You are on page 1of 12

National Tax Journal, December 2012, 65 (4), 10111022

PROPERTY TAX INCENTIVE PITFALLS


Daphne A. Kenyon, Adam H. Langley, and Bethany P. Paquin

This paper relies on a review of the literature on property tax incentives for business,
a new database on property tax economic development incentives, and several state
case studies to identify pitfalls in using this economic development tool. Several
potential reforms are identified.
Keywords: property tax, economic development, tax incentive
JEL Codes: H25, H71, Z18

I. INTRODUCTION
roperty tax incentives for business are one of many tools used by state and local
governments to promote economic development. Although Kenyon, Langley, and
Paquin (2012) conclude that state and local governments spend $5 billion to $10 billion
per year on property tax incentives, amounting to 1 to 2 percent of total state and local
property tax revenues, such incentives frequently fall short of achieving their economic
development goals. This article aims to identify several of the major pitfalls in using
property tax incentives for business, and suggests potential reforms.
Property tax incentives for business take many forms: (1) property tax abatement
programs; (2) tax increment financing; (3) enterprise zones; (4) firm-specific property
tax incentives; and (5) tax-exempt industrial development bond (IDB) issuance when
it is combined with full or partial property tax exemption. To obtain information on the
first three types of property tax incentives, this paper relies heavily on detailed appendix
tables in Kenyon, Langley, and Paquin (2012), which in turn rely heavily on the online
database entitled Significant Features of the Property Tax, published since 2008 by
the Lincoln Institute of Land Policy and the George Washington Institute of Public
Policy.1

See Significant Features of the Property Tax, Lincoln Institute of Land Policy and George Washington
Institute of Public Policy, http://www.lincolninst.edu/subcenters/significant-features-property-tax/.

Daphne A. Kenyon: Lincoln Institute of Land Policy, Cambridge, MA, USA (dkenyon@lincolninst.edu)
Adam H. Langley: Lincoln Institute of Land Policy, Cambridge, MA, USA (alangley@lincolninst.edu)
Bethany P. Paquin: Lincoln Institute of Land Policy, Cambridge, MA, USA (bethanypaquin@gmail.com)

1012

National Tax Journal

Property tax abatement programs, which have a very long history, allow partial or
full reduction in property tax liability for certain manufacturing, commercial, or retail
parcels. Tax increment financing (TIF), which was first used in the 1950s, generally
earmarks growth in property taxes or other revenues in a designated geographic area to
pay back bonds issued for infrastructure improvements in the area. Enterprise zones are
designated geographic areas, usually economically distressed, within which state and/
or local governments provide special tax preferences and other incentives to encourage
business investment. Not all enterprise zone programs include property tax incentives.
Firm-specific property tax abatements, which are typically part of a package of financial
incentives that is individually negotiated, allow partial or full reduction in property tax
liability for specific firms. Finally, when local governments issue tax-exempt IDBs on
behalf of a firm, the government typically holds title to the property where the development is taking place so the firm incurs no property tax liability unless a special provision
is made to require the firm to compensate the local government for some or all of the
property tax revenue forgone.
The objective of this paper is to use case studies on property tax incentives across
the United States to highlight pitfalls in their use and make suggestions for reform.
Our research has found eight major property tax incentive pitfalls, described below.
II. GRANTING INCENTIVES THAT DO NOT AFFECT LOCATION DECISIONS
The most fundamental error in extending property tax incentives to business is providing a tax incentive that does not change a firms location decision. Sometimes a business
lobbies policymakers for tax concessions after it chooses a site based on a variety of
factors. One reason that property tax incentives may not affect location decisions is
that property taxes are typically a small part of a firms cost. Input costs account for
three-quarters of the average manufacturing firms total costs, and labor accounts for
most of the remainder. More specifically, between 2004 and 2009, labor accounted for
21.8 percent of total costs for the manufacturing sector, and property taxes accounted
for 0.3 percent (Kenyon, Langley, and Paquin, 2012).
One example of a property tax incentive that apparently had no impact was the 2008
award of a property tax abatement to the pharmaceutical company Speracor by the
City of Marlborough, Massachusetts. Speracor began construction of a new facility
in Marlborough in 2007, the same year it applied for a property tax incentive, and the
city awarded the incentive in 2008, when the project was already underway (City of
Marlborough, 2008; Crocetti, 2008a). One city council member objected to granting
this abatement, noting the absurdity of trying to provide incentives for investment
that had already occurred (Crocetti, 2008b). The firms executive director of facilities
responded that, Its an incentive for us to continue in Marlborough (Crocetti, 2008b).
Nevertheless, it appears that Speracor had already decided to locate in Marlborough
before the incentive was granted.
One approach policymakers can take to increase the chance that property tax incentive dollars are not spent frivolously is to gather information in order to answer two

Property Tax Incentive Pitfalls

1013

key questions: (1) Are property taxes a significant component of a firms total costs?
and (2) Does the firm serve a national or international market? If the answer to both of
these questions is yes, there is a greater chance that the property tax incentive can affect
the firms location decision and that the local government is spending its property tax
incentive dollars wisely. Even before applying that rule of thumb, policymakers should
make it clear that not all firms applying for a property tax incentive will be granted one.
III. GRANTING INCENTIVES WHEN COSTS EXCEED BENEFITS
A second fundamental error in local government use of property tax incentives is that
without judicious use of the incentives, the cost of the tax incentives can exceed the
benefits provided by the firm receiving the incentives. If the incentive does not change
the firms location decision, the net benefit is likely to be negative, but there are other
considerations as well. A local government assessing whether the benefits of providing
a tax incentive exceed the costs should look at fiscal effects, labor market effects, and
economic and social effects.
Besides the revenue forgone when an incentive is granted, one important fiscal effect of
attracting a new facility is the potential increase in public service costs due to construction of a new facility or growth in employment and population. If a local government
has underutilized infrastructure, the cost of providing services to a new facility may be
small, but otherwise new public service costs can easily outweigh benefits provided by
the new facility (Altshuler and Gmez-Ibez, 1993).
With respect to labor market effects, it is important to not only look at the number
of new jobs but also consider how many jobs go to existing city residents versus commuters into the city or in-migrants. It is also important to consider the pay for the jobs.
If the new jobs pay only minimum wage, attracting a firm to a city is much less likely
to produce a net benefit for its residents (Bartik, 2004).
Finally, there is a range of other economic and social effects to consider. For example,
what impact does the attracted firm have on the profits of firms already part of the community? A new firm might purchase goods and services produced by existing firms and
thus have a positive impact, but a new firm might also compete with an existing firm or
drive it out of business. Attracting a new firm might increase property values or enhance
a communitys character, but it could also impose environmental or congestion costs.
A recent case where many of these issues arose was the creation of a TIF district in
2012 for big-box home improvement chain Menards in Garden City, Kansas (Ahmad,
2012a). The city council approving the plan expected that the development would draw
more shoppers to Garden City and create new retail jobs. The TIF project involved
major infrastructure improvements including extending a road, widening an existing
road, and adding turning lanes and signals, some of which were likely necessitated by
the new retail development. After the city council approved the TIF, a group of local
businesses appealed to the Finney County Commissioners to block the plan, arguing that
the new development would not strengthen the economy, but they were unsuccessful.
One existing business owner argued, All were doing is splitting up the pie (Ahmad,

1014

National Tax Journal

2012c). In addition, the Menards development is less than a mile away from a Home
Depot store, part of another big-box home improvement chain, which was granted a
tax incentive in 2003 (Ahmad, 2012b).
IV. ENGAGING IN DESTRUCTIVE BIDDING WARS WITH NEIGHBORING
JURISDICTIONS
Property tax incentives have been used either alone or together with state tax incentives in economic development battles that degenerate into destructive bidding wars.
The Kansas City metropolitan area, which spans 15 counties in Kansas and Missouri,
is a case in point. As of 2012, Kansas and Missouri had spent over $750 million over
five years in tax incentives and bonds for business development in the Kansas City
area, which did not include local incentives which were estimated to be millions more
(Hanna and Lieb, 2012). One particularly egregious example is Applebees moves of its
headquarters back and forth across state lines, and between Kansas localities, many of
which appear to have been motivated solely by tax incentives. Applebees moved from:
Atlanta to Kansas City, Missouri in 1988; moved to Overland Park, Kansas in 1993;
received a 10-year, 90 percent property tax abatement to move to a different Kansas
locality in 2007; and then announced in 2011 that it was moving back to Kansas City,
Missouri (Collison, 2012; Hanna and Lieb, 2012).2
In August 2011, a group of businesses asked the governors of Kansas and Missouri
to stop using incentives to lure businesses from one jurisdiction to another within the
Kansas City metropolitan area. In a letter to the governors, the businesses referred to
both states efforts to woo businesses over the border with incentives as an economic
border war. So far the governors do not appear interested in declaring a truce (Greenblatt, 2011).
New York City and Jersey City have long used tax incentives, including property
tax abatements, to compete for business development. Recently New Jersey Governor
Chris Christie made headlines for stepping up the pace of this tax competition through
extensive use of the Urban Transit Hub Tax Credit Program. In one case, Prudential Insurance, which had already received property tax abatement under the Urban
Enterprise Zone Program,3 was offered $250.8 million to move a few blocks away
within the city of Newark from old office space to a newly constructed office tower
(Bagli, 2012).
The Metro Denver Economic Development Corporation, whose members include 70
cities, counties and economic development organizations, offers a useful contrast to the
bidding wars in the Kansas City and New York City metropolitan areas (Metro Denver
Economic Development Corporation, 2004). In the mid-80s this organization adopted
2

Kansas City Business Journal, February 9, 2009, Applebees Job, Salary Levels Come up Short for
Abatement on HQ, http://www.bizjournals.com/kansascity/stories/2009/02/09/daily2.html.
See Discover Where Corporations are Getting Taxpayer Handouts Across the United States, Good Jobs
First, Subsidy Tracker, http://www.goodjobsfirst.org/subsidy-tracker.

Property Tax Incentive Pitfalls

1015

a Code of Ethics, which includes such guidelines as: (1) promote Metro Denver first
and individual communities second, and (2) never solicit another members prospects.
This agreement was tested in 2011 when Denver and Aurora, a Denver suburb, found
themselves in competition for the National Western Stock Show and Rodeo, which
had just been released from a 40-year lease within the city of Denver (Jackson, 2011a).
When the stock show proposed relocating to Aurora and an independent study showed
Denver would lose millions in tax revenue as a result of the relocation, discussions
among the two city councils and mayors ensued (Castellanos, 2011). At a meeting of
the two mayors, Denver Mayor Michael Hancock stated, The guiding principle of this
region is that we cooperate and work together (Jackson, 2011b). Aurora Mayor Steve
Hogan dropped his bid to attract the show (Illescas, 2011).
Although metro area agreements are far from common, localities in the Bay Area of
California, South Florida, and Columbus, Ohio area have reached similar agreements
(Patton, 2006; Ball, 2007). In 2011, the economic development organizations in Fort
Wayne, Indiana signed a similar agreement after witnessing the powerful collaborative
culture in Denver (Northeast Indiana Regional Partnership, 2011). Of course avoiding
destructive inter-local tax competition within a single state is easier than in metropolitan
areas spanning two or more states.
V. ALLOWING PROLIFERATION OF INCENTIVES
The good news with respect to using the property tax to promote economic development is that empirical evidence shows that property tax differentials within a
metropolitan area can have a significant impact on business location. A review of the
literature found that a 1 percent reduction in a jurisdictions property taxes will increase
economic activity (measured by employment and firm births and relocations) by 1.59
to 1.95 percent (Bartik, 1991).
But studies of the effectiveness of property tax abatements find that they are only
temporarily effective (Anderson and Wassmer, 2000). This apparent discrepancy can be
explained by the proliferation of such abatements. A single jurisdiction may be able to
significantly boost business investment through property tax incentives, but this effect
disappears over time as the copycat behavior of nearby jurisdictions leads them to adopt
similar policies, which reduce the impact of the first jurisdictions incentives. Over time
it is possible that all competing jurisdictions will have lower effective property tax rates
without any jurisdiction gaining a permanent advantage over another.
Illinois experience with TIF is an example of proliferation followed by a period of
reform (Talanker, Davis, and LeRoy, 2003). TIF was authorized in Illinois in 1977 and
eight years later the state had 27 TIF districts. Once the districts became eligible for
state aid, the number increased until by 2002 there were 782 such districts. Although
the finding of blight was one requirement for TIF enactment, upon occasion wealthy
districts were allowed to establish TIFs. A period of reform followed in which the standards for qualifying as a blighted area were narrowed and requirements for notification
and public hearings were added.

1016

National Tax Journal

There will always be political pressure for broadening of the criteria for eligibility for
property tax incentives, but it is important for state policymakers to resist this pressure.
If they do not, the effectiveness of such incentives declines and the only result is that
local government revenues are reduced.
VI. LACK OF TRANSPARENCY
Most state and local governments provide very little information about property tax
incentives for business. It is possible to ascertain whether a state has an enterprise zone,
property tax abatement or tax increment finance program and the qualifications for
those programs, but there is often no basic information on firm-specific tax incentives
or property tax exemptions used together with issuance of tax-exempt industrial development bonds. In order to evaluate the effectiveness of these tax incentives, however,
one must have information about the firm receiving the incentive, the amount of the
incentive, and the responses to the incentive, such as resulting increases in employment.
State governments are in the best position to provide information on tax incentive
programs. Currently 44 states produce tax expenditure reports, but only eight states
include tax expenditure estimates for the local property tax (Connolly and Bell, 2011).
Nonprofit groups can also help promote transparency. Good Jobs First has compiled
information on economic development subsidies in an online database called the Subsidy Tracker.4 Although it has information on many subsidy programs, with information
on individual businesses, for the most part the database does not have information on
property tax incentives.
Maryland is an example of a state that does not provide information on the incentives in its enterprise zone program. Maryland has 28 enterprise zones that offer firms
a credit against corporate income taxes as well as property tax credits. However, the
identity of the recipients of these credits is not disclosed (Pew Center on the States,
2012). In contrast, the State of Oregon has a government transparency initiative that has
been expanding. In 2011, the legislature enacted a requirement for more transparency
on tax breaks, including most enterprise zones (Robyn, 2011). The state now provides
information online on the name of the business, its address, the total amount of credits
it receives, and program outcomes and other information.
VII. LACK OF EVALUATION
A recent study of state evaluation of tax incentives found that 16 states did not publish
a document between 2007 and 2011 that assessed the effectiveness of a tax incentive
(Pew Center on the States, 2012). The challenge of evaluating property tax incentives
is greater because local governments typically have fewer resources and expertise than
state governments.
4

See Discover Where Corporations are Getting Taxpayer Handouts Across the United States, Good Jobs
First, Subsidy Tracker, http://www.goodjobsfirst.org/subsidy-tracker.

Property Tax Incentive Pitfalls

1017

Thus there is a state role for either reviewing the effectiveness of local property
tax incentives for business or aiding local governments in their efforts to do so. The
Connecticut General Assembly passed a law in 2010 requiring an assessment of the
economic and fiscal impact of the states tax credit and abatement programs every three
years. In the first such report, the Connecticut Department of Economic and Community
Development (2010) recommended elimination of the Enterprise Zone property tax
abatement program because it did not benefit the state.
It is important that such evaluations be done by an organization that is independent of
the entity granting the tax incentives. Minnesotas experience with its Job Opportunity
Building Zone Program (JOBZ) is instructive. Eligible businesses in these zones obtain
credits against property, income, sales, corporate franchise and employment taxes.5
The JOBZ program, which was established in 2004, had been annually evaluated since
2007 by the economic development agency administering the program, but it received
its first independent assessment in 2008. The independent evaluators estimated that
only 21 percent of the new jobs reported by the zone businesses were attributable to
the incentives. They further estimated the cost per job generated at $26,900 to $30,000
rather than the $5,000 to $6,000 estimate produced by the economic development agency
(Yunker and Kirschner, 2008).
VIII. ALLOWING ONE LOCAL GOVERNMENTS TO TAKE REVENUE FROM
ANOTHER
This flaw is most prevalent with the earmarking device known as TIF. As Youngman
(2011, p. 324) describes:
By far the greatest moral hazard posed by TIFs concerns the ability to freeze
the assessment base of overlapping jurisdictions, such as school districts. The
municipality establishing the TIF district may be able to appropriate value
increases, including those resulting only from inflation, from independent
districts with no power to block that transfer.
When this is the case, it gives the local government creating the TIF an incentive to
use TIF financing even when it does not generate economic growth. Throughout the
United States there is a great deal of variety in state laws on TIF approval (Kenyon,
Langley, and Paquin, 2012). In 2010 there were five states in which only the community redevelopment agency had to approve a TIF program (California, Florida,
Hawaii, New Jersey, and Rhode Island). In these states the potential for such abuse
is greatest. Indeed, the tendency for local governments to appropriate property tax
5

See JOBZ Overview, Minnesota Department of Employment and Economic Development, http://
www.positivelyminnesota.com/Business/Financing_a_Business/Tax-Free_Development_(JOBZ)/JOBZ_
Overview.aspx.

1018

National Tax Journal

revenues from school districts is one reason that California recently ended TIFs
(Youngman, 2011).
Eight states require school districts to approve TIF. Two states have the most inclusive
approval process, which could present the best arrangement. In Oregon, the city, county,
school district, state and all taxing entities must approve TIF. In South Carolina the
requirement is similar in that all affected taxing entities must approve TIF (Kenyon,
Langley, and Paquin, 2012, pp. 7071).
IX. STATE GOVERNMENT REIMBURSEMENT
State governments can affect the use of property tax incentives in other ways, one
of the most important of which is whether states reimburse local governments for
the revenue forgone when they grant property tax incentives. According to Dalehite,
Mikesell, and Zorn (2005), state governments reimburse local governments for use of
property tax incentives in Colorado, Connecticut, Kansas, Maine, Michigan, Oklahoma,
and Vermont. It stands to reason that if local governments do not have to worry about
the cost of tax incentives they are more likely to use them. As Dalehite, Mikesell, and
Zorn (2005, p. 165) argue, the state subsidy may induce local jurisdictions to award
abatements indiscriminately.
The state of Arizona takes a different approach. Instead of reimbursing local governments for the use of property tax incentives, it penalizes local governments in the Phoenix
area that use tax incentives to attract retail establishments. The law implementing this
policy was enacted in 2007 (Mitchell, 2007). When Governor Janet Napolitano signed
the legislation she made the following statement:
Today, I signed House Bill 2515, which will put an end to the practice of some
cities in Maricopa County giving huge tax breaks to retail businesses for locating within their municipalities. These tax breaks have gotten out of control and
have been offered to a host of businesses, many of whom were likely to locate
in Arizona regardless of whether they were offered a tax incentive. The use
of tax incentives to pit Maricopa County towns and cities against each other
is not in the interest of Arizona or its taxpayers.6
Cities and towns that award incentives must report them to the state. Then the municipalitys state aid is reduced by the amount of the incentive awarded, spread over five years.
Incentives awarded prior to 2007 are exempt. The law also does not prohibit incentives
that apply to all retail businesses in a town nor does it apply to redevelopment projects
in areas with lower than average household income.7
6

See Arizona Republic, July 2, 2007, Governors Signing Statement, Vetoes and Signed Bills, http://www.
azcentral.com/arizonarepublic/local/articles/0702napolitano-actions0703excerpts.html.
See Retail business location municipal tax incentives; prohibition; penalty; exceptions; definitions,
Ariz. Rev. Stat. 42-6010, http://www.azleg.gov/FormatDocument.asp?inDoc=/ars/42/06010.
htm&Title=42&DocType=ARS.

Property Tax Incentive Pitfalls

1019

X. CONCLUSION
Although tax competition for economic development has a long history in the United
States and its reform appears to be an intractable challenge, there is reason to be optimistic about improving the use of property tax incentives. State governments control
local government taxing powers, and as this paper illustrates, several states have taken
action to make better use of property tax incentives. Other states could follow their
lead. Local governments also have tools, such as metropolitan area cooperation agreements or guidelines for offering tax incentives, which can help them use property tax
incentives for business more effectively.
REFERENCES
Ahmad, Shajia, 2012a. City Approves Plans for Retail Project. Garden City Telegram, June 6,
http://www.gctelegram.com/news/retail-development-project-plans-6-6-12.
Ahmad, Shajia, 2012b. Home Depot Sales Tax Reimbursement Set to Expire Next Summer.
Garden City Telegram, May 30, http://www.gctelegram.com/news/home-depot-sales-tax-5-30-12.
Ahmad, Shajia, 2012c. Merchants Speak Against TIF. Garden City Telegram, May 8, http://
www.gctelegram.com/news/merchants-against-TIF-district-5-8-12.
Altshuler, Alan A., Jos A. Gmez-Ibez, and Arnold M. Howitt, 1993. Regulation for Revenue:
The Political Economy of Land Use Exactions. Brookings Institution, Washington, DC.
Anderson, John E., and Robert W. Wassmer, 2000. Bidding for Business: The Efficacy of Local
Economic Development Incentives in a Metropolitan Area. W.E. Upjohn Institute for Employment Research, Kalamazoo, MI.
Bagli, Charles V., 2012. Christie Leaning on Tax Subsidies in Hunt for Jobs. The New York
Times, April 4, http://www.nytimes.com/2012/04/05/nyregion/christie-gives-new-jersey-firmstax-breaks-for-short-moves.html?pagewanted=all.
Ball, Brian R., 2007. Economic Development Officials Pledge Cooperation With Incentives. Business First of Columbus, January 26, http://www.bizjournals.com/columbus/
stories/2007/01/29/story8.html?page=all.
Bartik, Timothy J., 1991. Who Benefits from State and Local Economic Development Policies?
W.E. Upjohn Institute for Employment Research, Kalamazoo, MI.
Bartik, Timothy J, 2004. Thinking About Local Living Wage Requirements. Urban Affairs
Review 40 (2), 269299.
Castellanos, Sara, 2011. Study: Denver Would Lose Millions if Stock Show Moved. Denver
Business Journal, October 5, http://www.bizjournals.com/denver/news/2011/10/05/denverofficials-to-get-key-stock-show.html?page=all.
City of Marlborough, 2008. Tax Increment Financing Agreement by and between the City of
Marlborough and Speracor Inc. City of Marlborough, MA, http://www.marlborough-ma.gov/
Gen/MarlboroughMA_PublicNtcs/08-Item%204%20-1201,%20Sepracor%20Tif.pdf.

1020

National Tax Journal

Collison, Kevin, 2012. Freightquote, Major JoCo Business, is the Latest Border War Target.
Kansas City Star, May 23, http://article.wn.com/view/2012/05/23/Freightquote_major_JoCo_
biz_with_1200_employees_latest_borde/.
Connecticut Department of Economic and Community Development, 2010. An Assessment
of Connecticuts Tax Credit and Abatement Programs. Department of Economic and Community Development, Hartford, CT, http://www.ct.gov/ecd/lib/ecd/decd_sb_501_sec_27_
report_12-30-2010_final.pdf.
Connolly, Katrina D., and Michael E. Bell, 2011. Strengthening the Local Property Tax: The
Need for a Property Tax Expenditure Budget. Working Paper. Lincoln Institute of Land Policy,
Cambridge, MA.
Crocetti, Paul, 2008a. Marlborough Approves Tax Breaks for Speracor. The MetroWest
Daily News, December 2, http://www.metrowestdailynews.com/news/x777792945/Marlboroughapproves-tax-breaks-for-Sepracor.
Crocetti, Paul, 2008b. Marlborough Finance Board Wrestles over Speracor Tax Break. The
MetroWest Daily News, October 21, http://www.metrowestdailynews.com/news/x1052810297/
Marlborough-finance-board-wrestles-over-Sepracor-tax-break.
Dalehite, Esteban G., John L. Mikesell, and C. Kurt Zorn, 2005. Variation in Property Tax Abatement Programs Among States. Economic Development Quarterly 19 (2), 157173.
Greenblatt, Alan, 2011. Kansas City Businesses Want to End the Economic Border War.
Governing: The States and Localities, Washington, DC, http://www.governing.com/topics/
economic-dev/kansas-city-businesses-want-end-economic-border-war.html.
Hanna, John, and David A. Lieb, 2012. A Border War for Business in KC Area. St. Louis Post
Dispatch, May 17, http://www.stltoday.com/news/national/a-border-war-for-business-in-kc-area/
article_fa25c727-3f84-582b-a9e7-c4fdfb74e47a.html.
Illescas, Carlos, 2011. Aurora Mayor Not Interested in Coaxing Stock Show Out of Denver.
The Denver Post, December 23, http://www.denverpost.com/news/ci_19605372.
Jackson, Margaret, 2011a. Denver Council Panel Open to National Western Stock Show Move.
The Denver Post, May 12, http://www.denverpost.com/business/ci_18044973.
Jackson, Margaret, 2011b. Denver Withdraws from Subsidy Application for National Western Stock Show Relocation. The Denver Post, November 19, http://www.denverpost.com/
breakingnews/ci_19367088.
Kenyon, Daphne A., Adam H. Langley, and Bethany P. Paquin, 2012. Rethinking Property Tax
Incentives for Business. Lincoln Institute of Land Policy, Cambridge, MA.
Metro Denver Economic Development Corporation, 2004. Code of Ethics. Metro Denver,
Denver, CO, http://www.metrodenver.org/about-metro-denver-edc/code-of-ethics.html.
Mitchell, Stacy, 2007. Arizona Bans Tax Breaks for Retail Development. Institute for Local
Self-Reliance, Washington, DC, http://www.ilsr.org/arizona-bans-tax-breaks-retail-development/.

Property Tax Incentive Pitfalls

1021

Northeast Indiana Regional Partnership, 2011. Regional Leaders Formally Commit to Culture
of Collaboration, Vision 2020, Fort Wayne, IN, http://www.neindiana.com/vision/news-media/
detail/vision-news/2011/11/21/regional-leaders-formally-commit-to-culture-of-collaboration.
Patton, Wendy, 2006. State and Local Anti-Poaching Agreements: Background Information. Policy Matters Ohio, Columbus, OH, http://www.policymattersohio.org/wp-content/
uploads/2011/09/anti-poaching_backgrounder.pdf.
Pew Center on the States, 2012. Evidence Counts: Evaluating State Tax Incentives for Jobs and
Growth. The Pew Charitable Trusts, Washington, DC.
Robyn, Mark, 2011. Oregon Governor Signs Transparency Bill for Economic Development Tax
Breaks. Tax Foundation, Washington, DC, http://taxfoundation.org/blog/oregon-governor-signstransparency-bill-economic-development-tax-breaks.
Talanker, Alyssa, Kate Davis, and Greg LeRoy, 2003. Straying from Good Intentions: How States
are Weakening Enterprise Zone and Tax Increment Financing Programs. Good Jobs First, Washington, DC, http://www.cdfa.net/cdfa/cdfaweb.nsf/ordredirect.html?open&id=strayinggjf.html.
Youngman, Joan M, 2011. TIF at a Turning Point: Defining Debt Down. State Tax Notes (May
2): 321329.
Yunker, John, and David Kirchner, 2008. Evaluation Report: JOBZ Program. Office of the
Legislative Auditor, St. Paul, MN, http://www.auditor.leg.state.mn.us/ped/pedrep/jobz.pdf.

Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.

You might also like