You are on page 1of 40

The capital structure of Swiss

companies: An empirical analysis


using dynamic panel data
Philippe GAUD
HEC-University of Geneva

Elion JANI
HEC-University of Geneva

40, Bd. du Pont dArve


PO Box, 1211 Geneva 4
Switzerland
Tel (++4122) 312 09 61
Fax (++4122) 312 10 26
http: //www.fame.ch
E-mail: admin@fame.ch

Martin HOESLI
HEC-University of Geneva, FAME
and University of Aberdeen (Business School)

Andr BENDER
HEC-University of Geneva and FAME

Research Paper N 68
January 2003
FAME - International Center for Financial Asset Management and Engineering

THE GRADUATE INSTITUTE OF


INTERNATIONAL STUDIES

RESEARCH P APER SERIES


The International Center for Financial Asset Management and Engineering (FAME) is a private
foundation created in 1996 at the initiative of 21 leading partners of the finance and technology
community together with three Universities of the Lake Geneva Region (Universities of Geneva,
University of Lausanne and the Graduate Institute of International Studies).
Fame is about research, doctoral training, and executive education with interfacing
activities such as the FAME le ctures, the Research Day/Annual Meeting, and the Research
Paper Series.
The FAME Research Paper Series includes three types of contributions:
First, it reports on the research carried out at FAME by students and research fellows.
Second, it includes research work contributed by Swiss academics and practitioners
interested in a wider dissemination of their ideas, in practitioners' circles in particular.
Finally, prominent international contributions of particular interest to our constituency are
included as well on a regular basis.
FAME will strive to promote the research work in finance carried out in the three partner
Universities. These papers are distributed with a double identification: the FAME logo and the
logo of the corresponding partner institution. With this policy, we want to underline the vital
lifeline existing between FAME and the Universities, while simultaneously fostering a wider
recognition of the strength of the academic community supporting FAME and enriching the
Lemanic region.
Each contribution is preceded by an Executive Summary of two to three pages explaining in nontechnical terms the question asked, discussing its relevance and outlining the answer provided.
We hope the series will be followed attentively by all academics and practitioners interested in
the fields covered by our name.
I am delighted to serve as coordinator of the FAME Research Paper Series. Please contact me
if you are interested in submitting a paper or for all suggestions concerning this matter.
Sincerely,

Prof. Martin Hoesli


University of Geneva, HEC
40 bd du Pont d'Arve
1211 Genve 4
Tel: +41 (022) 705 8122
Martin.Hoesli@hec.unige.ch
INTERNATIONAL CENTER FOR FINANCIAL A SSET M ANAGEMENT AND ENGINEERING
40 bd du Pont d'Arve P.O. Box 3 CH-1211 Geneva 4 tel +41 22 / 312 0961 fax +41 22 / 312 1026
http://www.fame.ch e-mail: admin@fame.ch

THE CAPITAL STRUCTURE OF SWISS COMPANIES:


AN EMPIRICAL ANALYSIS USING DYNAMIC PANEL DATA

Philippe GAUD
Elion JANI
Martin HOESLI
Andr BENDER
January 2003

The capital structure of Swiss companies: an empirical analysis


using dynamic panel data

Philippe Gaud*, Elion Jani**, Martin Hoesli*** and Andr Bender****

This draft: 21 January 2003

Abstract
In this paper, we analyze the determinants of the capital structure for a panel of 106 Swiss
companies listed in the Swiss stock exchange. Both static and dynamic tests are performed for
the period 1991-2000. It is found that the size of companies, the importance of tangible assets
and business risk are positively related to leverage, while growth and profitability are
negatively associated with leverage. The sign of these relations suggest that both the pecking
order theory and trade off hypothesis are at work in explaining the capital structure of Swiss
companies, although more evidence exists to validate the latter theory. Our analysis also
shows that Swiss firms adjust toward a target debt ratio, but the adjustment process is much
slower than in most other countries. It is argued that reasons for this can be found in the
institutional context.

JEL classification: G32


Keywords: Capital structure, dynamic panel data, trade-off theory, pecking order theory
*

University of Geneva (HEC), 40 boulevard du Pont-dArve, CH-1211 Geneva 4, Switzerland, email:


philippe.gaud@hec.unige.ch
**
University of Geneva (HEC), 40 boulevard du Pont-dArve, CH-1211 Geneva 4, Switzerland, email:
elion.jani@hec.unige.ch
***
University of Geneva (HEC and FAME), 40 boulevard du Pont-dArve, CH-1211 Geneva 4, Switzerland
and University of Aberdeen (Business School), Edward Wright Building, Dunbar Street, Aberdeen AB24
3QY, UK, email: martin.hoesli@hec.unige.ch
****
University of Geneva (HEC and FAME), 40 boulevard du Pont-dArve, CH-1211 Geneva 4, Switzerland,
email: andre.bender@hec.unige.ch
Address correspondence to: Martin Hoesli, University of Geneva, HEC, 40 boulevard du Pont-dArve, CH-1211
Geneva 4, Switzerland, email: martin.hoesli@hec.unige.ch
We thank Jaya Krishnakumar and Andi Kabili for helpful discussions and suggestions. We are also grateful to
the participants at the University of Geneva (HEC) finance research seminars. The usual disclaimer applies.

Executive summary
One of the most important decisions in the field of corporate finance pertains to financial
policy. Using debt financing can have both positive and negative effects on the value of the
firm. On the one hand, debt financing is value-enhancing for the firm because it provides a tax
shield. Furthermore, debt allows to reduce the conflicts of interest between managers and
shareholders. On the other hand, the use of debt may increase bankruptcy costs and may lead
the managers of firms with growth opportunities to accept sub-optimal investment
opportunities. In addition, debt often does not constitute an appropriate solution to finance
highly innovative start-up companies. Empirical research in this area has mainly focused on
the U.S market, and less evidence exists for European countries. The aim of this paper is to
contribute to the empirical literature by analyzing the determinants of the capital structure of
Swiss companies. We analyze a panel of 106 firms for the period 1991-2000.
The capital structure decisions of firms can be explained by two alternative theories: the trade
off theory (TOT) and the pecking order theory (POT). The TOT posits that there exists a trade
off between the costs and benefits of debt financing that leads to an optimal capital structure.
In order to maximize the value of the firm, managers should determine the optimal level and
then aim at reaching that level. In contrast, according to the POT, firms adopt a pecking order
behavior: they first use internal financing, then debt and issue equity as a last resort only. This
is because of informational asymmetries between managers and outside investors.
The debate as to which theory better explains the capital structure choices of firms is
unresolved. Empirical research has shown that managers have a preference for internal
sources of financing, but this does not imply that an optimal capital structure does not exist.
Indeed, from a dynamic perspective, the preference for internal financing can be viewed as a
slowing factor in the adjustment process towards an optimal capital structure.
Financing decisions are dynamic by nature and any empirical study, which hypothesizes that
firms aim at a debt-to-equity target, must take into account the adjustment process towards
that target. We investigate the determinants of a target capital structure for Swiss firms and
the role of the adjustment process, which is a trade off between the adjustment costs towards a
target ratio and the costs of being in disequilibrium. The method used allows us to consider

that the observed debt-to-equity ratio is not the optimal level and that the latter can change
over time.
Our results are often in contradiction with pecking order theory. First, according to this
theory, firms with few tangible assets should be more sensitive to informational asymmetries.
However, we observe a positive relationship between tangible assets and leverage which may
suggest that firms use tangible assets as collateral when issuing debt. Second, according to the
POT, informational asymmetries should be more severe for small size firms, but we observe a
positive correlation between size and leverage. This leads us to reject the hypothesis that size
acts as an inverse proxy for informational asymmetries, but rather that size is an inverse proxy
for the probability of bankruptcy which is consistent with the TOT. Third, in our sample,
growth firms are less levered than non-growth firms, which suggests that equity is preferred
to debt to avoid bankruptcy costs.
In our sample, we find a negative relationship between profitability and debt level. This result
is usually interpreted as evidence for the pecking order theory (POT). However, such a
relationship is also consistent with the TOT in the short run. For example, according to the
TOT, despite the fact that the contemporaneous profitability is a determinant of leverage, the
cash-flow generated during the year can be used partly to decrease the level of debt.
Overall, our results suggest that both the pecking order theory and trade off hypothesis are at
work in explaining the capital structure of Swiss companies, although more evidence exists to
validate the latter theory. Our analysis shows that Swiss firms adjust toward a target debt
ratio, but the adjustment process is much slower than in most other countries. A possible
explanation for this is that being in disequilibrium is not costly for Swiss firms. It is argued
that reasons for this can be found in the characteristics of Swiss firms, which are mature
firms, and the institutional context that favored easy credit. In particular, Swiss companies
experienced rather low growth during the 1990s, which implied that internal financing was
sufficient to cover new capital expenditures. In such circumstances, firms did not aim towards
their target ratio.

The capital structure of Swiss companies: an empirical analysis


using dynamic panel data

1. Introduction
Since the seminal Modigliani and Miller (1958) paper showing that subject to some
conditions the impact of financing on the value of the firm is irrelevant, the literature on
capital structure has been expanded by many theoretical and empirical contributions. Much
emphasis has been placed on releasing the assumptions made by MM, in particular by taking
into account corporate taxes (Modigliani and Miller, 1963), personal taxes (Miller, 1977),
bankruptcy costs (Stiglitz, 1972; Titman, 1984), agency costs (Jensen and Meckling, 1976;
Myers, 1977), and informational asymmetries (Myers, 1984). Two main theories dominate
currently the capital structure debate1: the trade off theory (TOT) and the pecking order theory
(POT).

The TOT posits that firms maximize their value when the benefits that stem from debt (the tax
shield, the disciplinary role of debt, and the fact that debt suffers less from informational costs
than outside equity) equal the marginal cost of debt (bankruptcy costs, and agency costs
between shareholders and bondholders). The POT, developed by Myers (1984), is a
consequence of informational asymmetries existing between insiders of the firm and outsiders
(i.e. the capital market). Thereafter, addressing the issue of how companies choose their
financing mix has been primarily an empirical question, and such studies have been plentiful
in the last decade. However, empirical studies dealing with capital structure are not recent
(Taggart, 1977; Marsh, 1982; Jalilvand and Harris, 1984; Titman and Wessels, 1988). The
latter authors made a significant contribution in formulating and testing the determinants of
the capital structure as identified by theory. These authors caution on the difficulty of finding
suitable proxies for the determinants of capital structure.

Most initial studies examined the case of U.S. companies. The cross section analysis by Rajan
and Zingales (1995) is one of the first attempts to test for the G7 countries the theoretical and
empirical lessons learnt from the U.S. studies. These authors find similar levels of leverage
across countries, thus refuting the idea that firms in bank-oriented countries are more
1

For an in-depth review of literature on capital structure, see Harris and Raviv (1991).

leveraged than those in market-oriented countries. However, they recognize that this
distinction is useful in analyzing the various sources of financing. Rajan and Zingales (1995)
find that the determinants of capital structure that have been reported for the U.S. (size,
growth, profitability, and importance of tangible assets) are important in other countries as
well. They show that a good understanding of the relevant institutional context (bankruptcy
law, fiscal treatment, ownership concentration, and accounting standards) is required when
identifying the fundamental determinants of capital structure. The analysis by Booth et al.
(2001) suggests that the same determinants of capital structure prevail in ten developing
countries. These studies, however, do not shed any light on the adjustment process of the
capital structure.

Other studies, which have addressed the dynamic nature of capital structure decisions, suffer
from some limitations also. For example, the results of Taggart (1977), Marsh (1982), and
Jalilvand and Harris (1984) may be biased as they use future information about leverage as a
proxy of the optimal debt ratio. Moreover, the tests of the target adjustment model lack power
as they are unable to reject the target adjustment hypothesis even when financing is generated
according to POT only (Shyam-Sunders and Myers, 1999). With respect to the empirical
validation of pecking order theory, Chirinko and Singha (2000) show that the tests by ShyamSunders and Myers (1999) may be misleading. In addition, Frank and Goyal (2002) reject the
fact that the debt level is determined fundamentally by the financing deficit, and find evidence
of mean reversion of leverage, the adjustment process being influenced by the variables used
by Rajan and Zingales (1995).

Recent work has benefited from the advances in econometrics. Kremp et al. (1999), De
Miguel and Pindado (2001), and Ozkan (2001) focus on the dynamics of the capital structure
decisions, offering better insight on the adjustment process toward the target debt-to-equity
ratio. Kremp et al. (1999) analyze a large panel of French and German firms and confirm the
existence of a dynamic adjustment process. They provide further evidence that the
institutional framework is important when analyzing the determinants of the capital structure.
They stress the role of the Hausbank system in Germany, and the impact of tax policy and the
end of the so-called indebtedness economy in France. These findings are confirmed by De
Miguel and Pindado (2001) who show that firms have a target leverage ratio in Spain, and
that companies adjust to the target ratio relatively fast. The institutional context again is

important. They argue that adjustment costs are lower in Spain than in the U.S. for instance,
because of the major role of bank financing.

The aim of this paper is to analyze the determinants of the capital structure in Switzerland.
We add to the relatively limited literature on the dynamics of the capital structure decision by
examining the dynamics of the relationship between leverage and a set of explanatory
variables. The analysis is conducted using panel data pertaining to 106 Swiss companies for
the period 1991-2000. A total of 967 observations are available for analysis. Our results show
that both the pecking order theory and the trade off theory are at work, although more
evidence exists to validate the latter theory. Also, we find that the speed of adjustment is quite
slow in Switzerland as compared to other countries. We argue that the complexity and
specificity of the Swiss institutional framework help explain why Swiss firms do not suffer
too much from being away from their target ratios.

The paper is organized as follows. In section 2, we provide an overview of the literature on


the determinants of the capital structure. The models and the data are presented in section 3,
while the results from using both the static and dynamic models are discussed in section 4.
Finally, section 5 contains some concluding remarks.

2. The determinants of capital structure


In this section, we provide a review of the six main variables that have been used in previous
studies examining the determinants of capital structure.
2.1 Growth opportunities
For companies with growth opportunities, the use of debt is limited as in the case of
bankruptcy, the value of growth opportunities will be close to zero. Jung et al. (1996) show
that firms should use equity to finance their growth because such financing reduces agency
costs between shareholders and managers, whereas firms with less growth prospects should
use debt because it has a disciplinary role (Jensen, 1986; Stulz, 1990).

Myers (1977) shows that firms with growth opportunities may invest sub-optimally, and
therefore creditors will be more reluctant to lend for long horizons. This problem can be
solved by short-term financing (Titman and Wessels, 1988) or by convertible bonds (Jensen

and Meckling, 1976; Smith and Warner, 1979). From a pecking order theory perspective,
growth firms with strong financing needs will issue securities less subject to informational
asymmetries, i.e. short-term debt. If these firms have very close relationships with banks,
there will be less informational asymmetry problems, and they will be able to have access to
long term debt financing as well.

A common proxy for growth opportunities is the market value to book value of total assets.
Firms with growth opportunities should exhibit a greater market-to-book than firms with less
growth opportunities, but Harris and Raviv (1991) suggest that this is not necessarily the case.
This will typically occur when assets whose values have increased over time have been fully
depreciated, as well as when assets with high value are not accounted for in the balance sheet
(e.g. the brand name Nestl).

Rajan and Zingales (1995) find a negative relationship between growth opportunities and
leverage. They suggest that this may be due to firms issuing equity when stock prices are
high. As mentioned by Hovakimian et al. (2001), large stock price increases are usually
associated with improved growth opportunities, leading to a lower debt ratio.

2.2 Size
Large size companies tend to be more diversified, and hence their cash flows are less volatile.
Size may then be inversely related to the probability of bankruptcy (Titman and Wessels,
1988; Rajan and Zingales, 1995). Ferri and Jones (1979) suggest that large firms have easier
access to the markets and can borrow at better conditions. For small firms, the conflicts
between creditors and shareholders are more severe because the managers of such firms tend
to be large shareholders and are better able to switch from one investment project to another
(Grinblatt and Titman, 1998). However, this problem may be mitigated with the use of short
term debt, convertible bonds, as well as long term bank financing. Most empirical studies
report indeed a positive sign for the relationship between size and leverage (Rajan and
Zingales, 1995; Frank and Goyal, 2002; Booth et al., 2001). Less conclusive results are
reported by other authors (Kremp et al., 1999; Ozkan, 2001). For Germany, however, Rajan
and Zingales (1995) find that a negative relationship exists. Kremp et al. (1999) confirm the
finding of Rajan and Zingales (1995) for Germany and argue that the negative relationship is
not due to asymmetrical information, but rather to the characteristics of the German
6

bankruptcy law and the Hausbank system which offer better protection to creditors than is the
case in other countries.

2.3 Profitability
One of the main theoretical controversies concerns the relationship between leverage and
profitability of the firm. According to the pecking order theory, firms prefer using internal
sources of financing first, then debt and finally external equity obtained by stock issues. All
things being equal, the more profitable the firms are, the more internal financing they will
have, and therefore we should expect a negative relationship between leverage and
profitability. This relationship is one of the most systematic findings in the empirical literature
(Harris and Raviv, 1991; Rajan and Zingales, 1995; Booth et al., 2001).

In a trade-off theory framework, an opposite conclusion is expected. When firms are


profitable, they should prefer debt to benefit from the tax shield. In addition, if past
profitability is a good proxy for future profitability, profitable firms can borrow more as the
likelihood of paying back the loans is greater.

Dynamic theoretical models based on the existence of a target debt-to-equity ratio show (1)
that there are adjustment costs to raise the debt-to-equity ratio towards the target and (2) that
debt can easily be reimbursed with excess cash provided by internal sources. This leads firms
to have a pecking order behavior in the short term, despite the fact that they aim at increasing
their debt-to-equity ratio (Fischer et al., 1989; Leland, 1998).

2.4 Collaterals
Tangible assets are likely to have an impact on the borrowing decisions of a firm because they
are less subject to informational asymmetries and usually they have a greater value than
intangible assets in case of bankruptcy. Additionally, the moral hazard risks are reduced when
the firm offers tangible assets as collateral, because this constitutes a positive signal to the
creditors who can request the selling of these assets in the case of default. As such, tangible
assets constitute a good collateral for loans. According to Scott (1977), a firm can increase the
value of equity by issuing collateralized debt when the current creditors do not have such

guarantee. Hence, firms have an incentive to do so, and one would expect a positive relation
between the importance of tangible assets and the degree of leverage.

Based on the agency problems between managers and shareholders, Harris and Raviv (1990)
suggest that firms with more tangible assets should take more debt. This is due to the behavior
of managers who refuse to liquidate the firm even when the liquidation value is higher than
the value of the firm as a going concern. Indeed, by increasing the leverage, the probability of
default will increase which is to the benefit of the shareholders. In an agency theory
framework, debt can have another disciplinary role: by increasing the debt level, the free cash
flow will decrease (Grossman and Hart, 1982; Jensen, 1986; Stulz, 1990). As opposed to the
former, this disciplinary role of debt should mainly occur in firms with few tangible assets,
because in such a case it is very difficult to monitor the excessive expenses of managers.

From a pecking order theory perspective, firms with few tangible assets are more sensitive to
informational asymmetries. These firms will thus issue debt rather than equity when they need
external financing (Harris and Raviv, 1991), leading to an expected negative relation between
the importance of intangible assets and leverage.

Most empirical studies conclude to a positive relation between collaterals and the level of debt
(Rajan and Zingales, 1995; Kremp et al., 1999; Frank and Goyal, 2002). Inconclusive results
are reported for instance by Titman and Wessels (1988).

2.5 Operating Risk


Many authors have included a measure of risk as an explanatory variable of the debt level
(Titman and Wessels, 1988; Kremp et al., 1999; Booth et al., 2001). Leverage increases the
volatility of the net profit. Firms that have high operating risk can lower the volatility of the
net profit by reducing the level of debt. By so doing, bankruptcy risk will decrease, and the
probability of fully benefiting from the tax shield will increase. A negative relation between
operating risk and leverage is also expected from a pecking order theory perspective: firms
with high volatility of results try to accumulate cash during good years, to avoid under
investment issues in the future.

2.6 Taxes
The impact of taxation on leverage is twofold. On the one hand, companies have an incentive
to take debt because they can benefit from the tax shield. On the other hand, since revenues
from debt are taxed more heavily than revenues from equity, firms also have an incentive to
use equity rather than debt. As suggested by Miller (1977), the financial structure decisions
are irrelevant given that bankruptcy costs can be neglected in equilibrium. DeAngelo and
Masulis (1980) show that if non-debt tax shields exist, then firms are likely not to use fully
debt tax shields. In other words, firms with large non-debt tax shields have a lower incentive
to use debt from a tax shield point of view, and thus may use less debt. Empirically, this
substitution effect is difficult to measure as finding an accurate proxy for the tax reduction
that excludes the effect of economic depreciation and expenses is tedious (Titman and
Wessels, 1988). According to Graham (2000), the tax shield accounts on average to 4.3% of
the firm value when both corporate and personal taxes are considered.

3. Models and Data

3.1

Static Model

The static model tests the Modigliani and Miller (1958) hypothesis that leverage is a random
variable. More specifically, the leverage is regressed on a set of explanatory variables, and if
MM holds, then these variables should not be significant from a statistical point of view. We
use explanatory variables to proxy for the determinants of capital structure as presented in
section 2. We do not take into account the tax effect for two reasons. First, this would reduce
substantially the size of our sample due to the lack of data regarding taxes. Moreover,
choosing the appropriate marginal tax rate of firms is crucial in determining the tax shield and
such choice is not straightforward (Graham, 2000). We posit that leverage can be explained
by the following variables:

Leverage = f(growth, size, profitability, tangibles, risk)

We use two proxies to measure the leverage. The first proxy refers to book values only and is
defined as the ratio of total debt over total assets. The other proxy is based on the market
capitalization of equity. Two measures of leverage are used to control for possible spurious
9

correlations that may result from a discrepancy between one of our proxies for leverage and
the debt-to-equity ratio computed by the managers (Titman and Wessels, 1988). It is
important to obtain the same sign from the various explanatory variables whether we use
market capitalization or book value. To check further the robustness of our results, we also
run the regressions by only considering long term debt. Although these results are not
reported in the tables, they are discussed whenever necessary.

Growth opportunities (GROWTH) are proxied by the market-to-book value of assets. Other
proxies also have been used in the literature, such as R&D and marketing expenses, or capital
expenditures (Titman and Wessels, 1988), but such items are difficult to measure from
published financial statements, and hence are not considered in this study. We use the natural
logarithm of sales as proxy for size (SIZE). This measure is the most common proxy for size
(Titman and Wessels, 1988; Rajan and Zingales, 1995; Ozkan, 2001). An alternative proxy
could be the natural logarithm of total assets, but it is subject to more accounting problems.
Various proxies can be used to measure profitability (PROF). We choose the return on total
assets, which is calculated as the ratio of EBIT to total assets (Rajan and Zingales, 1995;
Booth et al., 2001). We use the ratio of the sum of tangible assets and inventories to total
asset as a proxy for collaterals (TANG). Adding inventories to the tangible assets is motivated
by the fact that debts are used partly to finance inventories, and in most cases inventories
maintain some value when the firm is liquidated (Kremp et al., 1999).

Proxying for the operating risk is a difficult task because such a measure should rely on
expectations concerning a firms profitability as compared to that of the market and should
also take into account the specific nature of the firms assets. Many authors use the volatility
of operating profits of each company as a proxy (Titman and Wessels, 1988; Booth et al.,
2001). Kremp et al. (1999) measure the operating risk as the squared difference between the
firms profitability and the cross section mean (i.e. across firms) of profitability for each year.
We add to this squared measure the sign of the difference between the profitability of the firm
and the average profitability. This measure is better than using the more intuitively appealing
difference as the latter is highly collinear with the PROF variable.

Legal differences across countries, varying degrees of exports by companies, the nature of the
business and the risk profile of shareholders and managers suggest that the Swiss firms are
very different from each other. Furthermore it is likely that macroeconomic shocks and
10

changes in the institutional context have occurred in recent years. For these purposes, we
prefer panel data analysis, as it is possible to include time effects as well as to control for the
heterogeneity of firms by including firm-specific effects, which may be random or fixed.
However, the fixed effects model is costly in degrees of freedom because it is equivalent to
the use of a dummy variable for every firm (Greene, 1993). The random effects model
assumes the independence between error terms and explanatory variables. Chow tests are
performed in this study to control for the presence of firm specific effects (Hsiao, 1986). The
Hausman test is then performed to validate the exogeneity of the firm specific effect with
dependent variables (Hausman, 1978). If the two null hypotheses are rejected, then the fixed
effect model will be retained. A Wald test of the joint significance of time dummy variables is
also used.

In order to ease comparison, we also report simple pooled ordinary least squares as well as
pooled ordinary least squares with dummy variable for time and sectors and Fama-McBeth
type estimations.

Our static model to analyze firms with panel data is as follows:


yit = ' xit + i + t + uit

(1)

with i = 1,.,N and t=1,.,T


and
y it : the leverage of firm i in year t
xit : a K x 1 vector of explanatory variables
: a K x 1 vector of constants
i : firm effect assumed constant for firm i over t
t : time effect assumed constant for given t over i
uit : error term

3.2

Dynamic Model

Capital structure decisions are dynamic by nature and should be modelled as such. If there is a
target leverage ratio, then firms should take the appropriate steps to reach this objective.
Claiming that the adjustment process is without cost is unrealistic. Taking transaction costs
into account, the model can be written as follows:

11

yit yit 1 = yit* yit 1

(2)

with 0< <1

where yit* is the target leverage ratio estimated from equation (1).
The coefficient is between 0 and 1 and is inversely related to adjustment costs. When

=0, then yit = yit-1, which means that there is no move toward the target debt ratio because
the adjustment costs are too high. When =1, then y it = yit* , so the adjustment occurs without
frictions.
Once developed, equation (2) becomes:
yit = (1 ) y it 1 + xit + i + t + u it

(3)

Panel data analysis allows us to study the dynamic nature of the capital structure decisions at
the firm level. However, the fixed or random effects models may give biased and inconsistent
estimators because the error term may be correlated with the lagged variable. To deal with
variables that may be correlated with the error term, we use instrumental variables. Using
instrumental variables has the additional advantage of solving problems encountered in static
models, mainly the simultaneity bias between the leverage measure and the explanatory
variables, and measurement error issue. For panels with a limited number of years and a
substantial number of observations, Arellano and Bond (1991) suggest estimating equation (3)
in first differences2 and using all lags of the level of variables from the second lag as
instruments.

We use the Arellano and Bond (1991) two-step GMM estimator for our dynamic model which
allows for heteroskedasticity across firms. The GMM estimator is consistent if there is no
second order serial correlation between error terms of the first-differenced equation. A m2
statistic which follows a N(0,1) distribution under the null hypothesis E[it, it-2]=0 is used
to test for lack of second order serial correlation. Concerning the instruments, we report the
Sargan statistic, which tests the over-identifying restrictions. It must be noted that the Sargan
test rejects too often in presence of heteroskedasticity. In addition, we report two Wald
statistics. Wald 1 is a test of the joint significance of the time dummy variables and is
2

Using first differences eliminates the specific firm effect, thus avoiding any correlation problem between
unobservable firm specific characteristics and explanatory variables.

12

asymptotically distributed as

2 under the null hypothesis of no relationship. Wald 3 is a test

of the joint significance of the capital structure determinants.

Arellano and Bond (1991) show that when the number of firms is limited, the asymptotic
standard errors associated with the two-step estimates may be biased downward. However,
the one-step estimators are less efficient than the two-step estimators even in presence of
homoskedasticity of the error terms. Since the standard errors associated with the one-step
estimators are more reliable to make inferences, the results using both methods are reported in
this study.

3.3

Data

Our data consist of Swiss firms listed on the Swiss stock exchange SWX for the period 19912000. We use annual data extracted from Worldscope. Banks, insurance companies, utility
companies, and some other companies, whose business is highly regulated, such as railway
companies, are excluded from the sample. This is motivated by the fact that such companies
have to comply with very stringent legal requirements pertaining to their financing. Our
sample thus contains primarily industrial, commercial and service companies, for which
managers have considerable leeway concerning financial decisions.

We deflate our data using 1992 as base year. Company financial statements and the Swiss
stock guide are used to fill any gaps in the data, and to check the data. We exclude
observations (i.e. a given company in a given year) for which we have negative figures on the
balance sheet, except for retained earnings and other assets3. Our sample is trimmed
applying a methodology similar to that of Kremp et al. (1999). We exclude observations for
which profitability, collaterals and growth opportunities are outside the interval defined by
plus/minus five times the interquartile range. Concerning the measure of leverage, we only
exclude observations for which the leverage is higher than the third quartile plus five times
the interquartile range. We choose the period 19912000 because a new business law required
Swiss firms to comply with new accounting rules since 1991. Before 1991, there would be too
many missing observations. To run the dynamic panel regressions, we need a minimum of six

When firms adopted the new accounting rules in the beginning of the 1990s, a badwill might have appeared,
and hence negative other assets may exist.

13

consecutive years for a company to be included. This leaves us with a sample of 106 firms
and a total of 967 observations.

Table I contains summary statistics for selected years of the time period (1991, 1994, 1997,
and 2000), as well as for the total period 1991-2000. The importance of leverage diminishes
over the period, with a sharper decrease when market values of equity are considered than
when book values are used. Whereas both proxies for leverage are roughly equal in 1991, this
leverage ratio amounts to 54.2% in 2000 when market values are used and to 40.2% when
book values are used. Over the period, companies on average have grown in size, and have
increased the relative importance of intangible assets in their balance sheet. The market-tobook ratio has increased from 1.10 in 1991 to 1.87 in 2000, but remains low which confirms
the fact that the Swiss market is a value market rather than a growth market. The
profitability of Swiss companies has increased over the period, and not surprisingly the higher
return levels are accompanied by higher levels of risk.

The correlation coefficients between variables are reported in Table II. Correlations are
generally low, except the correlation between profitability and risk. In fact, a high correlation
between these two variables would be expected. To check whether these two variables are
collinear, we perform a VIF test. Our VIF tests are substantially lower than 10, so collinearity
should not constitute a problem (Chaterjee and Price, 1977).

4.

Results

4.1 Static Analysis

In table III we present the regression results for the static analysis. The level of R2 varies from
14.3% to 60.0%. The R2s are substantially higher when the market capitalization of equity is
used rather than the book value of equity. The Chow test is significant at the 1% level, and
confirms the presence of firm-specific effects. The Hausman test indicates that the fixed effect
model should be used when market data are considered, whereas the random effect model
should be preferred when using book values. When such estimators are considered, all
variables are significant at the 1% level, except the RISK variable when book values are
considered. The Wald 1 tests of the joint significance of the time dummy variables are
satisfied, except when book values are used for panel estimation, suggesting that

14

macroeconomic events and changes in the institutional context play a significant role on the
borrowing decision of Swiss firms.

SIZE plays a positive role and the coefficients are significant for all estimations. For the
profitability variable (PROF), we find a negative relationship with leverage and all the
coefficients are again significant at the 1% level. For the other three variables, the results vary
more across specifications. The RISK variable is positively related to the importance of
leverage and in all cases significant at the 1% level when the market values of equity are
considered, but not when book values are considered. The GROWTH variable negatively
impacts on leverage and is significant at the 1% level when market values are used only, but
is significant in all cases with panel data estimations. Tangible assets (TANG) have a positive
impact that is significant at the 1% level for all panel data estimations and for the OLS
estimations with market values. In summary, when panel data are used, the SIZE, TANG, and
RISK variables have a positive impact on leverage, whereas GROWTH and PROF have a
negative impact. All these relations are significant at the 1% level when either market values
or book values of equity are used, except for the SIZE variable, which is only significant
when market values are used.

When using long-term debt in lieu of total debt to compute the leverage, the tests confirm that
firm-specific effects exist and that the random effects models give the best estimations. We
obtain the same sign and the same significance for all coefficients, except for the RISK
variable, which is now significant at the 5% level when using book values and the variable
SIZE, which looses its significance.

The positive impact of size on leverage is consistent with the results of many empirical
studies (Rajan and Zingales, 1995; Booth et al., 2001; Frank and Goyal, 2002). It leads us to
reject the hypothesis that size acts as an inverse proxy for informational asymmetries, but
could suggest that size acts as an inverse proxy for the probability of bankruptcy. Recall that
the variable SIZE is not significant any more when leverage is computed with long-term debt
only. One possible explanation is that large companies have easier access to the bond markets
(Ferri and Jones, 1979). The development of financial markets has pushed large companies to
search for better credit conditions. Consequently, there has been a tendency for banks to grant
more loans to small and medium size companies. The market for short term debt securities

15

being not well developed in Switzerland, this allows banks to select between borrowers. As
they will prefer large firms to small ones, the sign of the SIZE coefficient is positive.

As reported in several other studies, the PROF variable is negative and significant in all cases
(Rajan and Zingales, 1995; Booth et al., 2001; Frank and Goyal, 2002). This finding provides
support for the pecking order theory. However, caution has to be exercised before the
dynamic nature of the relation between leverage and profitability is examined (Frank and
Goyal, 2002; Titman and Wessels, 1988). The positive impact of RISK for the fixed effects
estimation when using market data implies that firms, which perform below average, are less
levered. In other words, companies with high operating risk try to control total risk by
limiting financial risk.

The coefficient of the TANG variable is positive and significant for the panel data
estimations, and this result is similar to those reported in previous research (Rajan and
Zingales, 1995; Kremp et al., 1999; Frank and Goyal, 2002). This result suggests that firms
use tangible assets as collateral when negotiating borrowing, especially long term borrowing.
The observed sign of the relationship does not confirm the sign that would be expected when
using the pecking order theory framework. In such a framework, firms with less tangible
assets are more subject to informational asymmetries, and are more likely to use debt principally short term debt - when they need external financing.

The negative sign of GROWTH confirms the hypothesis that firms with growth opportunities
are less levered. To analyze further this relationship, we divide our sample in two subsamples
using the median growth as cut-off. The negative sign and significance of the coefficient
remains irrespective of the leverage measure for the high growth firms. Concerning the low
growth firms, which are typically no growth firms as the market-to-book ratio is below one,
we observe a negative relationship between GROWTH and leverage when market values are
used, and a positive relation when leverage is measured with book values.

The latter relation can be explained by the fact that in our sample companies with low growth
opportunities typically belong to either of the following two categories: (1) companies with
cash-cow activities or (2) companies in financial distress. For the former type of company,
current activities generate sufficient cash to renew assets, and even to support a marginal
increase of assets. Any remaining cash will increase cash and cash equivalents. Retained
16

earnings will increase also, leading to a lower leverage ratio. Moreover, as highlighted by La
Porta et al. (1998), these companies are often family-owned (such as Loeb, Vetropak, and
Bucher), and have a strong tax incentive not to distribute any remaining cash. In addition, the
repurchase of shares is too costly for this type of company. For companies in financial distress
(such as Axantis, and WMH), banks are reluctant to lend funds, as the prospects are not
encouraging. In some cases, these companies have been forced to sell some of their activities,
often with a capital gain, making it possible to reduce the debt-to-equity ratio level. When
market values are used, the above-mentioned financial operations will have a strong negative
impact on the market value of equity4. Therefore, the debt-to-equity ratio may even increase.
4.2

Dynamic Analysis

The dynamic analysis makes it possible to study the financing behavior of Swiss firms over
time and whether there are adjustment costs. As the model is estimated in first differences and
one or more lagged variables are used as explanatory variables, our sample is reduced from
967 to 755 observations. To examine the impact of profitability over the dynamics of
borrowing, we add the lagged profitability in equation (3). This is motivated by the fact that
we want to test the persistence of a pecking order financing, which we find in our static
model. Models such as those of Fischer et al. (1989) and Leland (1998) postulate the
existence of an optimal debt-to-equity ratio, but find pecking order behavior in the short run
due to the adjustment costs. Despite the fact that the contemporaneous profitability is a
determinant of the importance of leverage, the cash flow generated during the year can be
used partly to decrease the level of debt.

For the dynamic model, we test various specifications concerning the endogeneity of the
explanatory variables. Only the results of the model that posits that all variables are
endogenous are reported in this paper. Not surprisingly, this is the best-specified model
because all variables are based upon accounting values and are thus determined
simultaneously. Arellano and Bond (1991) show that two-step estimators may be biased for
small samples and recommend the use of a one-step estimator to draw inferences. We present
the two types of estimations in table IV, however. The Sargan and m2 tests suggest that a
dynamic specification of our model for the sample of Swiss firms is valid. Only the Sargan
4

As mentioned by Goyal et al. (2002), the change of sign may also be a statistical phenomenon because book
leverage and MTB have the same denominator.

17

test for the one-step estimator does not confirm the validity of our instrumental variables.
However, as Arellano and Bond (1991) note, the Sargan test has an tendency to reject too
often in the presence of heteroskedasticity.

The size of the coefficient of the lagged leverage is high and it is in all cases significant at the
1% level. For the Swiss market, the size of the coefficient is in the 0.708-0.844 range for the
one-step estimations. The coefficient is smaller when we use market data suggesting that
managers use market values when adjusting their leverage toward the target ratio. Caution has
to be exercised when cross-country comparisons are made, but such comparisons are
interesting however. The adjustment process is slow in Switzerland compared to the results
for other countries as reported in many studies: De Miguel and Pindado (2001) find a (1-) of
0.21 for Spain, Shyam-Sunder and Myers (1999) a value of 0.41 for the U.S., Kremp et al.
(1999) a value of 0.47 for Germany, and Ozkan (2001) a value of 0.45 for the U.K. For
France, the speed of adjustment is comparable to that for Switzerland as 1- = 0.72 as
reported by Kremp et al. (1999).

The adjustment process is a trade off between the adjustment costs towards a target ratio and
the costs of being in disequilibrium. If the costs of being in disequilibrium are greater than the
adjustment costs, then the estimated coefficient should be close to zero (Ozkan, 2001). For
example, De Miguel and Pindado (2001) explain the small coefficient that they find for the
Spanish market by the importance of bank credit. They argue that Spanish companies have
low transaction costs when borrowing funds from banks, and that such financing leads to
lower agency costs between creditors and shareholders. It could seem appropriate to use the
same explanation for the Swiss market because companies in both countries mostly rely on
banks for their long term borrowing needs. According to the World Bank (1999), the public
debt ratio is 5.7% for Spain and 7.9% for Switzerland, as compared e.g. to 27.4% for the U.S.
However, the reason used to explain the adjustment process for Spain does not necessarily
hold for Switzerland. Unlike Spain, which was in a boom market during the 1990s, the growth
in Switzerland during that period was smaller, and therefore less capital expenditures were
made and internal financing was sufficient. Whenever the Swiss companies needed external
funds to finance their investments they relied on borrowing more than capital increases.
However, it remains difficult to tell whether these decisions may be considered as a result of a
POT or TOT behavior since the POT and the dynamic specification of the TOT may both

18

consider the use of debt in this case5. There is also a purely mechanical reason that can
explain the lower level of debt within the framework of a dynamic TOT model. When stock
prices increase due to a market boom without an increase in the size of assets nor in the value
of the growth options, this will lead to a decrease of the leverage, even below the target level6.

Some institutional factors tend to lead to a high level of debt rather than a low level of debt.
Hertig (1998) shows that Swiss firms have benefited from relatively easy credit during the
period under study. This is because loans were often granted based more on personal
relationships, than based upon objective criteria. The large banks were the first to modify their
organization by splitting credit analysis from credit decisions, and by using criteria based on
company expected earnings. In contrast, cantonal banks, in part due to political reasons, have
been more inclined to continue granting loans based on the old system of credit, thus
providing Swiss firms with relatively inexpensive financing given the risk incurred. It is
difficult, however, to measure the effect of the cantonal bank behavior on the capital structure
policy of listed companies as they predominantly finance non-listed SMEs. There might be
some indirect effects however.

As far as corporate governance is concerned, Hertig (1998) shows that the role of large banks
in Switzerland during the period under review is quite limited. For example, the stockholdings
of large banks giving them more than 10% of the voting rights in industrial companies is less
than 5% of their total assets (BNS, 1992-2001). One of the consequences of the passive role
of bank representatives on the boards of Swiss companies, the high concentration of
ownership (La Porta et al., 1998), and the lack of control in bank credit proceedings is that
agency costs stemming from the conflicts of interest between lenders and borrowers are
mainly borne by lenders. This will lead to an increase in the use of debt.

For the above reasons, we can conclude that being in disequilibrium due to a mechanical
effect is not so costly. Two factors appear to explain the slow adjustment process of the debt
level towards the target. On the one hand, there is a purely mechanical reason due to the boom
5

As the small companies have relatively more bank credit in their balance sheet than larger companies, we
expect the adjustment costs to be smaller for these firms than for large firms. To test this conjecture, we divide
our sample in two subsamples of small and large companies, respectively, using the median of sales to
discriminate firms between both subsamples. However, we find for the small firms the same coefficient for the
size variable as we do for large companies.
6

In this situation managers may be inclined to raise capital which would further reduce the debt level. Such
behavior, however, has not been observed in our sample.

19

of the stock market that leads companies to find themselves with a lower leverage than the
target. On the other hand, easy credit policy has enabled companies to borrow to finance new
investments. Such firms will often have an above-target leverage. Such behavior is rational as
the risk premium on bank loan interest rates is too low.

An additional result from the dynamic analysis is the coefficient of the lagged profitability
variable (PROFit-1), which is positive and significant at the 1% level when total debt is
considered. The impact of lagged profitability on leverage, however, is only half that of
current profitability. The coefficient on lagged profitability is not significant when long term
debt only is used. This result confirms a short-term pecking order behavior by Swiss firms.
One possible reason could be that Swiss banks have made use of historical data when granting
loans; in such a context, one would expect past profitability to play an important role.
5.

Concluding Remarks

This paper presents a study of the determinants of capital structure for Swiss companies. The
analyses are performed using data pertaining to 106 firms for the period 1991-2000. Both
static and dynamic tests are conducted, and panel data specifications are used. The dynamic
analysis is conducted using a combination of the GMM approach and instrumental variables
to check for endogeneity in variables.

Our results show that the size of companies, the importance of tangible assets and business
risk are positively related to leverage, while growth and current profitability are negatively
associated with leverage. The dynamic analysis suggests that there exists a target debt-to
equity ratio. Lagged profitability has a positive impact on leverage, which confirms the
prediction of a short term pecking order behavior towards the target ratio. However, the
adjustment process is shown to be very slow. We argue that the most realistic explanation is
that being in disequilibrium is not costly for Swiss companies.

Once data for a longer time period are available, research should focus on the analysis of the
stability of the speed of adjustment of Swiss firms towards the target debt-to-equity ratio.
Also, the results contained in our paper suggest that macroeconomic events and the
institutional context play an important role on the capital structure decisions of Swiss
companies. It would seem appropriate that further research focus on the role played by the

20

institutional framework, such as the impact of taxation and that of the relative importance of
the various sources of credit (securitized debt vs. bank debt).

From an empirical perspective, emphasis should be placed on constructing dynamic models


that enable to discriminate between the various factors that impact on the target and those that
impact on the speed of adjustment. Finally, focus should be placed on the ownership structure
of Swiss companies to examine how firms make their financing decisions.

21

References
Arellano, M. and Bond, S., Some tests of specification for panel data: Monte Carlo evidence and an application
to employment equations, Review of Economic Studies, Vol. 58, 1991, pp. 277-297.
Booth, L., Aivazian, V., Demirguc-Kunt, A. and Maksimovic, V., Capital structure in developing countries,
Journal of Finance, Vol. 56, 2001, pp. 87-130.
BNS, Statistiques des crdits, Bulletin Trimestriels de Statistiques Bancaires, Banque Nationale Suisse, 19922001.
Chaterjee, S. and Price, B., Regression analysis by example, New York: John Wiley, 1977.
Chirinko. R.S. and Singha A.R., Testing static tradeoff against pecking order models of capital structure: a
critical comment, Journal of Financial Economics, Vol. 58, 2000, pp. 417-425.
DeAngelo, H. and Masulis, R., Optimal capital structure under corporate and personal taxation, Journal of
Financial Economics, Vol. 8, 1980, pp. 3-29.
De Miguel, A. and Pindado J., Determinants of capital structure: new evidence from spanish panel data,
Journal of Corporate Finance, Vol. 7, 2001, pp. 77-99.
Fama, E.F. and MacBeth, J.D., Risk, return, and equilibrium: empirical tests, Journal of Political Economy,
Vol. 81, 1973, pp. 607-636.
Frank, M. and Goyal, Testing the pecking order theory of capital structure, forthcoming Journal of Financial
Economics, 2002.
Ferri, M. and Jones, W., Determinants of financial structure: a new methodological approach, Journal of
Finance, Vol. 34, 1979, pp. 631-644.
Fischer, E.O., Heinkel, R. and Zechner, J., Dynamic capital structure choice: theory and tests, Journal of
Finance, Vol. 44, 1989, pp. 19-40.
Goyal, V. K., Lehn, K. Racic, S., Growth opportunities and corporate debt policy: the case of the U.S. defense
industry Journal of financial economics, Vol.64, 2002, pp. 35-59.
Graham, J. R., How big are the tax benefits of debt?, Journal of Finance, Vol. 55, 2000, pp. 1901-1940.
Greene, W.H., Econometric analysis, 3rd ed. Prentice-Hall international, 1997.
Grossman, S. and Hart, O., Corporate financial structure and managerial incentives, In McCall, J. (ed.), The
economics of information and uncertainty: University of Chicago Press, 1982.
Guide des actions suisses. Verlag Finanz und Wirtschaft AG (ed.), 1991-2001.
Harris, M. and Raviv, A., Capital structure and the informational role of debt, Journal of Finance, Vol. 45,
1990, pp.321-49.
Harris, M., and Raviv, A., The theory of capital structure, Journal of Finance, Vol. 46, 1991, pp. 297-355.
Hausman, J., Specifications tests in econometrics, Econometrica, Vol. 46, 1978, pp. 1251-1271.
Hertig, G., Lenders as a force in corporate governance: criteria and practical examples for Switzerland, In
Hopt, K.J. et al. (ed), Comparative corporate governance -The state of the art and emerging research-,
Oxford University Press, 1998.
Hsiao, C., Analysis of panel data, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, England, 1986
Hovakimian, A., Opler, T. and Titman, S., The debt-equity choice, Journal of Financial and Quantitative
Analysis, Vol. 36, 2001, pp. 1-24.
Jalilvand, A. and Harris R.S., Corporate behavior in adjusting to capital structure and dividend targets: an
econometric study, Journal of Finance Vol. 39, 1984, pp. 127-145.
Jensen, M., Agency costs of free cash flow, corporate finance and takeovers American Economic Review, Vol.
76, 1986, pp. 323-329.
Jensen, M. and Meckling, W., Theory of the firm: managerial behavior, agency costs and capital structure,
Journal of Financial Economics, Vol. 3, 1976, pp. 305-360.
Jung K., Kim, Y. and Stulz, R., Timing, investment opportunities, managerial discretion, and the security issue
decision, Journal of Financial Economics, Vol. 42, 1996, pp. 159-185.
Kremp, E., Stss E., and Gerdesmeier, D. Estimation of a debt function: evidence from French and German firm
panel data, in Sauv, A., Scheuer, M. (ed.) Corporate finance in Germany and France. A joint research
project of Deutsche Bundesbank and the Banque de France, SSRN working paper, 1999.
La Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silanes, F., Shleifer, A. and Vishny, R.W., Law and finance, Journal of Political
Economy, Vol.106, 1998, pp.1113-1155.
Leland, H.E., Agency costs, risk management and capital structure, Journal of Finance, Vol. 53, 1998, pp.
1213-1243.
Marsh, P., The choice between equity and debt: an empirical study, Journal of Finance, Vol. 37, 1982, pp.
121-144.
Miller M., Debt and taxes, Journal of Finance, Vol. 32, 1977, pp. 261-275.
Modigliani, F. and Miller, M.H., The cost of capital, corporate finance, and the theory of investment, American
Economic Review, Vol. 48, 1958, pp. 261-297

22

Modigliani, F. and Miller, M.H., Corporate income taxes and the cost of capital: a correction, American
Economic Review, Vol. 53, 1963, pp. 433-92.
Myers, S.C., Determinants of corporate borrowing, Journal of Financial Economics, Vol. 5, 1977, pp. 147175.
Myers, S.C., The capital structure puzzle, Journal of Finance, Vol. 34, 1984, pp. 575-592.
Myers, S.C. and Majluf, N.S., Corporate financing and investment decisions when firms have information that
investors do not have, Journal of Financial Economics, Vol.13, 1984, pp. 187-221.
Ozkan, A., Determinants of capital structure and adjustment to long run target: evidence from UK company
panel data, Journal of Business Finance and Accounting, Vol. 28, 2001, pp.175-199.
Rajan, R.G. and Zingales, L., What do we know about capital structure? Some evidence from international
data, Journal of Finance, Vol. 50, 1995, pp. 1421-60.
Scott, J., Bankruptcy, secured debt, and optimal capital structure, Journal of Finance Vol. 32, 1977, pp. 1-19.
Shyam-Sunder, L., and Myers S. C., Testing static tradeoff against pecking order models of capital structure,
Journal of Financial Economics, Vol. 51, 1999, pp. 219-244.
Smith, C.W. and Warner, J.B., On financial contracting: an analysis of bond covenants, Journal of Financial
Economics, Vol. 7, 1979, pp. 117-116.
Stiglitz, J. E., Some aspects of the pure theory of corporate finance: bankruptcies and takeovers, Bell Journal of
Economics and Management Science, Vol. 3(2), 1972, pp. 458-482.
Stulz, R., Managerial discretion and optimal financing policies, Journal of Financial Economics, Vol. 26,
1990, pp. 3-27.
Taggart, R.A., A model of corporate financing decisions, Journal of Finance, Vol. 32, 1977, pp. 1467-1484.
Titman, S. and Wessels, R., The determinants of capital structure choice, Journal of Finance, Vol. 43, 1988,
pp. 1-19.
Titman, S., The effect of capital structure on the firms liquidation decision, Journal of Financial Economics,
Vol. 13, 1984, pp. 137-152.
White, H., A heteroskedasticity-consistent covariance matrix estimator and a direct test for heteroskedasticity,
Econometrica, Vol. 48, 1980, pp. 817-838.

23

Table I: Descriptive statistics


This table presents descriptive statistics for the variables used in our estimations. The data are from
Worldscope and the sample contains 106 Swiss firms listed on the Swiss stock exchange (SWX) for which we
have a minimum of six consecutive years of data for the period 1991-2000. DTAB is the ratio of total debt to
total assets where the total assets are measured with book values. DTAM is the ratio of total debt to total assets
where the total assets is the sum of the book value of debt plus the market value of equity at the end of the year.
SIZE is the natural logarithm of sales in real terms (base year = 1992). TANG is the ratio of tangible assets plus
inventories to total assets using book values. GROWTH is the ratio of market value of assets (book value of
assets plus market value of equity less book value of equity) to book value of assets. PROF is the ratio EBIT to
total assets. RISK is the squared difference between the firms profitability (PROF) and the cross section mean
of profitability for year t. To this squared measure we add the sign of the difference between the firms
profitability and the cross section mean. Summary statistics include the mean and the standard deviation for
years 1991, 1994, 1997, and 2000. For the total period (1991-2000), we also report the minimum and maximum.
1991
Mean Std
DTAB
0.573 0.135
DTAM
0.569 0.186
SIZE
13.356 1.660
TANG
0.569 0.202
GROWTH 1.095 0.392
PROF
0.066 0.046
RISK
0.016 0.401
N
85
Year

1994
Mean Std
0.575 0.153
0.518 0.196
13.523 1.611
0.571 0.188
1.245 0.500
0.077 0.056
0.053 0.783
100

1997
Mean Std
0.563 0.151
0.468 0.197
13.645 1.672
0.549 0.193
1.456 0.808
0.082 0.059
0.011 0.926
105

2000
Mean Std
0.542 0.157
0.402 0.191
13.895 1.611
0.465 0.178
1.874 1.645
0.092 0.066
0.097 1.065
86

Mean
0.566
0.497
13.583
0.548
1.370
0.077
0.037

1991-2000
Std
Min
0.152 0.004
0.203 0.001
1.631 9.055
0.191 0.000
0.846 0.590
0.060 -0.257
0.908 -10.302
967

Max
0.892
0.883
18.287
0.987
11.810
0.358
7.111

24

Table II: Pearson correlation coefficients between variables and VIF coefficients
This table presents the Pearson correlation coefficients for the variables used in our estimations and VIF
(variance inflation factor) tests between dependent variables. The data are from Worldscope and the sample
contains 106 Swiss firms listed on the Swiss stock exchange (SWX) for which we have a minimum of six
consecutive years of data for the period 1991-2000. DTAB is the ratio of total debt to total assets where the total
assets are measured with book values. DTAM is the ratio of total debt to total assets where the total assets is the
sum of the book value of debt plus the market value of equity at the end of the year. SIZE is the natural logarithm
of sales in real terms (base year = 1992). TANG is the ratio of tangible assets plus inventories to total assets
using book values. GROWTH is the ratio of market value of assets (book value of assets plus market value of
equity less book value of equity) to book value of assets. PROF is the ratio EBIT to total assets. RISK is the
squared difference between the firms profitability (PROF) and the cross section mean of profitability for year t.
To this squared measure we add the sign of the difference between the firms profitability and the cross section
mean.

DTAM
DTAB
SIZE
TANG
MTB
PROF
RISK

DTAM

DTAB

0.6985
-0.0113
0.2920
-0.6725
-0.6295
-0.4480

0.1533
0.0581
-0.2519
-0.4145
-0.3615

SIZE

-0.3573
0.0738
0.0748
0.0305

TANG

-0.3056
-0.3200
-0.2326

MTB

0.5413
0.4155

PROF

VIF

0.8744

1.15
1.31
1.48
5.23
4.37

25

Table III: Static results


In this table we present various static estimations of the determinants of leverage. The data are from Worldscope and the sample contains 106 Swiss firms listed on the Swiss
stock exchange (SWX) for which we have a minimum of six consecutive years of data for the period 1991-2000. DTAB is the ratio of total debt to total assets where the total
assets are measured with book values. DTAM is the ratio of total debt to total assets where the total assets is the sum of the book value of debt plus the market value of equity
at the end of the year. SIZE is the natural logarithm of sales in real terms (base year = 1992). TANG is the ratio of tangible assets plus inventories to total assets using book
values. GROWTH is the ratio of market value of assets (book value of assets plus market value of equity less book value of equity) to book value of assets. PROF is the ratio
EBIT to total assets. RISK is the squared difference between the firms profitability (PROF) and the cross section mean of profitability for year t. To this squared measure we
add the sign of the difference between the firms profitability and the cross section mean.
For the Fama-McBeth approach, we report the average of the time series of coefficients from cross sectional regressions. The models with year dummy variables and year
and sector dummy variables use a dummy for each year 1992-2000 and a dummy for each sector defined by the first digit SIC code, respectively. Standard errors are reported
in brackets. When appropriate, standard errors are White (1980) corrected for heteroskedasticity. *** indicates significance at the 1% level. ** indicates significance at the
5% level. * indicates significance at the 10% level. Wald 1 is a test of the joint significance of time dummy variables. Wald 2 is a test of the joint significance of sector dummy
variables. Wald 1 and 2 are asymptotically distributed as 2 under the null hypothesis of no relationship. The Chow test is a F test for the equality of two sets of coefficients.
The Hausman test is a test with H0: random effects are consistent and efficient, versus H1: random effects are inconsistent. Degrees of freedom are reported in brackets.

26

OLS
DTAM
Intercept
SIZE

Fama-McBeth
DTAB

DTAM

DTAB

Estimations with dummy variables for:


Years
Years and sectors
DTAM
DTAB
DTAM
DTAB

0.652
0.445
0.718
0.410
(0.051)*** (0.053)*** (0.054)*** (0.045)***
0.010
0.017
0.010
0.018
0.010
0.017
0.010
0.017
(0.003)*** (0.003)*** (0.002)*** (0.002)*** (0.003)*** (0.003)*** (0.003)*** (0.004)***
0.051
-0.020
0.021
-0.019
0.047
-0.023
0.062
-0.006
(0.027)***
(0.027)
(0.025)
(0.021)
(0.027)*
(0.027)
(0.028)*
(0.030)
-0.105
-0.009
-0.165
0.012
-0.099
-0.008
-0.099
-0.009
(0.018)***
(0.006)
(0.023)***
(0.014)
(0.018)***
(0.006)
(0.018)***
(0.006)
-2.263
-1.083
-2.054
-1.253
-2.208
-1.086
-2.122
-1.003
(0.253)*** (0.158)*** (0.144)*** (0.249)*** (0.246)*** (0.162)*** (0.241)*** (0.172)***
0.074
0.004
0.083
0.019
0.068
0.003
0.063
0.000
(0.015)***
(0.010)
(0.016)***
(0.020)
(0.015)***
(0.011)
(0.014)***
(0.011)

Panel data with:


Fixed effects
Random effects
DTAM
DTAB
DTAM
DTAB

0.025
(0.009)***
0.210
(0.034)***
-0.063
(0.005)***
-1.540
(0.125)***
0.038
(0.007)***

0.034
(0.009)***
0.112
(0.036)***
-0.020
(0.005)***
-0.701
(0.132)***
-0.006
(0.007)

0.019
(0.005)***
0.186
(0.029)***
-0.068
(0.005)***
-1.627
(0.123)***
0.041
(0.007)***

0.026
(0.006)***
0.090
(0.031)***
-0.019
(0.005)***
-0.738
(0.129)***
-0.005
(0.007)

0.600

0.259

0.599

0.258

0.535

0.143

0.561

0.154

0.550
17.9(10)

0.176
0.8(10)

0.567
187.6(10)

0.188
17.05(10)

20.3(105)

19.3(105)
29.7(14)

10.1(14)

967

967

TANG
MTB
PROF
RISK
R2 ajusted

0.580

0.205

0.598

0.210

0.588

0.210

0.595

0.204

R within
R between
2

R overall
Wald 1
Wald 2
Chow
Hausman
N

21.1(10)

967

967

10

10

967

7.3(10)

967

15.6(10)
4.7(5)

967

4.5(10)
2.8(5)

967

967

967

27

Table IV: Dynamic results


In this table we present Arellano and Bond one-step and two-step GMM estimators. The data are from
Worldscope and the sample contains 106 Swiss firms listed on the Swiss stock exchange (SWX) for which we
have a minimum of six consecutive years of data for the period 1991-2000. DTAB is the ratio of total debt to
total assets where the total assets are measured with book values. DTAM is the ratio of total debt to total assets
where the total assets is the sum of the book value of debt plus the market value of equity at the end of the year.
SIZE is the natural logarithm of sales in real terms (base year = 1992). TANG is the ratio of tangible assets plus
inventories to total assets using book values. GROWTH is the ratio of market value of assets (book value of
assets plus market value of equity less book value of equity) to book value of assets. PROF is the ratio EBIT to
total assets. RISK is the squared difference between the firms profitability (PROF) and the cross section mean
of profitability for year t. To this squared measure we add the sign of the difference between the firms
profitability and the cross section mean. Robust standard deviations are reported in brackets. *** indicates
significance at the 1% level. ** indicates significance at the 5% level. * indicates significance at the 10% level.
Wald 1 is a test of the joint significance of time dummy variables. Wald 3 is a test of the joint significance of the
estimated coefficients. Wald 1 and 3 are asymptotically distributed as 2 under the null hypothesis of no
relationship. The Sargan test of over-identifying restrictions is asymptotically distributed as 2 under the null of
instrument validity. The m2 test is a test for second order autocorrelation of residuals and is distributed as
N(0,1).
Arellano-Bond Estimator (two-step)

DTit-1

Arellano-Bond Estimator (one-step)

DTAM

DTAB

DTAM

DTAB

DTAM

DTAB

DTAM

DTAB

0.609

0.759

0.726

0.889

0.708

0.734

0.777

0.844

(0.059)*** (0.045)*** (0.063)*** (0.050)*** (0.108)*** (0.101)*** (0.121)*** (0.102)***


SIZE

0.066

0.075

0.060

0.078

0.069

(0.011)*** (0.013)*** (0.011)*** (0.013)*** (0.017)***


TANG
MTB
PROF

0.052

0.069

0.048

(0.021)**

(0.018)***

(0.022)**

0.119

0.020

0.126

0.017

0.176

0.114

0.192

0.138

(0.042)***

(0.044)

(0.045)***

(0.046)

(0.092)*

(0.137)

(0.093)**

(0.141)

-0.092

0.000

-0.095

-0.002

-0.070

-0.002

-0.072

-0.004

(0.011)***

(0.004)

(0.012)***

(0.005)

(0.019)***

(0.009)

(0.019)***

(0.010)

-0.989

-0.838

-0.979

-0.854

-0.954

-0.745

-0.927

-0.736

(0.126)*** (0.098)*** (0.118)*** (0.105)*** (0.196)*** (0.154)*** (0.194)*** (0.166)***


PROFit-1

0.331

0.406

0.399

0.451

(0.142)***

(0.201)**

0.006

0.028

0.010

(0.009)

(0.009)***

(0.010)

(0.074)*** (0.063)***
RISK

0.025

0.012

0.028

0.016

0.025

(0.005)***

(0.005)**

Wald 1

164.0(8)

22.8(8)

151.6(8)

25.6(8)

73.5(8)

14.41(8)

73.2(8)

16.4(8)

Wald 3

934.8(6)

1003.7(6)

952.5(7)

1015.7(7)

342.1(6)

236.7(6)

353.9(7)

271.6(7)

Sargan

35.7(35)

36.5(35)

38.0 (35)

32.2 (35)

48.9(35)

68.0(35)

48.2(35)

61.1(35)

m2

0.94

-1.41

1.22

-1.59

0.83

-1.48

1.14

-1.75

755

755

755

755

755

755

755

755

(0.005)*** (0.006)*** (0.008)***

28

RESEARCH PAPER SERIES


Extra copies of research papers are available to the public upon request. In order to obtain copies of past or future works, please
contact our office at the following address: International Center FAME, 40 bd. du Pont dArve, Case Postale 3, 1211 Geneva 4.
As well, please note that these works are available on our website www.fame.ch, under the heading "Research" in PDF format for
your consultation. We thank you for your continuing support and interest in FAME, and look forward to serving you in the future.
N 67: Linear-Quadratic Jump-Diffusion Modelling with Application to Stochastic Volatility
Peng CHENG, HEC Lausanne and FAME, Universit de Lausanne and Olivier SCAILLET, HEC Genve
and FAME, Universit de Genve; November 2002
N 66: Optimal Asset Allocation for Pension Funds Under Mortality Risk During the Accumulation
and Decumulation Phases
Paolo BATTOCCHIO, IRES, Universit Catholique de Louvain; Francesco MENONCIN, IRES, Universit
Catholique de Louvain and Olivier SCAILLET, HEC Genve and FAME, Universit de Genve; January 2003
N 65: Exploring for the Determinants of Credit Risk in Credit Default Swap Transaction Data:
Is Fixed-Income Markets Information Sufficient to Evaluate Credit
Daniel AUNON-NERIN, HEC-University of Lausanne and FAME; Didier COSSIN, HEC-University of Lausanne,
FAME and IMD; Tomas HRICKO, HEC-University of Lausanne and FAME and Zhijiang HUANG, HECUniversity of Lausanne and FAME; December 2002
N 64: Dynamic Allocation of Treasury and Corporate Bond Portfolios
Roger WALDER, University of Lausanne, International Center FAME and Banque Cantonale Vaudoise;
December 2002
N 63: Understanding the Economic Value of Legal Covenants in Investment Contracts:
A Real-Options Approach to Venture Equity Contracts
Didier COSSIN, HEC-University of Lausanne, FAME and IMD; Benot LELEUX, IMD, Entela SALIASI,
HEC-University of Lausanne and FAME; October 2002
N 62: Integrated Market and Credit Risk Management of Fixed Income Portfolios
Roger WALDER, University of Lausanne, International Center FAME and Banque Cantonale Vaudoise;
November 2002
N 61: A Framework for Collateral Risk Control Determination
Daniel AUNON-NERIN, HEC-University of Lausanne and FAME; Didier COSSIN, HEC-University of Lausanne,
FAME and IMD; Fernando GONZLEZ, European Central Bank and Zhijiang HUANG, HEC-University of
Lausanne and FAME; December 2002
N 60: Optimal Dynamic Trading Strategies with Risk Limits
Domenico CUOCO, The Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania; Hua HE, School of Management, Yale
University and Sergei ISSAENKO, The Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania; Winner of the 2002 FAME
Research Prize
N 59: Implicit Forward Rents as Predictors of Future Rents
Peter ENGLUND, Stockholm Institute for Financial Research and Stockholm School of Economics;
ke GUNNELIN, Stockholm Institute for Financial Research; Martin HOESLI University of Geneva
(HEC and FAME) and University of Aberdeen (Business School) and Bo SDERBERG, Royal Institute
of Technology; October 2002

N 58: Do Housing Submarkets Really Matter?


Steven C. BOURASSA, School of Urban and Public Affairs, University of Louisville; Martin HOESLI,
University of Geneva (HEC and FAME) and University of Aberdeen (Business School) and Vincent S. PENG,
AMP Henderson Global Investors; November 2002
N 57: Nonparametric Estimation of Copulas for Time Series
Jean-David FERMANIAN, CDC Ixis Capital Markets and CREST and Olivier SCAILLET, HEC Genve
and FAME, Universit de Genve; November 2002
N 56: Interactions Between Market and Credit Risk: Modeling the Joint Dynamics of Default-Free
and Defaultable Bond Term Structures
Roger WALDER, University of Lausanne, International Center FAME and Banque Cantonale Vaudoise;
November 2002
N 55: Option Pricing With Discrete Rebalancing
Jean-Luc PRIGENT, THEMA, Universit de Cergy-Pontoise; Olivier RENAULT, Financial Markets Group,
London School of Economics and Olivier SCAILLET, HEC Genve and FAME, University of Geneva; July 2002
N 54: The Determinants of Stock Returns in a Small Open Economy
Sverine CAUCHIE, HEC-University of Geneva, Martin HOESLI, University of Geneva (HEC and FAME) and
University of Aberdeen (School of Business) and Duan ISAKOV, HEC-University of Geneva and International
Center FAME; September 2002
N 53: Permanent and Transitory Factors Affecting the Dynamics of the Term Structure of Interest Rates
Christophe PRIGNON, Anderson School, UCLA and Christophe VILLA, ENSAI, CREST-LSM and
CREREG-Axe Finance; June 2002
N 52: Hedge Fund Diversification: How Much is Enough?
Franois-Serge LHABITANT, Thunderbird University, HEC-University of Lausanne and FAME;
Michelle LEARNED, Thunderbird University; July 2002
N 51: Cannibalization & Incentives in Venture Financing
Stefan ARPING, University of Lausanne; May 2002
N 50: What Factors Determine International Real Estate Security Returns?
Foort HAMELINK, Lombard Odier & Cie, Vrije Universiteit and FAME; Martin HOESLI, University of Geneva
(HEC and FAME) and University of Aberdeen; July 2002
N 49: Playing Hardball: Relationship Banking in the Age of Credit Derivatives
Stefan ARPING, University of Lausanne; May 2002
N 48: A Geometric Approach to Multiperiod Mean Variance Optimization of Assets and Liabilities
Markus LEIPPOLD, Swiss Banking Institute, University of Zurich; Fabio TROJANI, Institute of Finance,
University of Southern Switzerland; Paolo VANINI, Institute of Finance, University of Southern Switzerland;
April 2002
N 47: Why Does Implied Risk Aversion Smile?
Alexandre ZIEGLER, University of Lausanne and FAME; May 2002

N 46: Optimal Investment With Default Risk


Yuanfeng HOU, Yale University; Xiangrong JIN, FAME and University of Lausanne; March 2002
N 45: Market Dynamics Around Public Information Arrivals
Angelo RANALDO, UBS Asset Management; February 2002
N 44: Nonparametric Tests for Positive Quadrant Dependence
Michel DENUIT, Universit Catholique de Louvain, Olivier SCAILLET, HEC Genve and FAME,
University of Geneva; March 2002
N 43: Valuation of Sovereign Debt with Strategic Defaulting and Rescheduling
Michael WESTPHALEN, cole des HEC, University of Lausanne and FAME; February 2002
N 42: Liquidity and Credit Risk
Jan ERICSSON, McGill University and Olivier RENAULT, London School of Economics; August 2001
N 41: Testing for Concordance Ordering
Ana C. CEBRIN, Universidad de Zaragoza, Michel DENUIT, Universit Catholique de Louvain,
Olivier SCAILLET, HEC Genve and FAME, University of Geneva; March 2002
N 40: Immunization of Bond Portfolios: Some New Results
Olivier de La GRANDVILLE, University of Geneva; February 2002
N 39: Weak Convergence of Hedging Strategies of Contingent Claims
Jean-Luc PRIGENT, Thema, Universit de Cergy-Pontoise; Olivier SCAILLET, HEC Genve and FAME,
University of Geneva; January 2002
N 38: Indirect Estimation of the Parameters of Agent Based Models of Financial Markets
Manfred GILLI, University of Geneva; Peter WINKER, International University in Germany; November 2001
N 37: How To Diversify Internationally? A comparison of conditional and unconditional asset allocation methods.
Laurent BARRAS, HEC-University of Geneva, International Center FAME; Duan ISAKOV, HEC-University of
Geneva, International Center FAME; November 2001
N 36: Coping with Credit Risk
Henri LOUBERG, University of Geneva, Harris SCHLESINGER, University of Alabama; October 2001
N 35: Country, Sector or Style: What matters most when constructing Global Equity Portfolios? An empirical
investigation from 1990-2001.
Foort HAMELINK, Lombard Odier & Cie and Vrije Universiteit; Hlne HARASTY, Lombard Odier & Cie;
Pierre HILLION, Insead (Singapore), Academic Advisor to Lombard Odier & Cie; October 2001
N 34: Variable Selection for Portfolio Choice
Yacine AT-SAHALIA, Princeton University & NBER, and Michael W. BRANDT, Wharton School,
University of Pennsylvania & NBER; February 2001
(Please note: The complete paper is available from the Journal of Finance 56, 1297-1351.)
N 33: The Characteristics of Individual Analysts Forecast in Europe
Guido BOLLIGER, University of Neuchtel and FAME; July 2001

N 32: Portfolio Diversification: Alive and Well in Euroland


Kpat ADJAOUTE, HSBC Republic Bank (Suisse), SA and Jean-Pierre DANTHINE, University of Lausanne,
CEPR and FAME; July 2001
N 31: EMU and Portfolio Diversification Opportunities
Kpate ADJAOUT, Morgan Stanley Capital International, Geneva and Jean-Pierre DANTHINE, University
of Lausanne, CEPR and FAME; April 2000
N 30: Serial and Parallel Krylov Methods for Implicit Finite Difference Schemes Arising in Multivariate
Option Pricing
Manfred GILLI, University of Geneva, Evis KLLEZI, University of Geneva and FAME,
Giorgio PAULETTO, University of Geneva; March 2001
N 29: Liquidation Risk
Alexandre ZIEGLER, HEC-University of Lausanne, Darrell DUFFIE, The Graduate School of Business,
Stanford University; April 2001
N 28: Defaultable Security Valuation and Model Risk
Aydin AKGUN, University of Lausanne and FAME; March 2001
N 27: On Swiss Timing and Selectivity: in the Quest of Alpha
Franois-Serge LHABITANT, HEC-University of Lausanne and Thunderbird, The American Graduate School
of International Management; March 2001
N 26: Hedging Housing Risk
Peter ENGLUND, Stockholm School of Economics, Min HWANG and John M. QUIGLEY, University
of California, Berkeley; December 2000
N 25: An Incentive Problem in the Dynamic Theory of Banking
Ernst-Ludwig VON THADDEN, DEEP, University of Lausanne and CEPR; December 2000
N 24: Assessing Market Risk for Hedge Funds and Hedge Funds Portfolios
Franois-Serge LHABITANT, Union Bancaire Prive and Thunderbird, the American
Graduate School of International Management; March 2001
N 23: On the Informational Content of Changing Risk for Dynamic Asset Allocation
Giovanni BARONE-ADESI, Patrick GAGLIARDINI and Fabio TROJANI, Universit della Svizzera Italiana;
March 2000
N 22: The Long-run Performance of Seasoned Equity Offerings with Rights: Evidence From the Swiss Market
Michel DUBOIS and Pierre JEANNERET, University of Neuchatel; January 2000
N 21: Optimal International Diversification: Theory and Practice from a Swiss Investor's Perspective
Foort HAMELINK, Tilburg University and Lombard Odier & Cie; December 2000
N 20: A Heuristic Approach to Portfolio Optimization
Evis KLLEZI; University of Geneva and FAME, Manfred GILLI, University of Geneva; October 2000

N 19: Banking, Commerce, and Antitrust


Stefan Arping; University of Lausanne; August 2000
N 18: Extreme Value Theory for Tail-Related Risk Measures
Evis KLLEZI; University of Geneva and FAME, Manfred GILLI, University of Geneva; October 2000
N 17: International CAPM with Regime Switching GARCH Parameters
Lorenzo CAPIELLO, The Graduate Institute of International Studies; Tom A. FEARNLEY, The Graduate Institute
of International Studies and FAME; July 2000
N 16: Prospect Theory and Asset Prices
Nicholas BARBERIS, University of Chicago; Ming HUANG, Stanford University; Tano SANTOS, University
of Chicago; September 2000
N 15: Evolution of Market Uncertainty around Earnings Announcements
Duan ISAKOV, University of Geneva and FAME; Christophe PRIGNON, HEC-University of Geneva
and FAME; June 2000
N 14: Credit Spread Specification and the Pricing of Spread Options
Nicolas MOUGEOT, IBFM-University of Lausanne and FAME; May 2000
N 13: European Financial Markets After EMU: A First Assessment
Jean-Pierre DANTHINE, Ernst-Ludwig VON THADDEN, DEEP, Universit de Lausanne and CEPR
and Francesco GIAVAZZI, Universit Bocconi, Milan, and CEPR; March 2000
N 12: Do fixed income securities also show asymmetric effects in conditional second moments?
Lorenzo CAPIELLO, The Graduate Institute of International Studies; January 2000
N 11: Dynamic Consumption and Portfolio Choice with Stochastic Volatility in Incomplete Markets
George CHACKO, Harvard University; Luis VICEIRA, Harvard University; September 1999
N 10: Assessing Asset Pricing Anomalies
Michael J. BRENNAN, University of California, Los Angeles; Yihong XIA, University of Pennsylvania; July 1999
N 9:

Recovery Risk in Stock Returns


Aydin AKGUN, University of Lausanne & FAME; Rajna GIBSON, University of Lausanne; July 1999

N 8:

Option pricing and replication with transaction costs and dividends


Stylianos PERRAKIS, University of Ottawa; Jean LEFOLL, University of Geneva; July1999

N 7:

Optimal catastrophe insurance with multiple catastrophes


Henri LOUBERG, University of Geneva; Harris SCHLESINGER, University of Alabama; September 1999

N 6:

Systematic patterns before and after large price changes: Evidence from high frequency data
from the Paris Bourse
Foort HAMELINK, Tilburg University; May 1999

N 5:

Who Should Buy Long-Term Bonds?


John CAMPBELL, Harvard University; Luis VICEIRA, Harvard Business School; October 1998

N 4:

Capital Asset Pricing Model and Changes in Volatility


Andr Oliveira SANTOS, Graduate Institute of International Studies, Geneva; September 1998

N 3:

Real Options as a Tool in the Decision to Relocate: An Application to the Banking Industry
Pascal BOTTERON, HEC-University of Lausanne; January 2000

N 2:

Application of simple technical trading rules to Swiss stock prices: Is it profitable?


Duan ISAKOV, HEC-Universit de Genve; Marc HOLLISTEIN, Banque Cantonale de Genve; January 1999

N 1:

Enhancing portfolio performance using option strategies: why beating the market is easy.
Franois-Serge LHABITANT, HEC-University of Lausanne; December 1998

International Center FAME - Partner Institutions


The University of Geneva
The University of Geneva, originally known as the Academy of Geneva, was founded in 1559 by Jean Calvin
and Theodore de Beze. In 1873, The Academy of Geneva became the University of Geneva with the
creation of a medical school. The Faculty of Economic and Social Sciences was created in 1915. The
university is now composed of seven faculties of science; medicine; arts; law; economic and social sciences;
psychology; education, and theology. It also includes a school of translation and interpretation; an institute of
architecture; seven interdisciplinary centers and six associated institutes.
More than 13000 students, the majority being foreigners, are enrolled in the various programs from the
licence to high-level doctorates. A staff of more than 2500 persons (professors, lecturers and assistants) is
dedicated to the transmission and advancement of scientific knowledge through teaching as well as
fundamental and applied research. The University of Geneva has been able to preserve the ancient European
tradition of an academic community located in the heart of the city. This favors not only interaction between
students, but also their integration in the population and in their participation of the particularly rich artistic and
cultural life. http://www.unige.ch

The University of Lausanne


Founded as an academy in 1537, the University of Lausanne (UNIL) is a modern institution of higher
education and advanced research. Together with the neighboring Federal Polytechnic Institute of Lausanne,
it comprises vast facilities and extends its influence beyond the city and the canton into regional, national, and
international spheres.
Lausanne is a comprehensive university composed of seven Schools and Faculties: religious studies; law; arts;
social and political sciences; business; science and medicine. With its 9000 students, it is a medium-sized
institution able to foster contact between students and professors as well as to encourage interdisciplinary
work. The five humanities faculties and the science faculty are situated on the shores of Lake Leman in the
Dorigny plains, a magnificent area of forest and fields that may have inspired the landscape depicted in
Brueghel the Elder's masterpiece, the Harvesters. The institutes and various centers of the School of
Medicine are grouped around the hospitals in the center of Lausanne. The Institute of Biochemistry is located
in Epalinges, in the northern hills overlooking the city. http://www.unil.ch

The Graduate Institute of International Studies


The Graduate Institute of International Studies is a teaching and research institution devoted to the study of
international relations at the graduate level. It was founded in 1927 by Professor William Rappard to
contribute through scholarships to the experience of international co-operation which the establishment of the
League of Nations in Geneva represented at that time. The Institute is a self-governing foundation closely
connected with, but independent of, the University of Geneva.
The Institute attempts to be both international and pluridisciplinary. The subjects in its curriculum, the
composition of its teaching staff and the diversity of origin of its student body, confer upon it its international
character. Professors teaching at the Institute come from all regions of the world, and the approximately 650
students arrive from some 60 different countries. Its international character is further emphasized by the use
of both English and French as working languages. Its pluralistic approach - which draws upon the methods of
economics, history, law, and political science -reflects its aim to provide a broad approach and in-depth
understanding of international relations in general. http://heiwww.unige.ch

Prospect Theory
and Asset Prices
Nicholas BARBERIS
University of Chicago

Ming HUANG
40, Bd. du Pont dArve
PO Box, 1211 Geneva 4
Switzerland
Tel (++4122) 312 09 61
Fax (++4122) 312 10 26
http: //www.fame.ch
E-mail: admin@fame.ch

Stanford University

Tano SANTOS
University of Chicago

2000 FAME Research Prize


Research Paper N 16

FAME - International Center for Financial Asset Management and Engineering

THE GRADUATE INSTITUTE OF


INTERNATIONAL STUDIES

You might also like