You are on page 1of 20

High Educ (2013) 65:523

DOI 10.1007/s10734-012-9578-4

Regulatory autonomy and performance: the reform


of higher education re-visited
Jurgen Enders Harry de Boer Elke Weyer

Published online: 16 October 2012


 Springer Science+Business Media Dordrecht 2012

Abstract The main aim of this article is to contribute to the understanding of organizational autonomy and control in higher education reform and related expectations as
regards the performance of universities. Our analyses draws on principal-agent models as a
normative theory of policy reform, and institutionalist approaches in public policy and
institutional design as an analytical theory of policy reform. We discuss how the dominant
narrative of political reform moves away from traditional beliefs in university autonomy
that are built on institutional trust and linked to professional autonomy. In the emerging
narrative of political change, autonomy becomes re-defined as the new organizational
autonomy of universities as both strategic actors and as an addressee of governmental
control. The concept of regulatory autonomy captures the use of organizational autonomy
of universities as a tool of a new regime of governmental control. Exemplified by the
Dutch case, we analyze autonomy policies for strengthening managerial discretion and
internal control of universities that are combined with regulatory policies for external
control that steer organizational choices. Regulatory autonomy thus aims at aligning
universities more closely with governmental goals and improve respective performance.
Our literature review shows, however, that there is scarce, inconclusive and methodologically problematic evidence for a link between organizational autonomy and performance. We point at promising avenues for further research on autonomy and performance
as two core concepts in the contemporary higher education debate.
Keywords University autonomy  Organizational control  Performance 
Higher education reform

J. Enders (&)  H. de Boer  E. Weyer


Center for Higher Education Policy Studies, University of Twente, Postbus 217,
7500 AE Enschede, The Netherlands
e-mail: j.enders@utwente.nl

123

High Educ (2013) 65:523

Introduction
Over the last three decades, public sector reforms have at the face of it aimed at giving
public organizations more autonomy from governments. Placing public organizations more
at arms length of direct control from political authorities has been advocated as a way of
improving performance in service provisions. It has been widely discussed how democratic
governments are changing their relationships with public service organizations, what the
implications for their external and internal control might be, and what such changes deliver
in terms of expected improvements of public services (Pollitt and Bouckaert 2000;
Christensen and Lgreid 2006; Olsen 2009). Autonomization has thus been part and
parcel of the wider debates about shifts from government control to a regulatory state
(Majone 1996) and from Old Public Administration to New Public Management
(Dunleavy and Hood 1994). Higher education in Europe has been no stranger to such
reforms and the question of the autonomy and control of the university is of significant
scholarly and policy interest.
The main aim of this paper is to contribute to the conceptual and empirical understanding of governmental control and organizational autonomy in higher education studies.
Our approach is to link up higher education studies to the wider scholarly literature on
public management reform, principal-agent relationships, and sociological approaches in
the study of public policy and institutional design. First, we ask: what is the meaning of
autonomy in the narrative of change of contemporary higher education policy? In order to
understand the historically contingent and changing nature of the concept, we begin our
analyses by looking at the shifting meaning of autonomy from the past based on institutional trust and professional autonomy to the present based on organizational autonomy.
We point to contextual and political factors accounting for the reformulation of autonomy
within the field of higher education. Second, how can we empirically assess the effect of
political reforms for autonomy and control of universities as organizations? We distinguish
between formal and real organizational university autonomy and develop a multi-dimensional taxonomy for its empirical study. Our taxonomy is applied to the Dutch case that
highlights our theses of regulatory autonomy, that is the uses of organizational autonomy
as a tool of governmental regulation within a new regime of governmental control. The last
research question posed in this article is: What empirical evidence do we hold for a link
between university autonomy and performance? In this section, we turn to international
studies on organizational autonomy and performance in higher education, and discuss their
findings and limitations. In the conclusion, we summarise our findings and point to
promising future avenues for studies on organizational autonomy and performance as two
core concepts in contemporary higher education debates.

The changing idea of university autonomy


At the very heart of the contemporary debate about university reform and state-university
relations is the question of university autonomy. As autonomy is contextually and
politically defined (Neave 1988: 31) the meaning of autonomy changes over time. The
purpose of this section is to analyse a major shift in the idea of autonomy that is underpinning much of the political reform of the university. We argue that the dominant narrative of reform implies a shift towards the organizational autonomy of universities as
emerging actors in the field of higher education, and point to contextual and political
factors which account for the reformulation of university autonomy.

123

High Educ (2013) 65:523

When considering if and to what extent universities might have become more autonomous actors, it is obviously important to clarify what is meant by this term in general as
well as in the context of university reform. In its classical meaning autonomy refers to
auto (self) and nomos (rule or law) and autonomia refers to the right to self-government, e.g. to a state free to determine the rules and norms by which it wants to live
(Ostwald 1982, in Ballou 1998: 103). Key for our understanding is thus that autonomy
refers to both the actors self (having ability or capacity) and the actors relationship to its
environment (independence or freedom from external control). Historically, the right of the
university to govern itself has always been an important though contested issue (Perkin
1991) and was intimately tight to the issue of the professional autonomy of academics
(Enders 2006), i.e. their role and powers in the self-governance of the university as well as
their academic freedom to pursue teaching and research without fear of intervention or
punishment. The modern conception of the university embraced the idea of the university
as a distinctive social institution which deserves special status in terms of autonomy and
academic freedom based on a social compact that evolved between higher education, the
state and society. The belief that the university requires autonomy from substantial
political or corporate influence to function optimally was in turn linked to the role of the
state as the guardian of the university in substantive matters, guaranteed state funding, at
least in continental Europe, strong professional self-governance and protection of academic
freedom.
This idea of the autonomy of the university was reflected in the idealist tradition of the
modern university, most namely in the Humboldtian model, as well as in influential
conceptions of the university in the social theory of modernity. In the functionalist tradition, Parsons theorized the emergence of the autonomous modern university as part and
parcel of the social differentiation of modern society, the emergence of a functionally
superior setting of societal sub-systems and their related professions (Parsons and Platt
1973). In a related though different influential conception build into the Mertonian sociology of science, the autonomy of science called for a limited or protective role of the state
viz-a-viz the university as the dominant organizational host of scientific discovery.
Bourdieus (1988) field concept theorized higher education as a field with a high degree of
autonomy in that it generates its own organizational culture consisting of values and
behavioral imperatives that are relatively independent from forces emerging from the
economic and political fields. For Bourdieu, the relative autonomy of science as well as the
role of higher education in the social reproduction of society and the related proximity of
the university to societal elite legitimate its autonomy. Bourdieus framework thus
emphasises the autonomy of the field not as a given product of consensus but as a
dynamic product of a permanent conflict within a mediating context linking the university
to the external environment (Naidoo 2004: 467). Accordingly, autonomy varies from one
period to another, from one field to another, and from one national tradition to another.
In the continental European model of higher education (Clark 1983), the development
of the modern university and of the academic profession was intimately tight to the
emergence of the modern nation-state, its political institutions and bureaucratic apparatus.
State-university relationships developed a specific form characterized by a strong role of
the state as well as of the academic profession. On the one hand, the state functioned as a
strong regulator and funder of universities exercising bureaucratic control over procedural
matters. On the other hand, the state protected the autonomy of the university as a social
institution, academic freedom as well as academic self-governance, and substantial matters
were delegated to academics within a broad state framework. The protection of academic
freedom and guaranteed funding by the state enabled universities to establish normative

123

High Educ (2013) 65:523

and constitutive principals without being subject to strong external design (Olsen 2007).
The university as an organization developed, however, very limited authority and capacity
to regulate itself, e.g. in terms of its organizational boundaries, related entry and exit
requirements, its size and shape, its broader character and functions. In consequence,
universities were bottom-heavy with low potency for collective action. Organizational
leadership was weak compared to other organizations. Organizational change took place
mainly through continuous local adjustments, while major change was difficult to achieve.
Central organizational policies were often weak and interventions on this basis may
have only minor, local effects (Weick 1976). It is the academic professionals who act
in the university as an arena, rather than the university itself as an organizational actor
(de Boer et al. 2007).
The new autonomy of universities
Over recent decades, this social compact has been eroding, and the special status of the
university as a social institution is no longer taken for granted. In many OECD countries
and beyond, higher education reformers developed measures within the context of wider
reforms of public services and public management (Hood 1991; Pollitt and Bouckaert
2000; Olsen 2009) in order to change the coordination of universities. Shifts in the way of
regulating and funding universities reflected the drive towards mass higher education as
well as the overriding concern on the appropriateness of the output of higher education and
research for economy and society (Naidoo 2008). Higher education had become bigger,
more expensive, less elitist, politically more visible and economically more strategic.
This is what occurred in many countries over the last decades. As the higher education
system massifies, so these external and governmental pressures on the higher education
subsystem may be expected to increase. Within the knowledge based economy, the connection between the higher education institution subsystem and policy goals of economic
growth become sharper. (Ferlie et al. 2009: 9). This is for instance clearly echoed in the
communiques of the European Union in the last decade. Models of state supervision,
instead of state control, of output control, instead of process control, of market-like
competition combined with attempts to strengthen the actorhood of universities as organizations have become prevalent.
This new idea of how to organize government-university relationships and the autonomy and control of universities has been inspired by the growing popularity of New Public
Management approaches that find some of their theoretical background in principal-agent
theory. Three main assumptions are characteristic for modeling government-university
relationships in terms of principal-agent theory. First, and sharing some basic foundations
with economic neo-institutionalism (Furubotn and Pejovich 1974; Jensen and Meckling
1976; Pratt and Zeckhauser 1991; Moe 1984), the framework assumes that rational actors
strive to maximize their preferences according to their priorities. Given that the priorities
of the principal (the government) and the agent (the university) may differ problems can
arise due to a separation of interests. The second assumption is that there is a problem in
the asymmetry of information between those who command (the government) and those
who receive commands (the university). Agents may thus use their discretionary room
stemming from this asymmetry to pursue their own interests and will not necessarily act in
accordance with the goals of the principal. As a result of that, agency slack, defined as
unwanted independent action by an agent, is a potential problem which requires action
from the principal. The third assumption of principal-agent theory is that the rational
design of institutions will help to overcome these typical problems in the relationship.

123

High Educ (2013) 65:523

On the one hand, devolving authority from government to the university (autonomy) is
beneficial for government for various reasons. Universities hold expertise and information
not easily available to the government; universities can exercise internal control with closer
proximity to their primary activities and products; and governments can turn over some
risks to the universities. On the other hand, typical relationship problems arise because of
the self-interested opportunism of the university as an agent. Devolving authority from
the government to the university should thus go together with incentive structures to
control the university. Examples of such control mechanisms are specific rules (that limit
discretion), monitoring university behavior and performance, bonding universities in
performance contracts, creating competition between universities.
Principal-agent theory thus models the universities autonomy as part and parcel of a
new regime of control. The strengthening of universities as strategic organizational actors
with capacities for managerial self-regulation and internal control, and new tools of
governmental control are expected to increase organizational performance.
Across continental Europe, we can see the influence of such ideas about changing
principal-agent relationships between government and universities. Many governments
have announced attempts to step back from the traditional regime of state control and to
take a more distant framework setting role in the relationship with their universities. More
efficiency and effectiveness in university provision is expected by delegating some
authorities to universities as more autonomous and, separately, accountable organizations.
Such changes also have supported the view that universities should become more managed
enterprises (Bleiklie 1994). Through stronger executive leadership and professionalized
management structures strategic capacities of universities as organizations should be
strengthened. Another key element of the reforms is to increase the level of competition
between universities, to allocate resources according to the performance of the organization as a whole, and to shift the focus of state control from procedural matters to outputrelated monitoring of performance (accountability).
A new narrative about university autonomy has thus been emerging in which the university as an organization has become an important focus of attention in the systems
coordination. Universities are supposed to act as social entities that possess a certain degree
of autonomy and sovereignty, with self-interested goals as well as with rational means,
commanding independent resources and visible boundaries (de Boer et al. 2007).
The grand narrative noted above which finds some inspiration in principal-agent theory
appears to give a standard recipe for governing universities better and improving their
performance. However, we need to treat this with caution given competing theoretical
perspectives deriving from a sociological institutionalist approach in the study of public
policy and institutional design (Christensen 2009; Christensen and Lgreid 2006; Egeberg
2003). According to this approach, grand narratives of changing government-university
relationships might very well provide an important input into actual reforms. They represent changing belief systems about what appropriate and efficient ways of organizing this
sector might be. If they become internationally taken for granted, pressure will grow to
engage with related reforms and practices. What will be done, however, is not necessarily
what has been said, but an interpretation and adaptation of dominant models.
A main assumption of this approach is thus based on the concept of bounded rationality
(March and Simon 1958). Bounded rationality implies, first, that actors have limited
attention and information; they cannot address all alternatives and consequences. Reform
and response will thus not be the outcome of a near perfect rational choice but will be
limited in its capacity to deal with complex realities. Second, historical and cultural
traditions in organising government-university relationships will come into play as well.

123

10

High Educ (2013) 65:523

Path dependencies might constrain what is possible and the reform road taken reflects some
historical legacies and sector-specific trajectories. Build in here is also a negotiation
perspective, suggested by Cyert and March (1963) and March and Olsen (1983), stressing
that public decision-making processes might result from negotiations and compromises
between actors with different interests. (Christensen and Lgreid 2004: 11). Third, norms
and values that have been institutionalized within the organizational field of universities
interact with reforms aimed at changing the autonomy and control of the university.
Compatibility of reforms might be important for understanding their success and failure.
Change will be difficult if it does create disruptions undermining the legitimacy and trust in
the university as an institutionalized form. Fourth, changes in the formal autonomy situation of universities do matter but there are good reasons to assume that autonomy in
practice is not a perfect copy of formal autonomy. Formal rules for autonomy might be
implemented or not, and they cannot prescribe in advance practices in universities. Finally,
characteristics of the focal organizationssuch as the complexity of their tasks (and thus
the measurability of their outputs), or their size and agemight influence reform trajectories as well as their effectiveness. Also in this respect, universities as organizations are
certainly an interesting case characterized by unpredictability of results and task ambiguity, and by performance being based on professional expertise and recognition in interorganizational professional communities.
Institutional design for public sector organizationssuch as the issue of the autonomy
and control of universitieswill be the outcome of a blend of factors such as changing
political beliefs and goals, path-dependencies and political compromises, and organizational characteristics. These theories are skeptical when it comes to a standard model for
success in higher education.
In the following sections, we will thus go into practice in understanding organizational
autonomy and control in higher education and the related issue of university performance.
First, we will focus on the Dutch case as a particular example of higher education reform
and the empirical mapping of Dutch universities autonomy situation. Subsequently, we
will discuss international studies on the relationship between university autonomy and
performance.

Formal and real university autonomy: the Dutch case


Obviously, the grand narrative of change discussed above addresses the autonomy of the
university as an organization in a new way. In the following, we want to discuss the
autonomy situation of Dutch universitiesa case of particular interest given that Dutch
higher education policy has been a continental European front runner of reform in this
sector. From a birds eye view, key words of the governmental reform agenda seem to
suggest changing principal-agent relationships between government and universities as
well as a new freedom of universities: Deregulation and devolving authority from the
government; promoting self-organization of the sector; shifts from detailed ex ante control
to ex post performance monitoring; performance-based funding and more competition;
strengthening the position of the university as an organization and granting more autonomy
have all been on the governmental reform agenda. The generic character of the reform
narrative makes it at the same time difficult to empirically assess the new autonomy of the
university.
In doing so, our methodological approach builds on the work of Verhoest et al. (2004)
on measuring organizational autonomy of public sector organizations that we have applied

123

High Educ (2013) 65:523

11

to the world of higher education (de Boer et al. 2010). Following Verhoest et al., we
consider two kinds of organizational autonomy: autonomy as the level of the universities
decision making competencies and as the exemption of constraints on the actual use of
such competencies. Universities decision-making competencies has four dimensions:
Managerial autonomy addresses discretion over financial matters as well as human
resources management and management of other production factors (logistics, housing,
and organization). Policy autonomy indicates the extent to which a university can take
decisions about the quantity and quality of the goods and services to be delivered, and the
target groups it wants to reach. Governance autonomy concerns the extent to which universities can decide on internal structures and processes, and policy instruments.
The second kind of autonomy refers to the absence of constraints on the organizations
actual use of its decision making powers. Financial autonomy deals with the universities
dependency on governmental funding and alternative sources of income. Legal autonomy
relates to the legal status of the organization (e.g. public or private) and its implications for
the autonomy situation. Interventional autonomy refers to the extent to which the university is free from reporting requirements, evaluations or audits and from possible threats
of government intervention.
This comprehensive taxonomy fits the two main characteristics of autonomy discussed
earlier (the capacity to act and the freedom from external control) as well as the multidimensional and situational concept of autonomy. The taxonomy is in line with our focus
on the organization and integrates issues of autonomy and control (e.g. via accountability)
that usually tend to be separated in higher education studies. The focus on the organizations points, however, to a major limitation of the taxonomy that has little to say about
professional autonomy, especially aspects of academic freedom are not covered. The
taxonomy covers basic distinctions (such as procedural and substantial autonomy) as well
as integrating important sub-dimensions (such as organization/internal governance,
finance, personnel and academic matters) of earlier studies on university autonomy
(Anderson and Johnson 1998; Berdahl 1990; Estermann and Nokkala 2009; Moses 2007;
Levy 1980; Ordorika 2003). The outcomes of our application of the taxonomy to the
formal autonomy of Dutch universities are presented in the next section.
Formal autonomy of Dutch universities
With respect to human resource management Dutch universities have certainly gained in
autonomy because the government has been stepping back from detailed rules and regulations. Dutch universities are nowadays the employers of all their staff and can introduce
line management instruments. They can decide themselves on the number of academic
posts and select persons of their choice without governmental interference. The university
autonomy remains, however, restricted due to other actors and mechanisms. Salaries and
many other labor conditions are set by collective bargaining between the national employer
association and the unions, followed by local negotiations between the individual university and the local unions. The Collective Labor Agreements at the national level, legally
binding for the universities, comprises among other things agreements about minimum and
maximum salaries, detailed descriptions of staff positions and career ladders, job appraisals
and procedures for promotions. Managerial discretion is furthermore bound to the general
legal rules for hiring and firing in the Netherlands and the Dutch public service. Managerial
discretion has increased but is still being limited within the framework of national rules and
regulations.

123

12

High Educ (2013) 65:523

The universitys decision-making capabilities to manage financial affairs are considerable. Dutch universities can decide on how to spend the public operational grant, set the
tariffs for contract activities, borrow money form the capital market, build op reserves and
carry over unspent resources from 1 year to the next. They can set up and change rules for
internal budget allocation, develop their own managerial tools for internal performance
agreements or targets for budget allocation or organize internal competition in contests for
certain parts of the budget. Dutch universities can, however, not decide on tuition fees for
Bachelors and Masters programs: they must charge tuition fees that are fixed by the
ministry ( 1.732 annually).
The level of policy autonomy is relatively moderate to low. Dutch universities have to
accept all qualified Bachelors students (with exceptions for some disciplines), although
they may ask the minister to fix the number of study places for particular programs because
of huge demand in combination with limited capacity (so-called capacity fixus). Universities can select their Masters students and as the result of that determine themselves the
number of study places for Masters programs (again, with some exceptions). The development of new Bachelors and Masters programs is subject to both accreditation (by a
national agency) and ministerial approval. Research programming is up to the university.
However, research programming by governmental actors, increasingly including the
ministry of economic affairs as well as the research council, tries to set incentives for
organizational choices on preferred topics.
The level of governance autonomy is relatively moderate to low as well. The universities governance structure is to some extent prescribed by law. By means of university
bylaws the universities have some leeway to develop a structure to their taste, but within
the legal framework. Although appointed by the universitys supervisory board, the
national Act stipulates the guidelines for the selection of the rector. The members of the
supervisory board, all external, are appointed by the minister. National law also prescribes
a further top-down decision-making on managerial positions: the university leadership
appoints the deans and directors of central university research institutes, the deans appoint
head of departments etc. Traditional bodies of academic self-governance have been
abolished or have been disempowered by having a consultative function mainly.
As regards legal autonomy, the situation of Dutch universities has not changed. They
are public agencies bound to the general rules and regulations that apply.1 The financial
autonomy situation of Dutch universities has somewhat changed due to a modest trend
towards revenue diversification. Roughly two-third of the budget of Dutch universities
derives nowadays from the government. Universities are seriously dependent on this
income stream that comes with strings attached as regards funding by student numbers and
a related component to subsidize basic funding for research. Some shift of governmental
money for research to the research council and other bodies running governmental programs for research has, however, led to some revenue diversification. This implies that
Dutch universities are nowadays somewhat less dependent on direct governmental funding
while other actors (intermediary bodies, other ministries) have gained control over some
part of the funding of the university.
Finally, the interventional autonomy of Dutch universities is low since they face several
ex post reporting requirements. They must have internal and external evaluation systems
for both teaching and research. They have, across the board, the opportunity to decide on
the methods they want to use, but these methods are evaluated by a national agency.
1

Three of the thirteen universities have a private status. To qualify for public funding, or in general terms to
be treated equally as the other universities, the same rules apply to these private universities.

123

High Educ (2013) 65:523

13

They have to report on their activities in annual reports and audited financial statements.
Teaching programs are due to accreditation by an intermediary agency. In addition,
external research sponsors have established their own reporting requirements that might
range from rather loose procedures for research council grants to detailed prescriptions by
sponsors such as the government itself or the European Commission. This adds another
layer of control on the university.
This brief sketch already highlights the dynamic and ambiguous nature of the formal
autonomy situation of the Dutch university that would be blurred in generic statements
about the new freedom of universities. The balance of autonomy and control in relation to
the government has certainly changed. Overall, managerial autonomy in finance and
human resources has increased while new strings have been attached in parallel to
strengthening leadership and management in universities. Political and governance
autonomy are still rather limited. Legal autonomy has not changed and financial autonomy
from government is still low as well. Interventional autonomy has certainly decreased.
Further, the rhetoric surrounding Dutch university reform stresses their increased
autonomy while the government systematically down-played old and new forms of control.
The government is still very present in defining the rules of the game. Shifts towards more
formal autonomy of universities have been initiated by the government, in some cases
against the opposition of the universities, and government is controlling the autonomy of
the university. What has been given can also be taken away if the government would
decide to row back in its overall arrangement of governing universities.
Finally, the Dutch government has placed universities in a more complex multi-level
and multi-actor constellation of autonomy and control. Some control has been delegated to
collective bargaining; intermediary bodies have taken over some of the traditional governmental roles in rule setting and funding; new governmental actors have entered the
scene, and government appoints external board members of universities being expected to
control major aspects of financial policies, human resource management policies, and
strategic development of universities.
Formal and real autonomy: a contested relationship
The previous section has led us to a number of conclusions as regards the multi-dimensional empirical investigation of the autonomy of universities and the current formal
autonomy situation of Dutch universities. Arguably, an understanding of the formal
autonomy of universities goes beyond traditional perspectives focusing on the legal status
of public organizations only. Formal autonomy is, however, only one side of the coin.
Further understanding of the real autonomy of universities is needed as well.
From the point of view of a structural-instrumental perspective these two sides of the
coin would be expected to look pretty similar since the real autonomy of an organization
should reflect its formal autonomy. As we have argued earlier, there are conceptual
arguments for expecting that the degree of formal autonomy granted to universities does
not necessarily translate into the same degree of real autonomy.
Government might to some extent have stepped back from control of its universities
while it still remains the most important player in the field in terms of rule-setting and
funding. Nowadays, Dutch universities find themselves in a situation of regulatory
autonomy that has severe implications for the inter-linkages between autonomy and
control. Universities work in the shadow of hierarchy, and the Dutch government has
various times shown its interventionist capacities when universities tried to test the
boundaries of their new freedom. Under such circumstances, universities will try to

123

14

High Educ (2013) 65:523

anticipate the political and administrative position and up-coming policies, which is a wellknown mechanism from the study of decision-making within the ministerial bureaucracy
(Mayntz and Scharpf 1975). As a consequence, formal autonomy of the university will be
higher than the actual level of autonomy used because university leadership anticipates the
governments position. More importantly, Dutch autonomy policies interact with other
new regulatory policy instruments such as output funding, performance monitoring
and (bilateral) contracting. Universities have been granted more autonomy in financial and
human resource matters while new instruments attempt to steer organizational choices and
behavior more effectively. It allows the government to force universities under the pretext
of voluntary strategic choice into certain directions desired by the government, which
would not have been possible with old policy instruments. Under these circumstances, and
in line with propositions derived from principal-agent theory, organizational autonomy
becomes part and parcel of a new regime of control of universities. Along the same lines,
Dutch government is currently preparing further bonding of universities via performance
contracts.
University reformers might experience an implementation gap, and the university is not
an unlikely case for experiencing problems in actually implementing a new regime of
autonomy and control. One reason for this is that universities have traditionally been
different from many other organizations (loose coupling between administration and
academic core, high professional autonomy, weak leadership and management). Since the
mid-1980s, the Dutch were a continental European frontrunner in replacing the previous
centralized arrangements with an autonomy policy designed to grant universities increased
decisional leeway (Goedegebuure and Westerheijden 1991). Such radical change was,
however, met by skepticism from the universities. The result was that the policy impact on
organizational autonomy has not been as great as expected. The traditional approach to
policy-making, based on consensual and distributive policy, continued to prevail (de Boer
and Huisman 1999). It was in 1997, that the internal governance system of universities was
changed by law in order to force Dutch universities to develop managerial autonomy and
intra-organizational hierarchical steering capacities according to the logic of the verticalization of responsibility for decision-making.
Universities experience more autonomy in some dimensions while stronger (state)
control is exercised in other dimensions. Given the inter-dependencies between dimensions
of autonomy this might result into paradoxical effects for the organizational autonomy of
the university. In the Dutch case, managerial autonomy for budgeting in universities has,
for example, certainly considerably increased. At the same time, state-induced new control
technologies for financial auditing have effected in streams of rule setting and red-tape for
the organization that are likely to limit managerial discretion in this area. Managerial
autonomy for human resources has increased as well while traditional state control in this
area has partly been delegated to collective bargaining. Collective bargaining has resulted
into an impressive amount of binding rules and regulations that severely restrict the
decision-making capacity of the organization in this area. In addition, in areas where the
state relaxed control universities themselves have stepped in and created new rules and
mechanisms for internal control. Micro management of the government is replaced by
micro management of the university apex. Such observations point into the direction of a
Tocquevillian paradox that Hood and Peters (2004) noted in their review of public management reforms, namely the production of bureaucratic activity of a style even more rulebased and process-driven than the traditional forms of public bureaucracy that were meant
to be supplanted.

123

High Educ (2013) 65:523

15

The Dutch case also points to the usefulness of a task-specific perspective. We refer
here to the measurability of outputs of organizations that forms an important pre-condition for performance monitoring and bonding according to principal-agent models.
Wilson (1989) has classified public organizations along this dimension and developed
ideal types of public organizations confronted with specific control challenges. Arguably,
universities outputs are not as easily accessible as the outputs of organizations that
Wilson called production agencies. The Dutch response has been to invest into ever
growing amounts and specifications of outputs and related indicators derived from the
universities themselves as well as from system monitoring. Obviously, the increasing
efforts to make the activities and outputs of academic work more observable, measurable
and comparable reflect more general changes in political dispositions as regards principal-agent relationships between government and university. They also stimulate closer
performance monitoring within the universities. Related performance funding incentivizes universities to make strategic choices aligned with governments goals. Subsequently, government struggles, however, with two unwelcome consequences of success
in performance steering. First, standardization of performance monitoring and funding
leads to similar choices of universities undermining organizational specialization within
the system (or profiling of universities). Accordingly, government tries to implement
performance contracts including some premiums for profiling activities of universities.
Second, success in incentivizing growing quantitative outputs raises concerns about the
quality of products delivered. In consequence, further efforts are made to monitor quality
and to sanction deviant behavior that fuel the rise of internal and external audits and
evaluations.
Finally, Dutch reformers might have under-estimated the problem of the specific
nature of the university as an organization for internal managerial self-regulation and
control. Three decades of reform confirm that characteristics of the primary tasks of the
university strongly affects the potentials and barriers for managerial autonomy and
control. Musselin (2007) and Whitley (2007) have provided arguments to assume that
universities capacities to develop firm-like strategic actorhood will be limited even
under conditions of decreased state control, increased organizational autonomy and
growth of internal managerial control and surveillance. Such limitations are ascribed to
inherent characteristics of universities as part of the public science system, i.e. the
inherent technological uncertainty of their core activities and their deeply embedded
fragmentation. As organizations, universities thus possess limited discretion over
expected results. Further, systematic planning, coordination and integration are limited
by the division of academic labour along the lines of fields of research and teaching with
their specialist knowledge and skills. Central coordination and integration for collective
goal achievement will have to rely on the contributions of loosely coupled parts of the
organization to the whole. Under such conditions strategic choices are more similar to
those of holding companies and investment portfolio managers than entrepreneurial
decision-making in more authoritatively integrated and directed work organizations
(Whitley 2007: 25).
Dutch higher education reform re-visited
Our discussion of Dutch reforms highlight the ambiguous nature of reform as well as the
influence of principal-agent thinking. After the introduction of a new steering philosophy
entailing a new principal-agent relationship, government revised autonomy and control of
universities as an attempt to align changing political interests and organizational action.

123

16

High Educ (2013) 65:523

Organizational autonomy was increased in some ways while existing control mechanisms
were adapted and new ones were introduced. Specific rules that curtail university choice
(e.g. organizational structure and boundaries, legal status and financial dependencies) have
been maintained. Managerial capabilities for internal self-steering and control have been
strengthened (financial affairs and human resource affairs). Accountability requirements to
monitor agent behavior have been increased (quality assurance schemes, evaluation and
accreditation, performance monitoring). Incentives have been set to increase competition
and to control the flow of resources according to performance. Such instruments allow the
government to incentivize universities behavior into certain desired directions, which
would not have been possible with old policy instruments. Another more recent step
concerns attempts at contracting relationships between Dutch government and universities.
Contracts provide another instrument to align the agent to the goals of the principal and
might provide more security to the agent as regards expectations and funding. We also
witness a change in the principal structure itself from a dominant single principal (the
government, namely the ministry of education) to multiple principals (the government,
increasingly including other ministries, accreditation and funding bodies, evaluation
agencies).
At a first glance, Dutch higher education reform seem to have followed a master plan
that provides a clear break with the regime of the past. Our analyses points, however, at
reform dynamics that support expectations derived from sociological institutionalist
approaches in the study of public policy and institutional design. Over three decades, the
Dutch government has been struggling with implementation gaps, the persistence of traditional modes of consensual and distributive policies, resistance within universities
resulting in legal enforcement of change, the perennial problem of the measurability of
universities outputs, and limitations to a clear cut hierarchical regime of internal control in
universities. The current political compromise reflects changing political beliefs and goals
as well as politico-administrative path-dependencies and compatibility problems within the
field. We find support for the theses that neo-corporatist traditions as well as path
dependencies of the Rechtsstaat have constricted the possibilities for more radical
change (see also, Westerheijden et al. 2009). The formal organization as well as the
culture of universities have been quite alien to a reform agenda that has been partly
inspired by the idea that universities might be treated as production organizations. And
imperfect outcomes and unintended effects of policies of the past fuel on-going streams of
new policies.
After three decades of reform and re-reform a new regime of governmental control and
organizational autonomy has, however, emerged. Dutch universities have gained in
managerial autonomy while they have lost in institutional autonomy. Autonomy policies
for strengthening the internal control of universities and their actorhood as organizations
are combined with regulatory policies for external control that constrain organizational
choices and are expected to align universities more closely with governmental goals. When
government retreated from traditional forms of control in favor of self-regulation, it turned
towards control through different regulatory instruments and actors including the university as an organizational actor itself. Re-regulation has contributed to the emergence of a
multi-level and multi-actor playing field of organizational autonomy and direct or indirect
governmental control. Government has also repeatedly emphasized its interventionist
capacities in cases of systemic failure or low performance. Universities work nowadays in
the shadow of a complex hierarchy that aims at getting the incentives right in order to
control and improve their performance.

123

High Educ (2013) 65:523

17

University autonomy and performance: looking through a glass darkly


As we have discussed earlier, university reform including the autonomization of universities is claimed to make deliberate changes to the structures and processes of universities with the objective of getting them (in some sense) to run better. There is thus
growing interest in and use of organizational and system performance information in
higher education. Performance is becoming the ultimate dependent variable, particularly
because universities are increasingly considered from an instrumental perspective.
According to this view, support for the higher education system and its organizations can
no longer be based on institutional trust but depends on their contribution to society and
economy (Olsen 2007).
Consequently, and as we have exemplified by the Dutch case, higher education policy gets
instrumented by measures for output control, new accountability requirements, quality
assurance systems, performance-based funding mechanisms or the use of contracts that call
for related performance information. The new rules of the game are expected to set incentives
for universities to improve performance that trigger a need for performance-related information in order to identify strengths and weaknesses as well as strategic options.
While the attention for and use of performance measures in higher education has grown,
little political action has so far been taken to evaluate the impact of changes in systems
governance and organizational autonomy on the performance of universities and higher
education systems. Research in organizational studies has focused on regulatory public
agencies and shown a mixed picture of positive and negative correlations between organizational autonomy and performance (see Verhoest et al. 2010). Empirical investigations
into university autonomy and performance are a quite recent phenomenon. In the following
section, we will present and discuss their contributions to the debate and further hypotheses
building as well as their limitations.
Organizational autonomy and performance: previous studies re-visited
Research on university autonomy and performance has first emerged in the United States in
an era of declining public support for universities combined with increased state-wide
regulation and control. Various studies investigated the relationship between governance,
autonomy and performance paying special attention to the similarities and differences
between public and private universities, and the different systems of governmental oversight of their state universities by their board structures. Knott and Payne (2004) have
reviewed previous studies that pointed to superior performance of more autonomous private universities compared to public universities especially in research. As regards public
universities, Volkwein and Malik (1997) found no relationship between academic and
financial autonomy on the one hand and universities performance on the other hand.
Instead, size and wealth of the state and of the university correlated with research performance. Eykamp (1995) found financial autonomy as the most important autonomy
predictor of performance. In addition, constitutional autonomy, speed of appointments
made to the board by the governor, and campus size were found to be positively correlated
with performance. Knott and Payne (2004) looked as well into the impact of state governance structures, the autonomy and control of public universities, and their performance.
The systems governance structure influences important choices in terms of resource
allocation and sources of revenue. The governance structure may also have an indirect
effect on how organizational management makes decisions: in highly regulated structures
more attention is paid to politically prioritized issues such as lower tuition and a greater

123

18

High Educ (2013) 65:523

focus on students. Minimally regulated systems push managerial behavior in the direction
of a private university model focusing more on tuition revenues, research income and
research productivity. Their overall conclusion is that differences in political structures and
economic conditions of states and regions play a more important role for performance than
university autonomy. Controlling for such influences shows, however, that managerial
autonomy influence choices of resource allocation and sources of revenue that influence
performance.
Aghion and colleagues have conducted a number of studies on the relationship between
organizational autonomy and performance (Aghion et al. 2007, 2008, 2009). Their outcomes suggest that university research performance is positively correlated with university
autonomy, the level of funding and competition. Size (big is beautiful) as well as age
(reputation effect) matters for research performance (i.e. position in the Top 500 of the
Shanghai ranking). They also detect an interaction effect: higher levels of funding (i.e.
higher budgets per student) have more impact when combined with financial autonomy.
Their findings suggest a positive relationship between competition (for research grants) and
research output (i.e. position on the Shanghai ranking). To test the causality of these
relations, data for the U.S. were used and research performance was defined as the number
of patents. From these U.S. data, the researchers would () like to suggest (Aghion
et al. 2009: 24) a causal relationship between public university autonomy and competition
on the one hand and research output in terms of patents on the other hand. As regards their
findings for Europe, the study concluded, however, that there is not one single model for
success in the university sector. The best countries in research performance in Europe,
which include the UK, Scandinavian countries, the Netherlands and Switzerland, display
quite some diversity in terms of both funding and university autonomy.
Van der Ploeg and Veugelers (2008) looked into the relationships between organizational autonomy, funding and performance of Europes universities. Primarily based on
secondary analyses (using data from the Global Competitive Index of the World Economic
Forum, the Shanghai and THES rankings, OECD indicators and the Bruegel group), they
find some indications that a number of the better performing countries have high levels of
autonomy for their universities while weak performing countries tend to be lower on
autonomy. They found, however, prominent exceptions from this rule as well as a large
dispersion of autonomy characteristics among high and low performers.
Recently, de Boer et al. (2010) and Jongbloed et al. (2010) investigated such links at the
systems level. They categorized the funding and autonomy situation of thirty-three
European countries. For system performance eight dimensions were selected (access,
mature learners, graduation, employability, international student mobility, research output,
capacity to attract funding and cost effectiveness). For each performance indicator data for
the years 1998, 2002 and 2006 were retrieved. In the analyses, the possible links between
organizational autonomy and performance were controlled for the level of public investment in higher education (public expenditure on tertiary education as a percentage of GDP)
and for the economic standing of the countries (on the Global Competitive Index, GCI).
The studies draw the conclusion that within the right conditions (sufficient levels of public
expenditure, financial incentives, sufficient capacity to attract and retain productive staff
and sufficient capacity to meet demand) autonomous universities can contribute to
improved research productivity in their countries as well as to higher levels of educational
attainment. Organizational autonomy in academic staffing and related salary matters play
an important role. Funding reforms (stronger emphasis on performance, more funding for
research and the introduction of targeted research funding) and financial autonomy have
contributed to an increase in research productivity in some countries. Funding reforms

123

High Educ (2013) 65:523

19

have also contributed to an increased number of graduates in some countries by providing


incentives and autonomy to universities to grow. For other performance dimensions no
significant link to university autonomy could be found.
Does autonomy matter? And for what?
Our review of the literature provides various important implications for future research.
First, studies on the link between organizational autonomy and performance in higher
education are surprisingly scarce. The evidence is inconclusive, while the studies point to
organizational autonomy being one of the potential determinants of university performance.
Further studies are thus needed to enhance our conceptual and empirical understanding.
Second, various promising propositions for future research can be condensed from the
studies presented above. Organizational autonomy appears to be one predictor of the
quantity of output of the primary processes of universities in research and teaching (e.g.
numbers of graduates, articles published, number of patents, success in research grants). As
regards the autonomy situation of the university, universitys decision-making capabilities
to manage financial affairs as well as human resource affairs seem to be more important
variables than other dimensions of autonomy. Interaction effects are to be expected, such
as higher levels of funding having more impact when combined with autonomy in financial
affairs, or the interaction between organizational autonomy and the type and level of
competition within the field. Other variables need to be controlled for in testing the link
between autonomy and performance. This includes system variables (wealth of nation and
funding for higher education and research as an importantif not the most important
predictor of performance, competition within the field,) as well organizational characteristics (size, age, and organizational budget) that various studies have pointed at.
Evidently, the empirical evidence is inconclusive. The findings provide, however, some
support for thinking guided by an institutionalist economic logic, namely that more
autonomous universities that need to compete for resources are more productive. Especially in research, governmental control is likely to produce government failure and will
be less effective than making more autonomous universities with managerial discretion in
prime production factors compete for resources and performance. Some support can also
be found for an institutionalist sociological logic, namely that context matters, that organizational characteristics matter, and that there is not one single model for high performance or improving performance of universities to be expected.
Third, overcoming certain biases and limitations would greatly enhance our understanding of the predictors of university performance. The studies measure organizational
autonomy in very different ways; most studies rely on data on the formal autonomy
situation and do not distinguish between formal and real autonomy. Not (only) formal
autonomy but the way autonomy is put into action might explain performance. One of the
reasons for the inconclusiveness of the studies on autonomy and performance could thus be
related to problems on the side of the independent variable. Currently, our knowledge is
also biased towards certain indicators of universities research performance (except de
Boer et al. 2010; Jongbloed et al. 2010) as the dependent variable. This situation is
problematic for conceptual, normative and empirical reasons.
Just as autonomy, performance is a multidimensional concept. Performance is related to
missions, goals or purposes that will affect the what and how to be measured, as well as its
interpretation. Higher education systems are characterized by task complexity, multiple
and possibly conflicting goals. And various stakeholders have various legitimate expectations and interests with respect to the performance of the university. In modern mass

123

20

High Educ (2013) 65:523

higher education, universities and other higher education providers also are expected to
develop specific profiles. Thus, one size does not fit all if specialization is taken to be
seriously, and performance measures need to be aligned with organizational purposes and
goals (van Vught 2009).
Further, the study of Knott and Payne (2004) implicitly points to possible trade-offs
between different tasks and dimensions of performance (e.g. more autonomous universities
shifting attention from teaching to research). Another trade-off concerns the relationship
between quantitative output and quality of output. The data discussed are not inconsistent
with the idea of publication inflation, that is universities having incentives to increase
publication output irrespective of their impact in the field. The same holds for grade
inflation, that is, universities might have incentives to keep students enrolled as long as
possible if they are rewarded on enrolment and increase graduation rates if funding is based
on diplomas. Our studies will only be able to account for such trade-offs by applying
various dimensions of performance.
As with the concept of organizational university autonomy, the discussion above points
to the need for context-sensitive and multidimensional concepts and measures of performance. Hence, we argue that a multi-dimensional performance concept as it is used in some
ranking instruments, such as U-Multirank (van Vught and Ziegele 2012), is a good starting
point. The dimensions used are education profile, student profile, research involvement,
knowledge exchange, international orientation and regional engagement. This multidimensional perspective is stakeholder driven, accounts for different profiles and missions
of universities, and supports the concept of multiple excellences. Such a multidimensional
perspective would increase our knowledge on the contested relationships between autonomy and performance as two core concepts in contemporary higher education debates.

Conclusion
The main aim of this paper has been to contribute to the understanding of organizational
autonomy and control in higher education reform and related expectations as regards the
performance of universities. We discussed how the dominant narrative of political reform
moves away from traditional beliefs in university autonomy that are built on institutional
trust and linked to professional autonomy. The erosion of the traditional social compact
reflects deeper contextual and political changes as regards the role of higher education. In
the emerging narrative of political change, autonomy becomes re-defined as the new
organizational autonomy of universities as both strategic actors and as an addressee of
governmental control.
Our further empirical analyses was looking at the influence of principal-agent theory
inspired reforms and built on structural-instrumental and cultural perspectives on formal
and real autonomy applied to the Dutch case. The analyses highlights the influence of
principal-agent thinking on regulatory policies as well as politico-administrative pathdependencies of reforms and compatibility problems within the field. The current political
compromise reflects an autonomization of the university that is built into regulatory
policies for control that are expected to steer organizational behavior and to constrain
organizational choices. Dutch universities have gained in managerial autonomy while they
have lost in institutional autonomy. Governmental re-regulation has also installed a multilevel and multi-actor playing field of autonomy and control. Unintended effects and
insufficient outcomes of policies of the past stimulate further policies for bonding universities to the government and getting governmental incentives right.

123

High Educ (2013) 65:523

21

We thus conclude that notions of state supervision are misleading insofar they suggest
that government is stepping back from control in higher education. Notions of autonomy
and accountability are equally misleading insofar they suggest that performance monitoring is the price paid for more autonomy. Dutch universities are nowadays confronted
with a new regulatory regime of control in which their managerial autonomy is supposed to
be instrumental in aligning them to governmental goals and performance expectations.
This is what we call regulatory autonomy.
But does organizational autonomy matter for performance? Our review of international
studies on the link between organizational autonomy and performance reveals some
promising though preliminary conclusions. Expectedly, financial resources (wealth of
nations, funding for higher education, budgets of universities) turn out to be a strong
predictor of the quantity of output of the primary processes of universities. Universitys
managerial decision-making capabilities (financial and human resource affairs) appear to be
a co-predictor. Interaction effects have been observed with the degree of competition within
the field as well as with certain organizational variables (size, age). Evidently, our review of
the empirical literature provides some support for the institutionalist economic logic,
namely that more autonomous universities with managerial discretion that need to compete
for resources are more productive. Variations and exceptions are, however, hard to account
for. More in line with sociological approaches in the study of public agency, no one single
regulatory model for success of universities has so far been detected. The empirical evidence is inconclusive, partly because measures of university autonomy vary and mostly
address the formal autonomy situation. Performance measures tend to be biased towards
quantities in research output; and hardly account for the multiple-product character of
universities, various organizational missions, and effects on the quality of services provided.
Finally, and since our evidence is limited, we want to point to certain avenues for further
research on regulatory autonomy and performance. Our framework on organizational
autonomy and control in higher education could be applied in cross-national and crossorganizational comparative perspectives. A comparative analyses of the multi-dimensional
formal autonomy situation of universities would allow for further explanatory analyses of the
local adoption of changing regulatory policies and their effects on the real autonomy situation
of the universities. Further empirical investigation would thus address the analyses of university actors perceptions of their autonomy situation and for enhancing our understanding
of autonomy in use. Opening the black box of universities as organizations would also
greatly enhance our insight into the interaction between the external and internal control of
universities. Finally, context sensitive and multidimensional performance measures would
allow to further test the political theory of practice that assumes that a certain regime of
autonomy and control of universities would improve actual performance. After all, we want to
know if governance matters, and studies on the determinants of universities performance are
surprisingly scarce. In this respect, multidimensional approaches on performance are needed.
Acknowledgments We would like to thank the two anonymous reviewers of our paper for their constructive reviews and suggestions. We are indebted to Rajani Naidoo for her commentary and invaluable
advice on an earlier version of this paper.

References
Aghion, P., Dewatripont, C., Hoxby, M., Mas-Colell, A. & Sapir, A. (2007). Why reform Europes universities? Bruegel Policy Brief (04).

123

22

High Educ (2013) 65:523

Aghion, P. M., Dewatripont, C., Hoxby, M., Mas-Colell, A. & Sapir, A. (2008). Higher aspiration: An
agenda for reforming European universities, Bruegel Bleuprint, 5.
Aghion, P., Dewatripont, C., Hoxby, M., Mas-Colell, A., & Sapir, A. (2009). The governance and performance of research universities: Evidence form Europe and the U.S. Cambridge, MA: National
Bureau of Economic Research.
Anderson, D., & Johnson, R. (1998). University autonomy in twenty countries. Washington: Department of
Employment, Education, Training and Youth Affairs.
Ballou, K. (1998). A concept analysis of autonomy. Journal of Professional Nursing, 14(2), 102110.
Berdahl, R. (1990). Academic freedom, autonomy, and accountability in British Universities. Studies in
Higher Education, 19(2), 151164.
Bleiklie, I. (1994). The new public management and the pursuit of knowledge. Notat 9411. Bergen: LOS.
Bourdieu, P. (1988). Homo academicus. Cambridge: Polity Press.
Christensen, T. (2009). University governance reformPotential problems or more autonomy?. Oslo:
Department of Political Science, University of Oslo.
Christensen, T. & Lgreid, P. (2004). Regulatory agenciesthe challenges of balancing agency autonomy
and political control. Paper presented at the 20th anniversary conference of the Structure and Organization of Government Research Committee of the International Political Science Association,
Vancouver, June 1517, 2004.
Christensen, T., & Lgreid, P. (2006). Autonomy and regulation. Coping with agencies in the modern state.
Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.
Clark, B. R. (1983). The higher education system. Academic organization in cross-national perspective.
Berkeley: University of California Press.
Cyert, R. M., & March, J. G. (1963). A behavioral theory of the firm. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall.
de Boer, H. F., Enders, J., & Leisyte, L. (2007). Public sector reform in Dutch higher education: The
organizational transformation of the university. Public Administration, 85(1), 2746.
de Boer, H., & Huisman, J. (1999). The new public management in Dutch universities. In D. Braun &
F. X. Merrien (Eds.), Towards a new model of governance for universities?: A comparative view
(pp. 100118). London: Jessica Kingsley.
de Boer, H., Jongbloed, B., Enders, J., & File, J. (2010). Governance reform. Progress in higher education
reform across Europe. Volume 1: Executive summary and main report. Enschede: Center for Higher
Education Policy Studies.
Dunleavy, P., & Hood, C. (1994). From old public administration to new public management. Public Money
& Management, 14, 916.
Egeberg, M. (2003). How bureaucratic structure matters: An organizational perspective. In B. G. Peters &
J. Pierre (Eds.), Handbook of public administration (pp. 116126). London: Sage.
Enders, J. (2006). The academic profession. In J. J. F. Forest & P. Altbach (Eds.), International handbook
of higher education (pp. 522). Dordrecht: Springer.
Estermann, T., & Nokkala, T. (2009). University autonomy in Europe. Exploratory study (Vol. 1). Brussels:
European University Association.
Eykamp, P. W. (1995). Political control of state research universities: The effect of the structure of political
control on university quality and budget. Unpublished Ph.D. dissertation AAT 9544136, University of
California-San Diego. Available at: http://www.lib.umi.com/dissertations.
Ferlie, E., Musselin, C., & Andresani, L. (2009). The Steering of higher education systems: A public
management perspective. In C. Paradeise, E. Reale, I. Bleikle, & E. Ferlie (Eds.), University governance: Western European perspectives (pp. 829). Dordrecht: Springer.
Furubotn, E., & Pejovich, S. (1974). The economics of property rights. Massachusetts: Cambridge University Press.
Goedegebuure, L., & Westerheijden, D. (1991). Changing balances in Dutch higher education. Higher
Education, 21(4), 495520.
Hood, C. (1991). A public management for all seasons? Public Administration, 69(spring), 319.
Hood, C., & Peters, G. (2004). The middle age of new public management: Into the age of paradox? Journal
of Public Administration Research and Theory, 14(3), 267282.
Jensen, M. C., & Meckling, W. H. (1976). Theory of the firm: Managerial behaviour, agency costs and
ownership structure. Journal of Financial Economics, 76(3), 305360.
Jongbloed, B., de Boer, H., Enders, J., & File, J. (2010). Funding reform. Progress in higher education
reform across Europe. Volume 1: Executive summary and main report. Enschede: Center for Higher
Education Policy Studies.
Knott, J. H., & Payne, A. A. (2004). The impact of state governance structures on management and
performance of public organizations: A study of higher education institutions. Journal of Policy
Analysis and Management, 23(1), 1330.

123

High Educ (2013) 65:523

23

Levy, D. C. (1980). University and government in Mexico: Autonomy in an authoritarian system. New York:
Praeger.
Majone, G. (1996). Regulating Europe. London: Routledge.
March, J. G., & Olsen, J. P. (1983). Organizing political life. What administrative reorganization tells us
about government. American Political Science Review, 77, 281297.
March, J. G., & Simon, H. A. (1958). Organizations. New York: Wiley.
Mayntz, R., & Scharpf, F. W. (1975). Policy-making in the German federal bureaucracy. Amsterdam:
Elsevier.
Moe, T. M. (1984). The new economics of organization. American Journal of Political Science, 28(4),
739777.
Moses, I. (2007). Institutional autonomy revisited: Autonomy justified and accounted. Higher Education
Policy, 20(3), 261274.
Musselin, C. (2007). Are universities specific organizations? In G. Krucken, A. Kosmutzky, & M. Torka
(Eds.), Towards a multiversity? Universities between global trends and national traditions (pp. 6384).
Bielefeld: Transcript Verlag.
Naidoo, R. (2004). Fields and institutional strategy: Bourdieu on the relationship between higher education,
inequality and society. British Journal of Sociology of Education, 25(4), 457471.
Naidoo, R. (2008). The competitive state and the mobilised market: Higher education policy reform in the
United Kingdom (19802007). Paris: Critique Internationale/Presse de Science Po.
Neave, G. (1988). On being economical with university autonomy: Being an account of the retrospective
joys of a written constitution. In M. Tight (Ed.), Academic freedom and responsibility (pp. 3148).
Buckingham: Open University Press.
Olsen, J. P. (2007). The institutional dynamics of the European University. In P. Maassen & J. P. Olsen
(Eds.), University dynamics and European integration (pp. 2554). Dordrecht: Springer.
Olsen, J. P. (2009). Democratic government, institutional autonomy and the dynamics of change. Oslo:
ARENA working papers, 01.
Ordorika, I. (2003). The limits of university autonomy: Power and politics at the Universidad Autonoma de
Mexico. Higher Education, 46, 361388.
Parsons, T., & Platt, G. M. (1973). The American University. Harvard: Harvard University Press.
Perkin, H. (1991). History of universities. In P. Altbach (Ed.), International higher education: An encyclopedia (pp. 175198). Chicago: St. James Press.
Pollitt, C., & Bouckaert, G. (2000). Public management reform: A comparative analysis. Oxford: Oxford
University Press.
Pratt, J. W., & Zeckhauser, R. J. (Eds.). (1991). Principals and agents: The structure of business. Boston:
Harvard.
Van der Ploeg, F., & Veugelers, R. (2008). Towards evidence-based reform of European universities.
CESifo Economic Studies, 54(2), 99120.
Van Vught, F. (Ed.). (2009). Mapping the higher education landscape. Towards a European classification of
higher education institutions. Dordrecht: Springer.
Van Vught, F., & Ziegele, F. (Eds.). (2012). Multidimensional ranking: The design and development of
U-multirank. Dordrecht: Springer.
Verhoest, K., Peters, G. B., Bouckaert, G., & Verschuere, B. (2004). The study of organizational autonomy:
A conceptual review. Public Administration and Development, 24, 101118.
Verhoest, K., Verschuere, B., Meyers, F., & Sulle, A. (2010). Performance of public sector organizations:
Do managerial tools matter? In P. Lgreid & K. Verhoest (Eds.), Governance of public sector
organizations. Proliferation, autonomy and performance (pp. 211224). Houndsmills: Palgrave
Macmillan.
Volkwein, J. F., & Malik, S. M. (1997). State regulation and administrative flexibility at public universities.
Research in Higher Education, 38(1), 1742.
Weick, K. E. (1976). Educational organizations as loosely coupled systems. Administrative Science
Quarterly, 21, 119.
Westerheijden, D. F., de Boer, H., & Enders, J. (2009). Netherlands; An Echternach procession in different
directions; oscillating steps towards reform. In C. Paradeise, E. Reale, I. Bleikle, & E. Ferlie (Eds.),
University governance: Western European perspectives (pp. 103126). Dordrecht: Springer.
Whitley, R. (2007). Constructing universities as strategic actors: Limitations and variations. Paper presented at the conference The university in the market, Stockholm, Wenner-Gren Center, 13
November.
Wilson, J. Q. (1989). Bureaucracy: What government agencies do and why they do it. New York: Basic
Books.

123

Copyright of Higher Education is the property of Springer Science & Business Media B.V. and its content may
not be copied or emailed to multiple sites or posted to a listserv without the copyright holder's express written
permission. However, users may print, download, or email articles for individual use.

You might also like