countries have actually realized that tourism is of
great importance for employment and value-added generation
and have therefore taken measures to stimulate tourism demand
and support tourism enterprises. In general, national stimulus
packages concentrate on tourism promotion and marketing,
but several countries also focus on fiscal and monetary mea-
sures (UNWTO 2009b). Their introduction of such fiscal and
monetary schemes highlights the need for tourism enterprises
to access credit and increase their liquidity in order to stay in
business and employ people. Other measures applied are aimed
at publicprivate partnership and travel facilitation (e.g., visa
application process, cutting the costs of visas or abolishing
visa requirements for certain source markets).
In 2009, most of the advanced economies have been
experiencing a sharp decline in their GDP. It could have been
worse, but a major across-the-board economic policy effort
appears to have prevented an even worse collapse. We do not
know yet whether the signs of a slowdown in the contraction
of output and trade are indicators of a sustainable recovery or
only a temporary flash in the pan. In spite of such uncertain-
ties, projections by international organizations raise hopes
for a recovery in the OECD area in 2010, but this recovery
will be weak and fragile for some time yet (OECD 2009).
Moreover, we ought to expect the negative economic and
social consequences of the crisis to be long-lasting, and it
will be especially difficult to reduce the high unemployment
rates to a socially more acceptable figure. The recovery will
be slow, and only moderate growth rates are expected in the
medium term, also in tourism. This will affect the behavior
of investors and consumers alike. It is more than doubtful
whether tourism behavior will be the same after this crisis
than it was before.
A previous study (Smeral 2009) analyzed the impact of
the financial and economic crisis on European tourism as of
the end of March 2009. Since then, an updated and more
recent data set up to 2008 has become available, and also cer-
tain macroeconomic trends (especially the magnitudes of
GDP declines) have become more tangible and more open to
revision. The focus of the current study (completed by the
end of August 2009) is on delivering an update for the Euro-
pean case (tourism imports of the EU-15)
2
as well as on
analyzing and forecasting the demand for international travel
in the United States, Canada, Australia, and Japan in terms of
tourism imports. The article first develops a range of fore-
casting models to project demand for foreign travel, and
follows up with forecasts for 2009 and 2010, before discuss-
ing and comparing results. The conclusions will provide a
critical discussion of the macroeconomic framework condi-
tions and their impact on future tourism.
Modeling Tourism Demand
for Outbound Travel
Starting with the standard tourism demand model that results
from multistage budgeting, tourism demand for foreign
40
35
30
25
20
15
10
5
0
+5
+10
+15
+20
+25
2005 2006 2007 2008 2009
Figure 1. Turnover in the hotel and restaurant sector in the EU-
27 over the past 3 months
Source: Business survey of the European Commission. Time period
covered: January 2005 to July 2009.
Note: Balance of optimistic and pessimistic responses in percentage of
businesses polled, seasonally adjusted.
by Nita Valentin on October 15, 2010 jtr.sagepub.com Downloaded from
Smeral 33
travel in the five source markets of this study is basically
explained by their GDPs at constant prices and exchange
rates and the relative prices (Smeral 1988; Smeral and
Weber 2000).
Tourism demand for foreign travel is indicated by tour-
ism imports at constant prices and exchange rates (MR) of
the countries of Australia, Canada, Japan, the United
States and the EU-15. The GDP (BIPR) was chosen as the
main exogenous factor to explain the development of tour-
ism demand for outbound traveling because the tourism
import figures include a significant share of business trips
and the GDP also covers the development of business trips
whereas the real personal disposable income generally
indicates only the development of holiday demand. The
influence of prices on tourism import demand is captured
by the average price index for foreign stays, that is, the
price index of tourism imports (MP). The import price
index of a source market is defined as the weighted sum of
the consumer price indices of 19 important destinations
(with the weights given by the country-specific demand
according to the overnight structure; Smeral and Weber
2000). To indicate the development of the price index for
domestic tourism, the GDP deflator (BIPD) was chosen.
To avoid multicollinearity between exchange rates and
price indices in local currencies, all the price indices are
expressed in dollars, instead of using these two variables
separately in the estimating equations. Dummy variables
indicate data irregularities caused by statistical problems and
unexplainable outliers.
All the econometric estimations are based on annual data
covering the time period of 19772008. For the model esti-
mation, the loglinear functional form is used same as in
many previous studies. Applying the loglog linear approach
allows us to interpret the estimated parameters of the exog-
enous variables as demand elasticities.
Based on the standard tourism demand model, a general
autoregressive distributed lag model (ADLM) is specified as
follows (Smeral 1988; Song and Witt 2000; Song and Lin
2009; Enders 2004; Hill, Griffiths, and Lim 2008):
In MR
t
= g
1
+ g
2
In MR
t-1
+ g
3
In BIPR
t


(1) + g
4
In BIPR
t-1
+ g
5
In MP
t
+ g
6
In MP
t-1
+ g
7
In BIPD
t
+ g
8
In BIPD
t-1
+ Dummies + e
t
;
e
t
is an error term.
To specify the length of the time lag, it is important to
consider what types of time series are used. As annual values
are used here, it is quite realistic to assume in general a time
lag of 1 (Song and Witt 2003; Song and Lin 2009).
The general ADLM formulated above encompasses a
number of specific econometric and time-series models that
have been widely used in the specific literature on tourism
demand modeling and forecasting (Song and Witt 2000,
2003; Song and Li 2008). One of the most advanced
approaches belonging to the ADLM structure is the error
correction model (ECM; Enders 2004). From equation (1),
some algebraic operations produce an ECM (equation [2]):

ln MR
t
g
3
ln BIPR
t
g
5
ln MP
t
g
7
ln BIPD
t
1 g
2

ln MR
t1

g
1
1g
2

g
3
g
4
1g
2

ln BIPR
t1

g
5
g
6
1g
2

ln MP
t1

g
7
g
8
1g
2

ln BIPDt1
0
B
@
1
C
A
Dummies m
t
;

(2)
m
t
is an error term (white noise).
The ECM (equation [2]) covers short- and long-term rela-
tionships: the coefficients of the level variables reflect the
long-term demand elasticities, while the coefficients of the
differentiated variables reflect the short-term demand elas-
ticities. The expression - (1 - g
2
) is known as the error
correction parameter, the expression in the brackets is known
as the error correction mechanism. The error correction term
is greater than 1 and less than 0. Because of this, the system
will adjust itself in the direction of the equilibrium state by
considering the error correction parameter and the errors
made in the previous periods.
The estimates for the ECM (equation [2]) produced
insignificant parameters (based on the t-values) for the
level variables. Because the lagged level variables repre-
sent the cointegration as well as the long-term relationship,
eliminating these insignificant variables would violate the
ECM approach.
To produce reliable estimates, an elimination process is
used that eliminates variables with nonplausible signs as pro-
vided for in economic theory and statistically insignificant
parameters. At the end of this elimination process we obtain
a model structure that is known in the literature as the growth
rate model, which covers more or less only short-term rela-
tionships and considers principally the income and price
effects (Song and Witt 2000). To avoid multicollinearity, the
price indices are captured by a relative price index variable.
In a second version of this growth rate model, the
medium-term development of the foreign traveling habit
was modeled using a HodrickPrescott (HP) filter for the
dependent variables (tourism imports at constant prices and
exchange rates; Enders 2004; Hodrick and Prescott 1997;
Smeral 2009). The latter operation delivered a long-term
flexible trend for the development of the habits of outbound
traveling (HPMR; Smeral 2009).
Visiting foreign destinations is subject to trends that change
over time. Such flexible trends are captured using an HP filter.
Since medium-term development of the demand to travel
to foreign destinations is best described and captured by
a flexible trend of the dependent variable, this flexible
patternisolated by the HP filter methodwas used instead
of the lagged dependent variable as an indicator for the pat-
tern of habit effects (Smeral and Wger 2005; Smeral
2007, 2009).
by Nita Valentin on October 15, 2010 jtr.sagepub.com Downloaded from
34 Journal of Travel Research 49(1)
The relationships formulated above were estimated
econometrically on an OLS base, using the absolute
differences of the natural logarithms of annual values for
the period from 1978 to 2008, where one model
variant (equation [4]) considered the development of travel
habits:
ln MR
t
a
1
a
2
ln BIPR
t
a
3
ln
MP
BIPD

t
Dummies e
t
;

(3)
ln MR
t
b
1
b
2
ln BIPR
t
b
3
ln
MP
BIPD

t
b
4
ln HPMR
t
Dummies e
t
;

(4)
e
t
is an error term.
The estimation results for the models based on equation (3)
can be considered as very satisfying: the variances of the
exogenous variables could explain 70% to 80% of the
variances of the tourism imports of the different source
markets (Table 1). The coefficients of the estimated equations
were found to be statistically significant. The estimates for
the income and price elasticities had plausible dimensions
and signs such as can be expected from economic theory.
The equations for Canada and Japan were estimated with-
out constant terms because when considering the constant
term the estimations delivered insignificant coefficients and/
or coefficients with implausible magnitudes.
The highest income elasticities were measured for the
United States (3.4) and Japan (3.3). For Europe and Austra-
lia, the elasticity of tourism import with respect to changes in
GDP amounted to 2.2. The estimated income elasticities
were relatively low for Canada (1.0).
Equation (3)

Australia: ln MR
t
2:37 2:19ln BIPR
t
0:89ln
MP
BIPD

t
16:64D
2004
1:00 3:45 7:34 2:71
R
2
0:76; D:W: 2:00

Canada: ln MR
t
1:01ln BIPR
t
1:46ln
MP
BIPD

t
26:45D
1990
3:36 7:29 4:67
R
2
0:69; D:W: 2:01

United States: ln MR
t
6:21 3:36ln BIPR
t
0:88ln
MP
BIPD

t
2:95 4:91 7:25
R
2
0:87; D:W: 2:09

Japan: ln MR
t
3:34ln BIPR
t
0:90ln
MP
BIPD

t
33:24D
1988
24:23D
1991
28:65D
2006
5:26 5:15 3:08 2:39 2:87
R
2
0:76; D:W: 1:46

EU-15
a
: ln MR
t
1:38 2:22ln BIPR
t
1:12ln
MP
BIPD

t
9:36D
1980
11:00D
1992
1:29 5:32 4:74 3:86 4:52
R
2
0:79; D:W: 1:59
Equation (4)

EU-15
a
:ln MR
t
3:90 2:04ln BIPR
t
1:07ln
MP
BIPD

t
0:74ln HPMR
t
9:58D
1980
9:87D
1992
2:36 4:98 4:72 1:93 4:15 4:13
R
2
0:81; D:W: 1:71
MR .................. Real tourism imports (million $, at 2000 prices and exchange rates)
HPMR ............. Flexible trend of real tourism imports, derived using an HP filter
MP ................... Price index of real tourism imports ($ basis; 2000 = 100)
BIPR ................. Real gross domestic product (million $, reference year: 2000)
BIPD ................ GDP deflator ($ basis; 2000 = 100)
Dyyyy ............... Dummy variable for the year indicated (value = 1; for all other years value = 0)
b
t .................... Time index, 19782008
Table 1. Econometric Explanation of Real Tourism Imports of Five Different Source Markets for the Period 19782008
Source: IMF, OECD, UNWTO, WIFO, own calculations (EViews 6.0). t -statistics are in parentheses.
a. Excluding Austria.
b. The dummies are set for data irregularities.
by Nita Valentin on October 15, 2010 jtr.sagepub.com Downloaded from
Smeral 35
The estimation results for the elasticities of tourism
imports with respect to changes in relative prices were in
most cases similar and amounted to about 1; the only excep-
tion was Canada, where the estimation delivered a
significantly different and higher value for the price elastic-
ity (1.5).
The estimation results for the models based on equa-
tion (4) were only satisfactory in the case of the EU-15 (see
Table 1); for all the other source markets the coefficients of
the flexible trends of the medium-term travel habit were
not significant. The estimation results for the elasticity of
demand for outbound traveling by EU-15 citizens could be
seen as realistic with respect to the medium-term habitual
flexible trend for foreign travel (0.74); the estimation of the
import elasticity with respect to the changes in the GDP
amounted to 2.0.
Future Outlook
Based on the estimated equations (3) and (4) (the latter is
only valid for the EU-15), a forecast for 2009 and 2010 can
be derived for the real tourism imports of the source markets
dealt with in this article.
The forecast starts out from the assumptions on GDP
development trends, where we follow the recent forecasts
of the OECD (OECD 2009; Table 2):
In Australia the impact of the international economic
and financial crisis will be less severe than in most other
advanced countries. Weak exports and, in consequence,
sluggish private consumption and a strong decline in
investment demand combine to shrink GDP in 2009
(0.4%), after a growth rate of 2.3% in 2008. For 2010 a
moderate recovery is expectedGDP will grow by
1.2%but unemployment will rise and reach a level of
almost 8% (2008: about 4%). To mitigate the impact of
the crisis, the country expanded its economic policy, as a
result of which the general government financial balance
switched from a slight surplus in 2008 (+1.2% in terms of
the nominal GDP) to a significant deficit in 2009 (4.9%
in terms of the nominal GDP). The budget deficit is not
expected to be reduced in 2010.
The global recession has had a severe effect on the
Canadian economy. Decelerating since late 2007, the economy
started to contract by the end of 2008. By the beginning of
2009, foreign demand and fixed assets investment began to
shrink heavily. Consumers reduced their spending (especially
on housing) in response to losses in the value of their assets
and because of a growing uncertainty about labor market
expectations. After a GDP growth of only 0.4% in 2008, the
Canadian economy will shrink by 2.6% in 2009 and grow
minimally only (by 0.7%) in 2010. Same as its Australian
counterpart, the Canadian government turned the slightly
positive general government balance (+0.1%) into a
significant deficit (4.8%), in order to mitigate the effects of
the crisis.
The US economy is going through a severe recession,
although there are hopes that it will bottom out by the end of
2009 at the latest. Consumer demand is very weak already
for the second year: general uncertainties about the future, a
weak labor market and rising unemployment, an enormous
loss in wealth and tight credit conditions collude to keep
private households from spending money. The household
savings ratio (as a percentage of disposable income) amounted
to 0.6 in 2007, rose to 1.8 in 2008, and will reach a level of
5.4 in 2009; for 2010, it is expected to increase by an addi-
tional percentage point. Residential construction investments
plummeted by around one-fifth in 2008, and a contraction of
similar magnitude is expected for 2009. Investment in equip-
ment will shrink by 19% in 2009. Fiscal policy inflated the
negative general government balance to a level of 10% of the
GDP, providing a considerable boost for the economy, so
that GDP will decline by only 2.8% in 2009. A gradual
recovery should take hold in 2010, to result in an expected
GDP growth of 0.9%. The recovery will depend on financial
conditions staying stable and financial systems gradually
regaining investor confidence.
Japan is laboring under the most severe recession since
the Second World War. The slump in world trade will trigger
a sharp decline in exports by more than 30% in 2009. Invest-
ment in equipment will fall by almost 20%. Increasing
unemployment and lower wages lead to private spending on
consumption shrinking by 1.7% in 2009. In total, GDP will
decline by 6.8% in 2009. Thanks to its expansive fiscal
policy, the recession should bottom out by the end of 2009 at
the latest. There is a slight recovery on the horizon for 2010,
with an expected GDP growth of 0.7%. Moderate export
growth should balance out the decline in business invest-
ments and decelerate the fall in employment and wage rates.
In the Euro area, the downturn appears at present to be
slackening and might become less steep compared to the
plunge the economy took at the start of 2009. In general,
weak consumption, shrinking investment, and an unemploy-
ment rate surging from 7.5% (2008) to 10% (2009) make it
impossible to draw a favorable economic outlook. Neverthe-
less, the decline in economic activity should level off by the
Table 2. Real GDP 20082010
Percentage Changes from Previous Year
2008 2009 2010
Australia +2.3 -0.4 +1.2
Canada +0.4 -2.6 +0.7
United States +1.1 -2.8 +0.9
Japan -0.7 -6.8 +0.7
Euro area +0.5 -4.8 0.0
Source: OECD Economic Outlook, Vol. 2009/1, No. 85, June 2009.
by Nita Valentin on October 15, 2010 jtr.sagepub.com Downloaded from
36 Journal of Travel Research 49(1)
end of 2009, an expectation supported by recent business
surveys that suggest that the slump is approaching its bottom
line. After a slight GDP growth by 0.5% in 2008, economic
forecasts predict a decline by 4.8% for 2009 and stagnation
for 2010.
When analyzing the above forecasts, expectations are that
the recession in these source markets will bottom out by
2009 and their economies recover by 2010. GDP rates are
about to plunge in Japan and the EU-15, decline moderately
in the United States and Canada and decrease slightly in
Australia. By 2010, GDP rates should grow again by about
1%, whereas the economies of the EU-15 might stagnate. In
spite of the recovery, unemployment will continue to rise,
and no concepts have so far been developed to get people
back to work. Budget deficits will rise as well, and once
again there are no strategies on hand of how the debt burdens
could be reduced to a manageable size.
This evaluation of GDP forecasts improves confidence in
their development pattern for 2009 (yearly averages), but (in
the authors opinion) the shrinking process may well proceed
until 2010. For that reason, a pessimistic version (variant 2)
is calculated for 2010, which assumes that the forecasts are
lower by 1 percentage point than the OECD forecasts (vari-
ant 1; see Tables 2 and 3).
As to tourism prices, relative prices for outbound travel will
fall by at least 1% in 2009 and 2010. This negative trend is
based on the assumption that excess capacities, low occupancy
rates, and high fixed costs will depress relative tourist prices.
Regarding flexibility of travel habits, after a medium-term
growth rate of 2.5% per year since 2000, variant 1 assumes a
stagnation in 2009 and 2010. If, however, the recession takes
longer (variant 2), habitual foreign travel will decrease by at
least 1% in 2010 (following stagnation in 2009).
According to the forecast based on equation (3), demand
for outbound travel (real tourism imports) in the five source
markets (Australia, Canada, United States, Japan, EU-15) in
total will decline by about 11% in 2009, after a stagnation in
2008 (see Table 3). When accounting for the medium-term
development of travel habits in the EU-15, the total fall in
imports could be about 12.5%. It can be assumed that overall
international tourism will shrink by a slightly lesser extent as
some emerging countries can expect a positive development:
a decrease of some 10% seems to be likely.
The sharpest fall in demand for foreign travel in 2009 is
estimated for Japan (22%) and the United States (14.5%),
partly because of their relatively high income elasticities. In
the EU-15, demand for foreign travel will fall off by 11%;
when considering stagnating medium-term travel habits, the
decline will be even sharper and amount to 12.5%. These
EU-15 figures are more pessimistic by 1 to 1.5 percentage
points than those of the previous study carried out at the end
of March 2009 (Smeral 2009). In general, it needs to be
pointed out that if EU-15 imports could be split into overseas
and European destinations (which is a difficult statistical
problem), travel to overseas destinations would show a greater
decline than travel to nearer-situated neighboring countries.
Canadian tourism imports will be only just dented (1%),
Australias demand for foreign travel will decline by 2.5%.
In 2010, demand for foreign travel in the five source mar-
kets (whose spending on outbound travel accounts for some
80% of the total captured international tourism) should stag-
nate if the expected recovery occurs (variant 1), or wane at a
magnitude of 2.5% if the recovery of the economy takes
longer. When considering the medium-term development of
travel habits in the EU-15, total imports could shrink at a rate
of 2% to 4.5%.
According to variant 1, tourism imports of Japan will
increase by 3%. The Canadian demand for foreign travel will
rise by 2%, and tourism imports of Australia will grow by
only 1%. The more pessimistic view of variant 2 sets the
import development of Australia at 1% and Canada at only
+1% for 2010, and foresees stagnation for the imports of
Japan. Real outbound spending in the United States will
decline by another 2.5% in variant 1, or by 5.5% in the pes-
simistic variant 2.
Tourism imports in the EU-15 will shrink slightly in vari-
ant 1 (0.5%); when considering stagnating travel habits,
there will be a decrease of 3%. In variant 2, demand for for-
eign travel in the EU-15 will decline by 2.5%, or, if habitual
travel falls by 1%, by 5.5%.
Conclusions
Tourism has taken a bad battering from the global recession.
Yet surprisingly enough, the impact on international tourism
has so far been substantially softer than the slump experi-
enced by foreign trade and industrial production. One major
Table 3. Forecast Results for Real Tourism Imports for Five
Different Source Markets for the Years 2009 and 2010
Percentage Changes
from Previous Year
2009 2010
Variant 1 Variant 2
Equation (3)
Australia 2.4 +1.1 1.0
Canada 1.2 +2.2 +1.2
United States 14.7 2.3 5.7
Japan 21.8 +3.2 0.1
EU-15
a
10.9 0.3 2.5
Total 5 (added up) 11.2 0.2 2.5
Equation (4)
EU-15
a
12.6 2.8 5.6
Total 5 (added up) 12.3 1.9 4.6
Source: Own calculations.
a. Excluding Austria.
by Nita Valentin on October 15, 2010 jtr.sagepub.com Downloaded from
Smeral 37
reason might be the severe effect that the massive destocking
process has had on trade and production, whereas tourism
services, being perishable goods, cannot be stored (an empty
hotel bed, aircraft, or restaurant seat is lost forever and
cannot be double-booked the next day). In other words: as
tourism did not have to go through this vast destocking pro-
cess, the impact was much more muted. But there is another
side to the medal: the recovery process might take longer in
tourism than in production and trade because there is no
stock-building process going on in tourism.
A slower recovery of tourism compared to other economic
activities may also follow from the rise in unemployment until
2010 (possibly followed by stagnation at a high level) and a
freeze on incomes. Tight consumer budgets will obviously be
first spent on the necessary consumer goods (food, apparel,
rent, heating, etc.), while little or nothing will go into nonnec-
essary purchases such as travel or luxuries. Furthermore, the
loss in wealth (savings for retirement, for the childrens educa-
tion, for rebuilding the house, etc.) will increase the savings
ratio in the medium term, which will depress consumer
demand. Governmentsstill actively engaged in stabilizing
the economymust sooner or later reduce the huge debt
burden currently accumulated by increasing taxes and cutting
public spending (all this against a background of unsolved
problems in financing the social back-up systems), which will
in turn limit consumer expenditures.
Evidence that, in general, domestic tourism was hit much
less than long-distance travel has made tourism boards real-
ize that campaigns to boost domestic tourism might help
boost the sluggish demand. Yet seen from an international
macroeconomic view, these measures have only expansive
effects: they influence people to travel in their own country
instead of staying at home and saving the hypothetical travel
costs. On the other hand, campaigns organized to influence
people to travel to domestic rather than foreign destinations
could be seen as protective measures. Similar schemes in the
1930s aimed at promoting domestic industries, called beggar
my neighbour policies in the literature (Robinson 1947), are
generally looked at askance.
Furthermore, it appears that tourists increasingly tend to
book at the last moment, partly because of their lack of con-
fidence in their future job situation, partly because of existing
overcapacities, and partly because they hope to profit from
last-minute bargains and cheaper deals. In other words: tour-
ists have become highly price sensitive, a trend that may well
survive the crisis so that there is a genuine risk of price
wars. The consequences of such developments are dramatic
as, sooner or later, the resultant liquidity crunch will make it
impossible to carry out necessary investments and service
quality might deteriorate.
The forecasts in this article show a decline in aggregated
demand of 11% to 12.5% for foreign travel in the five
source markets (Australia, Canada, United States, Japan,
and EU-15) in 2009. Total world tourism spending on for-
eign travel might fall by about 10%. Given the present facts,
these figures appear to be plausible. Uncertainties exist for
2010: can we expect a sustainable recovery or are we in the
middle of crossing a wide-trough valley? Two scenarios are
presented that cover these two alternatives: a more optimis-
tic best-case scenario that foresees stagnating tourism
imports in the five source markets overall, and a less favor-
able scenario that expects a decline of 2%. The more
pessimistic view of tourism development sets the decrease
of aggregated tourism imports in the five source markets at
2.5% to 4.5%.
The forecasts made here assume that tourism demand
elasticities are symmetrical, that is, that the elasticities in up-
and downturns have a similar magnitude. But it is important
to bear in mind that income elasticities do not remain stable
across the business cycle: the relative fall in tourism demand
during a severe economic downturnreflecting, as it does,
the greater threat to a persons financial situation and job
securitywill be steeper than the relative increase in demand
during an economic upturn of a similar magnitude (Smeral
2009). For all those reasons, we have to consider that the
above forecast results are optimistic irrespective of the sce-
nario chosen, simply because income elasticity in severe
downturns might be underestimated so that a steeper decline
is perfectly conceivable. Estimating income elasticities for
the different stages of the business cycle could be an impor-
tant topic for the future tourism research agenda.
A consideration regarding the medium-term development
is that the negative economic and social consequences of the
crisis will accompany us for a long time. It will be difficult
to reduce the current high unemployment rates to figures that
are socially more acceptable. The economy will need time to
recover, and the financial systems may well remain fragile for
an even longer time. In the medium term, only moderate
growth rates are expected, also in the tourism industries. The
latter may be faced with massive structural change as a new
consumer with more limited financial and economic means
might emerge from the crisisa development that inciden-
tally offers a stimulus for future research.
Acknowledgment
I would like to thank my research assistant Sabine Fragner
(Austrian Institute of Economic Research) for her work in prepar-
ing the data, tables and figures as well as formatting the text.
Declaration of Conflicting Interests
The authors declared no conflicts of interests with respect to the
authorship and/or publication of this article.
Funding
The authors received no financial support for the research and/or
authorship of this article.
by Nita Valentin on October 15, 2010 jtr.sagepub.com Downloaded from
38 Journal of Travel Research 49(1)
Notes
1. The study was completed by the end of August 2009.
2. EU-15, always excluding Austria, since data are available only
from 1995, owing to changes in the national accounts system.
References
Enders, W. (2004). Applied Econometric Time Series. New York:
John Wiley.
European Travel Commission (ETC) (2009). European Tour-
ism 2009Trends & Prospects, Quarterly ReportQ2/2009.
Brussels, Belgium: ETC.
Hill, R. C., W. E. Griffiths, and G. C. Lim (2008). Principles of
Econometrics. 3rd edition. Hoboken, New Jersey: Wiley.
Hodrick, R., and E. Prescott (1997). Post-War Business Cycles:
An Empirical Investigation. Journal of Money, Credit and
Banking, 29 (1): 1-16.
International Monetary Fund (IMF) (2009). World Economic Out-
look, July, 2009. Washington, US: International Monetary Fund.
Organization for Economic Co-operation and Development
(OECD) (2009). OECD Economic Outlook, Vol. 2009/1, No. 85,
June 2009. Paris: OECD.
Robinson, J. (1947). Introduction to the Theory of Employment.
Oxford, UK: Macmillan.
Smeral, E. (1988). Tourism Demand, Economic Theory and Econo-
metrics: An Integrated Approach. Journal of Travel Research,
26 (4): 38-43.
Smeral, E. (2007). World Tourism ForecastingKeep it Quick
Simple and Dirty. Tourism Economics, 13 (2): 309-317.
Smeral, E. (2009). The Impact of the Financial and Economic Crisis
on European Tourism. Journal of Travel Research, 48 (1): 3-13.
Smeral, E., and A. Weber (2000). Forecasting International Tourism:
Trends to 2010. Annals of Tourism Research, 27 (4): 982-1006.
Smeral, E., and M. Wger (2005). Does Complexity matter?
Methods for Improving Forecasting Accuracy in Tourism: The
Case of Austria. Journal of Travel Research, 44 (1): 100-110.
Song, H., and G. Li (2008). Tourism Demand Modeling and
ForecastingA Review of Recent Research. Tourism Manage-
ment, 29 (2): 203-220.
Song, H., and Sh. Lin (2009). Impacts of the Financial Crisis on
Tourism in Asia. Journal of Travel Research, 49 (1): 16-30.
Song, H., and St. Witt (2000). Tourism Demand Modelling and
Forecasting. Amsterdam: Pergamon.
Song, H., and St. Witt (2003). Tourism Forecasting: The General-to-
Specific Approach. Journal of Travel Research, 42 (1): 65-74.
World Tourism Organization (UNWTO) (2009a). UNWTO World
Tourism Barometer, 7 (2).
UNWTO (2009b). Tourism and Economic StimulusInitial Assess-
ment. Madrid, Spain: UNWTO.
Bio
Egon Smeral is an economist at the Austrian Institute of Economic
Research in Vienna and university professor. His areas of research
are applied economic theory and politics (especially in the fields of
tourism economics, leisure and service sector economics), tourism
forecasting and modeling, impact analysis and Tourism Satellite
Accounts, designing and evaluating tourism policies and pro-
grammes, and marketing strategies.
by Nita Valentin on October 15, 2010 jtr.sagepub.com Downloaded from

You might also like