You are on page 1of 30

ADOPTION AND TERMINATION

OF EMPLOYEE INVOLVEMENT PROGRAMS



Running titleAdoption and Termination of EI Programs


Wei Chi*
Associate Professor
Tsinghua University


Richard B. Freeman
Professor
Harvard University and NBER


Morris M. Kleiner
Professor
University of Minnesota and NBER
Forthcoming in LABOUR 2011.


Abstract
Using an interview survey of manufacturing establishments that provide 10-years of
retrospective data on labor practices, we investigate factors associated with the adoption
and termination of employee involvement programs and the relation between these and
other human resource policies. In the period studied, more firms introduced than
terminated such programs but a sufficiently large number chose to eliminate such
programs to indicate that employee involvement does not fit in all business settings. Our
results show that business strategy and the use of other complementary human resource
policies affect the dynamics of EI use in U.S. manufacturing establishments.

*Corresponding author: e-51 School of Economics and Management, Tsinghua
University, Beijing, China, 100084. Tel.: (8610) 62795072. Fax: (8610) 62772021.
Email: chiw@sem.tsinghua.edu.cn.

1
Adoption and Termination of Employee Involvement Programs

1. Introduction

Employee involvement (EI) programsthe diverse set of personnel and human
resource (HR) practices that increase workers authority at workplaces and in business
decision making, such as total quality management, self-directed work teams, and
workplace committeesare widely heralded innovations in the US. Impressed by these
programs, the federal governments Commission on the Future of Worker-Management
Relations recommended in its 1994 report that the government encourage EI programs to
improve the quality of work life and productivity (Commission on the Future of Worker-
Management Relations, 19931994).
Most analyses of EI focus on the factors that lead firms to adopt EI policies and
on the impact of EI on outcomes. Studies show that adoption of EI is more likely in
competitive product markets among firms that respond to the market quickly and
flexibly; use new technologies that require skilled workers; have business strategies that
emphasize quality and innovation rather than low cost; and that adopt complementary HR
practices, such as high levels of training and incentive compensation plans (Arthur, 1992;
Osterman, 1994, 2000; Ichniowski and Shaw, 1995; Pil and MacDuffie, 1996; Dunlop
and Weil, 1996; Gittleman, Horrigan, and J oyce, 1998, and Lynch, 2007). Other studies
also show that EI promotes higher productivity, improves quality, raises customer
satisfaction and sales, and reduces quits and improves worker satisfaction (Arthur, 1994;
MacDuffie, 1995; Huselid, 1995; Banker et al., 1996; Berg et al., 1996; Dunlop and Weil
1996; ; Ichniowski, Shaw, and Prennushi, 1997; Freeman and Rogers, 1999; Freeman and
Kleiner, 2000; Batt, 2002; Batt, Colvin, and Keefe, 2002; Hunter, MacDuffie, and
Doucet, 2002; Bartel, 2004; Black and Lynch, 2004a, 2005). However, Godards (2004)

2
review indicates that EI is not a universal solution to the problems faced by a firm. Some
studies report that EI has modest impacts on outcomes that may not justify the cost of
these programs (Freeman and Kleiner, 2000; Cappelli and Neumark, 2001). Other
studies emphasize that the effects differ because business strategy and other business
characteristics and market factors are intermediaries in the relationship between EI and
financial performance (Huselid, 1995; Youndt et al., 1996)
Consistent with this analysis, there is a moderate rate of termination of EI
programs, particularly for quality of work life and quality circles (Goodman, 1980;
Rankin, 1986; Drago, 1988; Eaton, 1994).

Eaton (1994) estimates a 20 percent failure
rate for employee involvement practices in union establishments. Kleiner, Leonard, and
Pilarski (2002) present evidence of firms abandoning poorly performing EI programs.
Black and Lynch (2004a, 2004b) document that a substantial number of firms dropped or
lowered the percentage of employees participating in job rotation, profit sharing, or self-
managed teams between 1993 and 1996. Despite the failure of some EI programs, there
is little quantitative analysis of the reasons for the termination of EI, and no analysis of
decisions to introduce EI and to terminate EI in the same framework.
This study uses detailed on-site interviews of managers and workers in 51
manufacturing establishments on the history of their EI and related policies over ten years
to treat the decisions together in the same analytic framework. Retrospective reports on
10 years of EI programs allows us to create a pseudo-longitudinal data set to examine the
years in which firms adopted or terminated EI programs and their relation to other human
resource and management practices. Our sample size is small for a quantitative analysis,
but it is large for detailed on-site interview analysis that usually involves no more than a
handful of companies. We employ a Markov chain model to examine the movement of

3
firms to a long-term equilibrium of EI use in a way that can be applied to other studies of
the timing of adoption and termination of human resource programs.
2. Survey Design and Implementation
To describe and analyze the dynamics of EI use, we gathered data on the labor
relations practices of manufacturing establishments from 1986 to 1995, which covers the
period when EI programs increased rapidly. We identified establishments from the
Census of Manufacturers, which the U.S. Census Bureau has conducted every 5 years
since 1967.
1
We obtained the name and address of establishments surveyed by the
Census. We randomly selected establishments that had at least 50 employees at the time
they were drawn from the Census of Manufacturers in 1993 and were located in the Mid-
West to minimize travel costs. Some plants provided us with contact information of their
affiliate plants that were outside the Mid-Western region of the U.S. To increase sample
size, we contacted these affiliate plants as well, which provides us data on some
establishments within the same firm that we use in the analysis. In total, we contacted
111 plants, of whom fifty-one were willing to participate and allow researchers to visit
the plant, collect administrative data, and interview management and labor. The response
rate of 46 percent is higher than most mail or telephone surveys.
We collected the data on the history of the adoption and termination of employee
involvement and other labor and business practices through on-site visits in 1995-96 on
the notion that on-site interviews would provide more accurate data than phone or mail
surveys. The survey team interviewed general and human resource managers, workers,
and union representatives at the plants. All the data was collected in one visit except in
five cases where the manager/administrators did not have information and requested that
we return. We examined company records to obtain or verify some factual data such as

4
turnover, number of employees, etc. The surveyor(s) asked the company representatives
the questions and waited for the representatives to reach a consensus for each question
before filling out the survey response. The survey team also collected documents about
the business environment, technology, and production of the plants during the visits.
The survey team asked whether the plant had adopted particular employee
involvement programs and other human resource programs between 1986 and 1995, and
if so, in which year. We then asked whether the program was still in use, and if not, the
year the establishment terminated the program. The employee involvement practices
covered were job rotation, suggestion systems, quality of work life, quality circles, total
quality management, self-managed work teams, job redesign, joint labor-management
committees, and employee representation on the board of directors. These policies focus
on the workplace governance of the organization. In addition, the survey asked about the
adoption and timing of selection and staffing policieswhether the company had a
detailed screening process, personal interview, aptitude test, physical exam, reference
check, and probationary period; trainingwhether the company offered on-the-job
training, training in team building, on-site training, and tuition reimbursement;
performance appraisal policieswhether the company used assessment centers, formal
review sessions, and a standardized form to evaluate their employees periodically. The
survey also asked about financial incentive programswhether the company had an
individual incentive plan, employee stock ownership, cash or deferred profit sharing, gain
sharing, skill-based pay, employee stock purchase plan, and group bonuses that should
motivate workers on employee involvement committees.
The survey team also asked about business strategies and management policies. It
identified four categories of business strategy: growing market share, obtaining a market

5
niche, maximizing shareholder value of the firm, and short-term profit maximization. We
chose these categories to reflect whether the firm had a short-term or long-term
perspectives on the notion that plants with a long-term orientation, such as those seeking
a larger market share or increasing shareholder value, would be more likely to use the EI
practice than the plants with a short-term profit focus.
2
We asked the senior managers to
rate the establishments emphasis on these strategies on a 1 to 5 scale with 1 indicating a
little and 5 being a great deal. The senior manager and other managers also told us
whether the plant had undergone major restructuring since 1986 and, if yes, the year, and
number of times it had restructured; and whether the firm had changed the plant
manager/production leader since 1986.
The basic information on the plants included the year the plant was built, the
number of employees in the plant, whether the company had union representation, and
the average yearly turnover rate. The establishments were generally built in the 1950s
and 1960s, with an average age of 37 years. Three plants in the sample were, however,
built later than 1986 and thus could not provide data on practices and policies in some
years. This reduced the total number of plant-year observations from 510 to 496. The
plants had relatively large numbers of employees, with an average number of employees
of around 1100; only 5 plants had fewer than 100 employees. Twenty-seven of the 51
establishments had its production employees unionized. Eighteen plants are from seven
multi-establishment companies, while the others are single-establishment. The
establishments in the sample produce a wide range of products from foods and shoes, to
automobiles, electrical products, and steel, with the majority (65%) in durable goods.
The Appendix Table gives precise definition and descriptive statistics of the variables.
3. Qualitative information

6
During the interviews, we obtained considerable information about EI programs
that goes beyond the data from the structured survey. Managers cited reasons like
improving morale, changing technology, or just following the trend for adopting EI.
During the 1990s employee involvement was one of the major fads in U.S. industry.
One establishment in auto parts stated they had hired a consultant to review their
production processes, and he recommended an employee involvement program, which
they implemented. Others reported that new MBAs who had learned about EI in Human
Resources classes had recommended these programs to management. Some managers
also said their plant followed the leader. An aerospace company had heard about the
success of an EI program in auto manufacturing and hired the HR Vice President away
from the auto firm to implement EI in the aerospace company. Several managers said
they had heard about firms greatly increasing productivity through employee
involvement, and decided to adopt them.
Our interviewees also told us about some of the challenges they encountered after
introducing the EI, which in some cases led to the plant terminating EI policies. From the
interviews these reasons seemed idiosyncratic to the establishment. In one unionized auto
plant the union president wanted to negotiate the termination of EI because he thought it
resulted in increased productivity with fewer employees but offered no job protection
from management. A senior manager in aerospace observed that EI meetings take too
much time away from the production line. Another auto parts manufacturing manager
said it was too costly and didnt deliver on quality. Overall, the interview process
suggests that many of the firms adopted an EI program in a trial-and-error process,
following the prevailing practice and then terminated the program if they encountered
unexpected problems.

7
4. Trends in EI Use
The definition of exactly what programs define an EI system or create an
associated high-performance workplace is a fuzzy one. Some analysts include in their
definition alternative work practices and job design that promote workers participation
on the job, such as job rotation, teams, TQM, quality circles (Osterman, 1994, 2000).
Others treat a broader set of HRM practices including selection, training, appraisal, and
incentive compensation (Godard, 2004). We adopt the narrower definition of EI, and treat
incentive pay, selection, training, and appraisal programs as other human resource
management practices that may complement the EI policy. Specifically, we focus on the
nine programs listed in Table 1, which are directly related to workplace governance
issues
3
and use a terminology familiar to interviewed managers and workers. Since the
specific programs listed are often used together and since there are terminological
differences among respondents, there is invariably overlap among some of the programs
which could be viewed as part of the same innovation. For example, if a company
implements self-managed teams, it must involve some degree of job redesign; the
company might report both innovations or one or the other, depending on how it
introduced the changes.
Table 1 reports the mean proportion and standard deviation of the nine EI
programs among the establishments yearly from 1986 to 1995. The table shows an
upward trend in EI use in our sample. In 1995 job rotation and joint committees were the
most common programs. Seventy-five percent of the plants in the sample had job rotation
while 67 percent had joint labor management committees. Forty-seven percent of the
establishments in the sample had adopted TQM by 1995just slightly higher than the 42
percent reported by Black and Lynch (2004a) based on national survey data for 1994.

8
Worker participation on corporate boards is the least used policy. Note that the
prevalence of some EI programs fell over the period. The percentage of establishments
using quality circles dropped by 6 percentage points from 1986 to 1995. In addition, the
table shows that the upward trend in EI use varies over time: there are periods when
many establishments adopt programs, and periods when more are terminated.
Table 2 shows the correlations in 1986-1995 among our EI policies and between
them and three HR policies that are often associated with EI: selection, performance
appraisal, and training. The EI programs are generally positively correlated with each
other: the average of the correlation coefficients among them is 0.21, which suggests that
while the programs are used together, plants pick and choose among them (or possibly
use somewhat different terminologies). The EI programs are also moderately positively
correlated with the training, selection, and performance appraisal: an average correlation
coefficient of 0.13. Figure 1 aggregates the data on individual EI programs to display the
number programs in use in 1995 and gives the number of other HR programs (which goes
beyond the three examined in Table 2). This shows a substantial positive relation between
other HR programs and EI programs with a correlation of 0.29.
It is reasonable to expect that plants belonging to the same company adopt similar
practices due to corporate level decisions or the greater ease of learning what works
within a firm than learning what works in plants belonging to other firms. This suggests
that EI practices are likely to be more similar within companies than across plants. A
natural measure of similarity for vectors of 0/1 variables, such as our list of EI practices,
is the sum of the absolute difference between the presence or absence of each individual
program between two plants (which is related to the Hamming (1950) distance measure
of information theory). For example, if plant 1 of a multi-plant company had job rotation,

9
and plant 2 of the same company did not, the difference in job rotation would be one.
Add up the differences across 9 EI programs for each year gives a measure of the
difference in EI practices that varies between 0 and 9. The larger the number, the greater
the differences between the plants. In the case when a multi-plant company has more
than 2 plants, we calculate the number of differences in EI between all pairs of plants and
take the average across all the pairs as our measure of the distance. For instance, in a
company with 3 plants we would have average the 3 pairs; in a company with 4 plants,
we would average the 6 pairs. For comparison with single-plant companies we calculate
the average total number of differences across the 33 single-plant companies.
Table 3 gives the results of these calculations. Using a t test, two of the seven
multi-plant companies have significantly smaller within-company differences in the
presence/absence of EI than do single-firm plants but two of the multi-plant companies
have a significantly larger within-company differences. The remaining three show no
significant differences compared in our measure than the average of the 33 single-
company plants. Thus, these data do not support the view that the variation of EI among
plants within a company is smaller than the variation of EI across plants in different
companies. The implication is that introduction/termination of EI in our sample is largely
a plant level decision rather than the result of corporate policy.
Table 4 shows the number of plants with specified EI programs in the initial year
1986 and the number of plants adopting or terminating programs each year to 1995. The
numbers associated with individual programs in particular years show the number of
firms that introduce programs or the number that terminate them (those with negative
signs). For instance, the 3,-1 statistics for joint committees in 1991 tell us that 3
establishments adopted a joint committee and one establishment terminated its joint

10
committee program. The figures giving total numbers of adoptions and terminations
show that in most years some firms adopt programs while others terminated them.
Consistent with the national trend in EI over the period, the number of EI policies in
place increased from 134 in 1986 to 204 in 1995a 52 percent change. This change
resulted from 112 additions of programs and 42 terminations. We also measure the
dynamics of EI use in terms of the average number of years of EI use through 1995.
These statistics, given in Table 5, show that plants that terminated an EI program had the
program for at least 4 years. Those who kept the program had them for approximately 9
years (which is the average duration across the programs) through 1995. Of our nine EI
programs, self-managed work team and job redesign were adopted most recently, and
thus have the shortest average durations in use in 1995.
Figure 2 shows the percentage of plants using zero, one, or multiple EI policies in
1986 and 1995 and the percentage of plants by number of EI policies that would have
resulted in 1995 if firms chose their EI plans by random draws from an urn with a
probability consistent with the observed number of programs in 1995. Specifically, in
1995 the 51 firms had established 204 EI programs out of a possible 459 programs (=51
firms x 9 EI programs), giving the probability of a single program of 44.4%.
4
Between
1986 and 1995 the percentage of plants with zero policies declined significantly. Given
the relatively small sample size, the distributions are lumpy with concentrations of plants
at 0, 1, and 3 in 1986 and with what an exceptionally large number of plants at 8 in 1995.
The comparison of the actual distribution of firms by numbers of programs in 1995 with
the random draw distribution shows a greater concentration of establishments at the tails
of the distribution than expected under the random model. For instance, in the actual
distribution 12% of firms have more than 7 EI programs while the random model predicts

11
that just 5% would have more than 7 programs. Similarly, in the actual distribution 26%
of firms have 2 or fewer EI programs while the random model predicts 16%. This pattern
suggests that the EI policies are complementary in the sense that firms either have a lot or
a few relative to what they would be if the policies were independent.
5

Finally, while our analysis is limited to the 51 surveyed establishments, the
pattern of growth of EI over time fits with results from nationally representative samples
(Lynch 2007) to suggest that our findings on the dynamics of the EI introduction and
termination may generalize outside of the sampled establishments.
5. Measuring Intensity of EI
Many studies measure the intensity of EI use by forming a summated rating of the
intensity of specific EI programs using the particular scaling in the survey (Ichniowski
and Shaw, 1995; Pil and MacDuffie, 1996). This treats each program the same. As an
alternative procedure, we used the latent variable Rasch model from educational testing
to form an index of employee involvement. In educational tests the Rasch model gives a
bigger score to a correct answer on a problem where few students give the correct answer
than to a correct answer on a problem that many students get right. Analogously, our
Rasch index gives greater weight to policies that are relatively rare in forming an index of
the establishments intensity of EI. The virtue of the Rasch model is that it weighs more
heavily programs that are rare and thus potentially more indicative of the intensity of the
firm's commitment to EI. Formally, we posit the probability that a plant with a certain
program is a function of plant and EI policy characteristics:
(1)
( 1) ( , )
ij i j
P X u = = u
, i, establishment, j, EI practice,
where
u
denotes the index of employee involvement in an establishment, and

indicates
the rarity of the particular EI program. The probability that an establishment had a

12
specific policy depends on an establishments degree of EI use (
u
) and the frequency
level of an EI program (

). The function
u
is specified to have a logistic form, giving
equation (2):
(2)
exp( )
( 1)
1 exp( )
i j
ij
i j
P X
u
u

= =
+
, i, establishment, j, EI practice.
We use maximum likelihood to estimate the establishment parameter (
u
) and the
EI policy parameter (

).
6
The estimate of
u
is our measure of EI use in plants. Its value
ranges from 1 to 1. While conceptually preferable to a simple count of the number of EI
programs that an establishment has, the Rasch measure is highly correlated with a
summated rating count variable (r =0.98).
To examine the dynamics of adopting or terminating EI programs in a given year,
we use a 0/1 dependent variable that measures whether or not the firm added at least one
EI program between year t and year t+1; and whether or not the firm dropped at least one
EI program between year t and year t+1. To assess how explanatory factors affected these
decisions, we estimated the following models:
(3) 1 it it i t it
A X | o c

= + + +
, 1 it it i t it
T X | o c

= + + +
,
where A
it
is the measure of EI adoption in year t, and T
it
measures EI termination in year
t; X
it-1
are a set of time-varying explanatory variables lagged one year; and where i
o
are
individual plant dummy variables, which control for plant fixed effects, and t

are year
dummy variables. The two equations are estimated using the Least Square Dummy
Variable (LSDV) method, and specified as the linear probability model with White robust
standard errors. The LSDV estimators show how much a change in an explanatory
variable affects the probability.
7

13
Columns 1-4 of Table 6 reports the estimated coefficients and standard errors on
variables in regressions of the level of EI use on the explanatory variables for pooled
observations for all establishments and years. The odd-numbered regressions include
variables measuring plant-specific time-invariant characteristics, such as union status or
durable manufacturing. Since there may be other plant-specific variables impacting the
adoption and termination decisions, the even-numbered regressions drop these time-
invariant variables but include year and plant dummy variables to control for all observed
and unobserved plant fixed effects. The odd-numbered regressions are embedded in the
more general even-numbered models.
The first two columns use our Rasch measure of EI as the dependent variable. To
see whether the results are sensitive to the EI measure used, columns 3-4 estimate the
model using the summated rating index of EI that give the same weight to different EI
programs. This links our results to those in earlier studies that give each EI policy the
same weight. The estimates in columns 1 and 3 show that companies with group bonus
and gain-sharing and profit-sharing have higher EI use than companies without these
programs. This is consistent with the notion that EI programs are complementary with
these programs. In addition, individual incentive pay is also positively related to the
extent of EI. Unionized firms and larger plants are less likely to have EI programs. The
coefficients on the measures of management strategy show that firms that emphasized the
growth of market share made greater use of EI than managements that emphasized other
strategies. The estimates in columns 2 and 4, which include plant dummy variables and
less important, year dummies, give weaker results on some of the variables such as profit
sharing but find that firms that have programs to train and appraise workers were more
likely to use EI.

14
Columns 5 through 8 turn to the dynamics of the process. They give estimates of
the determinants of adoption and termination of EI use. We expect variables to have
opposite effects on adoption and termination. Factors that cause firms to adopt EI may
also explain why the firms keep the policies and thus reduce the rate of termination. This
is generally the case in these calculations. The estimated influence of the existing level of
EI in the top line is significantly negative in the adoption equation and significantly
positive in the termination equation. Comparing coefficients for other variables that are
significant in at least one of the equations, the coefficients have opposite signs in 5 of 7
cases. For instance, the column 6 estimates show that establishments that emphasize
market growth are more likely to adopt EI while the column 8 estimates shows that
emphasizing market growth reduces the likelihood of terminating a program. Firms
seeking niches in the market are less likely to introduce EI programs in the adoption
equation but more likely to terminate programs in the termination model.
6. Markov Analysis
The evidence in our sample that firms added and terminated EI programs in the
decade under study indicates that they were involved in a dynamic adjustment process
that had not settled down to some equilibrium mix of programs. With nine EI programs
and just ten years of data, a time series regression model will not readily illuminate the
dynamics of the adjustment process nor predict the possible equilibrium state to which
the firms might be heading. As an alternative, we apply a Markov chain model to our
data to exploit the longitudinal dynamics. The Markov model assumes that a system is
represented by a set of states, which we specify as the number of EI programs that a firm
has in a given year.
8
The model posits that firms change the number of programs
according to fixed transition probabilities dependent solely on the current state. For

15
instance, if a firm had no EI programs, the model might predict a 20% chance of moving
to one program, a 30% chance of moving to two programs, a 5% chance of moving to
three programs, and a 45% chance of maintaining the zero program status quo. A firm in
the state of having three EI programs would have different transition probabilities,
allowing for termination of some of those programs or adoption of other programs.
The process is represented by a transition matrix that gives the probability that the
firm changes the number of programs by adopting new ones or terminating existing ones
in the next period, or that it maintains its current EI system. Traditional matrix algebra
analysis of Markov models allows us to predict whether the EI use of the establishments
converges to a steady-state distribution, and if so, the distribution of EI use among the
establishments at the equilibrium.
Table 7 gives the Markov matrix that we use to analyze the adoption and
termination of EI programs. The elements of the matrix are obtained by averaging all
transitions in the data, regardless of year. The averaging is simple. If five firms had three
programs in year t and none changed their number of programs and five (possibly
different) firms had three programs in year n and three of the firms increased their
programs to four while two firms reduced them to two, our estimated transition matrix
would have a probability of staying with three programs of 0.5, of increasing to four
programs of 0.3, of decreasing to two programs of 0.2, and zero probability of other
transitions. The table groups the eight and nine programs together because we have few
observations for that part of the distribution.
9
The summary statistics in the table give the equilibrium distribution from the
Markov analysis and contrast that distribution with the initial distribution in 1986 and the
distribution in 1995. It shows that the initial distribution moved toward the equilibrium

16
over the period. As a measure of the distance between distributions, we take the sum of
the absolute value of the difference between the proportions in different states.
10
In 1986,
the actual distribution differed from the equilibrium distribution by 80 percentage points.
By 1995, the sum of the absolute value in the differences between the distribution and the
equilibrium distribution was just 16 percentage points. The model predicts that the
distribution would reach the equilibrium by 2006. Thus, the adoption and termination
process takes about 20 years to equilibrate, with much of the movement toward
equilibrium occurring within 10 years. Examining longitudinal human resource policy
data for the U.S. economy Lisa Lynch finds that manufacturing firms coalesce around a
core set of policies in the mid-to late 1990s (Lynch, 2007).
7. Conclusion
Our analysis of 10-year retrospective data from on-site visits to establishments
has found that even in a period of increasing EI use, many establishments terminate EI
programs. On-site interviews with the plant managers, workers and union representatives
suggested that the process of adopting and terminating EI is a trial-and-error process
which has a lot of uncertainties. But beneath this pattern our data reveal empirical
regularities. In our sample establishments were more likely to adopt EI programs and
less likely to terminate them when they had other advanced human resource practices and
when their business strategy emphasized growth of market shares. The factors that lead
firms to terminate programs paralleled those that lead firms to introduce them, suggesting
that both decisions reflected the aspects of the plants situation. Moreover, the
distribution of numbers of EI practices appears to converge over time. Our Markov chain
analysis suggests that the process reaches a steady state distribution in about 20 years
with most changes occurring during the first 10 years.

17
Notes

1
The Census of Manufactures asks all establishments in manufacturing (over 200,000
plants) about the business they conduct, geographic location, type of ownership, total
revenue, payroll, and employees. The data are confidential and only available with an
application to the Census.
2
The commonly used strategy categories in the literature are low cost, differentiation
(such as innovation or quality and service) and focus strategies (Porter, 1980; Delery and
Doty, 1996; Cabrera et al., 2003). The niche market strategy we asked is similar to the
focus strategy.
3
They are consistent with theory and empirical approaches developed by Ichniowski
and Shaw (1995), and Ichniowski , Shaw, and Prennushi, 1997).
4
An alternative calculation would use a multinomial which takes account of the
difference in the frequency of each particular program.
5
We find a similar pattern if we examine the introduction or termination of plans.
Plants introduce 5 or 6 policies at once in 7.5% of the cases when they adopt EI
programs, whereas if they adopted plants independently, they should almost never
introduce 5-6 plans at once. Similarly, in 8% of terminations plants terminate 2 or more
programs in 24% of the times they terminate 2 or more plants. Given the data in Table 4
both patterns are highly unlikely.
6
We use the Quest computer software package to estimate the Rasch measure of EI
system.
7
Estimates using probit and logit specifications showed similar results and are
available from the authors.
8
The alternative would be to take each possible combination of EI practices as a
possible state for the firm, but with nine different programs, there would be 512 (=2
9
)
possible combinations, which is non-tractable with our data. Thus, rather than modeling
the links between specific programs, we make the distribution of the number of programs
the target of analysis.
9
In fact, because we have so few observations on firms with eight policies, it turns out
be an absorbing state, which is highly unlikely with additional observations.
10
This is a widely used measure of the difference between two distributions. Half of the
sum of the absolute value of the differences gives the amount of change necessary for the
two distributions to be the same.
















18

References

Arthur J . (1992) The Link between Business Strategy and Industrial Relations Systems
in American Steel Minimills, Industrial and Labor Relations Review, 45(3): 488
506.
Arthur J . (1994) Effects of Human Resource Systems on Manufacturing Performance
and Turnover, Academy of Management Journal, 37(3): 670687.
Banker R., Field J .M., Schroeder R.G., and Sinha K.K. (1996) Impact of Work Teams
on Manufacturing Performance: A Longitudinal Field Study, Academy of
Management Journal, 39(4): 867890.
Bartel A.P. (2004) Human Resource Management and Organizational Performance:
Evidence from Retail Banking, Industrial and Labor Relations Review, 57(2):
181203.
Batt R. (2002) Managing Customer Services: Human Resource Practices, Quit Rates,
and Sales Growth, Academy of Management Journal, 45(3): 587597.
Batt R., Colvin A.J .S., and Keefe J . (2002) Employee Voice, Human Resource Practices,
and Quit Rates: Evidence from the Telecommunications Industry, Industrial and
Labor Relations Review, 55(4): 573594.
Berg P., Appelbaum E., Bailey T., and Kalleberg A. (1996) The Performance Effects of
Modular Production in the Apparel Industry, Industrial Relations, 35(3): 356
373.
Black S.E. and Lynch L.M. (2004a) What's Driving the New Economy? The Benefits of
Workplace Innovation, Economic Journal, 114: F97116.
Black S.E. and Lynch L.M. (2004b) How Workers Fare When Employers Innovate,
Industrial Relations, 43(1): 4466.
Black S.E. and Lynch L.M. (2005) Measuring Organizational Capital in the New
Economy in Corrado C., Haltiwanger J ., and Sichel D. (eds.) Measuring Capital
in the New Economy, Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.
Cabrera E.F., Ortega J ., and Cabrera A. (2003) An Exploration of Factors that Influence
Employee Participation in Europe, Journal of World Business, 38: 4354.
Cappelli P. and Neumark D. (2001) Do High-Performance Work Practices Improve
Establishment-Level Outcomes? Industrial and Labor Relations Review, 54(4):
737775.
Commission on the Future of Worker-Management Relations (Dunlop Commission).
19931994. http://digitalcommons.ilr.cornell.edu/key_workplace/2/.
Delery J .E. and Doty H.D. (1996) Modes of Theorizing in Strategic Human Resource
Management: Tests of Universalistic, Contingency, and Configurational
Performance Predictions, Academy of Management Journal, 39(4): 802835.
Drago R. (1988) Quality Circle Survival: An Exploratory Analysis, Industrial
Relations, 27(3): 336351.
Dunlop J .T. and Weil D. (1996) Diffusion and Performance of Modular Production in
the U.S. Apparel Industry, Industrial Relations, 35(3): 334355.
Eaton A.E. (1994) The Survival of Employee Participation Programs in Unionized
Settings, Industrial and Labor Relations Review, 47(3): 371389.
Freeman R.B. and Kleiner M.M. (2000) Who Benefits Most from Employee
Involvement: Firms or Workers? American Economic Review, 90(2): 219223.

19
Freeman R.B. and Rogers J . (1999) What Workers Want, Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University
Press.
Gittleman M., Horrigan M., and J oyce M. (1998) Flexible Workplace Practices:
Evidence from a Nationally Representative Survey, Industrial and Labor
Relations Review, 52(1): 99115.
Godard J . (2004) A Critical Assessment of the High-Performance Paradigm, British
Journal of Industrial Relations, 42(2): 349378.
Goodman P.S. (1980) Realities of Improving the Quality of Work Life: Quality of Work
Life Projects in 1980, Proceedings of the Spring IRRA Meetings, Labor Law
Journal, August: 487494.
Hamming R.W. (1950) Error detecting and error correcting codes, Bell System
Technical Journal, 29 (2): 147160.
Hunter L.W., MacDuffie J .P., and Doucet L. (2002) What Makes Teams Take?
Employee Reactions to Work Reforms, Industrial and Labor Relations Review,
55(3): 448472.
Huselid M. A. (1995) The Impact of Human Resource Management Practices on
Turnover, Productivity, and Corporate Financial Performance, Academy of
Management Journal, 38(3): 635672.
Ichniowski C. and Shaw K. (1995) Old Dogs and New Tricks: Determinants of the
Adoption of Productivity-Enhancing Work Practices, Brookings Papers on
Economic Activity, Social Issue Microeconomics: 165.
Ichniowski C, Shaw K. and Prennushi G. (1997) The Effects of Human Resource
Management Practices on Productivity: A Study of Steel Finishing Lines,
American Economic Review, 87(3): 291313.
Kleiner M.M., Leonard J .S., and Pilarski A.M. (2002) How Industrial Relations Affects
Plant Performance: The Case of Commercial Aircraft Manufacturing, Industrial
and Labor Relations Review, 55(2): 195218.
Lynch L. (2007) The Adoption and Diffusion of Organizational Innovation: Evidence
for the U.S. Economy, NBER Working Paper No. 13156.
MacDuffie J .P. (1995) Human Resource Bundles and Manufacturing Performance:
Organizational Logic and Flexible Production Systems in the World Auto
Industry, Industrial and Labor Relations Review, 48(2): 197221.
Osterman P. (1994) How Common Is Workplace Transformation and Who Adopts It?
Industrial and Labor Relations Review, 47(2): 173188.
Osterman P. (2000) Work Reorganization in an Era of Restructuring: Trends in
Diffusion and Effects on Employee Welfare, Industrial and Labor Relations
Review, 53(2): 179196.
Pil F.K. and MacDuffie J .P. (1996) The Adoption of High-Involvement Work Practices,
Industrial Relations, 35(3): 423455.
Porter M.E. (1980) Competitive Strategy, New York: Free Press.
Rankin T. (1986) Integrating QWL and Collective Bargaining, QWL Force, 5(1): 36.
Youndt M.A., Snell S.A., Dean J .W. J r., and Lepak D.P. (1996) Human Resource
Management, Manufacturing Strategy, and Firm Performance, Academy of
Management Journal, 39(4): 836866.




20
Table 1. Means and standard deviations of the proportion of establishments with EI programs by year, 1986-1995

Year (number of
reporting plants)
1986
(n=48)
1987
(n=48)
1988
(n=48)
1989
(n=48)
1990
(n=49)
1991
(n=51)
1992
(n=51)
1993
(n=51)
1994
(n=51)
1995
(n=51)
All years
(n=496)
J ob Rotation


0.47
(0.50)
0.47
(0.50)
0.47
(0.50)
0.48
(0.50)
0.53
(0.50)
0.63
(0.49)
0.69
(0.47)
0.73
(0.45)
0.75
(0.44)
0.75
(0.44)
0.60
(0.49)
Suggestion System


0.43
(0.50)
0.45
(0.50)
0.49
(0.51)
0.50
(0.51)
0.49
(0.50)
0.49
(0.50)
0.51
(0.50)
0.55
(0.50)
0.53
(0.50)
0.59
(0.50)
0.50
(0.50)
Quality of Work
Life

0.31
(0.47)
0.31
(0.47)
0.33
(0.47)
0.28
(0.45)
0.31
(0.47)
0.35
(0.48)
0.35
(0.48)
0.37
(0.49)
0.41
(0.50)
0.41
(0.50)
0.34
(0.48)
Quality Circles


0.35
(0.48)
0.37
(0.49)
0.37
(0.49)
0.30
(0.46)
0.27
(0.45)
0.29
(0.46)
0.22
(0.42)
0.24
(0.43)
0.27
(0.45)
0.29
(0.46)
0.30
(0.46)
TQM


0.35
(0.48)
0.37
(0.49)
0.37
(0.49)
0.32
(0.47)
0.33
(0.48)
0.45
(0.50)
0.43
(0.50)
0.41
(0.50)
0.43
(0.50)
0.47
(0.50)
0.39
(0.49)
Self-Managed
Work Team

0.10
(0.31)
0.10
(0.31)
0.10
(0.31)
0.10
(0.30)
0.16
(0.37)
0.22
(0.42)
0.29
(0.46)
0.35
(0.48)
0.31
(0.47)
0.33
(0.48)
0.21
(0.41)
J ob Redesign


0.22
(0.42)
0.22
(0.42)
0.22
(0.42)
0.22
(0.42)
0.25
(0.44)
0.29
(0.46)
0.31
(0.47)
0.35
(0.48)
0.41
(0.50)
0.43
(0.50)
0.30
(0.46)
J oint Labor -
Management
Committee
0.45
(0.50)
0.45
(0.50)
0.43
(0.50)
0.40
(0.49)
0.45
(0.50)
0.51
(0.50)
0.53
(0.50)
0.57
(0.50)
0.63
(0.49)
0.67
(0.48)
0.51
(0.50)
Employee
Representation
on Board of
Directors
0.06
(0.24)
0.06
(0.24)
0.06
(0.24)
0.06
(0.24)
0.08
(0.27)
0.08
(0.27)
0.06
(0.24)
0.06
(0.24)
0.06
(0.24)
0.06
(0.24)
0.06
(0.24)
Source: Interviews at 51 manufacturing establishments.
Notes: standard deviations are in parentheses.


21
Table 2. Correlation coefficients for EI policies and those policies with selected HR practices, 1986-1995

Job
Rotation
Suggestion
System
Quality
of work
Life
Quality
Circles
TQM Self-
Managed
Work
Team
Job
Redesign

Joint Labor-
Management
Committee
Employee
Representation
on Board of
Directors
Selection Performance
Appraisal
Suggestion
System
0.24*
Quality of work
Life
0.34* 0.25*
Quality Circles 0.02 0.27* 0.30*
TQM 0.14* -0.01 0.41* 0.26*
Self-Managed
Work Team
0.18* 0.10* 0.46* 0.17* 0.39*
J ob Redesign 0.22* 0.08 0.38* 0.10* 0.42* 0.51*
J oint Labor-
Management
Committee
0.20* 0.20* 0.33* 0.26* 0.37* 0.22* 0.48*
Employee
Representation
on Board of
Directors
-0.05 0.19* 0.26* 0.29* 0.09* 0.21* 0.12* 0.19*
Selection -0.02 0.06 0.18* 0.11* 0.11* 0.12* 0.14* 0.22* 0.05
Performance
Appraisal
0.10* -0.09* 0.20* 0.08 0.21* 0.08 0.29* 0.31* -0.13* 0.11*
Training 0.25* 0.05 0.20* -0.01 0.13* 0.08 0.09* 0.26* 0.21* 0.36* 0.29*
Source: Interviews at 51 manufacturing establishments.
Notes: * indicates that the pair-wise correlation coefficient between the two variables is significant at the 5% level.


22

Table 3. Differences in EI use between multi-plant and single-plant companies using the metric of the number of practices that differs
between establishments by year

1986 1987 1988 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995
Multi-plant companies
1 (2 plants) 2.00 2.00 2.00 2.00 4.00 3.00 2.00
2 (4 plants) 4.33 3.83 3.83 4.33 4.17 4.00 4.33 4.33 4.67 4.67
3 (2 plants) 2.00 1.00 1.00 1.00 2.00 2.00 1.00 2.00 2.00 2.00
4 (3 plants) 3.33 3.33 3.33 3.33 4.00 4.00 4.00 4.00 4.00 4.00
5 (2 plants) 3.00 4.00 4.00 5.00 3.00 3.00
6 (3 plants) 3.33 3.33 3.33 3.33 3.33 4.00 4.00 4.00 4.00 4.00
7 (2 plants) 6.00 6.00 6.00 6.00 6.00 6.00 5.00 5.00 6.00 6.00
Single-plant companies
(33 plants)
3.47 3.48 3.49 3.28 3.58 3.84 3.74 3.84 3.83 3.84
Source: Interviews at 51 manufacturing establishments.
Notes: the numbers indicate the total number of differences (in absolute values) in nine EIs between the plants belonging to the same company as
well as among the single-plant companies. If the number of pairs for comparison is greater than 2, we calculate the average total number of
differences. We test the differences between multi-plant and single-plant companies, such as multi-plant company 1, 2,,7 versus single plant
companies. Two of the seven multi-plant companies have a significantly smaller within-company variance in EI than the variance across the
single-plant companies; two have a significantly larger variance; the rest three are no different from single-plant companies.


23
Table 4. Number of establishments with specified EI programs and numbers adopting (+) or terminating (-) programs by year

Adoption of Policy
1986
(left-
censored) 1987 1988 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995
Total
Number at
end
J ob Rotation 23 1 3 5,-1 4 2,-1 2 38
Suggestion System 21 1 2,-1 2 -2 3 2,-2 1 3 30
Quality of Work Life 15 1,-2 2 2,-1 1,-1 2 2 21
Quality Circles 17 2,-1 -3 -2 1,-2 3,-4 1 2 1 15
TQM 17 1 -2 -2 3 6,-2 1,-1 -1 2 2 24
Self-Managed Work Team 5 -1 1 3 3, -1 5 3, -3 1 1 17
J ob Redesign 11 -1 1 2 2, -1 2 2 3 1 22
J oint Labor-Management
Committee 22 -1 -1 3 3, -1 2 2 3 2

34
Employee Representation on
Board of Directors 3 1 -1

3
Total Number of Adoptions
and Terminations (-)
4,-2 3, -11 5,-4 18, -2 24, -14 18, -2 14, -7 16 10 112, -42
Number of EI programs at the
51 establishments 134

136

128

129

145

155

171

178

194

204


Source: Interviews at 51 manufacturing establishments.
Notes: The numbers associated with individual programs with minus signs give the number of firms in the specified period that terminated
programs, while the positive numbers give the number that introduced the program.


24
Table 5. The duration of EI use before termination or by 1995


The total number of
adoptions
( - number of termination)

The mean
duration before
termination
(years)
The mean duration by
1995 if not terminated
(years)
J ob Rotation 40(-2) 4 9.3
Suggestion System 35(-5) 5 9.4
Quality of Work Life 25(-4) 8.5 9.7
Quality Circles 27(-12) 4.2 11.1
TQM 32(-8) 6.5 7.3
Self-Managed Work Team 22(-5) 8.3 4.6
J ob Redesign 24(-2) 10 5.7
J oint Labor-Management
Committee
37(-3)

7.7

9.8
Employee Representation on
Board of Directors
4(-1)

6

14
Source: Interviews at 51 manufacturing establishments.
Notes: The total number of adoptions is the sum of adoptions over time for each EI. Minus signs give the total number of terminations over time.


25
Table 6. Regression estimates for the analysis of the level of EI and adoption and termination of programs
Rasch
Level of EI
(1)
Rasch
Level of EI
(2)
Summated rating
index of EI
(3)
Summated rating
index of EI
(4)
Adoption
of EI
(5)
Adoption
of EI
(6)
Termination
of EI
(7)
Termination
of EI
(8)
EI value
t-1


-0.057*
(0.017)
-0.089***
(0.029)
0.017*
(0.010)
0.076***
(0.024)
Union

-0.745***
(0.147)
-1.148***
(0.227)
0.004
(0.047)
-0.013
(0.028)
Log Plant Size

-0.242*
(0.133)
-0.421*
(0.186)
-0.041
(0.027)
0.0003
(0.026)
Durable Manufacturing

-0.048
(0.176)
-0.295
(0.256)
0.088
(0.054)
0.024
(0.029)
Age of plant

-0.017
(0.009)
-0.008
(0.039)
-0.023
(0.014)
-0.013
(0.054)
-0.005*
(0.003)
0.022
(0.018)
-0.0002
(0.002)
0.006
(0.012)
Age Squared/100

0.009
(0.009)
0.001
(0.030)
0.011
(0.013)
-0.010
(0.043)
0.005*
(0.003)
-0.017
(0.015)
0.001
(0.002)
-0.004
(0.010)
Restructuring
t-1

-0.053
(0.215)
0.156
(0.170)
-0.745**
(0.354)
-1.096**
(0.442)
0.029
(0.072)
0.091
(0.100)
0.002
(0.038)
-0.099
(0.070)
Selection
t-1

0.021
(0.044)
-0.097*
(0.058)
0.080
(0.068)
0.004
(0.109)
0.022
(0.017)
0.023
(0.038)
0.005
(0.010)
0.023
(0.015)
Appraisal
t-1

0.155**
(0.080)
0.252**
(0.129)
0.287**
(0.113)
0.633***
(0.162)
0.054**
(0.024)
0.096
(0.068)
-0.017
(0.016)
-0.037
(0.030)
Training
t-1

-0.062
(0.115)
0.261***
(0.086)
0.152
(0.159)
0.850***
(0.163)
-0.002
(0.021)
-0.003
(0.047)
0.011
(0.018)
-0.009
(0.031)
Individual incentive pay
t-1

0.301**
(0.143)
0.568**
(0.220)
0.816***
(0.215)
0.430
(0.334)
0.013
(0.041)
0.033
(0.099)
-0.034
(0.027)
-0.194***
(0.072)
Gain sharing or group bonus
t-1

0.570***
(0.170)
0.511**
(0.200)
1.191***
(0.236)
0.459
(0.300)
-0.030
(0.046)
0.084
(0.102)
-0.022
(0.036)
0.071
(0.062)
Profit Sharing
t-1

0.142**
(0.058)
-0.112
(0.104)
0.177**
(0.090)
-0.128
(0.150)
-0.040
(0.024)
-0.010
(0.044)
0.011
(0.011)
0.031
(0.035)
Niche market
t-1

0.100
(0.090)
-0.119
(0.095)
0.163
(0.148)
-0.037
(0.149)
-0.029
(0.030)
-0.070*
(0.042)
0.019
(0.013)
0.004
(0.027)
Growth of market share
t-1

0.148**
(0.087)
0.143
(0.132)
0.195
(0.132)
0.102
(0.205)
0.025
(0.035)
0.134**
(0.065)
-0.044**
(0.021)
-0.056*
(0.033)
Max. shareholder value
t-1

-0.035
(0.066)
0.151
(0.107)
0.037
(0.095)
0.121
(0.163)
0.013
(0.021)
-0.023
(0.044)
0.014
(0.011)
-0.040
(0.033)
Short-term profit
maximization
t-1
0.028
(0.080)
-0.053
(0.130)
0.146
(0.121)
0.023
(0.175)
-0.043
(0.027)
-0.007
(0.054)
-0.004
(0.015)
0.001
(0.043)
Constant

0.565
(0.930)
-0.787
(1.027)
3.799***
(1.295)
-0.537
(1.779)
0.397*
(0.223)
-0.120
(0.520)
0.008
(0.096)
0.487
(0.266)
Adj. R
2
0.28 0.78 0.31 0.75 0.08 0.27 0.07 0.25
Year and Plant Fixed Effect
No Yes No Yes No Yes No Yes
Number of observations 445 445 445 445 445 445 445 445
Source: Interviews at 51 manufacturing establishments.
Notes: The number of observations is 445 because one year lag values are used (-51 observations), and also several firms were less than 10 years old by the survey year causing the unbalanced panel (the
total number of plant-year observations is 496). The level of EI is the Rasch value of EI for each year. Missing values of Plant Age, Size, Niche Market, Growth of Market Share, and Short-termProfit
Maximization are replaced by their mean value; dummy indicators of missing values for these variables are included in the regression to control for the effect of imputation. The estimates of these
dummy indicators are not reported for brevity. Standard errors are reported in parentheses. *, **, and *** indicate P <0.1, 0.05, and 0.01.


26

Table 7. Markov-Chain average transition matrix for the numbers of programs in year t to year t+1

YEAR t YEAR t+1
0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8&9
0 0.821 0.09 0.014 0 0.026 0.038 0.014 0 0
1 0.048 0.698 0.19 0.032 0.016 0 0 0.016 0
2 0 0.034 0.793 0.103 0.034 0.034 0 0 0
3 0 0 0.036 0.881 0.071 0.012 0 0 0
4 0 0 0 0.058 0.788 0.096 0.038 0.019 0
5 0 0 0 0.081 0.054 0.784 0.081 0 0
6 0 0 0 0 0 0.061 0.878 0.042 0.02
7 0 0.059 0 0 0 0.059 0 0.706 0.176
8&9 0 0.05 0 0 0 0 0 0 0.95

SUMMARY STATISTICS FROM MARKOV ANALYSIS
0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8&9
The initial vector for 1986 is 0.24 0.22 0.10 0.14 0.10 0.02 0.12 0.04 0.04
The 1995 vector is 0.04 0.04 0.18 0.22 0.14 0.16 0.12 0.02 0.10
The equilibrium vector is 0.02 0.04 0.10 0.26 0.15 0.14 0.14 0.03 0.12
It takes 20 iterations to reach equilibrium.

Source: Interviews at 51 manufacturing establishments.


27
Figure 1. Scatter diagram for numbers of EI policies adopted in establishments and numbers of other HR policies in establishments in 1995



Source: Interviews at 51 manufacturing establishments.

The
number
of EI in
use
Total number of other HR practices


28
Figure 2. The distribution of establishments by number of EI policies in 1986 and 1995

0
0. 05
0. 1
0. 15
0. 2
0. 25
0. 3
0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9
1986
1995
1995 pr edi ct

Source: Interviews at 51 manufacturing establishments.
Notes: No plants had all 9 EI policies in 1995. The number of plants in 1986 and 1995 is 48 and 51, respectively. 1995 predict denotes the
predicted probability of having 0-9 EI policies from the random draw distribution for 1995.




29
Appendix Table. Descriptive statistics of explanatory variables

Variable name Variable Definition Mean Standard Deviation
Union

=1 if a plant has a union representation; =0 otherwise; 0.54

Age of plant

Age of plant in years 37.32

29.71

Log Plant Size

Log of the Number of Production Workers in a plant 7.011

0.645

Durable Manufacturing

=1 if a plant manufactures durable products; =0 otherwise; 0.645



Restructuring

=1 if a plant has recently been restructured; =0 otherwise; 0.17



Selection

=the total number of selection programs used in a plant including a detailed
screening process, personal interview, aptitude test, physical exam,
reference check, and probationary period; takes a value from 0-6;
4.88

1.23

Appraisal

=the total number of performance appraisal programs used in a plant including
assessment centers, formal review sessions, and a standardized evaluation form;
takes a value from 0-3;
1.52

0.92

Training

=the total number of training programs used in a plant including on-the-job
training, team building training, on-site training, and tuition reimbursement;
takes a value from 0-4;
3.36

0.65

Individual incentive pay

=1 if a plant has adopted the individual incentive pay plan; =0 otherwise; 0.55

Gain sharing or group bonus

=1 if a plant has adopted a gain sharing plan or group bonus program; =0
otherwise;
0.40

Profit sharing

=1 if a plant has adopted an ESOP, cash or deferred profit sharing, or employee
stock purchase plan; =0 otherwise.
0.74

Niche market

The degree of a plants focusing on niche market in the scale of 1-5; 3.20

1.38

Growth of market
Share
The degree of a plants focusing on growth of market shares in the scale of 1-5; 3.63

1.33

Maximizing shareholder value

The degree of a plants focusing on maximizing shareholder value in the scale
of 1-5;
3.67

1.57

Short-term profit maximization

The degree of a plants focusing on short-term profit maximization in the scale
of 1-5;
3.51

1.14

You might also like