You are on page 1of 16

The Costs of Violent Crime

Giles Atkinson, Susana Mourato & Andrew Healey

1. Introduction
Few policy issues have the potential to arouse as much intense public
debate as whether governments are doing enough to combat criminal
activity (or whether the actions being taken are the most effective). For
example, statistics indicating the pervasiveness of different types of crime
and trends in crime rates are widely disseminated and debated. Similarly,
public surveys of the publics fear of crimeparticularly violent crime
have demonstrated growing concern about perceived crime risks amongst
the general public as well as among specific demographic groups. As a
result, governments in many countries are in the process of investing significant political capital in numerous initiatives that aim to reduce crime in
general or that target specific types of offending, such as gun crime. Of
course, these initiatives also involve the commitment of substantial economic resources. Hence, one interesting question is the extent to which
these policy interventions are informed by economic reasoning; that is,
with reference to some form of cost-effectiveness or costbenefit thinking.
The economics of crime covers a wide range of issues, such as the effective deterrence and punishment of criminal activity (see, Di Lulio, 1996,
for a survey). A number of studies have also devoted attention to the economic costs that crime (and the fear of crime) imposes on society.
Interestingly, many of these studies construe the true costs of crime
broadly to include both tangible costs (e.g. financial outlays on personal
security and the criminal justice system) and intangible costs (e.g. the anxiety suffered by potential victims or the pain and suffering imposed on
actual victims). Indeed, for certain types of crimein particular those

Giles Atkinson is lecturer in environmental policy at the London School of Economics and Political
Science (LSE). Susana Mourato is senior lecturer in environmental economics, Department of
Environmental Science and Technology, Imperial College London. Andrew Healey is research
fellow at LSE Health and Social Care.

WORLD ECONOMICS Vol. 4 No. 4 OctoberDecember 2003

79

Giles Atkinson, Susana Mourato & Andrew Healey

entailing violence or the threat of violenceit seems plausible to speculate that this intangible cost will be highly significant.
In this paper we review the findings of recent studies that have sought
to measure the costs of crime.
Firstly, we discuss those approaches that describe the big picture by
calculating the aggregate burden of all crime. While such studies have
yielded useful overall summaries about the magnitude of the crime problem, they have also revealed that surprisingly little is known, for example,
about the value of the intangible effects of crimes that entail actual violence or the credible threat of violence. However, a growing number of
contributions to this literature have begun the process of filling this gap
through novel applications of established valuation methodsused extensively, for example, in environmental economicsto a crime context.
Secondly, we discuss those new (micro) approaches that have sought to
value the preferences of individuals or households for reductions in crime
risks using stated preference methods such as contingent valuation.
Contingent valuation (CV) is a survey-based technique that typically
involves asking respondents to state their willingness to pay (WTP) for
specified policy changes: the elicited amounts are monetary measures of
respondents preferences (Mitchell and Carson, 1989; Bateman et al.,
2002). Although controversial, stated preference approaches are widely
used today to inform policy decisions. Indeed, this use has been codified
in policy-making by the recent publication by the UK Government of a
manual outlining best practice in using these methods in UK policy decisions (see, for example, Bateman et al. 2002). In the context of crime,
much of this work has focused on violent crime risks where the predominant costs are mainly intangible; that is, adverse impacts on well-being
associated with the physical pain and mental distress of victimisation. Of
course, placing a money value on the physical and psychological harm
resulting from violent crime is far from straightforward. Yet neither is it an
impossible task. Moreover, such findings have direct policy relevance
through the provision of valuable and new information about the benefits
of policy initiatives that aim to reduce crime.

2. The aggregate costs of crime


There is now a growing number of studies that seek to quantify the costs

80

WORLD ECONOMICS Vol. 4 No. 4 OctoberDecember 2003

The Costs of Violent Crime

of crime to society. Prominent amongst these contributions are those studies that assess the aggregate burden of criminal offending in a country.
These studies provide useful information primarily by indicating the magnitude of the crime problem, broadly construed, as a percentage of, say,
Gross Domestic Product (GDP) or in per capita terms. Moreover, in using
money values to convey these magnitudes, data, for example, about disparate tangible and intangible consequences of crime are described in a
readily comparable manner. Thus, estimates of aggregate burdens also
reveal useful information about the relative magnitude of the different
components of the costs of crime.
Such information might be a powerful argument for the strengthening
of policy efforts to reduce the incidence of crime. Even so, the specific policy implications of knowing the overall magnitude of the burden of crime
(and its components) are more limited. For example, this information does
not tell us which public policy interventions will be more cost-effective or,
more ambitiously, which will secure the greatest net benefits for society
(although some of the constituent data assembled might plausibly be redirected to this objective). Furthermore, any approach that seeks to paint
the overall picture will use a broad brush. As a result, it is almost inevitable
that some important details concerning gaps in our knowledge about the
intangible costs of crime are tackled in a relatively crude way (perhaps by
gap-filling missing data by borrowing values from other policy contexts).
Nevertheless, it is instructive to consider the question of what is the
money value of the aggregate burden of crime and then, bearing in mind
the above caveats, to consider in more detail how more policy-useful
measures of the benefit of reducing particular types of crime can be constructed. Recent illustrations of studies that have estimated the aggregate
burden of crime can be found for both the United States and the United
Kingdom. For example, in the case of the former, Anderson (1999) examines the problem within a rigorous costbenefit framework. A summary of
Andersons findings is provided in Table 1 and illustrates that the aggregate burden of US crime in 1997 has four components:
Firstly, crime-induced production is defined as expenditures that do not
contribute to welfare except for their association with crime. For example,
this category includes such items as financial outlays to protect ones person or household (so-called defensive expenditures) and the cost of
incarcerating criminals.

WORLD ECONOMICS Vol. 4 No. 4 OctoberDecember 2003

81

Giles Atkinson, Susana Mourato & Andrew Healey

Secondly, opportunity costs are


equal to the lost productivity of
those who spend time securing
Category of crime burden
Value
their assets from theft as well as
the lost productivity of both vicCrime-induced production ($ billion)
397
Opportunity cost ($ billion)
130
tims and offenders. InterestRisks to life and health ($ billion)
574
ingly, while it may seem obvious
Of which:
that the lost work days of victims
Value of lost life ($ billion)
440
is a cost of crime, Anderson also
Value of injuries ($ billion)
135
Transfers ($ billion)
603
imputes a value for the lost (legal)
work days of offenders (both in
Gross burden ($ billion)
1,705
Net burden (net of transfers) ($ billion)
1,102
planning and carrying out crimes
Per capita net burden ($)
4,118
and subsequent jail-time).
Source: Anderson (1999)
Thirdly, being a victim of
Note: Numbers may not sum due to rounding
crime often entails a loss to an
individual in excess of having to
miss work or incur medical expenses. For example, being a victim of a violent criminal assault can lead to a range of physical injuries and symptoms
of mental distress. The category of risks to life and health is intended to capture these intangible costs of crime.
Lastly, the category of transfers refers to the transfer of assets from victims to criminals. Intuitively, many would argue that the value of property
acquired by theft or fraud is a significant cost of crime. However, the cost
benefit approach that Anderson employs indicates that the correct treatment is more complicated. Put simply, costbenefit analysts might argue
that the transfer of assets (from the legal to the illegal economy) as a result
of a theft is purely that: a transfer. As such, it is not a true cost of crime.
The actual reasoning behind this claim is somewhat convoluted but worth
outlining in more detail. The argument is that the transfer of stolen goods
does not necessitate new production. Put another way, a replacement
DVD-player that a householder purchases following a burglary balances
the displaced purchase of the buyer of this stolen good. There are caveats
to this argument. Much will depend on the relative value that victim and
buyer place on the stolen good. For example, the stolen good may be a
family heirloom and hold significant sentimental value for the householder but not the (illegal) buyer. In this case, there is a net loss in the
Table 1: The aggregate burden of
crime in the United States, 1997

82

WORLD ECONOMICS Vol. 4 No. 4 OctoberDecember 2003

The Costs of Violent Crime

transfer of the good from


victim to criminal that
should be counted as a
Category of crime
Value
true cost of crime.
Aggregating these catCrime against households/individuals ( billion)
32.2
Of which:
egories, the gross burden
Murder ( billion)
1.2
(i.e. including transfers as
Wounding ( billion)
15.6
a cost) of crime in 1997
Common assault/robbery/mugging ( billion)
3.7
in the US was $1,705
Sexual offences ( billion)
2.5
Burglary (dwellings only) ( billion)
2.7
billion. This corresponds
Theft (incl. vehicle theft) ( billion)
4.4
to roughly 21% of US
Commercial and public sector victimisation ( billion)
9.1
GDP. Even subtracting
Fraud and forgery ( billion)
13.8
the value of transfers
Traffic/motoring/other ( billion)
4.8
from this total implies
Gross burden of crime ( billion)
59.9
that the net burden of
Per capita gross burden ()
1,015.3
crime is about 13% of US
Source: Brand and Price (1999)
GDP. Taking these findings at face value, it is
clear that crime places a huge drain on the economic resources of
the US.
A study by Brand and Price (2000) also found that the aggregate burden
of crime is highly significant for the United Kingdom. While this study differs in important ways to the research previously discussed, it covers the
same broad categories of crime burden (e.g. opportunity costs, crimeinduced production, risks to life and health, and transfers). However, the
authors in the UK case summarise their findings in terms of the costs of
particular types of crime. These are summarised in Table 2 and include
crimes against households and individuals, commercial and public sector
victimisation, fraud and forgery, and traffic/motoring and other miscellaneous crimes. Table 2 indicates that in a 12-month period over 1999/2000,
the aggregate burden of crime in the UK was 59.9 billion. This corresponds to about 7% of UK GDP. It should be noted that this total includes
transfers as Brand and Price include the full value of stolen assets as a cost
of crime. Even including this item as a true cost of crime, however, it is
apparent that this aggregate value is somewhat smaller in the UK than that
for the US case.
Table 2: The aggregate burden of crime in
the United Kingdom, 1999/2000

WORLD ECONOMICS Vol. 4 No. 4 OctoberDecember 2003

83

Giles Atkinson, Susana Mourato & Andrew Healey

3. Valuing the intangible costs of crime


An interesting aspect of both studies is the significance of intangible costs
in determining the aggregate burden of crime. In the US case, Table 1
indicates these intangibles (described in the table as risks to life and
health) are roughly one-third of the gross burden and roughly one-half of
the net burden of crime. Indeed, the sum of crime-induced production and
opportunity costs of crime is less than the value of risks to life and health. In
the UK case, Table 2 indicates that crime against households and individuals is the largest component of the aggregate (gross) burden of crime.
While not reported in the table, the study by Brand and Price estimates
that more than half of the 32.2 billion imputed to this category of criminal offence is attributable to the intangible costs arising from being a victim of crimes that entail physical injury or mental distress.
Both of these studies have sought to value the intangible costs of crime
using a range of secondary data. For example, Anderson (1999) bases his
estimates for the US on the value of statistical injuries from wage-risk
studies. Brand and Price (2000) base their conclusions on transferring estimates of the value of statistical injuries sustained in road traffic accidents.
While useful as a first approximation of the intangible costs of crime, if values are sensitive to the context in which injuries are sustained then this
value transfer method may not be reliable: Will people place a different
value on risks that occur in a crime context than, say, in a road traffic accident context? There are a number of reasons to believe that this is indeed
the case. These reasons include the very different nature of the risk (i.e. it
is involuntary rather than voluntary as in the workplace case) and the fact
that the exact nature of the injuries and, in particular, mental distress
sustained by crime victims, is also likely to be different from other risk
contexts.
Hence, there is increasing interest in attempts to value intangible costs
within a crime-specific context. An early example, using revealed preference methods, is a hedonic study of US house prices by Thaler (1978).
This estimated the implied willingness to pay for a reduction in the level
of (general) criminal offending as implied by house price variations.
Clearly, an advantage of this approach is that the information in market
prices reflects actual behaviour. However, there are also important limitations, including the inability to unbundle the costs of specific types of

84

WORLD ECONOMICS Vol. 4 No. 4 OctoberDecember 2003

The Costs of Violent Crime

offendingsee Gibbons (2002) for a more recent application to the UK


housing market. In addition, pioneering work by Cohen (1988) and Miller
et al. (1996) sought to evaluate the loss of quality of life resulting from
being the victim of a crime with reference to (US) jury compensation
awards for victims of physical assault. Despite concerns over the high variability observed for US compensation awards, Cohen (2001) points to evidence showing that jury awards can be predicted statistically according to
the severity of the crime.
The work by Cohen and others provides an illustration of those studies
that have tried to calculate the costs of specific types of crime, such as violent crime, using monetary values derived in an explicitly crime context.
More recently, a handful of studies have directly elicited willingness to pay
for reductions in the level of violent criminal offending using stated preference methods, such as the CV method. CV, for example, has been frequently applied to health and safety contextsmost notably in relation to
improved transport safety and health risks imposed by air pollution (see,
for example, Jones-Lee et al. 1985; Jones-Lee et al. 1995; Krupnick et al.
2002). A detailed overview of the literature on the valuation of public
health risks is provided by Hammitt and Graham (1999).
Cook and Ludwig (2000) and Ludwig and Cook (2001), in apparently
the first published CV study undertaken in a crime context, value the prevention of non-fatal incidents of gun-related violence in the US.
Respondents were askedusing the dichotomous choice format (i.e.
answering yes or no to a stated money value)whether they would
pay a specified dollar amount (which varied across respondents) for a specified dollar tax increase in return for a 30% reduction in gun injuries. The
results indicate that respondents place a high value on crime reduction
and thus appear to justify substantial public policy interventions to reduce
the incidence of gun crime in the US. Mean (annual) willingness to pay
per person for a 30% reduction in gunshot wounds was estimated to lie
between $203 and $239. In turn, this implied an aggregate value of a (statistical) gunshot wound of between $1,000,000 and $1,200,000. In other
words, this is the range of the typical (intangible) cost of a gunshot wound
in the US.
Cohen et al. (2001), again using CV, asked respondents to value the benefits of US public programmes to reduce criminal offending associated
with burglary, serious assaults, armed robbery, rape or sexual assault, and

WORLD ECONOMICS Vol. 4 No. 4 OctoberDecember 2003

85

Giles Atkinson, Susana Mourato & Andrew Healey

murder. Mean (annual) willingness to pay to reduce incidents of these


crimes by 10% was estimated to range between $111 for burglary to $147
for murder. Interestingly, this implied a value of a (statistical) crime of
$30,000 for the former and $9,700,000 for the latter.

4. Improving estimates of intangible crime costs


Studies of the valuation of intangible costs of violent crime are an important step forward in understanding the consequences of violent offending
for the well-being of victims. Of course, violent crime encompasses a
wide range of offences and outcomes. Hence, in order for these data to be
directly useful in crime policy evaluations, it is important that the criminal
offence end-points to be valued match those categories of offence actually
monitored by policy-makers. For example, in the UK such end-points
might correspond to the classification system adopted by the British
Crime Survey (BCS) and reported in studies such as Kershaw et al. (2000).
These are:
1. Common Assault (BCS code 13): Injury inflicted was trivial or
negligible.
2. Other Wounding (BCS code 12): Injury inflicted i.e. substantial bruising,
cuts, etc., but not amounting to a serious wound.
3. Serious Wounding (BCS code 11). Either: (a) Offender intended to
inflict really serious wound, or (b) A really serious wound was
inflicted and therefore risk of permanent injury or damage (medical
attention needed immediately for (b)).
In the first application of a CV study to the context of violent crime in
the United Kingdom, Atkinson et al. (2003) focused upon these three levels of offence; specifically, to elicit an individuals WTP to reduce the risk
of being a victim of each of these violent offences. This study focuses on
three specific types of violent crime not analysed in detail in previous
work. Moreover, these crimes correspond to categories of offence routinely
monitored by the UK Home Office. A final novelty of this study is that it
directs substantial attention to the construction of descriptions (to be
administered to respondents) of the likely health outcomes that victims of
violent crime, on average, are likely to suffer. These include the physical

86

WORLD ECONOMICS Vol. 4 No. 4 OctoberDecember 2003

The Costs of Violent Crime

injuries and psychological distress likely to be associated with being a victim of a violent assault.
Perhaps unsurprisingly, it turns out that the process of eliciting these
values is every bit as interesting as the outcome in terms of the findings
themselves. For example, even if it can be assumed that these categories
of offence and their consequences for victims are well understood by
experts in the crime policy field, such characterisations are far less likely
to be meaningful to the wider public. Of course, it is a sample of the latter
that comprises the respondents in a CV study. This means that, in designing a CV scenario to elicit WTP, respondents need to be presented with a
comparable but meaningful description of the symptoms likely to be suffered after a criminal offence. Moreover, this description must provide as
clear a signal as possible as to the way in which these symptoms would
affect lives and well-being.
The approach taken by Atkinson et al. was to describe these crime outcomes in terms of the experience for a typical victim. In other words, what
was conveyed to respondents was the idea that if they were to be subjected to an assault of a given severity tomorrow, then it would be reasonable to expect them, on average, to experience a core set of adverse
health outcomes. In turn, the basis for selecting this core set of symptoms
was through an extensive review of the relevant medical literature, as well
as expert advice from the field. In particular, this available evidence indicates that the most important categories of outcomes relate to physical
injuries (perhaps requiring medical treatment) as well as a potential array
of symptoms of mental distress, such as those characterising an episode of
acute or long-term psychological reaction to a traumatic event. Table 3
summarises the physical injury and mental distress descriptions used by
Atkinson et al. Thus, common assault was described to respondents as
entailing no injury and short-term distress whereas other wounding was said to
result in moderate injury and medium-term distress. Lastly, serious wounding
was described as involving serious injury and long-term distress.
Turning now to the findings of this application of CV to violent crime
prevention in the United Kingdom, we limit our discussion to summarising the basic WTP results and their implications for calculating the costs
of violent crime in the UK. (See Atkinson et al. 2003 for a fuller discussion
of study description, results/analysis and caveats.) Each respondent was
asked to consider the benefits to themselves of reducing the risk of

WORLD ECONOMICS Vol. 4 No. 4 OctoberDecember 2003

87

88
Medium-term distress profile
Repeated recollections of assault
Difficulty falling asleep or staying asleep
(one or two nights each week)
Difficulty concentrating on daily tasks
Symptoms last for two weeks

Short-term distress profile


Repeated recollections of assault
Feel shaken for a few hours after the assault

Symptoms last for one to two days

Minor physical discomfort for three weeks


followed by complete recovery

Moderate injury profile


Cuts and grazes
Extensive bruising to body and face
No medical attention required
Bruising to the body

No injury profile
None

Note: Adapted from Atkinson et al. (2003)

Psychological
distress

Physical injury

Other wounding

Common assault

Table 3: Injury descriptions

Long-term distress profile


Repeated recollections of assault
Difficulty falling asleep or
staying asleep (one or two nights
each week)
Difficulty concentrating on daily tasks
Feelings of nervousness
Symptoms last for six months

Serious injury profile


Concussion
Cuts (needing stitches)
Two broken ribs
Immediate medical attention required
and two nights in hospital
Pain and discomfort for a month
followed by complete recovery

Serious wounding

Giles Atkinson, Susana Mourato & Andrew Healey

WORLD ECONOMICS Vol. 4 No. 4 OctoberDecember 2003

The Costs of Violent Crime

Table 4: The cost of crime reduction: WTP and implied cost of statistical
crimes (/crime/year)

Variable
WTP
(Common assault)
WTP
(Other wounding)
WTP
(Serious wounding)

Risk of crime

WTP for risk reduction

Cost of statistical crime

Baseline risk (risk reduction)

Mean (95% CI)

Mean (95% CI)

4%
(2%)
1%
(0.5%)
1%
(0.5%)

106.31
(72.93139.69)
154.29
(108.21200.37)
178.33
(124.70231.96)

5,316
(3,8837,276)
30,858
(22,85841,548)
35,666
(26,40448,178)

Notes:
1. Adapted from Atkinson et al. (2003)
2. Calculated using parametric statistics on WTP.
3. CI: confidence interval.
4. Common assault (no injury + short-term psychological distress): risk reduction 2%
5. Other wounding (moderate injury + medium-term psychological distress): risk reduction 0.5%
6. Serious wounding (serious injury + long-term psychological distress): risk reduction 0.5%

suffering the health outcomes associated with one of the three types of
violent assault described in Table 3. Respondents were also informed of
the pre-policy risk of the incident (and its outcomes) occurring (column 2
in Table 4). These specified risks were an approximation of the actual
(average) risks of being a victim of a violent assault currently faced by a
member of the public in the UK. Each respondent was then asked to
express his or her WTP to reduce his or her chance of being a victim of
this offence by 50% over the next 12 months. The payment vehicle for
this change was a one-off increase in local charges for law enforcement.
This payment was justified to respondents as a contribution to the costs of
reducing the incidence of violent crime in the area where they live.
Table 4 (column 3) reports the mean WTP to reduce the risk of various
crime offences. The results show that mean WTP increases with the
severity of injury described to respondents. This is consistent with the
theory underpinning the use of WTP as a measure of value in that we
would naturally expect people to pay more where the severity of an
offence is increased. Note that although the severity of the incident is considerably higher for both other wounding and serious wounding when compared to common assault, the (baseline) risk (column 2) of being a victim of
these offences (1%) is four times smaller than the risk of suffering a

WORLD ECONOMICS Vol. 4 No. 4 OctoberDecember 2003

89

Giles Atkinson, Susana Mourato & Andrew Healey

common assault (4%). However, while it can be shown that meaningful statistical differences are found between WTP for reducing the risk of common assault and WTP to reduce the risk of serious wounding, this is not the
case between the other mean amounts. This is probably due to a combination of the large variation in individual responses and the relatively
small sample sizes available for each sub-sample. In all, there were 522
usable responses; however, each respondent was only asked to value one
category of criminal offence. In particular, it cannot be assumed that valuing violent crime is an easy or palatable cognitive task for people, and studies such as this represent only first forays into this important policy
domain.
From the point of view of estimating the costs of crime or the benefits
of policy interventions that seek to reduce crime by a given (predicted)
number of offences, a useful indicator is the cost of a statistical crime. Put
another way, this transformation gives the implied amount that the average individual would be willing to pay to avoid a violent crime happening
with certainty. It is this price which can be multiplied by the number of
incidents per year of a specific type of crime to obtain an estimate of the
aggregate costs of these three categories of violent crime. As an illustration, for the no injury (common assault) case, mean WTP for a 2% risk
reduction is 106.31, giving a value of 53.16 per percentage reduction in
risk. Multiplied by 100 this yields 5,316 as the estimate of the value of a
statistical common assault. If we multiply this value (i.e. 5,316) by the
number of incidents of common assault in a given year in the UK, then we
can provide an estimate of aggregate (annual) cost of this category of
offence.
Using data drawn from the 2001/2 British Crime Survey (Simmons et al.
2002), Table 5 summarises the number of incidents of common assault and
wounding (other- and serious-) and the aggregate costs of these categories of
offence. With regards to the number of incidents, column 2 indicates that,
particularly in the case of common assault, the risks of being a victim are far
from being trivially small. Column 3 makes it plain that this volume of
incidents involving violent crime therefore translates into a substantial
annual burden for society. Note that these coststhe product of the number of incidents of a category of offence and its cost per (statistical)
crimerefer only to the intangible costs of these crimes, i.e. the cost of the
pain and suffering inflicted on victims. It is also worth noting that Table 5

90

WORLD ECONOMICS Vol. 4 No. 4 OctoberDecember 2003

The Costs of Violent Crime

Table 5: The aggregate (intangible) cost of violent crime in England and


Wales, 2000/1

Common assault
Other wounding
Serious wounding
Total ( million)
Percentage of GDP (%)

No. of incidents (000s)

Intangible costs of crime ( million)

1,791
1,578
1, 81

9,521
17,822
2,905
30,248
3.0

Notes:
1. Underlying data on number of incidents adapted from Simmons and colleagues (2002). These are based on BCS interviews carried out in
a 12-month period over 2001/2. BCS respondents are asked to recall their experience of crime over the previous 12 months. Hence, these
data over the period during which the CV study in Atkinson et al. (2003) was implemented.
2. Simmons and Colleagues (2002) summarise data for total wounding only (659,000). Number of other- and serious-wounding incidents
estimated using information in Brand and Price (2000).
3. Numbers may not sum due to rounding.
4. GDP refers to Gross Domestic Product for United Kingdom (average of GDP for the years 2000 and 2001).

does not include other (official) categories of offence, such as robbery,


which frequently entail either the threat of or actual violence. Finally, the
findings on aggregate costs in Table 5 are not directly comparable with the
results of Brand and Price (2000) (see Table 2) as, for example, different
data on the number of incidents are used; however, see Atkinson et al.
(2003) for a discussion of the differences between costs per crime between
these two studies.
Turning now to the actual estimates of intangible costs of crime in
England and Wales over the period (mid) 2000 to (mid) 2001 (Table 5, column 3), it can be seen that the largest burden of about 17.8 billion is
imposed by the category of other wounding. The most frequent offence
common assaultis ranked second in terms of the magnitude of its aggregate (intangible) costs (9.5 billion). The overall intangible costs of
incidents involving serious wounding are ranked third, although these costs
still correspond to some 2.9 billion over the 2000/1 period. There are two
reasons for this last ranking. On the one hand, there are relatively fewer of
these offences (column 2). On the other hand, as discussed above, in practical terms the cost of an incident entailing serious wounding is not substantially higher than that of an incident entailing what would appear to be
far less serious outcomes. Such caveats notwithstanding, the total costs of
these crimes (estimated using crime-specific WTP data) are considerable30 billion, or about 3.0% of GDP.

WORLD ECONOMICS Vol. 4 No. 4 OctoberDecember 2003

91

Giles Atkinson, Susana Mourato & Andrew Healey

5. Concluding remarks
Our discussion has, in effect, come full circle. We began by describing two
recent studies that tried to estimate the aggregate cost or burden of crime,
which we described in terms of an effort to understand the big picture.
In doing so, we drew attention to the paucity of data in such studies, and
more generally, about the intangible costs of crime. As a result, studies of
aggregate costs of crime typically are forced to borrow value data elicited
in non-crime contexts. However, we also noted emerging interest in applying, to the crime context, stated preference methods such as CV used
extensively in other fields such as environmental policy. In particular, we
illustrated a recent example that used a CV study to elicit WTP to reduce
the risk of three different categories of violent crime in England and
Wales. Finally, we showed how the findings of that particular study can be
used to illustrate the aggregate costs of these crimes. The major distinction between this last example and the studies discussed in the first part
of this paper is that the former uses WTP data derived in an explicit crimecontext. Such studies are an important development.
Of course, understanding the big picture is just one application of
these data on the intangible costs of crime. Just as importantly, this information could enable better costbenefit comparisons by allowing a more
thorough appraisal of the benefits of policies that seek to reduce the incidence of violent crime. The studies we have described in the latter part of
this paper can be characterised as the first steps in facilitating this policy
application. Moving beyond these exploratory efforts would suggest the
need for further work in the application of stated preference methods to
crime reduction policies. Hence, the answers that policy-makers require
will not be available immediately. In the interim, this also suggests that
WTP data borrowed from existing similar but non-crime valuation studies remains a worthwhile first approximation. However, to reiterate, if context matters, monetary values derived from studies designed in an explicitly
crime context are ultimately a necessity.
Whilst there can be little argument against the view that valuing the
intangible costs of crime is an inherently challenging task, it is arguably
then less easy to justify avoiding doing so. It is an inescapable fact that in
a resource-constrained public policy environment, decision-makers
already place implicit valuations on crime and its impact on victims via the

92

WORLD ECONOMICS Vol. 4 No. 4 OctoberDecember 2003

The Costs of Violent Crime

relative public spending priorities that are given to different policies that
target criminal offending. A more explicit assessment is needed of the
monetary value of crime reduction, not just to improve the transparency of
public decision making but also to ensure that policy benefits can be compared directly with the costs of implementation. Whilst economic considerations are not the sole criterion for judging the desirability of specific
crime prevention programmes, this might lead to more consistent priority
setting where decision making is (at least partly) concerned with allocating available resources to maximum social advantage.
References
Anderson, D.A. (1999) The Aggregate Burden of Crime, Journal of Law and
Economics.
Atkinson, G., Healey, A. and Mourato, S. (2003) Valuing the Costs of Violent Crime:
A Stated Preference Approach, London School of Economics and Political Science,
mimeo.
Bateman, I., Carson, R.T., Day, B., Hanemann, M., Hanley, N., Hett, T., Jones-Lee,
M., Loomes, G., Mourato, S., Ozdemiroglu, E., Pearce, D.W., Sugden, R. and
Swanson, J. (2002) Economic Valuation with Stated Preference Techniques: A Manual,
Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.
Brand, S. and Price, P. (2000) The Economic and Social Costs of Crime, London: Home
Office Research Study 217.
Cohen, M.A. (1988) Pain, Suffering, and Jury Awards: A Study of the Costs of Crime
to Victims, Law and Society Review, 22: 538555.
Cohen, M.A. (2001) The Crime Victims Perspective in CostBenefit Analysis: The
Importance of Monetising Tangible and Intangible Crime Costs, in Welsh, B.,
Farrington, D.P. and Sherman, L.W. (eds.) The Costs and Benefits of Preventing Crime,
Colorado: Westview Press.
Cohen, M.A., Rust, R.T., Steen, S. and Tidd, S. (2001) Willingness to Pay for Crime
Control Programs, Vanderbilt University, mimeo.
Cook, P.J. and Ludwig, J. (2000) Gun Violence: The Real Costs, Oxford: Oxford
University Press.

WORLD ECONOMICS Vol. 4 No. 4 OctoberDecember 2003

93

Giles Atkinson, Susana Mourato & Andrew Healey

Corso, P.S., Hammitt, J.K. and Graham, J.D. (2001) Valuing Mortality-Risk
Reduction: Using Visual Aids to Improve the Validity of Contingent Valuation,
Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 23: 16584.
Di Lulio, J.J. (1996) Help Wanted: Economists, Crime and Public Policy, Journal of
Economic Perspectives, 10(1): 324.
Gibbons, S. (2002) The Costs of Urban Property Crime, London School of
Economics and Political Science, mimeo.
Hammitt, J.K. and Graham, J.D. (1999) Willingness to Pay for Health Protection:
Inadequate Sensitivity to Probability?, Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 18: 3362.
Jones-Lee, M.W., Hammerton, M. and Phillips, P.R. (1985) The Value of Safety:
Results from a National Sample Survey, Economic Journal, 95: 4972.
Jones-Lee, M.W., Loomes, G. and Phillips, P.R. (1995) Valuing the Prevention of
Non-Fatal Injuries: Contingent Valuation vs. Standard Gambles, Oxford Economic
Papers, 47: 676695.
Kershaw, C., Budd, T., Kinshott, G., Mattinson, J., Mayhew, P. and Myhill, A. (2000)
The 2000 British Crime Survey, England and Wales, London: Home Office.
Krupnick, A., Alberini, A., Cropper, M., Simon, N., OBrien, B., Goeree, R. and
Heintzelman, M. (2002) Age, Health and the Willingness to Pay for Mortality Risk
Reductions: A Contingent Valuation Survey of Ontario Residents, Journal of Risk and
Uncertainty, 24(2): 161186.
Ludwig, J. and Cook, P.J. (2001) The Benefits of Reducing Gun Violence: Evidence
from Contingent Valuation Survey Data, Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 22(3):
207226.
Miller, T.R., Cohen, M.A. and Wiersma, B. (1996) Victim Costs and Consequences: A New
Look, US Department of Justice, National Institute of Justice, Washington D.C.
Mitchell, R. and Carson, R. (1989) Using Surveys to Value Public Goods: The Contingent
Valuation Method, Resources for the Future, Washington.
Simmons, J. and Colleagues (2002) Crime in England and Wales, 2001/2, Home Office,
London.
Thaler, R. (1978) A Note on the Value of Crime Control: Evidence from the
Property Market, Journal of Urban Economics, 5: 137145.

94

WORLD ECONOMICS Vol. 4 No. 4 OctoberDecember 2003

You might also like