You are on page 1of 6

Definition of Safety and the Existence of “Optimal Safety”

D. Proske
University of Natural Resources and Applied Life Sciences, Institute of Mountain Risk Engineering, Vienna,
Austria

ABSTRACT: In this paper a definition of the term “safety” based on freedom of resources is introduced. Such
freedom of resources can also be used for the definition of the terms “danger” and “disaster”. Additionally the
terms “safety”, “danger” and “disaster” can be correlated to time horizons of planning. The introduced rela-
tionships will then be used for the discussion, whether “optimal safety” is achievable or not. Currently, “op-
timal safety” is being intensively discussed in many disciplines such as the field of structural safety. Consid-
ering the definition of “safety” this paper will show that “optimal safety” is rather a theoretical issue and can
not be achieved under real world conditions. This statement fits very well not only to considerations in the
field of system theory, but also to empirical observations. It is suggested, that the term “optimal safety” is in-
troduced as an assurance measure for engineers rather than for the public. As a solution the concept of inte-
gral risk management is introduced. One of the properties of this concept is the possibility of continuous im-
provement and therefore no optimal solution is claimed.

1 INTRODUCTION tage-disadvantage-analysis to a cost-benefit-analysis


is the inclusion of further advantages and disadvan-
1.1 Current developments
tages, which might not be directly presented as eco-
Over the last few years the question of optimal nomic values. For examples sometimes additional
safety has been discussed intensively in many fields measures such as those found within the quality of
such as structural engineering. This question is of life parameters are incorporated. Dimensions of such
particular interest for the development of general factors are shown in Fig. 2. The application of such
safety requirements. For example, within the last quality of life parameters has a long tradition in
decades, the general safety concept in structural en- medicine, and has been applied in structural engi-
gineering has been updated from the global safety neering for approximately one decade. For example
factor concept to the semi-probabilistic safety con- the Life Quality Index (LQI) by Nathwani et al.
cept initiating debates regarding the optimal safety (1997) has become widely used in several engineer-
of structures. ing fields (Proske 2004, 2008).
The question of optimal safety has been mainly
answered through the economical optimization of
the spending of resources. This includes the impor-
tant and true consideration that resources for humans Overall costs
Costs

and societies are limited. Minimum


In structural engineering usually the sum of the overall cost
production cost and the cost of failure (disadvan-
tages) are compared with the possible gains of creat-
ing such a structure (advantages). The combination
of these two cost components mentioned gives an Production cost Cost of failure
overall cost function with a minimum value accord- Parameters
ing to some adaptable structural design parameters
included, for example the chosen concrete strength
Figure 1. Widely used function of overall structural cost de-
(Fig. 1). This overall cost function is based on eco- pending on several parameters
nomic considerations. It is actually a cost-benefit
analysis, or, how it may be called here: an advan-
tage-disadvantage-analysis. The difference of advan-
Returning to the original question, the terms
“safety” and “optimal safety” still need to be de-
fined.

2 TERMS
2.1 The term “Safety”
The term “safety” is often defined as a situation with
a lower risk compared to an acceptable risk or as a
situation “without any danger impending”. Other
definitions describe safety as “peace of mind”.
Whereas the first definition using the term risk is al-
Figure 2. Dimension of quality of life according to Küchler &
Schreiber (1989)
ready based on a substitution, the later term using
“peace of mind” is a better definition. The author
considers “safety” to be the result of an evaluation
process of a certain situation. The evaluation can be
1.2 Limitation of the current developments carried out by every system that is able to perform a
Although the search for performance measures as a decision making process, such as animals, humans,
basis of optimization procedures has yielded in societies or computers which use some algorithms.
many fields to the application of quality of life pa- However, algorithms usually use some numerical
rameters, it does not necessarily mean that this strat- representation such as risk R for the description of
egy has been successful. It shows only that entirely safety S:
pecuniary based performance measures might be in- existing R ≤ permitted R → S
sufficient. If one considers for example the history (1)
existing R > permitted R → S
of quality of life measures in medicine since 1948,
one will find that now a huge variety of such pa- In contrast, the author considers human feelings
rameters (more than 1200) have been developed for as a result of a decision-making process. Therefore
very special applications. Such a specialization re- safety is understood here as a feeling. The decision-
quires major assumptions inside the parameters. For making process focuses mainly on preservation. Fur-
example, the LQI assumes a trade-off between thermore the decision-making process deals with,
working time and leisure time for individuals. Al- whether some resources have to be spent to decrease
though this might be true for some people, most hazards and danger to an acceptable level. In other
people enjoy working (von Cube 1997) if the work- terms “safety” is a feeling, which describes that no
ing conditions and the working content is fitting to further resources have to be spent to decrease any
personal preferences. The choice of using the aver- threats. If one considers the term “no further re-
age lifetime as a major indicator for damage has also sources have to be spent” as a degree of freedom of
been criticized (Proske 2004, but see also Müller resources, one can define “safety” as a value of a
2002). The question, whether a quality of life pa- function which includes the degree of freedom of re-
rameter can be constructed on only a very limited sources. Furthermore one can assume, that the de-
number of parameters still remains. Again Fig. 2 gree of freedom is related to some degree of distress
should be mentioned as giving an impression about and relaxation. Whereas in safe conditions relaxa-
the dimensions of quality of life (Küchler & Schrei- tion occurs, in dangerous situations a high degree of
ber 1989). distress is clearly reached.
The comparison between the different dimensions The possible shape of the function between de-
and the simplified definition of the LQI makes limi- gree of relaxation which ranges from “danger” to
tations visible. For example, many psychological ef- “peace of mind” and the value of the function as de-
fects are not considered. Since people are so gree of freedom of resources is shown in Fig. 3. It is
strongly affected by their individual, social and cul- assumed here, that the relationship is non-linear with
tural experience, these effects can rarely be excluded at least one region of over-proportional growth of
in quality of life measures and even further in deci- the relative freedom of resources. In Fig. 3 this re-
sion-making processes. Many works have been done gion of over-proportional growth is defined as the
in this field such as Fischhoff et al. (1981), Slovic starting point of the safety region:
(1999), Covello (1991), Zwick & Renn (2002) or
Schütz et al. (2003). For a general summary see S = { x | f ′′( x) = 0} (2)
Proske (2008).
However, the question still remains, where the
region of safety starts since other points are possible.
In Fig. 4 further points are shown considering either
regions of maximum curvature or the point of inflec-
tion. 1.0

Relative horizon of planning


Relative freedom of resources

1.0

0.0

Safety Danger and fear Peace of mind


Degree of relaxation
0.0
Figure 6. Assumed relationship between degree of relaxation
Danger and fear Peace of mind and relative horizon of planning
Degree of relaxation

Figure 3. Assumed function shape between degree of relaxa-

Relative freedom of resources


tion and relative freedom of resources 1.0
Relative freedom of resources

1.0 Yerkes-Dodson-Curve
c of m aximum human
performance

b 0.0
Safety
Danger and fear Peace of mind
a
Degree of relaxation
0.0
Figure 7. Assumed function shape between degree of relaxa-
tion and relative freedom of resources with the Yerkes-
Danger and fear Peace of mind
Dodson-curve as a relationship between human performance
Degree of relaxation and degree of distress

Figure 4. Assumed function shape between degree of relaxa-


tion and relative freedom of resources with different starting
Relative freedom of resources

1.0
points of the safety region
Creation of threats No perceived
threats
Relative freedom of resources

1.0

0.0

Danger and fear Peace of mind


Degree of relaxation
0.0
Figure 8. Assumed function shape between degree of relaxa-
Danger and fear Peace of mind
Disaster tion and relative freedom of resources and the return curvature
Degree of relaxation

-0.5

Figure 5. Assumed function shape between degree of relaxa-


tion and relative freedom of resources with the definition of a
disaster region with negative resources (the need for external
help)
The degree of relaxation (DoR) can be evaluated instead “optimal safety” is defined as a condition,
based on a function considering the input variables: which yields to a maximum performance of humans.
Such maximum performance is described in relation
DoR = f (a, b, c, d ...) (3)
to different degrees of stress and relaxation by the
Furthermore the influence parameters for the de- Yerkes-Dodson-curve as shown in Fig. 7 (Proske
gree of relaxation have to be chosen. As already 2008).
mentioned, safety is understood here as a feeling. By Fig. 7 indicates that humans do not reach a
definition, this is a subjective evaluation of a situa- maximum performance under extreme safe condi-
tion and therefore the term “perceived safety” is ac- tions or high degrees of freedom of resources. In-
tually a pleonasm. Often the terms “subjective risk stead, humans tend to return to unsafe regions reach-
judgment” and “subjective safety assessment” are ing for further gains as shown in Fig. 8. The way, in
used as well. However the term “perceived safety” which humans return to such stages are manifold.
has become very popular in scientific literature and For example, people may show learned helplessness
shall be used here. Since the term safety considers behavior or they may show homeostatis of risks as
subjective effects, the property of trust should be observed with ABS systems in cars.
mentioned as an example. Covello et al. (2001) have In general humans follow non-linear utility func-
stated that trust might shift the individual acceptable tions (Fig. 9) with high amounts of subjective ele-
risk by a factor of 2,000. That means, if one con- ments in the evaluation process of the utility.
vinces people through dialogue that a house is safe,
a much higher risk (no resources are spent) will be Utility function
accepted, whereas with only a few negative words
trust can be destroyed and further resources for pro-
tection are spent.
Many additional factors, such as voluntariness,
benefit, control, age and experience can be consid-
ered. The variety of such parameters shows, that the
loss gain
mathematical formulation of such a degree of dis-
tress and relaxation might be complicated and is
most frequently done by surveys.
Incidentally the introduced definition of safety
also gives the opportunity to define a relationship
between the terms disaster, danger and safety and
the freedom of resources (Fig. 5). The discussion on
safety has already introduced danger as a situation,
where the majority of resources are spent to re-
establish the condition of safety (= not spending re-
sources). Under an extreme situation of danger, no Figure 9. Utility function of gain and loss according to Kah-
freedom of resources exists anymore; since all re- nemann and Tversky (1981)
sources are spent to re-establish safety. The term
disaster then describes a circumstance, where the re- In scientific works in beta sciences often subjective
sources are overloaded (negative). Here external re- elements are neglected. However, decisions under
sources are required to re-establish safety. This in- real world conditions include such effects. The ques-
deed fits very well to common definitions of disaster tion remains, if “optimal safety” regions based on
stating, that external help is required. some beta scientific investigations indeed represent
Additionally the introduced definitions can be an “optimal safety”.
transferred to the time scale of planning and spend- Subjective judgment often considers many ele-
ing resources, as shown in Fig. 6. The time horizon ments, which seems to have only a small correlation
of planning alters dramatically in correlation with to the relevant indicator. However the wideness of
the states of danger and safety. Under the state of the parameter is extremely high. For example some-
safety and peace of mind the time horizon shows a one does not sign a working contract based on some
great diversity of planning times ranging from al- astrological consideration. In contrast scientific ap-
most zero time to decades or even longer. In emer- proaches mainly consider elements with high corre-
gency states, the time horizon only considers very lation to the relevant indicator (Fig. 10). Here major
short time durations, such as seconds or minutes. indetermination in nature may limit the scientific
It is necessary now to return to the term “optimal approach, as scale cascades found in many examples
safety”. This term is mainly applied as efficiency heavily influence such approaches.
criteria to reach a maximum of utility. Mostly the
Pareto criteria or the Kaldor-Hicks compensation
tests are used (Pliefke & Peil 2007). However, here
of “optimal safety”, since there is only “optimal
safety” for certain criteria given and some chosen
initial values. How strong the relation to the real
a) world problem is, remains to be proven.
On the other hand, an improvement of current
safety conditions should be gained. Here the concept
of risk informed decisions (Arrow et al. 1996) and
integral risk management (Kienholz et al. 2004)
b)
could be helpful. It does not promise an optimal
safety, but it promises permanent improvement (Fig.
11). This concept is much more realistic compared
to the concept of “optimal safety”.

Figure 10. Visualized correlation matrix of possible input vari-


ables for an investigation (rectangles) with increasing correla-
tion shown by increasing darkness and the choice of the pa-
rameters for an optimization procedure based on (a) a
subjective evaluation and (b) a rational model

Many works have shown the limitation of optimi-


zation processes not only for safety, but also for
other applications (Buxmann 1998). The following
remarks from the mathematical research project enti-
tled “Robust mathematical modeling” give the same
results (Société de Calcul Mathématique 2007): Figure 11. Integral risk management concept as a cycle accord-
“1. There is no such thing, in real life, as a pre- ing to Kienholz et al. (2004)
cise problem. As we already saw, the objectives are
usually uncertain, the laws are vague and data is
missing. If you take a general problem and make it 4 AKNOWLEDGEMENT
precise, you always make it precise in the wrong
way or, if your description is correct now, it will not The authors want to express there thanks to the
be tomorrow, because some things will have Austrian Research Foundation (FWF) for the sup-
changed. port of the study about indeterminacy and safety
2. If you bring a precise answer, it seems to indi-
concepts.
cate that the problem was exactly this one, which is
not the case. The precision of the answer is a wrong
indication of the precision of the question. There is
5 REFERENCES
now a dishonest dissimulation of the true nature of
the problem.” Arrow, K.J. 1951. Social Choice and Individual Values, Wiley,
Piecha (1999) states, that flowers in a room may New York
not be considered as the optimal functional design of Arrow, K.J.; Cropper, M.L., Eads, G.C.; Hahn, R.W., Lave,
decors in offices; however, Piecha has shown that L.B., Noll, R.G., Portney, P.R., Russell, M.; Schmalensee,
over the long-term small disturbances such as ones R.; Smith, V.K. and Stavins, R.N. 1996. Is there a role for
created by flowers might increase efficiency of the benefit-cost analysis in environmental, health and safety
regulations. Science, 272, pp. 221-222
workers. Furthermore as Arrows (1951) has shown Buxmann, O. 1998. Erwiderungsvortrag von Herrn Prof. Dr.-
no procedures exist to find optimal solutions for Ing. Otto Buxmann zur Ehrenpromotion: Ursachen für das
some types of systems. See here also Proske (2006) mechanische Verhalten von Konstruktionen bei Unfällen.
and Riedl (2000). Wissenschaftliche Zeitschrift der Technischen Universität
Dresden, 47, Heft 5-6, pp. 145-147
Covello, V.T. 1991. Risk comparisons and risk communica-
tions: Issues and problems in comparing health and envi-
3 SOLUTION ronmental risks. Kasperson, R.E. (Edr): Communicating
Risk to the Public. Kluwer Academic Publishers, pp.79-124
If initial values and the criteria for “optimal safety” Fischhoff, B., Lichtenstein, S.; Slovic, P.; Derby, S.L. &
can not be defined, one should dismiss the concept Keeney, R.L. 1981. Acceptable Risk, Cambridge: Cam-
bridge University Press
Kienholz, H., Krummenacher, B., Kipfer, A. & Perret, S. 2004.
Aspect of Integral Risk Management in Practice – Consid-
erations. Österreichische Wasser- und Abfallwirtschaft. Vol
56, Heft 3-4, March-April 2004, pp 43-50
Küchler T., Schreiber H.W. 1989. Lebensqualität in der All-
gemeinchirurgie - Konzepte und praktische Möglichkeiten
der Messung, Hamburger Ärzteblatt, 43, pp. 246-250
Müller, U. 2002. Quality of Life at its End: Assessment by Pa-
tients and Doctors. Health and Quality of Life. A. Gimmler,
C. Lenk & G. Aumüller (eds). LIT-Verlag Münster – Ham-
burg – Berlin
Nathwani, J. S.; Lind, N.C.; Pandey, M.D. 1997. Affordable
Safety by Choice: The Life Quality Method. Institute of
Risk Research, University of Waterloo, Ontario, Canada
Piecha, A. 1999. Die Begründbarkeit ästhetischer Werturteile.
Fachbereich: Kultur- u. Geowissenschaften, Universität
Osnabrück, Dissertation
Pliefke, T & Peil, U. 2007. On the integration of equality con-
siderations into the life quality concept for managing disas-
ter risk. In: Proceedings of the 5th International Probabilis-
tic Workshop, Taerwe & Proske (eds.), Ghent, pp. 267-282
Proske, D. 2004. Katalog der Risiken. Dirk Proske Verlag,
Dresden
Proske, D. 2006. Unbestimmte Welt. Dirk Proske Verlag, Dres-
den Wien
Proske, D. 2008. Catalogue of risks. Springer: Heidelberg,
Berlin, New York
Riedl, R. 2000 Strukturen der Komplexität – Eine Morphologie
des Erkennens und Erklärens. Springer Verlag, Heidelberg
Schütz, H, Wiedemann, P., Hennings, W., Mertens, J. & Clau-
berg, M. 2003. Vergleichende Risikobewertung – Konzep-
te, Probleme und Anwendungsmöglichkeiten, Abschlussbe-
richt zum BfS Projekt StSch 4217. Forschungsgruppe
Jülich GmbH – Programmgruppe Mensch, Umwelt, Tech-
nik
Slovic, P. 1999. Trust, Emotion, Sex, Politics, and Science:
Surveying the Risk-Assessment Battlefield, Risk Analysis,
Vol. 19, No. 4, pp. 689-701
Société de Calcul Mathématique 2007. Robust mathematical
modeling, http://perso.orange.fr/scmsa/robust.htm
Tversky, A. & Kahneman D. 1981 The Framing of Decisions
and the Psychology of Choice. Science, 211: pp 453-489
Von Cube, F. 1997. Fordern statt Verwöhnen. Piper Verlag
GmbH, München
Zwick, M. M.; Renn, O. 2002. Wahrnehmung und Bewertung
von Risiken: Ergebnisse des Risikosurvey Baden-
Württemberg 2001. Nr. 202, Mai 2002, Arbeitsbericht der
Akademie für Technikfolgenabschätzung und der Universi-
tät Stuttgart, Lehrstuhl für Technik- und Umweltsoziologie

You might also like