You are on page 1of 3

Trade One of the most lively and long-lived historical controversies centers on the causes of

British anti-slavery policies during the first years of the nineteenth century. Participants in this
debate dispute whether the health of the West Indian sugar industry had any impact on the
decision to abolish the slave trade in 1807. Advocates of what is commonly referred to as the
"Decline Thesis" believe that slavery's faltering profitability mandated abolition, whereas the
opposition tends to reject the very notion of economic hardship in the West Indies. Recent
historians tend to fall into this latter camp, their research focusing on how social and cultural
changes within England provided a fertile environment for reform movements to flourish. This
line of thought argues that the industrialization of Britain introduced new systems of production,
trade, and politics that fostered the emergence of the antislavery movement as the major
philanthropic agenda of the day. Despite these two differing opinions regarding the fundamental
cause of Britain's first major assault on slavery, both positions have relied upon economic theory
and application to bolster their points of view.
New evidence presented in this article resurrects the argument that planters were facing rapid
decline at the turn of the nineteenth century. Both sugar prices and estimated slave prices culled
from the Jamaica Archives confirm the contemporary commentary that outlines the problem of
"overproduction," which led to a financial crisis among British planters on the eve of the slave
trade's abolition. Previous studies have ignored both variations in transport costs and the
runaway inflation of the late-eighteenth century, creating an overoptimistic portrait of planters'
prospects and erroneously eliminating the role of West Indies from the abolition equation.
THE RISE AND FALL OF THE DECLINE THESIS In the mid-twentieth century, the most
popular explanation of the slave trade's demise came from the Manichean model of world history
purveyed by Clarkson--the first chronicler of British abolition and an active participant in the
fight to destroy the trade. The "Clarksonian" point of view pictured abolition as the consequence
of a divinely guided confluence of Christian thinkers toward social change within the empire, as
his diagram, reproduced in Figure 1, illustrates.
Clarkson's story of Christian progress remained the conventional interpretation of abolition a
century after the publication of his history. Coupland, the pre-eminent early-twentieth-century
scholar of British anti-slavery, echoed much of Clarkson's sentiment in his account of the
movement, though he saw the struggle not between good and evil but between morality and
national self-interest. According to Coupland, the slave system was a necessity" for Britain after
the loss of the North American colonies. Upon surveying "what was left of the old Empire,"
Parliament chose to follow a policy that protected the status quo of all economic arrangements,
including that of West Indian black-white relations and the slave trade. Subsequently, the early
anti-slave- trade campaigners became persona non grata in the eyes of the establishment.
Coupland interpreted the eventual success of the movement as a tribute to the single-mindedness
of the abolitionist "Saints" to raise public consciousness above the nation's economi c-self
interest. [2]

Williams' seminal book, Capitalism and Slavery, viciously attacked Coupland and other
followers of the Clarksonian tradition, claiming that they "sacrificed scholarship to
sentimentality and ... placed faith before reason and evidence." In Williams' view, Anglo
researchers had neglected to investigate the possibility of more worldly and structural causes of
slavery's destruction. Williams explained that previous studies had artificially inflated the
importance of the sugar industry in order to glorify the achievement of the abolitionists, thereby
failing to recognize the underlying materialist causes behind the prohibition of slave trading.
Earlier historians missed the fact that the new capitalistic economy had no need for the arcane
labor system of slavery. The success of British free trade following the American Revolution,
coupled with the publication of Adam Smith's The Wealth of Nations (Glasgow, 1776), exposed
the fact that the riches generated by the mercantilist system were actually a fiction on the
empire's balance sheet. Furthermore, a decline in both the importance and profitability of the
sugar industry made the slave system an outdated mode of production in a burgeoning
capitalistic economy. The cessation of the British slave trade had little to do with the evangelical
abolitionist movement in Britain and everything to do with the faltering profitability and political
influence of West Indian sugar producers. [3]
Capitalism and Slavery's narrative is a precursor of the world system model of economic
development that Karl Marx inspired; the early portion of the book links Britain's wealth to the
exploitation of the world's lesser-developed economies. Nevertheless, the heart of Williams'
argument that connects abolition and economic decline is based on a neoclassical economic
theory. Based on Ragatz's The Fall of the Planter Class, Capitalism and Slavery maintains that
the first planters enjoyed tremendous profits because they were early entrants into an industry
that was situated to enjoy a long-term rise in demand. The early slaveholders had not only the
best soils in the British West Indies but also the protection afforded by the Navigation Acts,
which guaranteed high sugar prices and exclusive trading privileges with North American
suppliers. Whether by design or by good fortune, the first sugar growers in Barbados, Jamaica,
and the smaller sugar islands amassed huge fortunes throughout the 100 years after I650. [4]
This trade policy, however, could not protect British sugar growers from increasing competition
within the empire. Ragatz suggested that the first blow came at the end of the Seven Years' War,
when Britain was poised to expand its Caribbean holdings. Established planters lobbied hard
against Britain's acquisition of additional sugar islands during the Peace of Paris. They were
successful in keeping Guadeloupe and Martinique under French rule, but they could not prevent
the cession of Grenada, the Grenadines, Dominica, St. Vincent, and Tobago to British rule. These
new islands with their fresh soil helped to accelerate Britain's expanding sugar economy.
McCusker estimates that between 1750 and 1775, British West Indian production more than
doubled; the contribution of the ceded islands enhanced production by 20 percent. Grenada alone
exported, on average, 12,000 hogsheads per year (a hogshead being roughly 1700 lb during this
period) to England after 1770. [5]

North American revolutionary politics intensified planters' economic pressures. The American
Revolution created a short- term crisis that, in Williams' words, introduced "the first stage in the
decline of the sugar colonies." During this period, planters were "entirely cut off from usual
Supplies from America." Food, in particular, became scarce, and slaves suffered the worst
consequences. Williams highlighted the financial crisis that ensued by noting the high mortality
rate of slaves during the Revolution. In Jamaica, 15,000 of them died of famine between 1780
and 1787. This catastrophe was even greater in the Leeward Islands and in Barbados, where the
majority of fields were devoted exclusively to sugar production, leaving planters unable to use
locally grown provisions to feed their workers. When prices for such goods as flour, Indian corn,
and salted meats doubled during the hostilities, most estate owners had to call a moratorium on
slavery's century-long expansion. Planter interest in slavery waned du ring the Revolution, and
during the first year of warfare, slave traders were forced to sail from island to island with little
hope of selling their cargo, despite low prices. [6]
For Williams, the importance of the Revolution lay not in its short-term effect, but in how it
revealed the inherent weakness of the crumbling mercantilist system and the artificiality of West
Indian wealth. The Williams' thesis claims that slavery did not come to an end because of
humanitarian or spiritual reform but because of its association with an arcane system of labor
that encouraged sugar output to be in excess of demand. The net wealth and profits generated
from the Caribbean sugar industry were no longer critical to the empire's economy. Williams
accordingly advised researchers to describe facts in ways "that you can touch and see, to be
measured in pounds sterling or pounds avoirdupois, in dollars and cents, yards, feet and inches,"
rather than in moral or spiritual terms. [7]
This call for empiricism did not go unheeded. Ironically, many subsequent economic and
quantitative studies were highly critical of Capitalism and Slavery. Drescher, the book's most
prominent critic, attacked Williams by questioning the basis for the decline narrative. He argued
that slavery was hardly a moribund institution in the years following the American Revolution.

You might also like