You are on page 1of 10

Introduction

The exchange rate of the rupee carries tremendous importance in a small open economy
like Mauritius where there likely exist significant pass-through of changes in the value of
the rupee onto domestic macroeconomic variables such as inflation and output. Since the
suspension of the Exchange Control Act in July 1994, the rupee has been on a managed
exchange rate float and has undergone large cycles, from about Rs17.50 per US$ at
around this period to more than Rs30.00 per US$ currently.
According to the Bank of Mauritius Act 2004, it is the responsibility of the Bank of
Mauritius to manage the exchange rate taking into account the orderly and balanced
economic development of the country. In so doing, the Bank has to tread a fine line in
seeking to reconcile the often-divergent interests of the different sectors of the economy
and steer the exchange rate of the rupee towards an appropriate level. Of particular
interest, therefore, is whether the exchange rate is consistent with some kind of
fundamental equilibrium or not. Although short-term foreign exchange movements can
often appear erratic, it is often believed that there are basic forces that push a currency
towards an equilibrium exchange rate.
The aim of is to determine such an equilibrium exchange rate for the rupee. This would
allow an assessment of how under- or over-valued the exchange rate is, in order to
evaluate any potential future effects on the economy. It focuses on the short term where
equilibrium exchange rate can be defined as the exchange rate that would pertain when its
fundamental determinants are at their current settings after abstracting from the influence
of random effects. In general, monetary models such as the Behavioural Equilibrium
Exchange Rate (BEER), Intermediate Term Model Based Equilibrium Exchange Rate
(ITMEER) and Capital Enhanced Equilibrium Exchange Rates (CHEER) are most
closely related to short-run equilibrium concepts.
We follow Stephens (2004) and rely on a CHEER, which combines the Purchasing Power
Parity (PPP) theory and the Uncovered Interest Parity (UIP) condition into a single
relationship and yields a nominal equilibrium exchange rate that is consistent with current
price levels and interest rates. The idea underlying this approach is that while PPP may
explain long-run movements in real exchange rates, the real exchange rate may be away
from equilibrium as a result of non-zero interest rate differentials.

Exchange rate
In the second half of 2008, the exchange rate of the rupee was driven mostly by
international economic developments whilst local factors had rather mitigated effects.
The intensification and deepening of the crisis, which enhanced risk aversion, pushed
investors towards safe havens like the US dollar and the Japanese yen. These currencies
remained well-supported as a result. This was mirrored in a depreciation of the rupee on
the local foreign exchange market. The rupee depreciated against major currencies from
July to December 2008, with the exception of the Pound sterling which tumbled to multiyear low on international markets.

Interventions by the Bank


In an attempt to smooth out the increased volatility prevailing on the domestic foreign
exchange market, driven mostly by international factors, the Bank intervened on eight
occasions between August and November 2008 to sell a total of US$172 million.
Transactions were carried out at exchange rates ranging from Rs27.95 to Rs31.90. This
was synonymous to mopping up around Rs5.2 billion from the money market.
Furthermore, with a view to countering possible adverse effects of the ongoing global
economic crisis on the domestic economy and to support the initiatives taken by the
government to stimulate the economy, the Bank, on 20 December 2008, introduced a
Special Foreign Currency Line of Credit for US$125 million equivalent to approximately
Rs4 billion. The objective was to support banks which might be facing non availability,
or inadequacy, of foreign exchange credit facilities from their usual sources, which may
adversely affect banks ability to finance the countrys requirements in trade. On 24
December 2008, one bank was granted a loan of US$5.0 million under the facility.

Exchange Rate Pass-Through to Prices


Exchange rate pass-through, broadly defined as the responsiveness of prices to
movements in the nominal exchange rate, is a complex mechanism. Any appreciation or
depreciation of the exchange rate is expected to impact not only on the prices of imported
finished goods but also on the prices of imported inputs that affect the cost of finished
goods and services. Knowledge of the degree and timing of exchange rate pass-through is
considered essential for a proper assessment of the monetary policy transmission as well
as for inflation forecasting. Using a VAR approach, an internal study has been carried out
to examine the extent of exchange rate pass-through in Mauritius over the period 1994Q3
to 2008Q3. This approach allows the quantification of exchange rate pass-through
directly from the data in terms of impulse responses that trace the speed and extent of the
pass-through of an exchange rate shock to other variables in the model. The study has
also assessed whether estimates of pass-through are symmetric or not. Variables used in
the VAR include a recursive distribution chain of pricing, which maps out the dynamic
effect of an exchange rate shock along three pricing stages in the following order: (i)
import prices, (ii) production prices, and (iii) consumer prices. The ordering and choice
of the price variables are motivated by the idea that prices are set at each of three
different stages import, production and consumption which together make up a
stylized distribution chain for goods and services. In addition to the distribution chain of
pricing, variables such as oil prices, output gap and broad money or interest rates have
been incorporated in the VAR model to estimate exchange rate pass-through. These
variables act as proxies for supply and demand shocks, and for monetary policy,
respectively. To derive impulse responses, variables in the model have been ordered in a
particular sequence so that those placed higher in the ordering have contemporaneous
impact on those placed lower in the ordering, but not vice-versa. The most exogenous
variable, oil prices, has been placed first on the premise that oil price shocks affect all
other variables in the system contemporaneously but oil prices are not themselves
affected contemporaneously by any of the other shocks. The next variables in the system
are the output gap and the exchange rate. With this ordering, a contemporaneous impact

of the demand shocks on the exchange rate is implicitly assumed while a certain time lag
on the impact of exchange rate shocks on output is also recognised. The price variables
have been ordered next and are thus contemporaneously affected by all of the preceding
variables. Following the pricing chain, import prices have been placed before producer
prices and consumer prices implying that pricing decisions at the import and production
stages can have a contemporaneous impact on consumer prices, but not vice versa. The
interest rate has been ordered last, allowing for the money market, and in particular
monetary policy, to react contemporaneously to all variables in the model. Over a tenquarter horizon, it has been found that the maximum impact of the exchange rate shock is
immediately felt in the case of import prices and producer prices while it takes two
quarters for the maximum impact of the exchange rate shock to be reflected onto
consumer prices. Thereafter, the effect of the shock on all price variables diminishes
substantially, turning negative after 2-4 quarters partly reflecting the adjustment process
by consumers in the domestic economy to the shock. Pass-through to import prices
amounts to about 100 per cent of the exchange rate shock in the first two quarters after
the shock, meaning that the elasticity of import prices with respect to the exchange rate is
approximately unity. The extent of pass-through to producer prices is considerably less
but still significant, with 35 per cent of the exchange rate shock reflected in producer
prices after one quarter and 28 per cent after two quarters. The response of consumer
prices is also quite significant and persistent as well. From about 13 per cent at the end of
the first quarter pass-through rises to some 38 per cent in the second quarter, and peaks at
around 40 per cent three quarters after the shock before gradually subsiding. The chart
below shows the pass-through elasticities of a one per cent shock in the exchange rate.

Effective Exchange Rate of the Rupee


Exchange rate pass through is the percentage change in local currency import prices
resulting from a per cent change in the exchange rate between the exporting and
importing countries (Goldberg and Knetter 1996). Exchange rate pass through can be
either incomplete or complete and refers not only to the effect of exchange rate changes
on import and export prices but also on consumer prices, producer prices, investments
and trade volumes. The extent and degree of exchange rate pass through points out the
importance of exchange rate fluctuations on domestic price inflation and also the extent
to which exchange rates and import prices influence domestic inflation.
Like many developing countries, Mauritius depends on the rest of the world and the level
of interdependence has increased in the last decade. Mauritius being a small island
economy with a domestic market insufficiently large to support large scale production
depends on imports from other countries to supply a large part of domestic consumption
and on exports to other countries to provide markets for much of its output. It is highly
vulnerable to any adverse economic changes in other economies. Mauritius has
increasingly liberalized its trade frontiers leading to lower barriers to trade, for both
goods and services. This has increased trade and intensified international competition. In
addition to greater trade and financial liberalisation, two specific changes have impacted
significantly the Mauritian economy namely the phasing out of the preferential access

obtained on the EU market for sugar exports and the dismantling of the Multi Fibre
Agreement for our textile products in 2005. In addition, currency markets show different
degrees of volatility, reflecting the particular economic circumstances that the country
faces through time. Exchange rate volatility is another crucial element that needs to be
considered for small countries that depend extensively on trade the case of Mauritius.
Exchange rate changes have thus important implications on both producer and consumer
price inflation. To our knowledge, there are no studies analysing exchange rate pass
though for the small island economy of Mauritius which is highly dependent on trade and
where food imports presently consists of 77 per cent of the total import bill.
Mauritius is a small open economy which is affected by movements in the domestic
exchange rate against various foreign currencies and the path of the rupee against the
trading currencies will determine the consequences on the economy. It is important that
an exchange rate index is calculated based on the several bilateral exchange rates that
apply to a particular currency in order to gauge the average value of that currency against
others. The index excludes mistaken generalizations that can result from changes peculiar
to a single currency. A weighted-average measure of the relevant bilateral exchange rates
has been computed to build an effective exchange rate (EER). The computation of the
proposed effective exchange rate index of the Bank of Mauritius, which will be known as
the MERI (Mauritius Exchange Rate Index) is described. Since two indices are being
suggested, they will be termed MERI1 and MERI2. The Bank may, in future, introduce
various other measures of an exchange rate index reflecting specific concerns for various
sectors of the economy.
MERI 1 is the Mauritius Exchange Rate Index, a nominal effective exchange rate
introduced in July 2008, based on the currency distribution of merchandise trade.
MERI 2 is the Mauritius Exchange Rate Index, a nominal effective exchange rate
introduced in July 2008, based on the currency distribution of merchandise trade and
tourist earnings.

Constructing the EER: To build any EER, the following issues need to be
addressed: (i) the choice and number of bilateral currencies to include, (ii) a measure of
international trade to use to weigh these currencies, (iii) the use of bilateral or multilateral
exchange rates, (iv) the use of arithmetic or geometric weight, and lastly (v) the base year
for the index.

Which Currencies: This choice has been influenced by the importance of the
currency distribution of trade flows of Mauritius with the rest of the world. While there
are some merits in including services, given that Mauritius is rapidly developing into a
services economy, data constraints prohibit the use of all services traded to be included in
deriving the currency distribution of services traded. Nonetheless, some of the foreign
exchange flows emanating from the services traded are considered. Tourist arrivals are

available by country of residence, and a currency distribution of tourist receipts can be


proxied using the total receipts based on the strict assumption that tourists would
obviously pay for their expenditures using the currency of their respective countries.
While this assumption is quite debatable, it nevertheless provides for a rational proxy.

Choosing the Measure of Trade: Traditionally, most EERs are weighted by some
measures of traded goods and services, the sum of exports plus imports. The total trade of
goods, that is, the sum of exports and imports of goods, has been used to derive the
weights for the MERI1. The weights for MERI2 have been calculated using the total
trade of goods and a proxy derived from tourism receipts. The approach that is mostly
followed to derive the EER is the use of multilateral weights, whereby each currency
receives a weight equal to its proportion of total trade. This method captures the impact
of major currencies on trade flows. The same approach is followed for deriving MERI 1
and MERI 2. Further, the geometric weights technique has been used to derive the two
weighted exchange rates MERI 1 and MERI2.

Base Period: The choice of the base year typically reflects the most recently available
data and has been chosen so that the weights characterise the structure of trade
throughout the period of analysis. The base period chosen for computing the EER is
January December 2007 = 100. The approach followed is to use continually updated
weights in an attempt to portray current trade patterns. That is, weights will be updated
annually to ensure that they reflect the most recent structure of trade flows.

The MERI: The MERI is designed to be a summary measure of the rupees


movements against the currencies of its important trading partners. MERI1 and MERI2
differ from each other in the sense that MERI1 uses the currency distribution of trade as
weights, while MERI2 includes the currency distribution of tourism receipts combined
with the currency distribution of trade as weights.
Tables 1 and 2 give the weights that have been used to derive MERI1 and MERI2
respectively. Table 3 shows the MERI1 and MERI2 since January 2007, while Chart 1
plots their evolution since the same period. Chart 2 shows the monthly
appreciation/depreciation of the rupee vis--vis US dollar, pound sterling and Euro
together
with
the
change
in
the
MERI1
and
MERI2.

Memoranda of Understanding
The Memoranda of Understanding entered into between the Bank of
Mauritius and other authorities are listed below:
Local
Financial Services Commission
Foreign
Jersey Financial Services Commission
Commission Bancaire Franaise
State Bank of Pakistan
Banco de Moambique
The Bank Supervision Department of the South African Reserve Bank
Central Bank of Seychelles
Hong Kong Monetary Authority

January 2009 Communiqu on Basel II


On 21 September 2007, at a special meeting of the Banking Committee, it was decided
that banks in Mauritius would be required to report as from the quarter ending March
2008, on a parallel-run basis, their capital adequacy ratio (CAR) under the Basel II
framework along with their CAR under the Basel I framework. Following on from this
decision, the Bank issued a series of guidelines required for the implementation of Basel
II and commenced parallel run from quarter ended March 2008, as scheduled. The Bank
monitored the performance of banks under the parallel-run exercise and assessed the
impact of the new framework on their capital requirements. The Bank is satisfied that the
banking sector in Mauritius has made significant progress and is adequately prepared to
move on to the Basel II framework. Accordingly, in consultation with representatives of
all banks in Mauritius and the Mauritius Bankers Association Ltd, the Bank has decided
to do away with the parallel-run exercise and move over to the full implementation of the
Standardised Approaches of the Basel II framework as from the quarter ending 31 March
2009.

Domestic Financial Markets Developments


Reflecting the generally weaker US dollar as well as domestic demand and supply
conditions, the dealt rupee exchange rate had appreciated by 0.81 per cent against the US
dollar, but had depreciated by 1.31 per cent and 0.19 per cent against the Pound sterling
and euro, respectively. In nominal effective terms, as indicated by the MERI1, the rupee
had remained broadly stable.

Staff Economic Outlook


The Banks Staff anticipated that domestic economic conditions would improve in 2014
as global economic activity recovered. Real output was projected to grow close to its
potential over the forecast horizon. Consumption and investment were expected to pick
up during the year as consumers and businesses became more confident about the
recovery and adjusted their behaviour accordingly. Downside risks to the domestic
growth outlook remained, however, from the continued process of fiscal consolidation
and the need for private sector deleveraging. Moreover, the weak recovery in the
Eurozone might still constrain external demand while the low Eurozone inflation could
impact on the euro and, consequently, rupee exchange rates.

From recent short-term dynamics, measured by annualised q-o-q CPI inflation, the
Banks Staff assessed that it was likely that inflation would sustain its current momentum
over the next quarter. Going forward, demand and external pressures on inflation were
expected to be subdued. However, higher wages in the public sector could still have some
spill-over effects as trade unions demand a similar increase for the private sector. It was
noted that wages had already increased in the transport sector and negotiations were ongoing for an upward revision in the sugar sector while 14 remuneration orders were under
review. While the domestic exchange rate had remained range-bound, the continued
dependence on foreign savings to finance the pronounced current account deficit
constituted a major risk factor.

The Monetary Policy Decision


The MPC concurred that the global economy had picked up since the September 2013
MPC meeting, with recovery taking hold in advanced economies, particularly the US and
UK. The Eurozone appeared likely to stay out of recession, although growth was
expected to remain weak and uneven. Emerging market economies were expected to
continue facing downside risks from the US Fed tapering and internal rebalancing in
China. Concurrently, while the global inflation outlook remained benign, it was noted
that a number of emerging economies had experienced increases in inflation as a result of
the depreciation of their domestic exchange rates. They had consequently raised their
policy rates while advanced economies had maintained an accommodative monetary
policy stance.

Mauritius: Mauritian rupee increasingly depreciates against the dollar


The Mauritian rupee has again lost its value between August and September 2014 against
the dollar according to figures from the Central Bank of Mauritius.
The latest report of the Central Bank of Mauritius indicates that the weight of the
currencies (index MERI * 1) in the trade in goods valued at 94.508 points in August has
reached 94.948 points last September.
Distribution of currency in trade and the income from tourism on the island (index MERI

2) encrypted on its side 94.187 points in August rose to 94.538 points in September.
The dollar is thus currently trading at about 31.80 rupees against 31.21 rupees in early
September.
A strong dollar against the Mauritian rupee should drain in its wake the higher import
prices and more expensive products by the end of the year for consumers, as reported the
Le Dfi Quotidien newspaper.
* Index MERI: Mauritius Exchange Rate Index (MERI), represents a weighted average
of the exchange rate of the rupee.
This index assesses the movements of the rupee against the currencies of major trading
partners of Mauritius.

Conclusion
This study examines the degree and extent of exchange rate pas through to import and
domestic prices and also the effect of external shocks such as oil price shocks and import
price shocks on domestic prices. So as to understand which shock better explains the
variance in import and domestic prices, the forecast error variance decomposition of each
price index have equally been studied. Another investigation carried out in this study is
on the existence and degree of causality from exchange rate to domestic and import
prices and vice versa. Using a structural
VAR model that incorporates a distribution chain, the results from granger causality test
indicate that bidirectional causality exist is one case where producer price granger causes
nominal effective exchange rate and vice versa while in other cases unidirectional
causality is found. It is equally found that nominal effective exchange rate, import and
producer prices do not granger cause consumer prices. The impulse response functions of
the structural VAR are used to calculate exchange rate pas through elasticity and the
results indicate that exchange rate pas through to consumer prices is highest and not
complete. The second larger impact of an exchange rate shock is felt on producer prices
and the smallest on import prices. Therefore pass through increases as one goes along the
distribution chain. The findings especially for the case of consumer and import prices are
not in line with other studies. But this can be explained by the fact that main sources of
imports being China and India, lower import prices can be expected given the cheap labor
and the low quality products from China. Moreover, the pricing to market practice can
explain the low pass through to import prices. As far as consumer prices are concerned
the reason behind the high pass through is the dependence of households consumption
on imported consumer goods where most of them are not subsidized. The increasing cost
of living in Mauritius and the change in the exchange rate regime can also explain the
high pass through in consumer prices. Externals shocks equally have an effect on import
and domestic prices. The results suggest that oil price shocks have a larger impact on
import prices compared to producer and consumer prices while import price shocks have
a larger influence on producer prices. The examination of external shocks in explaining
the variance in the price indices pointed out that the variance of import and producer

prices are explained mainly by oil price shock while for the case of consumer prices,
import prices explain most of its variance. External shocks thus play an important role in
the Mauritian economy whereby prices are exposed to external shocks. However,
Mauritius being a small island developing state is vulnerable to external shocks and thus
cannot do much to reduce the impact of these external shocks on the economy given the
extent of openness of the country. The study can be useful for policy makers such as
Central Bank, in controlling the price level in Mauritius. The indication that exchange
rate pass through to consumer prices is highest but still incomplete implies that domestic
policies such as monetary policy have a significant role in controlling consumer price
inflation. Given that import price shocks have an important impact on producer prices,
managing inflation at the level of imports could be effective to reduce producer price
inflation. Moreover, the variance of consumer prices is explained mainly by import
prices. Thus, managing inflation at import level and the monitoring of pricing technique
by importers can contribute in reducing consumer price inflation.
The Mauritian rupee, after having stabilised against the euro and the dollar on the
exchange between December 2013 and January 2014, depreciated again in April in the
wake of major foreign currencies.
The latest report of the Central Bank of Mauritius indicates that the weight of the
currencies (index MERI * 1) in the trade of goods valued at 94.053 points in March
reached 94.190 points in April.
Distribution of currency in trade and tourism on the island (index MERI 2) income was
93.811 points in March against 93.960 points in January, as reported by the Le Dfi
Quotidien newspaper.
The Mauritian rupee is trading this week at 30.58 rupees per dollar and 41.95 rupees to
the euro following the increase of these two indices referents.
* Index MERI: Mauritius Exchange Rate Index (MERI), represents a weighted average
of the exchange rate of the rupee. This index assesses the movements of the rupee against
the currencies of major trading partners of Mauritius.

References
Internet
McCarthy, J., 1999. Pass through of exchange rates and import prices to domestic
inflation in some industrialized economies.
Menon, J., 1996. The Degree and Determinants of Exchange Rate PassThrough: Market Structure, Non-Tariff Barriers and Multinational
Corporations.
Krugman, P., 1986. Pricing to market when the exchange rate changes.

You might also like