You are on page 1of 3

Aftermath of World War 2

The Second World War and Its Aftermath

SEARCH THIS EVENT


1941-1951
by Daniel Sanches, Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia

The outbreak of war in Europe substantially changed the way in which the
Federal Reserve System was expected to operate as the nations central bank in
a period during which US participation in the conflict was imminent. The most
important challenge for the System was to deal with the possibility of very large
fiscal deficits due to increased war expenditures. Even before the period of active
US participation in the conflict, the expansion of the defense program and the
decision to help finance allies purchases of war material from the United States
(under the so-called lend-lease program) significantly increased US government
financing needs. After the decision to actively participate in the conflict, the US
government substantially increased its expenditures, confirming previous
expectations. Despite the fact that the Treasury relied more heavily on taxation
than in World War I and despite increased tax revenue from the substantial
expansion of industrial production, the active participation in the war resulted in
a sharp increase in the federal deficit.

Perhaps the most important actions performed by the System during the war
were to control government bond prices to promote stable financial markets and
(even more critical) to help reduce the interest rates on financing the
extraordinarily large fiscal deficits associated with active participation in the war.
In 1939, shortly before the beginning of the conflict in Europe, the System made
some open-market purchases to influence the yields on short-term government
bonds. The goal was to promote stability in short-term funding markets and
prevent market disorder in the face of uncertainty at the outset of the war. Once
the United States formally entered the conflict, the system made a firm
commitment to support government bond prices. In April 1942, the Federal Open
Market Committee announced that it would maintain the annual rate on Treasury
bills at three-eighths of 1 percent by buying or selling any amount of Treasury
bills offered or demanded at that rate. For longer-maturity government
securities, the System also established a maximum yield (or a minimum price) by
standing ready to buy whatever amount of these securities was necessary to
prevent their yields from rising above the maximum yield. Such a commitment to
maintain low yields (high prices) of government bills and bonds necessarily
resulted in the purchase of a significant volume of government securities,
producing a substantial expansion of the Systems balance sheet and, in

particular, of the monetary base. Indeed, the monetary base increased by 149
percent from August 1939 to August 1948.

An additional factor contributing to the increase in the monetary base, and as


an immediate consequence of the outbreak of war in Europe, was the
acceleration of gold inflows as Britain and other allies paid for war materials and
other supplies produced domestically by shipping gold to the United States.
These two factors resulted in a vigorous expansion of the monetary base and the
money supply. As a result, inflation rose significantly during the period. This
happened despite price and wage controls and consumer credit controls (and
despite an increased willingness of the nonbank public to hold a significant
fraction of their wealth in the form of monetary assets as reflected by the
marked decline in the velocity of money observed during the war).1

Most economists at the time believed that as soon as the war ended the
economy would likely fall into recession and the unemployment rate would rise
substantially, partly because of the experience of previous wars (and the
previous decade of the Great Depression) and partly because of the widespread
Keynesian view that fiscal stimulus was the most effective means of boosting
domestic economic activity, and such stimulus was about to decline with the end
of the war. This belief, combined with the decision to continue to hold down
Treasury financing costs, certainly contributed to the continuation of the
government bond support program for much longer than what would be
consistent with price stability. The inability of Federal Reserve officials to
persuade the Treasury to let the System abandon the government bond support
program (in view of other policy considerations such as price stability) clearly
demonstrated that the Federal Reserve System was effectively under Treasury
control. As economist Allan Meltzer notes in his book, Chairman Marriner Eccles
described his work in wartime as a routine administrative job[T]he Federal
Reserve merely executed Treasury decisions (Meltzer 2003, 579).

Given its inability to control growth of the monetary base through openmarket operations or the discount window, under the constraints of the program
to support government bond prices, the System used other tools to try to control
private sector spending and curb inflation. The System imposed direct controls
on consumer credit (through regulation W) by introducing minimum down
payments and maximum maturities on consumer credit extended through
installment loans. Because the reallocation of resources to military production
restricted the supply of consumer durable goods, the controls imposed on
consumer credit aimed to restrict the demand for these goods in an effort to
reduce the pressure on prices. Another major action taken during the period was
the increase in the reserve requirements of commercial banks in 1941. However,
this measure, which was intended to restrain credit growth and the expansion of

bank liabilities, had only a minor effect on the money supply and the trend in the
price level.

The end of the war did not mean that the System was automatically freed
from Treasury influence. Six years would go by before monetary policy was
revived as a major instrument to influence aggregate spending and prices. In
March 1951, the Systems policy independence from the Treasury was
accomplished with the formal agreement between the Treasury and the System
known as the Treasury-Federal Reserve Accord.

Endnotes
1 The velocity of money is the ratio of nominal GDP to a measure of the money
supply (M1 or M2). It can be thought of as the rate of turnover in the money
supply (i.e., the number of times one dollar is used to purchase final goods and
services included in GDP).

Bibliography
Meltzer, Allan H. A History of the Federal Reserve, Volume 1: 1913-1951.
Chicago: Chicago University Press, 2003.

Friedman, Milton and Anna J. Schwartz. A Monetary History of the United States,
1867-1960. Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1963.

You might also like