You are on page 1of 5

The Pros And Cons Of Airport

Privatization Economics Essay


Published: 23rd March, 2015 Last Edited: 23rd March, 2015

I. Executive Summary
Airports have evolved mainly as government-run enterprises. Now, many airports seek privatization in part to
improve their abilities to compete in the new global economy. The manner of ownership covers a wide
spectrum: government-owned and controlled airports, government-owned corporations, independent airport
authorities, public-private partnerships with government majority ownership or with private majority ownership.
Reasons to privatize an airport include an improved ability for an airport to diversify its operations to enhance
profitability, to fund expansion, and to improve competitiveness. The arguments for privatization include that the
falling availability of public funds, and a need to change to the market-oriented outlook that private businesses
develop. Objections to airport privatization are related to the apprehension that a private operator will take
advantage of the monopoly that airports represent in air travel. Not all airports are suitable for privatization.
Some in the developed world, such as in the USA, are controlled by local governments and affected by airline
requirements. The less developed countries and their airport authorities lack sufficient funds to develop their
airports; although these countries need these airports, privatization is impractical, and alternate business plans
must be developed. Unlike other countries, Canada, Australia, and New Zealand have taken the path of mixed
public-private control to maintain power over matters that affect the public good. Privatization enables a long
term focus to meet the demands of international competition, to maintain a customer-focused plan, and to free
the government from providing subsidies to an unprofitable enterprise. The potential for Canada to completely
privatize the National Airport System Airports is small due to the serving of the public good under the current
system.

II Introduction
Airport privatization has become a trend in the past thirty years as economies change and the air transport
sector matures. Airport management and ownership, once mainly the domain of governments, has evolved into
a mix of public and private airport ownership. Airports must now compete with other airports around the world
for business, and government may not be the best owner for a globally-competitive enterprise. Airports must
have the freedom to compete on the commercial level, and not just provide a service to the travelling public.
Airports seek privatization in part to improve their abilities to develop a customer-focused business plan. This
paper will present a review of the history of privatization and predictions for the future of this trend, and a
comparison of the means, effects, and relative success of government/ public vs. private control.

What is airport privatization?


Simply put it is the transfer of ownership or management or both to the private sector (Graham 2008, 15). The
manner of ownership covers a wide spectrum: "airports owned and operated by government departments,
100% government-owned corporations, independent airport authorities, mixed enterprises with government
majority ownership and mixed enterprises with private majority ownership" (Tae et al 2006, abstract).

Analysis of the need to privatize


Airports have evolved mainly as government-run enterprises. They serve the public good, and were thus taken
on as any other part of public infrastructure would be. Bridges, roads, ports, and other transportation-related
projects have traditionally been part of the public good. However, many of these facilities are being privatized.
Roads and bridges are now conceived of as wholly privately developed and owned, or as public-private
partnerships.
Privatization can provide several benefits. It can remove the burden from the government's finances, spread
the risk associated with operations, and introduce ways to improve efficiency and competition. Often better

airport management can be put in place. For example, if the airport is run under a government department,
facility commercialization would be difficult. Private management can reorganize the accounting so that the
airport's costs and revenues can be monitored and adjusted, costs can be cut, and revenues boosted.
The arguments for privatization are many. Less public investment is needed; on the one hand, public funds are
less available than they once were, and on the other hand, private corporations have a market-oriented outlook
for their business plans. Improved access to commercial financial markets, improved ability for an airport to
diversify, and improved operational efficiency may be the result. Employees and management are motivated to
perform better. Lastly, a deregulated airline industry led to growth which the existing model of airport
management and ownership could not handle.
Privatization may be a better option if market forces can enable competition rather than a monopoly, meaning
less government regulation is necessary. This preserves the public good and makes the enterprise more likely
to be profitable. Conversely, if the potential exists for a monopoly in a market, then the involvement of the
government in ownership is necessary, and so is more government regulation. Table 1: "Government Control of
Essential Elements of operations in three countries", shows how Canada, Britain, and Australia deal with these
concerns by maintaining control in key areas of the public good of aeronautical standards, access, and pricing.

III. Privatization Strategies


Privatization does not mean handing over of complete ownership to a corporation. The most practical scenario
would be for a government to retain control over the type of facilities to be developed and other changes, while
the operator, the commercial enterprise, oversees "day-to-day and year-to-year operations" of the airport (de
Neufville 1999, 6). The net benefit to the public interest would seem to be the lack of necessity to raise funds to
expand or run the facility, or to service debt.

Types of Privatization
transfer of operations to private sector (Graham 2008, 25).
transfer of ownership to private sector (Graham 2008, 25).
share issues, IPOs: airport needs to make a profit; shareholders assume the risks
trade sale - sale of facilities
concession - control passes to private operator for a fixed period - this is how some new roads and bridges are
managed in North America - annual fee paid to government, which retains ownership (Graham 2008, 32).
a private operator finances and builds new facilities, pays annual fee to government, thingies ownership to the
government after a fixed period
management contract - an operator runs the facility, and either the operator gets a fee or the government
receives a percentage of revenue (Graham 2008, 34).
The better way to privatize is to share control between government and private interests. See Table 2: Degree
of control mix among different styles of government and full private ownership (from de Neufville 1999, 17) for
an illustration of how this is so.

Determining the potential of an airport for privatization


Not all airports are suitable for privatization, and the experience differs in the developed and less developed
worlds. In the developed world, the USA is an anomaly. Less privatization has happened there, and this may be
because most airports are under local control, and also under significant pressure from the airlines that use
them (de Neufville 1999, 5). Both entities can interfere with any contemplated changes. The approach used in
Canada, New Zealand, and Australia, has been to turn the airports into not-for-profit corporations. Such airport
authorities as Vancouver Airport Services, a not-for-profit corporation, operate their own and other airports.
The case in the less developed world for airport privatization differs due to the lack of both public and private
funds for infrastructure development. Still, these countries need these airports, and alternate business plans
must be developed. Less developed countries have much more growth potential in air transport and that can be

met with improved facilities and increased capacity (Button 2006, 14). The major part of their revenue is airside
(Button 2006, 14). Figure 1: "A generalization of airport trends in developing and developed countries" will
illustrate this phenomenon. Button (2006, 14) adds that airports in less developed countries do not generate
sufficient revenue to cover costs, so the governments must provide subsidies, and this makes these airports
unsuitable for privatization. A full privatization cannot be expected until a national economy can support
infrastructure improvements and an airport can prove its potential for profitability.

IV. Operating environment considerations regarding


privatization
The operating environment needs some favourable market conditions for success in privatization. External
market forces can encourage or prevent successful conversion to private control or ownership; Button asserts
that "[r]egulatory changes in airport policy in countries such as the UK came against a backdrop of successful
liberalization of many other markets, quite strong macroeconomic growth, and with fairly well defined
objectives" (2006, 3). A privatization could not proceed in the absence of these factors, as in the case of a less
developed country. There, the private sector has limited access to capital markets and the government may not
be able to afford to borrow internationally. The catch is that these economies lack sufficient development for an
investment to have acceptable risk levels; without the airport and other transportation infrastructure, though, the
country cannot develop.
The common operating factors are:
Competition exists for investor dollars with other forms of real estate - malls, offices, developable land. The
author of "US Airport Privatization" speculated in 1993 that the market for airports was not a speculative one.
Now, market opportunities are being found in airport privatizations.
Developers may not want to work with the government bodies, which regulate airports and airlines, or to be tied
to a long-term investment. Developers would look for opportunities that facilitate adaptability to changing
market conditions. Only a long-term strategy would work in this investment.
The labour contracts in force when the ownership switches over from public to private would likely have to
continue, hindering potential private operators.
Property taxes would have to reflect enhanced market value of an airport property. Most of an airport's real
estate is empty land, and therefore not directly capable of providing a profit to an operator.
Any airport has relations with the surrounding communities, but a private operator would be unable to negotiate
in an area of government responsibility.
In addition, other challenges, which may have hampered airport profitably before privatization, remain. These
include security, air traffic growth, airline strategies, airport competition, and international incidents such as
SARS or terrorism.
Political interference is always a possibility in the area of airport regulations, industry deregulation, and the
changing nature of the airline industry.
A conflict exists between the desires of a private operator to have looser regulations and the need for
government oversight of the industry.
Objections to airport privatization are related to the monopoly that airports represent in air travel (Graham 2008,
16). The fear is that the private operator will make a profit that could have gone to the government. These fears
are addressed by the nature of private enterprise, which seeks to run a business profitably.

Potential Economic Benefits of Airport Privatization


Originally airports were considered to be part of a nation's essential infrastructure, and less attention was paid
to profit than to operations (Frost & Sullivan). The three means of economic gains to be found in privatization
are: improvements in operating efficiency: the private for-profit business model more often leads to a further
exploration for means to cut costs and boost revenues than does public management; the introduction of new
management styles and marketing skills directed to serve users with a more consumer-oriented approach; and
the ability to make better investment decisions.

The trend in many countries is now to contemplating the potential for profit from an airport. The example of the
Vienna airport will serve to illustrate how privatization in a developed country can benefit an airport's
operations. Before 1978, the airport was a public utility and had to seek subsidies to cover losses. In 1978, the
airport management was reorganized so it would work like a commercial enterprise, but with public sector
shareholder ownership. A further reorganization took place in 1992 to address industry and customer needs
separately from the service divisions. Measures such as strategic planning and cost control were introduced to
improve the airport's competitive advantage (Graham 2008, 17). A share issue was made in 1992 for expansion
and improved commercial operations, signaling a transition to private sector control.
Privatization enables a long term focus to meet the demands of international competition, to maintain a
customer-focused plan, and to free the government from providing subsidies to an unprofitable enterprise.
Many privatizations have taken place because the potential for airside growth is limited. In other words, the
developed countries have reached saturation on airside growth, so they seek growth from commercial services.
This means shopping, restaurants, hotels, joint ventures are added to the airport to add value and capture
more dollars. In addition, Button asserts that the success of privatized airports has encouraged governments to
change the management and operations of their airports to mirror what the privately-run operations are doing
(2006, 3). Then, the facility is seen as a single monopoly, but as separate revenue-generating businesses.
Privatization seems to enable a better response to market forces by developing commercial potential.

VI. Potential for Further Airport Privatization in Canada


Canada has followed the route of maintaining almost all operational facets under shared control, with no
airports being fully privatized. See Table 3: Status of Privatization of Airports in Australia, Britain and Canada
before (B) and after Privatization (P) for a comparison of how control was changed after a degree of
privatization. Australia and Britain have given control of finance and operations to the private operators, while
Canada has retained it. To address local community and economy concerns, maintaining a partnership may be
the better route to follow, and experience will show which method is better. Despite what the author of "US
Airport Privatization" found, privatization in the airport industry is attractive to investors. However, Frost &
Sullivan report that by 2006, only two per cent of the world's commercial airports had been privatized, either
through management or ownership.
Canadian airports are classified as one of two types: Non NAS airports, meaning National Airport System
airports, with fewer than 200,000 passengers per year and which are locally and provincially owned and
operated; NAS airports, with more than 200,000 passengers per year, are owned by the federal government
but managed by boards of non-elected representatives. See Table 4 - "NAS Airports- Canada's National Airport
System", for a list of these NAS airports. They operate as not-for-profit entities under long term leases with the
federal government that are reflective of fair value, including the future earning potential (Canadian Airports
Council 2008).
Transport Canada, as the owner of the airports, has several aims in setting NAS airport rents. First they relate
to infrastructure stability, and ensure the air transport sector remains financially healthy, meaning both the
airport infrastructure and the airlines. The second aim relates to market conditions: to ensure an air transport
sector that is competitive with both other forms of transport and with international air transport systems, and
responsive to changing market conditions. The third serves the public good: the obtaining of a fair value for the
government (National Airports Rent Policy Review 2010). The NAP, the National Airport Plan, appears to
indicate that the federal government has no plans for complete privatization. Rents charged by the federal
government to the local airport authorities are calculated with respect to long-term cash flow forecasts and
capital expansion needs, and to valuations of international commercialized airports, particularly in the USA,
Australia, New Zealand, and Britain. Therefore, the NAS airports serve the Canadian public good by providing
a benefit to the Canadian public while remaining competitive.

VII. Conclusion
The encouraging factors include: continuing growth in air travel requires improvements in infrastructure that
most governments cannot afford; improvements in economies of scale through expansion of facilities and
concentration of services; still more commercial opportunities to be found for exploitation; investors with
longevity have the better chance for continued profitability than would newer entrants. Privatization seems
suitable for airports in more developed countries, because while more developed countries used to rely on
government financing, the private sector has more to invest in major infrastructure projects than the

government does. Allowing a private sector corporation to make profits could encourage the expansion of
facilities sooner than a government-owned airport would do this.
The fears that privatizing airports could be unsuccessful for the buyers and operators because of the untested
variables, such as real estate values and external forces acting on an enterprise, seem to have calmed down
with the growing body of experience in these operations. While ownership of facilities might be transferred to
the private sector, government regulations still affect the business. A private operator cannot exercise eminent
domain; it has to follow laws, while seeking to maximize his gain. Therefore an airport will never operate as an
entity that is entirely separate from government. Now the focus is on the next step. The potential for future
privatizations depends on the county's economic development and on its growth potential. In the long run, both
central and local authorities may have to pursue the course of even greater diversification and
commercialization of airport ownership structures.

Works Cited
Button, K 18 September 2006, Air Transportation Infrastructure in Developing
Countries: Privatization and Deregulation. Fundation Rafael del Pino conference on Comparative Political
Economy and Infrastructure Performance: the Case of Airports.
http://www.frdelpino.es/documentos/CONFERENCIASYENCUENT ROS/Reuniones%20de
%20expertos/Aeropuertos/Button%20Madrid%20Conference.pdf.
Canadian Airports Council 2008. "Ownership and Management of Canada's Airports".
http://www.cacairports.ca/english/canadas_airports/index.php.
Craig, V J 2 March 2000, Risk & Due Diligence in Airport Privatization.
http://www.icao.int/icao/en/ro/nacc/aps/09_craig.pdf.
De Neufville, R 1999, Draft: Airport Privatization Issues for the United States.
http://ardent.mit.edu/airports/ASP_papers/airport%20privatization%20issues%20for%20US.PDF.
Frost & Sullivan 25 April 2006, Abstract: Potential Economic Benefits of Airport
Privatization. http://www.marketresearch.com/product/display.asp?productid =1286859.
Graham, A 2008, Managing Airports: An International Perspective. 3rd edn.
Butterworth-Heinemann: Oxford. http://books.google.ca/books?hl=en&lr=&id=5
Aa0rtzn8vgC&oi=fnd&pg=PR7&dq=The+privatization+and+commercialization+of+China
%27s+airports&ots=BbvkOe6cju&sig=TiTmeH5HQg0RTuYo7IShMjE2kcY#v=onepage&q=privatization&f=false.
Oum, T, Nicole A, and Chunyan Y May 2006, Privatization, corporatization, ownership
forms and their effects on the performance of the world's major airports". Abstract. Journal of Air Transport
Management Volume 12, Issue 3, Pages 109-121. Air Transport Research Society Conference, Rio de Janeiro,
July 2005. Vancouver. http://www.sciencedirect.com/science?_ob=ArticleURL&_ udi=B6VGP-4J14SM6-&_user=10&_coverDate=05%2F31%2F2006&_rdoc=
1&_fmt=high&_orig=search&_sort=d&_docanchor=&view=c&_searchStrId=1273863512&_rerunOrigin=scholar.
google&_acct=C000050221&_version=1&_urlVersion=0&_userid=10&md5=1c0d7c71dc3b52a6727c4c147f36f
7c5.
Transport Canada 15 March 2010. "National Airports Rent Policy Review: Terms of
Reference". http://www.tc.gc.ca/eng/policy/ace-nap-nap1-762.htm.
US Airport Privatization: Why It Won't Work 1993, Airport & Aviation Appraisals,
Inc. http://www.airportappraisals.com/includes/articles/Article-Privatization.pdf.

You might also like