You are on page 1of 17

The Extent, Pattern, and Degree of Market

Integration: A Multivariate Approach for


the Brazilian Rice Market
Gloria Gonzalez-Rivera
and Steven M. Helfand

Downloaded from http://ajae.oxfordjournals.org/ at Niedersaechsische Staats- und Universitaetsbibliothek Goettingen on June 5, 2015
The extent, pattern, and degree of integration are analyzed in a multivariate system with cointe-
grating restrictions. The extent of the market is found by identifying locations that are linked by
trade and where prices share identical longrun information (permanent component). The pattern
of integration characterizes interdependence and is analyzed by estimating a vector error correction
model. The degree of integration is calculated with persistence proles of the long run relations.
We demonstrate that bivariate models are inadequate for capturing the spatial dynamics of price
adjustment. The methodology is applied to the Brazilian rice market and policy implications are
discussed.

Key words: Brazil, market integration, permanent component, persistence proles, rice.

Prices in an integrated spatial market are framework of multivariate cointegration, this


determined simultaneously in numerous loca- article introduces two novel features to the
tions. An important empirical question, with analysis of market integration: (1) the search
relevance for the spatial design of economic for the geographic boundaries of the mar-
policy, is how the information contained in ket, and (2) the use of persistence proles to
prices is transmitted from one location to study the degree of integration of different
another in the short and long run. The locations that belong to the market.
multi-location nature of the market suggests While there is general agreement that
that a multivariate approach is necessary for market integration somehow relates to the
answering this question. Nevertheless, most ow of goods and information across space,
studies of market integration have employed time, and form, the provision of a widely
a bivariate approach. This is true of stud- accepted denition with testable components
ies based on linear cointegration and of has proven to be an elusive task. We propose
those that use switching regime methodolo- a denition that relies on two related dimen-
gies.1 The objective of this artlce is to illus- sions: trade and information. For a market to
trate the advantages of a multivariate analysis be called integrated, we require that the set
and to stress the limitations of a bivariate of locations share both the same traded com-
approach to market integration. Within the modity and the same long run information. In
a cointegration framework, this second con-
dition is equivalent to requiring the existence
Gloria Gonzalez-Rivera
is associate professor and Steven M.
Helfand assistant professor in the Department of Economics at of one and only one integrating factor that
the University of California, Riverside. is common to all series of prices. Thus, given
This article was written as part of a larger project on spatial a set of locations, we propose a sequential
economics called NEMESIS (www.nemesis.org.br). The project
is based at IPEA in Rio de Janeiro and has been supported by procedure based on Johansen (1988, 1991)
a grant from the Brazilian government under a program called to search for the single common factor. This
PRONEX. We also thank the Center for Agricultural Studies at
the Getulio
Vargas Foundation for providing us with the pro-
multivariate search for the extent of the mar-
ducer prices, Jesus
Gonzalo for useful conversations and com- ket differentiates our article from previous
puter code that assisted us in estimating the permanent compo- studies of market integration.
nent, Chris Barrett, two anonymous referees, and Kusum Mundra
for valuable research assistance. A single common factor implies that there
1
Among the most important bivariate contributions to this lit- must be n 1 cointegrating vectors in an n
erature are Ravallion; Goodwin and Schroeder; Sexton, King and location market. If we were to normalize the
Carman; Alexander and Wyeth; Dercon; and Baulch. Two notable
multivariate exceptions are Goodwin; and Asche, Bremnes, and n 1 cointegrating vectors with respect to a
Wessels. given location, we would nd that all loca-
Amer. J. Agr. Econ. 83(3) (August 2001): 576592
Copyright 2001 American Agricultural Economics Association
Gonzalez-Rivera and Helfand Pattern and Degree of Market Integration 577

tions were cointegrated pair-wise. However, We propose to use a different measure that
this is not sufcient to justify a bivariate anal- is robust to any ordering of the variables in
ysis of the market for at least two reasons. the system. It was developed by Pesaran and
First, it would be very difcult to determine Shin and is called a persistence prole. A
which locations belong to the same market persistence prole characterizes the response
with a bivariate approach. Of the n(n 1)/2 of a cointegrating relation to a system-wide,
pairwise combinations, only n 1 are rel- rather than to an individual, shock. It mea-
evant. The exercise would be unnecessarily sures the reaction time of each long run
complicated and would likely lead to incon- equilibrium relation to absorb a system-wide

Downloaded from http://ajae.oxfordjournals.org/ at Niedersaechsische Staats- und Universitaetsbibliothek Goettingen on June 5, 2015
clusive results. Second, a cointegrated system shock. Persistence proles are unique func-
can be written as a vector error correction tions that allow us to quantify the degree of
(VEC) model. In a system with n locations, integration of all locations that belong to the
each equation of the VEC is likely to contain same economic market.
error correction terms and lags from numer- The article is organized as follows. First,
ous other locations in the market. A bivariate we describe the methodology for estimat-
model necessarily restricts each equation of ing the extent, pattern, and degree of inte-
the VEC to have at most one error correction gration. In the following section, we apply
term, and lags only from the two states con- the methodology to the Brazilian rice market
sidered. In all but very special market struc- for the period 19701997. Finally, we provide
tures, this would grossly misspecify the model. conclusions.
Most of the literature on market integra-
tion has focused on estimating the cointe-
grating vectors. Since the integrating factor Characteristics of an Integrated Market
is eliminated when the cointegrating relation
is estimated, no attention has been paid to The Extent of the Market
nding the common long run component that
gives rise to cointegrated prices. In this paper, There is general agreement that market inte-
we present the estimation of the integrating gration somehow relates to the ow of goods
factor according to the methodology pro- and information across space, time, and form.
posed by Gonzalo and Granger. This method- The provision of a widely accepted denition,
ology is particularly attractive because the however, has proven to be an elusive task. To
common factor is associated with observable avoid confusion, we begin by dening explic-
variables and allows for the identication of itly what we mean by market integration.
the location(s) that contribute to the long run A market with n geographically distinct
behavior of prices. locations will be considered integrated if the
Finally, we propose to study market inte- following two conditions are satised:
gration as a question of degree. At one end
of the continuum are locations that do not (1) There must be physical ows of goods
belong to the market. Within the market, we connecting all n locations either di-
seek to offer a ranking of all locations from rectly or indirectly.
less to more integrated. We dene the degree (2) The n locations must have a corresp-
of integration between locations that belong onding vector of prices {p1t  p2t 
to the same market as the reaction time to    pnt } that can be decomposed as
remove disequilibria. A measure of reaction pit = ai ft + pit  i = 1    n, and
time that is commonly used in the literature ai = 0, where ft is the integrating fac-
are impulse response functions. An important tor that characterizes the permanent
limitation of these functions is that they are (long run) component of the price,
not uniquely identiable when shocks to the and pit is the transitory (short run)
system are correlated. In a study of spatial component for each location.
prices it is unreasonable to expect uncorre-
lated errors because the time series of prices The basic elements of this denition are the
are highly correlated. The usual solution existence of trade and that ft is common to
a Cholesky decompositionimposes a recur- all series of prices. The physical ow of goods
sive ordering on the variables in the system. via trade is important to ensure that arbi-
The impulse response functions, however, are trage occurs, but by itself does not guarantee
not invariant to the ordering. For every order integration because there may exist markets
we would calculate a different reaction path. with very thin or intermittent trade for which
578 August 2001 Amer. J. Agr. Econ.

a common integrating factor for all i and t in market i. Suppose that Pt can be decom-
does not exist. Similarly, the existence of an posed into two components as follows
integrating factor, by itself, does not ensure
integration because there may be physically (1) Pt = Ans ft + Pt
isolated markets that exhibit co-movements
of prices that result from seasonal patterns where ft is an s 1 vector of s(s < n) com-
or policies. The denition does not imply mon unit root factors and Pt is an n 1 vec-
that all the participating locations process the tor of stationary components. Every element
relevant information simultaneously. It does in the vector Pt can be explained by a lin-

Downloaded from http://ajae.oxfordjournals.org/ at Niedersaechsische Staats- und Universitaetsbibliothek Goettingen on June 5, 2015
require that all locations should be connected ear combination of a smaller number of I (1)
either directly or indirectly through trade and common factors fjt (permanent component)
long run information. plus an I (0) or transitory component (for
Our denition provides an operational instance pit = sj=1 aij fjt + pit ). In the long
framework to search for the extent, or geo- run, the variables pit move together because
they share the same stochastic trends. The
graphic boundaries, of an integrated mar-
representation (1) is known as the com-
ket. The rst step is to identify the set of
mon factor representation and its existence
locations that is connected either directly or
is guaranteed if and only if there are n s
indirectly through continuous unidirectional
cointegrating vectors among the elements of
trade. Because domestic trade data do not
the vector Pt (Granger representation theo-
exist for many developing countries, we begin
rem in Engle and Granger). A major result of
by estimating annual trade ows for each the Granger representation theorem is that a
location in the market. This allows us to cointegrated system can be written as a VEC
exclude locations that experience trade rever- model
sals (exporters that become importers and
vice versa). It also permits us to identify loca- (2) Pt = + Pt1 + 1 Pt1 + 2 Pt2
tions that are close to self-sufciency and are
thus candidates for experiencing discontinu- + + p1 Ptp+1 + t
ous trade.2 Once we identify the set of loca- where  and  are n n matrices and  has
tions that is tied together through trade, we reduced rank ns. The matrix  can be writ-
begin the search for those states that share a ten as  =
, where is an n (n s)
common integrating factor. matrix of coefcients, and is an n (n s)
A novel feature of this article is our focus matrix of cointegrating vectors. Using this
on the relevance and implications of search- expression for , we have Pt1 =
Pt1 =
ing for a single common integrating factor. Zt1 . The error correction term, also known
Most of the literature on market integra- as short run disequilibrium, is Zt1 =
Pt1 ,
tion has focused on estimating and testing and is the matrix of adjustment coefcients.
the cointegrating vectors, thus neglecting the The elements of the matrix cancel the com-
information contained in the integrating fac- mon unit roots in Pt and, in the long run, link
tor(s). Cointegrating vectors and integrating the movements of the elements of Pt .
factors, however, are intimately related. The In this context, our denition of the extent
existence of one and only one integrating fac- of an integrated market requires that s = 1
tor for all prices implies that (1) prices must because we are searching for locations that
be cointegrated, and (2) there must be n 1 share the same long run information.3 The
cointegrating vectors. If transactions costs are common factor representation (1) becomes
non-stationary, then n 1 cointegrating vec- pit = ai1 f1t + pit  i = 1    n. Search-
tors must be found when prices are measured ing for just one common factor is equivalent
net of transactions costs. A formal analysis of to searching for n 1 cointegrating vectors.
the implications of a single integrating factor This is a key point because it differentiates
follows. our article from previous studies on market
Consider an n 1 non-stationary I (1) vec- integration. In our approach, the economic
tor of log-prices Pt = {p1t  p2t     pnt } where
pit is the log-price of a commodity at time t
3
If there were more than one common trend, for example two,
some prices could be generated by the rst common trend, some
by the second, and some by a combination of the rst and second
2
When trade reversals or discontinuities are important, then a trends. We would not call these markets integrated because the
switching regime model would be required. Barrett, Baulch, Li long run movements in prices would be governed by different
and Barret, and McNew and Fackler have stressed this point. components.
Gonzalez-Rivera and Helfand Pattern and Degree of Market Integration 579

market is not given a priori by the set of thus adding a second common trend to the
locations where a good is produced and/or m+1 locations. If we nd one common trend,
consumed. Nor is the existence of cointe- we repeat the procedure by adding locations
grated prices sufcient to nd the market. one at a time. If not, we exclude the loca-
It needs to be found through a multivari- tion that added a second trend and repeat
ate search for a single common factor. In the the procedure until the number of locations is
case of Brazilian rice, although we have 19 exhausted. This sequential procedure may be
locations we show that only 15 belong to the subject to some pre-testing problems. Future
same economic market. research should study the econometric prob-

Downloaded from http://ajae.oxfordjournals.org/ at Niedersaechsische Staats- und Universitaetsbibliothek Goettingen on June 5, 2015
The search for the largest set of loca- lems of sequential exclusion. To ameliorate
tions that share n 1 cointegrating vectors is potential problems, we have considered dif-
conducted in a multivariate framework: the ferent orders. In our application, the exclu-
reduced rank VAR proposed by Johansen sion of locations is invariant to the order in
(1988, 1991). Johansens test for the number which they have been analyzed.
of cointegrating vectors focuses on testing Finally, after nding the n 1 cointe-
the rank of . The process of testing for grating vectors, we proceed to estimate the
the rank of  occurs jointly with the esti- common factor. We follow the methodology
mation of the cointegrating vectors and vec- proposed by Gonzalo and Granger to esti-
tor error correction model. Thus, in contrast mate f1t . This methodology is particularly
to the two-stage EngleGranger methodol- attractive because the common factor is asso-
ogy, Johansens approach is a one-stage pro- ciated with observable variables and it allows
cedure. When the number of cointegrating for the identication of the location(s) that
relations is identied, we have not only esti- contribute to the long run behavior of the
mated the cointegrating vectors but have also market price. The estimation of the common
estimated the short run dynamics of the sys- factor is easily derived from the specica-
tem given by equation (2). tion of the error correction model (2). Two
The existence of n 1 cointegrating vec- conditions are needed to identify the com-
tors implies that the vectors can be normal- mon factor. The rst one imposes that f1t be
ized in such a way that all locations will be a linear combination of the elements of the
cointegrated pair-wise. This is not sufcient, vector of prices {p1t  p2t     pnt } so that f1t
however, to justify a bivariate analysis of the is observable. The second condition imposes
market because the true vector error correc- that, in equation (1), the transitory compo-
tion model is still a multivariate system. Thus, nent Pt does not Granger-cause the perma-
a bivariate system will in general be mis- nent component Af1t in the long run. Thus,
specied due to the omission of potentially any shock that affects the transitory compo-
relevant variables. This leads to inconsistent nent is not transmitted to the long run fore-
estimates of the parameters of the bivariate cast of Pt . This condition implies that in the
VEC as well as of any other estimator based vector error correction model the only linear
on it. combination of {p1t  p2t      pnt } such that
To determine which locations belong to the Pt does not have any long run effect on Pt is
same market, we recommend starting with
the maximum set of locations, n, and testing (3) f1t =
Pt
for n 1 cointegrating vectors. We do this by
performing Johansens likelihood ratio test where
= 0. This orthogonality condi-
based on the trace statistic. If the number of tion means that the vector eliminates the
cointegrating vectors is less than n 1, we error correction term Zt1 =
Pt1 from the
need to identify those locations that should vector error correction model, guaranteeing
be removed from the system. In order to do no effect of the transitory component on the
so we implement a sequential procedure. We long run forecast of Pt . Equation (3) can be
start with a core of m locations (m < n) and used to reveal the locations that contribute
test for the number of cointegrating vectors. to the transmission of long run information.
If the number is m 1 we add an additional This is important for the design of economic
location. With m + 1 locations, either the new policy. Price support, or stabilization poli-
one shares a common trend with the previous cies, for example, could be targeted at those
m locations or it does not. In the rst case, we locations that form f1t . The transmission of
should nd m cointegrating vectors, while in policy to the rest of the market would be
the second, we should continue to nd m 1, guaranteed.
580 August 2001 Amer. J. Agr. Econ.

The Pattern of Interdependence model. The tests for weak exogeneity and
for further restrictions can then appropriately
In this article, the pattern of interdependence reduce the system. At the end of the empiri-
refers to the set of relationships among the cal section of this article, we compare bivari-
different locations of the market as revealed ate and multivariate estimations of the VEC
through an analysis of the vector error cor- in order to expose the biases that could occur
rection model. The VEC in equation (2) sum- due to the misspecication of the model.
marizes the short run dynamics of the vector
Pt as a function of a proportion of past dis-

Downloaded from http://ajae.oxfordjournals.org/ at Niedersaechsische Staats- und Universitaetsbibliothek Goettingen on June 5, 2015
equilibria Zt1 plus p 1 lags of each pi . In The Degree of Integration
this model, the matrix of adjustment coef- Many studies have attempted to answer ques-
cients is of particular interest because it con- tions about the degree of market integration
tains the necessary information to uncover based on partial measures derived from a
the spatial structure of the market. Further-
bivariate VEC model. It has been customary
more, this matrix provides the key to choos-
to look at the size of the adjustment coef-
ing between a bivariate and a multivariate
cients () or the statistical signicance of the
analysis of the system.
lag structure ( ). Our goal is to jointly eval-
There are different patterns that could be
uate the estimates of equation (2) and sum-
observed in a VEC. Several examples follow.
marize them in a single measure that denes
Suppose that we were to nd that all ele-
the degree of integration. Impulse response
ments of the matrix were statistically sig-
functions have been used extensively for this
nicant. Then we would have a system in
which each location reacts to every single purpose. They trace the impact over time of
disequilibrium or error correction term of a shock in location j on the price of location
every other location. This would be a case of i. The main drawback of impulse response
extreme interdependence where the informa- functions is that they are not unique when
tion contained in prices is generated in every the shocks are correlated. In a study of spa-
single location. In such a market, it is obvious tial prices it is unreasonable to expect to have
that a bivariate analysis would be grossly mis- orthogonal shocks because the time series of
specied because it would be omitting numer- all prices are highly correlated. The solution
ous relevant variables. adopted in the literature has been to orthog-
As a second example, suppose that there onalize the shocks with a Cholesky decom-
was an exogenous central location i that positon of the covariance matrix of errors.
dominated the long run behavior of the sys- This decomposition is not invariant to the
tem. In this case, we should observe that in ordering of the variables of the system and
the equation of the VEC for location i all ij  consequently, for every order, we have a dif-
j = 1    n 1 should be statistically zero. ferent impulse response function. Imposing a
This is a test for weak exogeneity with the recursive ordering on the variables is a very
null hypothesis H0 : ij = 0, j = 1    n 1. strong identifying assumption, and not justi-
A failure to reject the null hypothesis sug- able in most studies of market integration.
gests the existence of an exogenous location It is because impulse response functions are
that by itself would be the integrating fac- likely to be misleading and difcult to inter-
tor of the system. Even in this case, however, pret that we propose an alternative measure
a bivariate analysis would be inappropriate that does not require the imposition of an
unless further tests were performed. A bivari- ordering on the system.
ate VEC would only be justied if it were The long run equilibrium among prices can
also true that each location only adjusted to be written as:
its own disequilibrium with respect to the
exogenous location. Thus, in addition to an (4) p1t = (ci /1i )
exogenous location, all jk k = i would have (2i /1i )p2t (ni /1i )pnt
to be statistically zero.
Between the two extremes described above, + zit i = 1     (n s)
many other patterns are possible. In order to
reveal the pattern of interdependence in a where ci is a constant and all other variables
market, or to determine if a bivariate speci- are as dened above. Suppose that there is
cation is adequate, it is necessary to begin a shock to the underlying VAR that disturbs
with a multivariate vector error correction the long run equilibrium among the pit , that
Gonzalez-Rivera and Helfand Pattern and Degree of Market Integration 581

is |zit | = 0. Because equation (4) is a coin- t1 ) = E{[Zt+k E(Zt+k | t1 )] | t1 }2


tegrating relation, the vector Zt is station- where Zt+k E(Zt+k | t1 ) is the k + 1 fore-
ary. This implies that the effect of the shock cast error of Zt . According to this interpre-
will be transitory and eventually die out, and tation, denition (5) says that a persistence
the long run equilibrium will be restored. We prole is the change in the variance of the
dene the degree of integration as the reac- forecast of Zt+k with respect to the variance
tion time for each of the long run equilibrium of the forecast of Zt+k1 based on the infor-
relations to absorb a system-wide shock. This mation set t1 .
depends on all of the estimated coefcients of From equation (1) and Zt = c +
Pt , we

Downloaded from http://ajae.oxfordjournals.org/ at Niedersaechsische Staats- und Universitaetsbibliothek Goettingen on June 5, 2015
, and  . By analyzing the joint impact of have Zt = c +
Aft +
Pt = c +
Pt ,
these coefcients, it becomes possible to con- where the last equality follows from
A = 0
struct a consistent ranking of markets based because Zt is stationary. Consequently, we
on reaction times. We adopt the methodology have
of Pesaran and Shin and construct persistence 
proles. Hz (k) =
Var(Pt+k | t1 )
A persistence prole characterizes the 
Var(Pt+k1 | t1 )
response of the cointegrating relation Zt =

Pt to a system-wide, rather than to an indi- where k = 0 1 2    To facilitate the comp-


vidual shock, where the response is mea- arison among different proles, we scale
sured in units of variance. A system-wide Hz (k). For k = 0 Hz (0) =
{Var(Pt |
shock is understood as a draw from the t1 )} =
. Dene a diagonal matrix
multivariate distribution of the vector t = G that contains the inverse of the square
{1t  2t     nt }. The advantage of consider- root of the diagonal elements of Hz (0) G =
ing a system-wide shock is that the persis- diag{H11 (0)1/2     Hns ns (0)1/2 }. The sca-
tence proles are unique functions and there led persistence prole is dened as
is no need to orthogonalize the individual
shocks. At time t, the variancecovariance (6) hz (k) = GHz (k)G = {hij (k)}
matrix of the shock t is . We study the k = 0 1 2   
propagation through time (t + 1 t + 2    )
of the variance of the shock, conditioning Upon impact, at time k = 0, the prole
on information up to time t 1. Thus, with hii (k) = 1 for i = 1    n s.
an initial shock to the economy at time t,
and considering the information up to time
t 1, the persistence prole focuses on the The Brazilian Rice Market
incremental variance of the disequilibrium
error at time t + k, as the time horizon
Determining the Extent of the Market
increases by one period. In stationary sys-
tems, a shock will eventually die out. This The spatial pattern of production, consump-
implies that its incremental variance becomes tion, and trade. Rice production in Brazil is
smaller as time passes and approaches zero as concentrated in a small number of states. In
time goes to innity. Pesaran and Shin dene the 1970s, ve of Brazils twenty-ve states
the (unscaled) persistence prole as produced 65% of the countrys rice. By the
  1990s, these same areas (reconstituted in
(5) Hz (k) = Var Zt+k | t1 seven states) had increased their share to
  75% of national production. While produc-
Var Zt+k1 | t1 tion data in Brazil are available on an annual
basis, data on consumption are virtually non-
k = 0 1 2    existent. In order to estimate inter-state trade
ows, we rst had to estimate state level con-
where t1 is the information set containing sumption on an annual basis with data on
information up to time t 1, Var (Zt+k | t1 ) population and per capita rice consumption.4
is the variance of Zt+k conditional on the
information set, and k is the time horizon.
The denition (5) has an appealing interpre- 4
The production and population data come from the Anuario
tation if we observe that Var(Zt+k | t1 ) is Estatstico do Brasil, Fundacao
Instituto Brasileiro de Geograa
e Estatstica (IBGE), various years. The consumption data come
also the variance of the k + 1 step ahead from ofcial IBGE consumption/expenditure surveys conducted
forecast error of Zt . We can write Var(Zt+k | in 1974, 1987, and 1996.
582 August 2001 Amer. J. Agr. Econ.

Table 1. Estimated Inter-State Trade of Rice for Selected States


Tradea Index of Self-Sufciency
(Percent of National Production) (Production/Consumption)
State 197079 198089 199095 197079 198089 199095
North (N) 21 05 05 06 09 09
Acre (AC) 01 01 02 06 15 20
Para (PA) 14 12 09 05 06 07

Downloaded from http://ajae.oxfordjournals.org/ at Niedersaechsische Staats- und Universitaetsbibliothek Goettingen on June 5, 2015
Northeast (NE) 26 87 136 09 06 05
Maranhao (MA) 95 58 22 58 24 14
Ceara (CE) 19 40 42 03 02 03
Rio Grande do Norte (RN) 09 13 15 01 00 00
Paraba (PB) 12 17 19 02 01 01
Pernambuco (PE) 31 24 25 00 01 01
Bahia (BA) 42 41 46 01 01 02
Sergipe (SE) 03 03 04 05 05 04
Southeast (SE) 323 343 339 04 03 03
Minas Gerais (MG) 33 51 60 08 06 05
Espirito Santo (ES) 11 12 13 05 04 04
Rio de Janeiro (RJ) 88 80 94 01 01 01
Sao Paulo (SP) 191 200 173 03 02 02
South (S) 163 255 403 19 28 43
Parana (PR) 11 18 26 11 07 05
Santa Catarina (SC) 01 20 40 10 17 26
Rio Grande do Sul (RS) 152 254 389 31 56 89
Center-West (CW) 206 180 77 42 32 18
Mato Grosso do Sul (MS)b 25 07 28 14
Mato Grosso (MT) 118 75 48 66 65 36
(GO)c
Goias 97 89 12 38 32 13
a Positive values indicate exports and negative values indicate imports.
b Mato Grosso do Sul was created in 1977. Prior to 1977 it was part of Mato Grosso.
c In 1988 Goias was divided in two and Tocantins was created. In the 199095 period, Tocantins exported 2.6% of national production.

Table 1 presents the estimates of inter-state trade occurred continuously with a steady
trade for the 19 states for which we have ow of trucks transporting rice from surplus
continuous price data. These states accounted to decit regions.5
for over 90% of production and consumption. The Southeast of Brazil is home to more
The rst three columns show the difference than 40% of the population. This region con-
between a states share of national produc- sistently imported over 30% of national rice
tion and its share of national consumption for production, with most of the decit com-
three sub-periods, thus providing estimates of ing from Sao Paulo. The Northeast was the
exports (positive numbers) and imports (neg- only other region with a signicant shortage
ative numbers) as a share of national produc- of rice. With the exception of Maranhao, all
tion. The nal three columns show an index of the other Northeastern states were clear
of self-sufciency, dened as the ratio of a importers. Regardless of how small the abso-
states production share to its consumption lute size of their decits, the self-sufciency
share. A ratio close to one implies that a state index reveals that none of these states pro-
is close to self-sufcient. duced more than half of their consumption,
and most produced only 1020%. Steady
Table 1 shows that although rice is often
inows of rice from as far away as Rio
considered to be a non-tradable good for
Grande do Sul have always been necessary.
Brazil as a nation, it was traded extensively
within the country. Approximately half of
Brazilian rice was traded across state borders 5
Continuous trade ows are conrmed by Ereias for the state
throughout the period. Since the demand for of Rio Grande do Sul. Interviews conducted by the authors in
the Rio Grande do Sul Rice Institute (IRGA) and in the Getulio

rice is constant throughout the year, and rice Vargas Foundation (FGV) also conrmed that continuous trade
is stored predominantly in producing regions, is the normal state of affairs.
Gonzalez-Rivera and Helfand Pattern and Degree of Market Integration 583

The distant Northern part of the country is with real monthly producer prices that were
relatively isolated and as a region it is close obtained from the Getulio Vargas Founda-
to self-sufcient. The physical isolation and tion (FGV).7 By having our sample run from
poor infrastructure of this region led us to 1973:01 to 1997:08 we were able to include
expect that states located here were unlikely a total of nineteen states. At a later stage
to belong to the national economic market. in the analysis, after determining that sev-
Acre, in addition, exhibits a clear trade rever- eral states did not belong to the system, the
sal as it transitions from being an importer in sample period was extended back to 1970:01.
the 1970s to an exporter in the 1990s. For this Two versions of the Augmented Dickey

Downloaded from http://ajae.oxfordjournals.org/ at Niedersaechsische Staats- und Universitaetsbibliothek Goettingen on June 5, 2015
reason it would be inappropriate to include Fuller (ADF) test were performed, one which
Acre in the VEC. excluded and one which included a constant
Other than Maranhao, the principal sur- in the regression. The time series were not
plus states were located in the Center-West smooth enough to entertain the possibility
and South. The Center-West accounted for a of a deterministic trend in the regression.
larger share of trade than the South in the We also conducted F tests for the joint null
1970s, yet by the 1990s the Southespecially hypothesis of a constant equal to 0 and a
Rio Grande do Sulwas exporting ve times unit root. The optimal number of lags in each
as much as the Center-West. Along with its regression was chosen according to the AIC
neighbor Santa Catarina, Rio Grande do Sul and SIC criteria.
was different from the other states in two For the states in the Center-West, South,
important ways. First, it produced irrigated and Southeast, we could not reject the
rice that was subject to far less production hypothesis of a unit root at the one percent
variability than the rain-fed rice produced in signicance level with any of the tests. In the
other states. Second, it produced higher qual- Northeast and in the North, the statistical evi-
ity rice. Both of these facts have important dence was mixed. In particular, for Maranhao,
implications and will be discussed below. Paraba, and Sergipe in the Northeast, and
We have demonstrated that with the excep- for Para and Acre in the North, the introduc-
tion of Acre, rice trade occurred with no tion of a constant in the regression made a
reversals and was apparently continuous. In difference for the results of the tests. With a
the early 1970s this might not have been true constant, we rejected the unit root at the one
for Parana and Santa Catarina. Our annual percent signicance level, but without a con-
trade estimates indicate that these two states stant we did not. Furthermore, the estimated
hovered around self-sufciency in the rst values of the roots were the smallest among
half of the decade. Price differentials, in con- all the states, ranging from 0.89 to 0.94. With
trast, were consistent with the pattern of the exception of Maranhao, these states were
trade that prevailed throughout the rest of very small in terms of production and con-
the period. The possibility that discontinuous sumption of rice. At this point in the analy-
trade might distort our econometric estimates sis, we maintain the unit root hypothesis for
led us to conduct additional tests for param- all 19 states. Additional evidence is found at
eter constancy that will be described below. a later stage for removing most of these bor-
We conclude that the inclusion of the early derline states.
1970s does not generate a problem for our In table 2, we implemented the sequen-
model.6 A plausible explanation is that even tial procedure described above to deter-
if the excess supply and demand in these mine which states shared the same common
two states was small, it was still sufcient to stochastic trend. Column 1 of table 2 shows
keep their prices close to the parity levels. the sequence of locations that were analyzed.
These two states were, in addition, constantly We started with a core of ten important states
exposed to competitive pressures because in the Center-West, South, and Southeast.
large quantities of rice owed through their Different sequences were analyzed and the
territories. results were invariant to the ordering. The
Searching for a single common trend. We value of the likelihood ratio test is shown
conducted tests for unit roots in the log- in parentheses for those cases in which the
prices of rice in nineteen states. We work null hypothesis could not be rejected. At the

6 7
The same conclusion is reached for the next most likely can- All prices are in constant reais, the Brazilian currency, of
didates to experience discontinuous trade: MG in the 1970s, and 12/1995. The monthly producer prices were deated by the Gen-
MA, MS, and GO in the 1990s. eral Price Index (IGP-DI) of the Getulio
Vargas Foundation.
584 August 2001 Amer. J. Agr. Econ.

Table 2. Johansens Likelihood Ratio Test for the Number of Cointegrating Vectors
(Trace Statistic, 1973:011997:08) H0 : r = h; H1 : r > h
Signicance Level (%)
Series Included 20 10 5
Center-West + South + Southeast = 10 10 9 9 (6.43)
10 + MA = 11 10 10 10 (5.78)
11 + BA = 12 11 11 11 (5.60)

Downloaded from http://ajae.oxfordjournals.org/ at Niedersaechsische Staats- und Universitaetsbibliothek Goettingen on June 5, 2015
12 + SE = 13 12 12 12 (5.56)
13 + PE = 14 13 13 13 (5.46)
14 + CE = 15 14 14 (4.94) 13 (19.22)
15 + RN + PB = 17 16 (4.24) 13 (50.44) 8 (205.80)
17 + AC + PA = 19 13 (93.12) 9 (242.50) 8 (290.48)
Note: r is the number of cointegrating vectors. The values of the likelihood ratio tests are in parentheses. The critical values are from MacKinnon, Haug
and Michelis (1996), and extrapolation. See footnote 8 in the text.

5% signicance level, we found one common a single common trend with the other states.
trend among the original ten states. Regard- For Rio Grande do Norte and Paraba,
less of the order chosen, we continued to nd the one-common-trend hypothesis was only
one common trend when four Northeastern accepted at the 20% signicance level, imply-
states were added (MA, BA, SE and PE). ing a very high probability of committing a
Ceara (CE) entered the set of one-common- Type I error. Furthermore, at the 510% sig-
trend markets at the 10% signicance level, nicance levels, the inclusion of any of these
and at the 20% signicance level Rio Grande four states actually reduced the number of
do Norte (RN) and Paraba (PB) could also cointegrating vectors to a smaller number
be included. For Acre (AC) and Para (PA), than that of the original set, implying more
the two Northern states, thirteen cointegrat- than one common trend.
ing vectors were found at the 20% level, The fact that producer prices in four states
implying six common trends. did not share a common trend with the other
The conclusion that we draw regarding the fteen should be interpreted carefully. First,
extent of the market is that fteen states in the case of Acre this could be due to the
belonged to the same economic market: those trade reversal and the results might differ for
in the Center-West, South, and Southeast, sub-periods. A second observation is that, due
plus MA, BA, SE, PE and CE in the North- to a lack of time series data on transactions
east. All fteen states were shown to engage costs, the failure to nd a single common
in a signicant amount of unidirectional inter- trend could indicate either a lack of integra-
state trade. They also shared a single com- tion or non-stationary transactions costs.9 In
mon trend at a signicance level smaller fact, the two Northern states are in a remote
than 10%.8 Thus, the rice from these fteen region of the country in which transporta-
states were substitutes for each other to some tion is more difcult in the rainy months of
degree and arbitrage through trade tied their the year. Similarly, the two excluded North-
prices together. eastern states had rice prices in the 1990s
Four states did not appear to belong to this that were far too high to be consistent with
market. Acre was excluded on the grounds distance and average transactions costs. It is
that it experienced a trade reversal. Together our view, however, that even if we are not
with Para, Acre was also found not to share able to pinpoint the cause for not nding a
single common trend, with the exception of
8
For the fteenth series (CE), the value of the likelihood ratio Acre the result is still meaningful. It suggests
test (19.22) is very close to the 5% critical values, 19.96 and that there is something qualitatively different
20.26, that are taken from the tables in Osterwald-Lenum and
MacKinnon, Haug, and Michelis. Critical values are calculated about the rice market in these states and it
for a maximum of 11 random walks in Osterwald-Lenum and is likely to be related to high and/or unusual
12 in MacKinnon, Haug, and Michelis. Our system contains up
to 19 variables. In order to calculate critical values we have t-
ted a quadratic polynomial on the number of random walks to
9
MacKinnon, Haug and Michelis critical values and extrapolated Fackler makes a similar point about the difculty of inter-
the critical values corresponding to 13 up to 19 random walks. preting the failure to nd cointegration. Goodwin provides an
The R2 of this regression is equal to 1. For cointegration in large empirical example by only nding cointegration in international
systems see Gonzalo and Pitarakis. wheat markets when transportation costs are included.
Gonzalez-Rivera and Helfand Pattern and Degree of Market Integration 585

transactions costs. Even if we were to nd The Pattern of Interdependence


that net of transactions costs the prices in
these states did share the same trend with Cointegration. In table 3, we present
the other fteen, the need to net transac- the normalized cointegrating vectors as in
tions costs out only for these states would still Phillips.10 The normalization is done with
indicate a signicant difference with the rest. respect to the Sao
Paulo (SP) market. The
Policy implications related to transportation 14 cointegrating vectors are readily inter-
and marketing could still be drawn, and they pretable because they consist of 14 pair-wise
would likely extend beyond the rice market. relationships. We thus explain the long run

Downloaded from http://ajae.oxfordjournals.org/ at Niedersaechsische Staats- und Universitaetsbibliothek Goettingen on June 5, 2015
equilibrium between pairs of markets (MS
Estimation of the integrating factor. In this and SP, MT and SP, etc.). For our system,
section the permanent component is esti- the long run equilibrium relations shown in
mated according to equation (3). We esti- equation (4) become
mated the integrating factor as
pit = ci + i pSP t + z it
ft = 0034pMS t 0036pMT t
i = 1     n 1
+ 0373pGO t 0102pMA t
+ 0267pCE t + 0017pPE t where pSP t is the price in the Sao
Paulo mar-
ket. Thus, in the case of Goias for example,
0070pBA t 0037pSE t we have: pGO t = 043 + 105pSP t + z it .
+ 0000pPR t 0316pSC t The values of i range from 0.58 to 1.08.
In most cases, the hypothesis that i = 1
0081pRS t 0279pMG t cannot be rejected at the 1% level. There
+ 0310pES t 0361pRJ t are several cases that clearly diverge from
this pattern. Cointegrating vectors can differ
+ 0890pSP t from (1 1) as a result of transactions costs
We tested the null hypothesis that the coef- (Dercon), as well as for other reasons.11 In
cients corresponding to MS, MT, PE, BA, Brazil, for example, most rice is stored and
SE, PR and RS were statistically 0. The test milled in producing regions, and then shipped
statistic equals 0.39 and is distributed as a 2 to decit areas to meet demand. It follows
with seven degrees of freedom. The p-value that spatial arbitrage at the producer level
associated with the test is 0.99. Consequently occurs indirectly through the wholesale mar-
we could not reject the hypothesis that these ket for milled rice. As a result, the differ-
coefcients equal 0. The integrating factor, ences in state-level producer prices measure
re-estimated with the imposed restrictions, is elements of arbitrage across form as well as
space. Thus, in addition to transactions costs,
f1 = 0363pGO t 0110pMA t
the cointegrating vectors capture regional dif-
+ 0280pCE t 0250pSC t ferences in policies, technologies, and product
quality.
0274pMG t + 0341pES t
The coefcients in the cointegrating vec-
0389pRJ t + 0817pSP t tors suggest that large transactions costs
or other factors differentiated several states
The estimated permanent component shows
from the rest. There is no evidence that dis-
the role of the different states in shaping
continuous trade was the source of these
the long run behavior of the price of rice.
The contribution of Sao Paulo (SP) to the results. Although the cointegrating vector for
permanent component of the domestic price Rio Grande do Sul has the second small-
dominates the other states. Public policy tar- est i , we have already demonstrated that
geted at Sao
Paulo would have the greatest it exported rice continuously. The i in the
impact on the long run component of prices equation for Maranhao is the smallest in
in Brazil. Furthermore, it is clear that the table 3. In order to ensure that this was
long run component of the price is driven by
two forces: the production side of the market 10
The lag length of the VAR was chosen by performing a series
represented by states from the Center-West of F-tests on the lag structure. With three lags, the residuals
(GO), the Northeast (MA), and the South seemed to behave like white noise.
11
(SC), and the consumption side of the mar- See Companhia de Financiamento da Produca o for a snapshot
of transfer costs in Brazil around 1980. It provides evidence of
ket, which mainly involves the Southeast (SP, both additive costs such as freight and proportional charges such
RJ, ES, and MG). as inter-state taxes, sales commissions, and nancial fees.
586 August 2001 Amer. J. Agr. Econ.

not caused by the possibility of discontinu- misspecied, we performed Lagrange multi-


ous trade in the 1990s when it became only plier tests for serial correlation, RESET tests
a modest exporter, we re-estimated the sys- for functional form, GARCH and Whites
tem through 12/1989. The estimated i was tests for heteroskedasticity, and CUSUM and
virtually identical (0.57 rather than 0.58). We CUSUMSQ tests for model stability.13 In the
reached the same conclusion for Parana and overall system, there was no evidence of
Santa Catarina in the 1970s, and for all other either serial correlation or seasonal patterns
states that were only marginal traders during in the residuals of the VEC. This conrmed
sub-periods of the sample. that the lag structure was appropriate to cap-

Downloaded from http://ajae.oxfordjournals.org/ at Niedersaechsische Staats- und Universitaetsbibliothek Goettingen on June 5, 2015
The coefcients in the equation for ture the dynamics of prices. Similarly, a lin-
Maranhao can be explained by high trans- ear specication of the VEC was found to
actions costs. Maranhao is the farthest state be satisfactory. The CUSUM test, based on
from Sao Paulo, with a distance of 2970 km the cumulative sum of the recursive resid-
between their capital cities. The transactions uals, did not indicate any stability problem
costs were reected in the average prices in the conditional mean. The CUSUMSQ
in these two states. Maranhao had the low- test, based on the cumulative sum of squared
est price of all 15 states, while Sao Paulo recursive residuals, pointed toward a more
had the highest. The cointegrating vector for volatile period between 1990 and 1995 for the
Rio Grande do Sul, which is no farther from states in the South and Southeast. This was
Sao
Paulo than the Center-West, reects the in agreement with the mild heteroskedastic-
fact that this state produced a higher quality ity that we found in the same states and is
rice, used a different technology (irrigation), attributable to a combination of high ina-
and was subject to a somewhat different pol- tion and a reduction of support prices in
icy environment. These factors also explain these years.14 We re-estimated the model for
the estimates for Santa Catarina. Producers the period 19701989 and found that while
in these two states had a different support the estimation results remained essentially
price than in the other regions and relied on unchanged, most of the heteroskedasticity
storage credit to a much higher degree. disappeared. Heteroskedasticity by itself does
Cointegrating vectors that diverge from the not affect the consistency of the estimates
general pattern reect structural differences of the conditional mean, but it does affect
with the other states. These states did, nev- the standard errors. As a result, we used
ertheless, belong to the same economic mar- heteroskedasticity-consistent standard errors.
ket. As we demonstrate below, differentiated We proceeded to explore the spatial pat-
cointegrating vectors do not necessarily imply tern of interdependence by conducting a
a lack of interdependence or a low degree of series of F-tests for weak exogeneity and
integration. Granger causality on the estimated coef-
The Vector Error Correction Model. cients from the unrestricted VEC. These tests
Table 4 presents the adjustment coefcients permit us to determine if there are one or
from the restricted vector error correction more exogenous statesa necessary nding
model that we estimated. This table permits in order to justify the use of a bivariate
us to highlight the problems of misspeci- model. The tests also permit us to remove
cation that would have arisen in a bivariate unnecessary terms from the VEC and to esti-
model. It also allows us to analyze the pattern mate a more parsimonious restricted speci-
of interdependence in the Brazilian rice mar- cation. Weak exogeneity of location A with
ket. Before discussing table 4, we explain the respect to the j locations in region B, for
testing that led to the restricted specication. example, implies that the price in location A
We began by estimating an unrestricted does not respond to disequilibria in region B.
vector error correction model for the 15 Consequently, in equation (2) for location A
states as a system of seemingly unrelated we should nd that the adjustment coef-
regressions (SUR). Every equation in the cients Aj corresponding to the error cor-
system had the same number of variables rection terms from region B all equal 0. If
on the right-hand side: the 14 error cor- we found a state to be weakly exogenous
rection terms from table 3, 2 lags for each
pi , and a dummy for the outlier January 13
Results from the unrestricted model and all tests are available
1990.12 To ensure that the system was not from the authors.
14
Unlike Shively, the heteroskedasticity that we nd does not
12
Production fell by 33% in 1990 and the average price for appear to be attributable to storage. It is present in consuming
Brazil rose substantially. and storing states, and is largely conned to the early 1990s.
Table 3. Normalized Cointegrating Vectors: Johansens Method (1970:011997:08)

Gonzalez-Rivera and Helfand


Center-West Northeast South Southeast
MS MT GO MA CE PE BA SE PR SC RS MG ES RJ
Statei 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 100
SP 097 106 105 058 089 089 095 073 108 079 065 091 097 085
(004) (008) (006) (012) (010) (008) (009) (007) (004) (008) (008) (003) (008) (007)
Constant 004 063 043 215 064 057 026 141 057 102 189 049 007 081
(027) (047) (034) (071) (056) (046) (054) (043) (026) (044) (048) (020) (044) (042)
Note: (1) Standard errors in parentheses. (2) Error Correction1 = PMS t 097PSP t + 004; Error Correction2 = PMT t 106PSP t + 063, etc.

Table 4. Adjustment Coefcients () From The Restricted Vector Error Correction Model (1970:011997:08)
Center-West Northeast South Southeast
Error
Correction MS MT GO MA CE PE BA SE PR SC RS MG ES RJ SP
(MS, SP) 035 017 014 009

(MT, SP) 020 007 008 007
(GO, SP) 017 012 020 011 013
(MA, SP) 003 011
004

Pattern and Degree of Market Integration


(CE, SP) 004 011 013 018
007
(PE, SP) 028 013
(BA, SP) 022 005

(SE, SP) 030 004
(PR, SP) 020
(SC, SP) 006 018 018 010
(RS, SP) 007 032
(MG, SP) 021 015 009 049 012 019

(ES, SP) 008 014 011 031 013
012
018 013
(RJ, SP) 011 016 010 014 033 038 012
Adj. R2 043 028 038 037 027 022 025 022 039 032 030 053 047 050 042
Note: Iterative SUR estimation with heteroskedasticity-consistent errors. Coefcients not signicant at the 5% level are not shown in the table.
Statistically signicant at 5% level.
Statistically signicant at 1% level.

587
Downloaded from http://ajae.oxfordjournals.org/ at Niedersaechsische Staats- und Universitaetsbibliothek Goettingen on June 5, 2015
588 August 2001 Amer. J. Agr. Econ.

with respect to other states, we then tested shown in the table, also underscored the cen-
for Granger causality with respect to the trality of the Southeast in the adjustment
same states. The absence of Granger causality process. Both Sao Paulo and Minas Gerais
implies that the price in location A is not lin- appeared in every equation in the Southeast
early inuenced by the lagged variables from and South, and one or the other appeared in
region B. each equation in the Center-West. It would
Table 4 presents the coefcients of adjust- be incorrect, however, to model the Brazilian
ment () from the restricted VEC model. rice market as having a central market (as
The most important observation relates to in the Ravallion approach). Not only does

Downloaded from http://ajae.oxfordjournals.org/ at Niedersaechsische Staats- und Universitaetsbibliothek Goettingen on June 5, 2015
the limitations of a bivariate model. A bivari- the Southeast contain four states, but there
ate specication would only be appropriate in were many other important channels through
the unlikely event that we were to nd both a which information was conveyed.
single exogenous state and all other locations Another important nding is that the three
responding only to error correction terms states in the South were the least interdepen-
dent in the country. They did not adjust to
involving this exogenous state. If this were
error correction terms from other regions of
the case, we should nd an empty column
the country and there were only three states
in table 4, implying that the state is weakly (GO, MA, and RJ) that responded to them.
exogenous, and a maximum of 14 signicant They did, however, adjust to their own dis-
error correction terms in the table, with all of equilibria with Sao Paulo and their prices
them involving the weakly exogenous state. were Granger caused by lagged prices from
Neither of these conditions was present in the Southeast. These results point to a cer-
the Brazilian rice market. The complexity of tain degree of market segmentation by qual-
adjustment patterns in the market suggests ity. This is a somewhat surprising result given
that the estimation of a bivariate VEC con- the importance of Rio Grande do Sul as a
structed from any two of our fteen states producer for the rest of the country.15 It sug-
would likely have led to important biases due gests that although different qualities of rice
to the omission of many relevant locations. were substitutes and had a stationary long
Even if we were to have limited attention to run relationship, the degree of substitution
the most important exporting and importing was probably low and it only bound their
states in the countryRio Grande do Sul and prices together in the long run.
Sao
Pauloboth dynamic equations would A nal observation is that differences in
have been misspecied due to the exclusion the cointegrating vectors did not appear to be
(respectively) of one and ve statistically sig- correlated with a states pattern of interde-
nicant error correction terms. In the nal pendence. In spite of similarities in their coin-
section of this article we explore the conse- tegrating vectors, Maranhao and Rio Grande
quences of this type of model misspecica- do Sul had very different forms of insertion
tion for the estimated path of adjustment by in the market.
comparing the bivariate and multivariate per-
sistence proles. For now, the conclusion that Persistence Proles and the
we draw is that the pattern of adjustment in a Degree of Integration
spatially integrated market is likely to be very Figure 1 shows selected persistence pro-
complex. A bivariate model is only appropri- les that were calculated from the restricted
ate in a limited number of very special mar- model according to the methodology descri-
ket structures. bed above. These graphs show the estimated
Table 4 shows that although there was no reaction time for each of the 14 long run
state that was weakly exogenous with respect equilibrium relations to absorb a system-
to the entire market, it was also the case that wide shock. The gure shows the proles
not all states interacted. As the principal con- over a twenty month horizon for (MG, SP),
suming region of the country, the states in (GO, SP), (BA, SP), and (MA, SP). The
the Southeast appeared to represent a cen- proles indicate that disequilibria between
tral location through which price information Minas Gerais (MG) and Sao Paulo (SP), for
was processed. These four states were inu- example, are removed rather quickly, while
enced by error correction terms from every
other region in the country, and they inu- 15
Barros and Filho nd a similar result for the South. They nd
enced adjustment in every other region. The no causality in either direction between the producer price in
lag structure of each equation, which is not Rio Grande do Sul and the retail price in Sao Paulo.
Gonzalez-Rivera and Helfand Pattern and Degree of Market Integration 589

Downloaded from http://ajae.oxfordjournals.org/ at Niedersaechsische Staats- und Universitaetsbibliothek Goettingen on June 5, 2015
Figure 1. Persistence proles from the restricted VEC model (1970:011997:08)

this is not the case for Maranhao (MA) and Table 5. Estimated Half-Lives of the Per-
SP. When there is a system-wide shock that sistence Proles (months)
affects the long run equilibrium between SP
1970:011997:08
and MG, 45% of the adjustments take place
in the rst month, and nearly 80% within State Restricted Unrestricted
three months. Disequilibria between Goias MG 120 113
(GO) and SP are removed a bit slower, with MS 135 120
only 68% of the adjustments occurring within GO 171 183
three months. MA actually overshoots at rst, MT 172 163
and after three months 70% of the effect of SE 177 191
the shock remains. PR 189 215
While the proles capture the entire path RJ 201 183
of adjustment between a given state and SP, PE 245 255
it would be useful to construct a statistic SC 263 295
to summarize the information in the graph. ES 266 272
For this purpose, we have calculated the BA 286 305
median persistence, or half-life, of the effect RS 316 343
of the shock for each state with SP, dened CE 381 416
as the number of months necessary for 50% MA 513 434
of the adjustments to take place. This infor-
mation is shown in table 5 for the restricted
and unrestricted models. shares a border with SP as well, and is on the
The second column of table 5 shows the trade route from GO to SP. Thus, all of the
half-lives for the restricted model. The states rice that comes from GO and the other states
have been divided into three groups. The in the Center-West must pass through MG.
rst group, which has half-lives that are two The second group of states has half-lives
months or less, includes the three states in between 2.45 and 3.16 months. These states
the Center-West that export rice to Sao
Paulo are consumers in the Northeast (PE and BA),
(MS, MT, and GO), the three neighbors of producers in the South (SC and RS), and
Sao
Paulo that are also important consumers the only state in the Southeast that does not
(MG, PR, and RJ) and the small state Sergipe share a border with SP (ES). Since the North-
(SE). Adjustment between SP and both MG eastern states are only indirectly linked to
and MS happens the fastest, with half-lives SP through common suppliers, the reduced
under 1.35 months. Not only does MS supply speed for Pernambuco (PE) and Bahia (BA)
rice to SP, but they also share a border. MG relative to the rst group is understand-
590 August 2001 Amer. J. Agr. Econ.

able. Rio Grande do Sul (RS), as we have half-life, and the mean persistence. The mean
noted throughout the article, is an exception. persistence of disequilibria is a weighted
Adjustment with SP happens relatively slowly average of the information from the entire
in spite of the strong trade ties that exist. The 20-month horizon, although it weights the
low degree of integration is most likely due most distant months least because the dis-
to differences in the quality of the rice that equilibria at that horizon are negligible. In
is grown in each state. If middle and high spite of the smaller adjustment coefcients
income consumers prefer the higher quality that would have led us to expect slower
rice that is produced in RS and are hesitant adjustment, the comparison reveals that the

Downloaded from http://ajae.oxfordjournals.org/ at Niedersaechsische Staats- und Universitaetsbibliothek Goettingen on June 5, 2015
to substitute even when harvests are poor bivariate models estimated a quicker path of
and prices rise, then the cross price elasticity adjustment. On average, the bivariate half-
of demand for these products would be low. lives were slightly smaller (6.9%), and the
The channel of transmission from the pro- bivariate mean proles were substantially
ducer price in one state to the producer price smaller (34%). In three cases the discrep-
in the other, through consumption decisions ancies between the multivariate and bivari-
in SP, would consequently be rather weak.16 ate half-lives were in the 1933% range, and
The third group of states belongs to the dis- in eleven of the fourteen cases the bivariate
tant Northeast. Not only are the links with
mean proles were 3055% smaller. These
SP indirect, but the distances are far greater.
discrepancies reect the misspecication of
Finally, the last column of the table shows
that the results from the unrestricted model the VEC that arises from excluding relevant
are quite similar. error correction terms. It is also related to
the loss of explanatory power in the bivari-
Multivariate versus Bivariate Models ate models. On average, the adjusted R2 from
the bivariate VECs was almost 20% lower. In
We estimated 14 bivariate models in order several cases, such as Pernambuco (PE) and
to highlight the problems that could arise Rio Grande do Sul (RS), the loss of explana-
with this approach in the context of a spa- tory power was more than 40%.
tially integrated market. For comparability
with the multivariate model, all 14 bivariate
models included Sao Paulo. The results indi-
cated that the problems with the bivariate Conclusions
approach did not appear to extend to the esti-
mation of the slope coefcient in the cointe- In this article we posed the question of mar-
grating vectors. In no case did these diverge ket integration as one of degree. As a result,
by more than 6%. Since our system has a we provided a ranking of all locations from
single common trend and all states are coin- less to more integrated. To achieve this objec-
tegrated pair-wise, this is not surprising. The tive, we introduced two novel features to the
adjustment coefcients from the vector error market integration literature. First, we con-
correction models, in contrast, revealed much ducted a multivariate search to determine the
more substantial discrepancies. The bivariate geography of the market. Second, we used a
models appear to estimate the adjustment measure of the degree of integrationa per-
coefcient between each state and Sao Paulo sistence prolethat does not suffer from
with a downward bias. In 13 of the 14 cases the drawbacks of impulse response functions.
the adjustment coefcients were smaller in Our denition of an integrated market
the bivariate model, and the average differ- requires that the set of locations share the
ence was 31%. In four cases the coefcient same traded commodity and the same long
was less than half of what was estimated in run information. With information on rice
the multivariate model, and in one case it was from 19 states in Brazil, we found that only
almost double. 15 belonged to the same economic market.
We calculated two descriptive statistics Two of the four excluded locations were no
from the persistence proles: the median, or more physically isolated than other states
from the same region of the country. To the
16
We thank Ignez and Mauro Lopes for this insight. They also
extent that these locations were excluded
observed that the government was more likely to permit imports due to poor physical or marketing infrastruc-
in response to a poor harvest in RS than in the Center-West ture, the consequences are likely to extend
due to the importance of this states rice for urban middle-class
consumers. This had the effect of mitigating the impact of events beyond the rice market, thus impeding the
in RS on price transmission to other states. ability of these two states to improve their
Gonzalez-Rivera and Helfand Pattern and Degree of Market Integration 591

welfare through specialization and trade. Fur- Publicas.


G.C. Delgado, J.G. Gasques, and
thermore, we estimated the common integrat- C.M.V. Verde, eds., pp. 51565. (IPEA Serie
ing factor for the 15 states in the market as 127.) Braslia: IPEA, 1990.
a linear combination of prices in eight loca- Baulch, B. Transfer Costs, Spatial Arbitrage, and
tions. These states provide the key to the Testing for Food Market Integration. Amer.
transmission of long run information. Thus, J. Agr. Econ. 79(May 1997) :47787.
public policy could be targeted at a relatively Companhia de Financiamento da Producao (CFP).
small number of locations and still be effec- Analise das Distorcoes
dos Precos Domesticos
tive in terms of inuencing the entire market.

Downloaded from http://ajae.oxfordjournals.org/ at Niedersaechsische Staats- und Universitaetsbibliothek Goettingen on June 5, 2015
en Relaca o aos Precos de Fronteira: Um
Once the extent of the market was deter- Estudo Preliminar. (Colecao Analise
e
mined, we then used persistence proles Pesquisa, 30.) Brasilia
:CFP, 1983.
to measure the degree of integration. We Dercon, S. On Market Integration and Lib-
demonstrated that large volumes of trade eralisation: Method and Application to
were not sufcient to generate a high Ethiopia. J. Dev. Stud. 32(October 1995):
degree of integration. Among other factors, 11243.
it appears that physical distance and distance Engle, R.F., and C.W.J. Granger. Co-Integration
in product space (quality) can both lead to and Error Correction :Representation, Esti-
a low degree of integration. Future research mation, and Testing. Econometrica 55(March
should focus on explaining the determinants 1987) :25176.
of the degree of integration. We believe that Ereias, A.C.S. Analise
das Margens de Comercial-
this is an area of inquiry with highly relevant izacao
do Setor Orizcola Gaucho."
MS The-
implications for policy. sis, Federal University of Rio Grande do Sul,
Finally, we emphasized the shortcomings of
1999.
a bivariate approach to market integration.
Fackler, P. Spatial Price Analysis: A Method-
The major problem lies in the misspecica-
ological Review. Unpublished, Department
tion of the vector error correction representa-
of Agricultural and Resource Economics, NC
tion of a cointegrated system. When relevant
State, 1997.
variables are omitted, the estimators become
Fundacao
Instituto Brasileiro de Geograa e
inconsistent. This inconsistency is carried for-
ward to any other statistic that is based on Estatstica (IBGE). Anuario Estatstico do
the vector error correction model, including Brasil. Rio de Janeiro: IBGE, various years.
impulse response functions and persistence . Estudo Nacional da Despesa Familiar:
proles. Consumo Alimentar, Despesas das Famlias,
Dados Preliminares, Tabelas Selecionadas. Rio
de Janeiro: IBGE, 1978.
[Received November 1998;
. Pesquisa de Orcamentos Familiares, 1987 and
accepted September 2000.]
1996. From www.IBGE.gov.br.
Gonzalo, J., and C.W.J. Granger Estimation
of Common Long-Memory Components in
References Cointegrated Systems. J. Bus. Econ. Stat.
13(January 1995) :2735.
Alexander, C., and J. Wyeth. Cointegration Gonzalo, J., and J.Y. Pitarakis, Comovements in
and Market Integration: An Application to Large Systems. Working Paper 95-38, Dept.
the Indonesian Rice Market. J. Dev. Stud. of Stat. and Econ., Universidad Carlos III de
30(January 1994) :30328. Madrid, 1995.
Asche, F., H. Bremnes, and C.R. Wessels. Product Goodwin, B.K. Multivariate Cointegration Tests
Aggregation, Market Integration, and Rela- and the Law of One Price in International
tionships Between Prices: An Application to Wheat Markets. Rev. Agri. Econ. 14(January
World Salmon Markets. Amer. J. Agr. Econ. 1993) :11724.
81(August 1999) :56881. Goodwin, B.K., and T.C. Schroeder. Cointegration
Barrett, C.B. Market Analysis Methods: Are Our Tests and Spatial Price Linkages in Regional
Enriched Toolkits Well Suited to Enlivened Cattle Markets. Amer. J. Agr. Econ 73(May
Markets? Amer. J. Agr. Econ. 78(August 1991) :45264.
1996) :82529. Johansen, S. Estimation and Hypothesis Testing
Barros, G.S.C., and J.G.M. Filho. Transmissao of Cointegration Vectors in Gaussian Vec-
de Precos e Margens de Comercializacao de tor Autoregressive Models, Econometrica, 59
Produtos Agrcolas. Agricultura e Polticas (November 1991) :155180.
592 August 2001 Amer. J. Agr. Econ.

.Statistical Analysis of Cointegration Vec- Statistics. Oxford Bull. Econ. Stat. 54(August
tors. J. Econ. Dyn. Control 12(June/Septem- 1992) :46172.
ber 1988) :23154. Pesaran M.H., and Y. Shin. Cointegration and
Li, J.R., and C.B. Barrett, Distinguishing Between Speed of Convergence to Equilibrium.
Equilibrium and Integration in Market Anal- J. Econometrics, 71(March 1996) :11743.
ysis. Unpublished, June 1999. Phillips, P.C.B. Optimal Inference in Cointe-
MacKinnon, J.G., A.A. Haug, and L. Michelis. grated Systems, Econometrica, 59(March
Numerical Distribution Functions of Likeli- 1991) :283306.
Ravallion, M. Testing Market Integration, Amer.

Downloaded from http://ajae.oxfordjournals.org/ at Niedersaechsische Staats- und Universitaetsbibliothek Goettingen on June 5, 2015
hood Ratio Tests for Cointegration. Work-
ing paper, Department of Economics, Queens J. Agr. Econ. 68(February 1986) :1029.
University, 1996. Sexton, R.J., C.L. King, and H.F. Carman. Mar-
ket Integration, Efciency of Arbitrage, and
McNew K., and P.L. Fackler. Testing Mar-
Imperfect Competition: Methodology and
ket Equilibrium: Is Cointegration Informa-
Application to U.S. Celery. Amer. J. Agr.
tive? J. Agr. Res. Econ. 22(December 1997) :
Econ. 73(August 1991) :56880.
191207.
Shively, G.E. Food Price Variability and Eco-
Osterwald-Lenum, M. A Note with Fractiles of nomic Reform: An ARCH Approach for
the Asymptotic Distribution of the Maxi- Ghana. Amer. J. Agr. Econ. 78(February
mum Likelihood Cointegration Rank Test 1996) :12636.

You might also like