You are on page 1of 51

Mathematics for Economists 326

January 6, 2016

Mathematics for Economists 326

January 6, 2016

1 / 177

Preliminaries

Mathematics for Economists 326

January 6, 2016

2 / 177

Sets

A set is any collection of elements. Sets of objects will usually be denoted


by capital letters, A, S, T for example, while their members by lower case,
a, s, t for example (English or Greek). A set S is a subset of another set T
if every element of S is also an element of T . We write S T . If S T ,
then x S x T .

Mathematics for Economists 326

January 6, 2016

3 / 177

Sets

The set S is a proper subset of T if S T and S 6= T ; sometimes one


writes S ( T or S T in this case. Two sets are equal sets if they each
contain exactly the same elements. We write S = T whenever
x S x T and x T x S.
I

The upside down A, , means for all

The backward E , means there exists.

Mathematics for Economists 326

January 6, 2016

4 / 177

Sets

A set S is empty or is an empty set if it contains no elements at all. It is a


subset of every set. For example, if A = {x | x 2 = 0, x > 1}, then A is
empty. We denote the empty set by the symbol . The complement of a
set S in a universal set U is the set of all elements in U that are not in S
and is denoted S c . For any two sets S and T in a universal set U, we
define the set difference denoted S\T , as all elements in the set S that are
not elements of T . Thus, we can think S c = U\S.

Mathematics for Economists 326

January 6, 2016

5 / 177

Sets

For two sets S and T , we define the union of S and T as the set
S T {x | x S or x T }.
We define the intersection of S and T as the set S T {x | x S and
x T }.

Mathematics for Economists 326

January 6, 2016

6 / 177

Sets

The following are some important identities involving the operations


defined above.
A B = B A, A B = B A (Commutative laws)
A (B C ) = (A B) (A C ), A (B C ) = (A B) (A C )
(Distribute laws)
(A B) C = A (B C ), (A B) C = A (B C ) (Associative
laws)

Mathematics for Economists 326

January 6, 2016

7 / 177

Sets

The collection of all subsets of a set A is also a set, called the power set of
A and denoted by P(A). Thus, B P(A) B A.

Example
Let A = {a, b, c}. Then, P(A) = {, {a}, {b}, {c}, {a, b},
{a, c}, {b, c}, {a, b, c}}.

Mathematics for Economists 326

January 6, 2016

8 / 177

Sets

The order of the elements in a set specification does not matter. In


particular, {a, b} = {b, a}. However, on many occasions, one is interested
in distinguishing between the first and the second elements of a pair. One
such example is the coordinates of a point in the x y -plane. These
coordinates are given as an ordered pair (a, b) of real numbers. The
important property of ordered pairs is that (a, b) = (c, d) if and only if
a = c and b = d.

Mathematics for Economists 326

January 6, 2016

9 / 177

Sets

The product of two sets S and T is the set of ordered pairs in the form
(s, t), where the first element in the pair is a member of S and the second
is a member of T . The product of S and T is denoted
S T {(s, t) | s S, t T }.
The set of real numbers is denoted by the special symbol R and is defined
as
R {x | < x < }.

Mathematics for Economists 326

January 6, 2016

10 / 177

Sets
Any n-tuple, or vector, is just an n dimensional ordered tuple (x1 , . . . , xn )
and can be thought of as a point in n dimensional Euclidean space. This
space is defined as the set product
Rn |R {z
R} {(x1 , . . . , xn ) | xi R, i = 1, . . . , n}.
n times

Often, we want to restrict our attention to a subset of Rn , called the


nonnegative orthant and denoted Rn+ , where
Rn+ {(x1 , . . . , xn ) | xi 0, i = 1, . . . , n} Rn .
Furthermore, we sometimes talk about the strictly positive orthant of Rn
Rn++ {(x1 , . . . , xn ) | xi > 0, i = 1, . . . , n} Rn+ .

Mathematics for Economists 326

January 6, 2016

11 / 177

Functions

A function is a relation that associates each element of one set with a


single, unique element of another set. We say that the function f is a
mapping, map, or transformation from one set D to another set Y and
write f : D Y .
We call the set D the domain and the set Y the codomain of the mapping.

Mathematics for Economists 326

January 6, 2016

12 / 177

Functions

If y is the point in the range mapped into by the point x in the domain,
we write y = f (x). In set-theoretic terms, f is a relation from D to Y
with the property that for each x D, there is exactly one y Y such
that xfy (x is related to y via f ).
The range of f is the subset of the codomain that contains all f (x); that is,
range(f ) = {y Y |x D s.t. f (x) = y }

Mathematics for Economists 326

January 6, 2016

13 / 177

Functions
The image of a subset S D under f is the set of points in the range into
which some point in S is mapped, i.e.,
f (S) {y Y | y = f (x) for some x S}
The inverse image (or preimage) of a set of points A Y defined as
f 1 (A) {x D | f (x) A}.
The graph of the function f is the set of ordered pairs
G {(x, y ) | x D, y = f (x)}.

Mathematics for Economists 326

January 6, 2016

14 / 177

Functions

If f (x) = y , one also writes x 7 y . The squaring function s : R R, for


example, can then be written as s : x 7 x 2 . Thus, 7 indicates the effect
of the function on an element of the domain. If f : D Y is a function
and S D, the restriction of f to S is the function f |S defined by
f |S (x) = f (x) for every x S.
There is nothing in the definition of a function that prohibits more than
one element in the domain from being mapped into the same element in
the range.

Mathematics for Economists 326

January 6, 2016

15 / 177

Sequences in R

A sequence is a function k 7 x(k) whose domain is the set {1, 2, 3, . . .} of


all positive integers. I denote the set of natural numbers by N = {1, 2, . . .}.
The terms x(1), x(2), . . . , x(k), . . . of the sequence are usually denoted by
using subscripts: x1 , x2 , . . . , xk , . . . . We shall use the notation {xk }
k=1 , or
simply {xk }, to indicate an arbitrary sequence of real numbers.

Mathematics for Economists 326

January 6, 2016

16 / 177

Sequences in R

A sequence {xk } of real numbers is said to be


1. nondecreasing if xk xk+1 for k = 1, 2, . . .
2. strictly increasing if xk < xk+1 for k = 1, 2, . . .
3. nonincreasing if xk xk+1 for k = 1, 2, . . .
4. strictly decreasing if xk > xk+1 for k = 1, 2, . . .
A sequence that is nondecreasing or nonincreasing is called monotone.

Mathematics for Economists 326

January 6, 2016

17 / 177

Sequences in R: Convergence

Definition
The sequence {xk } converge to x if for every > 0, there exists a natural
number N such that |xk x| < for all k > N . The number x is called
the limit of the sequence {xk }. A convergent sequence is one that
converges to some number.

Definition (Alternative definition)


The sequence {xk } converges to x if for every > 0, |xk x| < for all
but finitely many k.

Mathematics for Economists 326

January 6, 2016

18 / 177

Sequences in R

Note that the limit of a convergent sequence is unique. A sequence that


does not converge to any real number is said to diverge. In some cases we
use the notation limk xk even if the sequence {xk } is divergent. For
example, we say that xk as k . A sequence {xk } is bounded if
there exists a number M such that |xk | M for all k = 1, 2, . . . .

Mathematics for Economists 326

January 6, 2016

19 / 177

Sequences in R
It is easy to see that every convergent sequence is bounded. The converse
is true only for monotone sequences.

Theorem
Every bounded monotone sequence is convergent.

Theorem
Suppose that the sequences {xk } and {yk } converge to x and y ,
respectively. Then,
1. limk (xk yk ) = x y
2. limk (xk yk ) = x y
3. limk (xk /yk ) = x/y , assuming that yk 6= 0 for all k and y 6= 0.

Mathematics for Economists 326

January 6, 2016

20 / 177

Exercise 1
lim

n+1

n =?

Hint: (a b)(a + b) = a2 b 2 .

Exercise 2


1 n
lim 1 +
e
n
n
Hint: Take logs and use the fact log0 (1) = 1

Exercise 3
xk = 2, xk+1 =

xk + 2

Mathematics for Economists 326

January 6, 2016

21 / 177

Mathematics for Economists 326

January 6, 2016

22 / 177

Mathematics for Economists 326

January 6, 2016

23 / 177

Vectors
An n-vector a is an ordered n-tuple of numbers.
a = (a1 , a2 , . . . , an )
The operations of addition, subtraction and multiplication by scalars of
vectors are defined in the obvious way.
The dot product (or inner product) of the n-vectors a = (a1 , a2 , . . . , an )
and b = (b1 , b2 , . . . , bn ) is defined as
a b = a1 b1 + a2 b2 + + an bn =

n
X

ai bi

i=1

Mathematics for Economists 326

January 6, 2016

24 / 177

Vectors

Proposition
If a, b, and c are n-vectors and is a scalar, then
1. a b = b a,
2. a (b + c) = a b + a c,
3. (a) b = a (b) = (a b).
4. a a = 0 = a = 0
5. (a + b) (a + b) = a a + 2(a b) + b b.

Mathematics for Economists 326

January 6, 2016

25 / 177

Vectors

The Euclidean norm or length of the vector a = (a1 , a2 , . . . , an ) is


q

kak = a a = a12 + a22 + + an2


Note that kak = ||kak for all scalars and vectors.

Lemma (Cauchy-Schwartz inequality)


|a b| kak kbk

Mathematics for Economists 326

January 6, 2016

26 / 177

Vectors
The Cauchy-Schwartz inequality implies that, for any a, b Rn ,
1

ab
1.
kakkbk

Thus, the angle between nonzero vectors a and b Rn is defined by


cos =

ab
, |0, ]
kak kbk

This definition reveals that cos = 0 if and only if a b = 0. Then


= /2. In symbols,
a b a b = 0

Mathematics for Economists 326

January 6, 2016

27 / 177

Line and Hyperplane


Definition
The straight line in Rn that passes through the point a and b is the set of
points
{x | x = ta + (1 t)b for some t R}
Alternatively, we can eliminate t and write the equation for the line as
xn an
x1 a1
= ... =
b 1 a1
bn an

Definition
The hyperplane in Rn that passes through the point a = (a1 , . . . , an ) and
is orthogonal to the nonzero vector p = (p1 , . . . , pn ), is the set of all
points x = (x1 , . . . , xn ) such that
p (x a) = 0
Mathematics for Economists 326

January 6, 2016

28 / 177

Exercise 4
What is the equation of the line through (1, 5, 3), (4, 6, 0)?

Exercise 5
What is the equation of the plane through (1, 1, 1), (-1, 1, -1), and (1, -1,
-1)?

Mathematics for Economists 326

January 6, 2016

29 / 177

Mathematics for Economists 326

January 6, 2016

30 / 177

Point Set Topology in Rn

Consider the n-dimensional Euclidean space Rn , whose elements, or


points, are n-dimensional vectors x = (x1 , . . . , xn ). The Euclidean distance
d(x, y ) between any two points x = (x1 , . . . , xn ) and y = (y1 , . . . , yn ) in
Rn is the norm kx y k of the vector difference between x and y . Thus,
q
d(x, y ) = kx y k = (x1 y1 )2 + . . . + (xn yn )2

Mathematics for Economists 326

January 6, 2016

31 / 177

Point Set Topology in Rn


If x, y , and z are points in Rn , then
d(x, z) d(x, y ) + d(y , z) (triangle inequality )
If x0 is a point in Rn and r is a positive real number, then the set of all
points x Rn whose distance from x0 is less than r , is called the open ball
around x0 with radius r .
This open ball is denoted by Br (x0 ). Thus,
Br (x0 ) = {x Rn | d(x0 , x) < r }

Mathematics for Economists 326

January 6, 2016

32 / 177

Point Set Topology in Rn


Definition
A set S Rn is open if, for all x0 S, there exists some > 0 such that
B (x0 ) S.
On the real line R, the simplest type of open set is an open interval. Let S
be any subset of Rn . A point x0 S is called an interior point of S if
there is some > 0 such that B (x0 ) S. The set of all interior points of
S is called the interior of S, and is denoted int(S).
A set S is said to be a neighborhood of x0 if x0 is an interior point of S,
that is, if S contains some open ball B (x0 ) (i.e., B (x0 ) S) for some
> 0.

Mathematics for Economists 326

January 6, 2016

33 / 177

Point Set Topology in Rn

Theorem
1. The entire space Rn and the empty set are both open.
2. The union of open sets is open.
3. The intersection of finitely many open sets is open.

Mathematics for Economists 326

January 6, 2016

34 / 177

Point Set Topology in Rn


Each point in a set is either an interior point or a boundary point of the
set. The set of all boundary points of a set S is said to be the boundary of
S and is denoted S or bd(S). Given any set S Rn , there is a
corresponding partition of Rn into three mutually disjoint sets (some of
which may be empty), namely;
1. the interior of S, which consists of all points x Rn such that N S
for some neighborhood N of x;
2. the exterior of S, which consists of all points x Rn for which there
exists some neighborhood N of x such that N Rn \S;
3. the boundary of S, which consists of all points x Rn with the
property that every neighborhood N of x intersects both S and its
complement Rn \S.
The closure of a set S Rn is the union of the interior of the set and its
boundary, S = int S S. For a closed set, its closure is the set itself.
Mathematics for Economists 326

January 6, 2016

35 / 177

Topology and Convergence

The basic idea to do so is to apply the arguments developed earlier to R


n
coordinate-wise. A sequence {xk }
k=1 in R is a function that for each
natural number k yields a corresponding point xk in Rn .

Definition
A sequence {xk } in Rn converges to a point x Rn if for each > 0,
there exists a natural number N such that xk B (x) for all k N, or
equivalently, if d(xk , x) 0 as k .

Mathematics for Economists 326

January 6, 2016

36 / 177

Topology and Convergence

Definition
A set S Rn is bounded if there exists a number M R such that
kxk M for all x S. A set that is not bounded is called unbounded.
Similarly, a sequence {xk } in Rn is bounded if the set {xk |k = 1, 2, . . .} is
bounded.

Mathematics for Economists 326

January 6, 2016

37 / 177

Topology and Convergence

Theorem (Closed Sets)


A set S Rn is closed if and only if every convergent sequence of points
in S has its limit in S.
The next concept of compact sets is used extensively in both mathematics
and economics.

Definition
A set S in Rn is compact if it is closed and bounded.

Mathematics for Economists 326

January 6, 2016

38 / 177

Continuous Functions

Consider first a real-valued function z = f (x) = f (x1 , . . . , xn ) of n


variables. Roughly speaking, f is continuous if small changes in the
independent variables cause only small changes in the function value.

Theorem
A function f from S Rn into Rm is continuous at a point x0 in S if and
only if f (xk ) f (x0 ) for every sequence {xk } of points in S that
converges to x0 .

Mathematics for Economists 326

January 6, 2016

39 / 177

Limits of functions

Definition
L is a limit of function f : S R at x0 S, L = limxx0 f (x), if
xn x0 = f (xn ) L

Corollary
A function f : S R is continuous at x0 S if and only if
f (x0 ) = lim f (x)
xx0

Mathematics for Economists 326

January 6, 2016

40 / 177

Calculus: Functions of a Single Variable


The derivatives of function f () are defined as the limits
f 0 (x) = lim

h0

f (x + h) f (x)
,
h

f 0 (x + h) f 0 (x)
,
h0
h

f 00 (X ) = lim
and so on.

In general, a function may or may not have a derivative. If a function


possesses a continuous derivatives f 0 , f 00 , . . . , f n , it is called n-times
continuously differentiable, or a C n function.

Mathematics for Economists 326

January 6, 2016

41 / 177

Calculus: Single Variable

Some rules of differentiation is provided below:


For constants, : d/dx = 0.
For sums: d/dx[f (x) g (x)] = f 0 (x) g 0 (x).
Power rule: d/dx(x n ) = nx n1 .
Product rule: d/dx[f (x)g (x)] = f (x)g 0 (x) + f 0 (x)g (x)).
Quotient rule: d/dx[f (x)/g (x)] = (g (x)f 0 (x) f (x)g 0 (x))/[g (x)]2 .
Chain rule: d/dx[f (g (x))] = f 0 (g (x))g 0 (x).

Mathematics for Economists 326

January 6, 2016

42 / 177

Partial derivatives

Definition
Let y = f (x1 , . . . , xn ). The partial derivative of f with respect to xi is
defined as
f (x)
f (x1 , . . . , xi + h, . . . , xn ) f (x1 , . . . , xi , . . . , xn )
lim
h0
xi
h
y /xi or fi (x) or fi 0 (x) are also used to denote partial derivatives.

Mathematics for Economists 326

January 6, 2016

43 / 177

Gradients

Suppose that F (x) = F (x1 , . . . , xn ) is a function of n variables defined on


an open set A in Rn , and let x 0 = (x10 , . . . , xn0 ) be a point in A. The
gradient of F at x 0 is the vector


F (x 0 )
F (x 0 )
0
,...,
F (x ) =
x1
xn
of first-order partial derivatives.

Mathematics for Economists 326

January 6, 2016

44 / 177

Directional Derivative

We define the derivative of f along the vector a by


fa0 (x) = lim

h0

f (x + ha) f (x)
h

or, with components,


f (x1 + ha1 , . . . , xn + han ) f (xi , . . . , xn )
h0
h

fa0 (x1 , . . . , xn ) = lim

Usually, we normalize ||a|| = 1.

Mathematics for Economists 326

January 6, 2016

45 / 177

Gradient chain rule and directional derivative

Let x : R Rn be a C 1 function. Then


df (x(t))
= f (x(t)) x 0 (t)
dt

Corollary (Directional derivative through gradient)


fa0 (x) = f (x) a

Mathematics for Economists 326

January 6, 2016

46 / 177

Exercise 6

Find the derivative of f (x1 , x2 ) in the direction a = (1/ 2, 1/ 2)

Mathematics for Economists 326

January 6, 2016

47 / 177

Mathematics for Economists 326

January 6, 2016

48 / 177

Level Surface
Definition
For a function f : Rn R, and for a given x0 Rn , the level surface
through x0 is defined as
{x Rn : f (x) = f (x0 )}.

Definition
A curve on the surface through x0 is a mapping x : R Rn such that
f (x(t)) = f (x0 ),

x(0) = x0

Mathematics for Economists 326

January 6, 2016

49 / 177

Tangent Hyperplane

Definition
The tangent hyperplane is formed by the set of all tangent vectors x 0 (t0 )
of the curves on the level surface through x0 .
Applying the chain rule to f (x(t)) = f (x0 ), we see that the gradient
f (x0 ) is orthogonal to the tangent hyperplane.

Corollary
The tangent hyperplane to the level surface at point x0 is given by
{x Rn : f (x0 ) (x x0 ) = 0}

Mathematics for Economists 326

January 6, 2016

50 / 177

Gradient

Theorem
Suppose that f (x) = f (x1 , . . . , xn ) is C 1 . Then, at points x where
f (x) 6= 0, the gradient f (x) = (f1 (x), . . . , fn (x)) satisfies:
1. f (x) is orthogonal to the level surface through x.
2. f (x) points in the direction of maximal increase of f .
3. kf (x)k measures how fast the function increases in the direction of
maximal increase.

Mathematics for Economists 326

January 6, 2016

51 / 177

You might also like