You are on page 1of 17

How do banks make money?

A variety of business strategies

Robert DeYoung and Tara Rice

Introduction and summary none of these assumptions are accurate. Moreover,


Banks make money many different ways. Some banks failing to recognize this can result in a misleading
employ traditional banking strategies, attracting house- analysis of bank performance.
hold deposits in exchange for interest payments and This is the second of two companion pieces on
transaction services and earning a profit by lending How do banks make money? appearing in this issue
those funds to business customers at higher interest of Economic Perspectives. In the first article, we fo-
rates. Other banks employ nontraditional strategies, cus on the remarkable increase in noninterest income
such as credit card banks or mortgage banks that offer at U.S. commercial banks during the past two decades,
few depositor services, sell off most of their loans the regulatory and technological catalysts for this his-
soon after making them, and earn profits from the fees toric change, and how this newfound reliance on non-
they charge for originating, securitizing, and servicing interest income can affect bank performance. In this
these loans. In between these two extremes lies a article, we explain how deregulation and technologi-
continuum of traditional and nontraditional approach- cal change have encouraged U.S. commercial banks
es to bankingfocusing on local markets or serving to become less like each other in virtually all aspects
customers nationwide; catering to household custom- of their operationsincluding the generation of non-
ers or business clients; using a brick-and-mortar de- interest incomeand how the resulting divergence in
livery system or an internet delivery system; and so on. banking strategies has affected the financial performance
This panoply of business strategies is a relatively of these companies. We define a variety of banking
new development in the U.S. banking industry, made business strategies based on differences in product mix,
possible by deregulation, advances in information tech- funding sources, geographic focus, production tech-
nology, and new financial processes. To date, academ- niques, and other dimensions, and examine the finan-
ic economists have performed very little systematic cial performance of established U.S. banking companies
analysis of the relative profitability, riskiness, or long- that used these strategies from 1993 through 2003. While
run viability of these different banking business models. we recognize that bank size can have implications for
Academic studies of bank performance tend to focus strategic choice and financial performance, we do not
on issues of regulatory concern (for example, capital use bank size to define any of the strategy groups.
adequacy, bank insolvency) or investor concern (for We draw a number of conclusions about how
example, the reaction of bank stock prices to bank banks make money and how this may matter for the
mergers) rather than broader questions of competitive future of the banking industry. First, we find substan-
strategy. Moreover, many so-called studies of banking tial differences in profitability and risk across the
business strategies focus myopically on banking com- various banking strategy groups. Importantly, low
pany size. Although banks of different sizes often do profitability does not necessarily doom a banking
different things in different ways, size is a poor proxy
for strategy: It assumes that the banking strategy space Robert DeYoung is a senior economist and economic
has only one dimension; it assumes that a banks size advisor and Tara Rice is an economist in the Economic
Research Department of the Federal Reserve Bank of
always constrains its choice of a business model; and Chicago. The authors thank Carrie Jankowski and Ian
it assumes that two banks of the same size always use Dew-Becker for excellent research assistance and Rich
the same strategy. As we demonstrate in this article, Rosen for helpful comments.

52 4Q/2004, Economic Perspectives


FIGURE 1 underpinnings of our financial system,
A strategic map of the banking industry
which we address in detail in the two sec-
tions that follow.
hard INFORMATION QUALITY soft DeYoung, Hunter, and Udell (2004)
small high argue that two generic banking strategies
have emerged from the fog of deregula-
tion and technological change. This is il-
lustrated in figure 1, which describes the
strategic aftermath of deregulation and
UNIT
technological change using four parame-
SIZE
COSTS ters: bank size, bank unit costs, product
differentiation, and information quality.
The vertical dimension in the map mea-
sures bank size, with large banks at the
large low
bottom and small banks at the top. Large
size allows banks to achieve low unit costs
standardized PRODUCT DIFFERENTIATION personalized through scale economies. The horizontal
dimension measures the degree to which
Source: DeYoung, Hunter, and Udell (2004).
banks differentiate their products and ser-
vices from those of their competitors. To
provide personalized financial services,
strategy. High average return strategies like corporate banks must have non-quantifiable, or soft, informa-
banking tend to generate high amounts of risk, while tion about their customers. In this framework, banks
low average return strategies like community banking select their business strategies by combining a high
tend to generate less risk; thus, on a risk-adjusted basis, or low level of unit costs with a high or low degree
both high-return and low-return strategies may be fi- of product differentiation. The positions of the circles
nancially viable. Second, we find that very small banks indicate the business strategies selected by banks and
operate at a financial disadvantage regardless of their the relative sizes of the circles indicate the relative
competitive strategy. This suggests that the number of sizes of the banks.
very small U.S. banking companies is likely to continue The first of these two generic strategies, repre-
to decline in the future. However, our analysis suggests sented by the small bubbles in the upper right-hand
that the business strategies typically associated with corner of the map, is a traditional banking strategy.
small banks are financially viable when practiced by Small banks operating in local markets develop close
larger-than-average small banks, and we stress that relationships with their customers, provide value to
under some circumstances even very small banking depositors through person-to-person contact at branch
companies can succeed. Third, we find some evidence offices, and make relationship loans to information-
that banking companies without discernable competi- ally opaque borrowers (for example, small businesses)
tive strategies tend to perform poorly, as do banks that that do not have direct access to financial markets.
employ traditional banking strategies without embracing Although these locally focused banks operate with
efficient new production methods. Both of these find- relatively high unit costs, they can potentially earn
ings are consistent with fundamental precepts of high interest margins: They pay low interest rates to
good strategic management. a loyal base of core depositors and they charge high
Banks have become less alike interest rates to borrowers over which they have mar-
ket power due to information-based switching costs.
Prior to the 1990s, banking companies in the U.S. These banks earn fee income mainly through service
were relatively (though not completely) homogeneous. charges on their deposit accounts.
In contrast, todays commercial banking companies The second of these two generic strategies, rep-
are substantially different from each other in terms resented by the large bubbles in the lower left-hand
of size, geographic scope, organizational structure, corner of the map, is a nontraditional banking strategy.
product mix, funding sources, service quality, and cus- Large banks take advantage of economies of scale in
tomer focus. This strategic diversity is a byproduct of the production, marketing, securitization, and servic-
two decades of deregulation and technological change ing of transaction loans like credit cards and home
dramatically disruptive changes in the structural mortgages. These banks operate with low unit costs,

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago 53


but they tend to earn low interest margins FIGURE 2
because the loans they produce are essen- Noninterest income to assets
tially financial commodities that are sold
in highly competitive markets. Large percent
amounts of noninterest income (for exam- 3.5
ple, fees from loan origination, securitiza-
3.0
tion, and servicing) are essential for this
model to be profitable. Note that this ap- 2.5
proach to commercial banking became
possible only after geographic deregula- 2.0
tion allowed banks to achieve larger scale
1.5
and after new technologies (for example,
credit scoring models, asset securitiza- 1.0
tion) permitted banks and other financial
0.5
institutions to create transaction loans.
It is important to observe that the 0.0
highly stylized banking strategies por- 1986 90 95 2000 03
trayed in figure 1 are characterized not
just by differences in bank size, but more < $100 million $1$10 billion
fundamentally by differences in customer $100 million$1 billion >$10 billion
preferences, information quality, pricing
structures, and production techniques. As
such, this analysis implies that there is a
rich diversity of potentially profitable business strate- displacement to the left, indicating that transaction
gies for serving retail and commercial banking cus- deposits have become a less important funding source
tomers. More fundamentally, it implies that the for many banking companies. On the other hand, the
banking companies pursuing those strategies should stable right-hand side of the distribution indicates
have grown less like each other than in the past. that transaction deposits have remained a core source
Indeed, there is evidence that they have. Figures 2 of funding for many other commercial banks. Again,
and 3 illustrate two of the dimensions across which this is consistent with the strategic dichotomy illus-
U.S. banking companies have become less alike since trated in figure 1.
1986. (The data used to construct these figures are Although some of the growing dissimilarities
described in the previous article. See table 2 of that across banking companies are clearly associated with
article and the associated text.) growing differences in bank size, there are rich stra-
Figure 2 shows that the intensity of noninterest tegic differences across commercial banking compa-
income at banking companies of different sizesvery nies that have little to do with size. As we show later
small (with inflation-adjusted assets less than $100 in this article, these strategic differences lead to sub-
million), small ($100 million to $1 billion), mid-sized stantial heterogeneity in the financial performance of
($1 billion to $10 billion), and large (greater than $10 banking companies. But before we get to that analysis,
billion)has systematically diverged over the past we need to review the fundamental changes to the
two decades. Noninterest income has become more banking environment that allowed banking companies
important on average for banks of all four sizes; how- to grow so dissimilar in the first place.
ever, it has increased by only about 25 percent for the
smallest banking companies while more than doubling Deregulation and banking business
for the largest banking companies. These trends are strategies
consistent with the emergence of the strategic dichot- Over the past 25 years, U.S. commercial banking
omy depicted in figure 1. has been transformed from a heavily regulated indus-
Banks have also grown less alike in the way they try, in which banks were prohibited from competing
fund their loans and other investments. Figure 3 dis- with each other, to a largely deregulated industry, in
plays the distribution of transaction deposits to assets which commercial banks compete vigorously among
for banking companies in 1986 and 2003.1 This distri- themselves, as well as with investment banks, securi-
bution has flattened out over time, but not symmetri- ties firms, and insurance companies. This historic in-
cally. On the one hand, there has been a considerable dustry deregulation, in conjunction with dramatic

54 4Q/2004, Economic Perspectives


FIGURE 3
Divergence in transactions deposits to assets,
histogram for 1986 and 2003
percent of banks
7

1986

5 2003

0
0 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9
transaction deposits to assets

advances in banking technology, laid the groundwork on geographic and product market expansion in the
for new business strategies at commercial banks. years prior to deregulation, and these commentators
Deregulation has transformed almost every facet argue that deregulation was the optimal government
of the banking industry. It has been pro-competitive response because the relative cost of maintaining the
by allowing banks to expand into neighboring cities restrictions to one interest group (for example, large
and states, to offer financial products and services that banking companies) had became less than the rela-
had previously been reserved for non-bank financial tive benefit of maintaining the restrictions to other
institutions, and to set deposit interest rates according interest groups (for example, small local banks that
to market forces. Deregulation has been pro-efficien- had been protected from competition).
cy: It encouraged scale economies by allowing banks Deregulation has been a continuous and ongoing
to grow larger; cost and revenue synergies by allow- process since the mid-1970s. Spong (2000) and
ing banks to broaden their product lines; and opera- DeYoung, Hunter, and Udell (2004) offer in-depth
tional efficiencies by exposing banks to increased treatments of the evolution of banking and financial
market competition. And deregulation has been pro- regulations over the past quarter-century and the im-
technology by allowing banking companies to attain pact of those changes on the structure, strategies, and
the large size necessary to fully benefit from declin- performance of commercial banks. We limit our dis-
ing cost technologies such as credit scoring and asset cussion here to just three deregulatory acts that have
securitization, to launch mass-market advertising, proven to be especially influential for the competitive
and to better reduce risk via diversification. strategies of commercial banking companies.
Kane (1996), Kroszner and Strahan (1997, 1999), The Depository Institutions Deregulation and
and others argue that it was the behavior of banking Monetary Control Act of 1980 sought to equalize the
companies themselves that brought deregulation. competitive positions of commercial banks and thrift
Banks routinely circumvented regulatory constraints institutions. Among other things, the act expanded

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago 55


the lending powers of thrift institutions to better match Act gave banking companies the freedom to enter new
those of commercial banks; increased deposit insur- states either by purchasing existing banking franchis-
ance coverage to $100,000 for all insured depository es or by opening new branches and allowed multi-
institutions; authorized new products such as NOW bank holding companies to consolidate their separate
(negotiable order of withdrawal) accounts nationwide; banking affiliates into systems of branch offices.
and required the Federal Reserve to price its financial These changes had their most visible impact on
services (for example, check clearing) and make those the structure of the banking system. A wave of inter-
services, as well as the discount window, available for state mergers and acquisitions has created a handful
all commercial banks and thrifts. But for commercial of nearly nationwide banking companies (for exam-
banking strategies, the most fundamental and far-reach- ple, Bank of America, Citibank, J. P. MorganChase),
ing consequence of this act was the six-year phase out as well as a second tier of superregional banking
of Regulation Q. companies (for example, Wells Fargo, Fifth Third,
Since the 1930s, Regulation Q had limited the Wachovia), most of which exceed the size of the
interest rates that banks could pay their customers on largest pre-RiegleNeal banking companies. This geo-
time and savings deposits. Whenever competition for graphic expansion has, in turn, provided new oppor-
deposits increasedfor example, if a new deposit- tunities for both large and small banking companies
taking institution entered the local market or if alter- to improve their operational efficiency. Duplicative
native investment vehicles became more attractive back office systems (such as payroll and accounting)
than bank depositsbanks could not respond by pay- and organizational expenditures (separate boards of
ing higher rates to their depositors. Instead, banks directors, bank examinations, and so on) could be
compensated depositors for below-market interest eliminated by consolidating individual banks into net-
rates by giving them a bundle of related services works of branches. Automated, information-intensive
(for example, check printing, safety deposit boxes, applications like credit scoring and asset securitization
travelers checks) free of charge. This situation was became more cost effective as business volume in-
extremely inefficientbanks could, at best, only re- creased. Entry by large, out-of-state banking companies
spond crudely to changes in deposit market conditions has increased competitive rivalry in local banking mar-
and, in a world of bundled pricing, banks had little kets and created incentives for increased efficiency at
incentive to develop innovative deposit services for local banks (DeYoung, Hasan, and Kirchhoff, 1998).
which they could charge customers. But the economies made possible by increased
Since the phase-out of Regulation Q, banks have bank size can come at a cost, especially for large re-
gradually reduced bundled pricing in favor of charging tail banks. For example, automated credit card lend-
explicit fees for individual retail deposit products and ing and online bill-paying are low-cost ways to produce
adjusting deposit interest rates up and down to reflect large volumes of traditional banking services, but
market conditions. Free to charge explicit fees for these processes have changed the nature of retail
depositor services, banks had greater incentives to banking from a high-touch, relationship-based service
offer new deposit-related products such as money-mar- to an arms-length, financial commodity business.
ket mutual funds, online bill pay, and overdraft protec- DeYoung, Hunter, and Udell (2004) argue that this
tion. Free to pay market rates for deposits, efficiently change has had a profound influence on the business
run banks that could use deposits the most productive- strategies of large banking companies: Because com-
ly became able to bid those funds away from less ef- modities do not command high margins, large banking
ficient banks. companies may come to rely on marketing and the
The RiegleNeal Act of 1994 eliminated nearly creation of brand images to support prices (much like
all barriers to the geographic expansion of banking other large consumer product companies). And al-
companies across state boundaries. This federal mea- though geographic deregulation has put community
sure put the finishing touch on over 20 years of piece- banks at a cost disadvantage relative to large banking
meal deregulation by the states, which began in the companies, the small size of community banks can
mid-1970s with the removal of existing restrictions work to their strategic advantage by allowing them to
on in-state branching in a handful of individual states provide the personal service for which deposit custom-
and culminated with a number of multi-state compacts ers are willing to pay higher prices (or accept lower
that allowed banking companies to own and operate interest rates) and for which small business custom-
affiliates in other states. By sweeping away most fed- ers are willing to pay higher interest rates.
eral restrictions and remaining state restrictions on The GrammLeachBliley Act of 1999 expanded
interstate banking and branching, the RiegleNeal the permissible activities of commercial banking

56 4Q/2004, Economic Perspectives


companies. Formally, GrammLeachBliley (GLB) and their nonbank rivals have become continuous in-
repealed sections 20 and 32 of the GlassSteagall Act novators, forever attempting to improve and expand
of 1933, a Depression-era law that effectively pro- the number and variety of financial products and ser-
hibited commercial banks from engaging in investment vices that they offer.
banking activities. In practice, GLB allows well-run To be sure, technological change would have oc-
commercial bank holding companies to engage in se- curred in the banking industry even in the absence of
curities underwriting, securities brokerage, mutual deregulation. But deregulation sped the application
fund services, financial advisement, and related activi- of new technologies by allowing banks to achieve the
ties without limitation, so long as these activities are scale necessary to use new technologies efficiently and,
conducted in a separate affiliate of the holding com- by enhancing competition, deregulation provided banks
pany. For well-run banks with federal charters, GLB with incentives to adopt and adapt these new technolo-
permits separately capitalized financial subsidiaries. gies. As discussed above, this process also worked in
Similar to the RiegleNeal Act, GLB was preced- the opposite direction, with technological advance
ed by a series of regulatory rulings during the 1990s speeding the progress of deregulation. As new technolo-
that incrementally relaxed restrictions on banking gies increased the efficiency of large-scale banking
powers. For example, the Office of the Comptroller and created synergies between traditional and nontra-
of the Currency granted national banks to power to ditional banking products, the industry and its advo-
sell insurance from offices in small towns, and the cates were able to bring pressure to break down the
Federal Reserve partially relaxed the limitations on barriers to geographic expansion. This included bold
the amount of revenue a banking company could gen- circumvention of existing legal constraints on geographic
erate in its Section 20 securities subsidiaries. But the and product market expansion, the most famous of
new product powers granted by GLB made a bigger which was the 1998 merger of banking giant Citibank
difference by completely relaxing the restrictions on with insurance giant Travelers, more than a year before
the permissible volumes of nonbanking activities and the passage of the GrammLeachBliley Act in 1999.
by allowing commercial banks to engage in complete- Technological changes in the banking industry can
ly new activities such as merchant banking. be roughly separated into two categories: improvements
Some commercial banks now provide one-stop- in data processing and communications technologies and
shopping for the typical retail customer, including the emergence of entirely new financial instruments,
mortgage loans, credit cards, checking accounts, in- markets, and production processes. The former has
vestment products and advice, and insurance products. allowed financial information to flow more quickly,
Similarly, some commercial banks now offer a full accurately, and cheaply; the latter largely reflects the
range of financing options to their corporate custom- manner in which banking companies and their competi-
ers, including loans, debt underwriting, and stock un- tors have exploited these new information flows. To-
derwriting. In either case, GLB allows commercial gether, these phenomena have played key roles in the
banks to expand their traditional banking business evolution of bank business strategies and the ways that
into less traditional financial service areas by lever- banks make money. We offer three examples here.
aging their existing distribution networks as well as
the proprietary information they have gleaned over Payment services
the years about their retail and corporate customers. Faster information flows have transformed the
manner in which banks provide payment services to
Technological innovation and banking their customers. The development and expansion of
business strategies electronic payment channels and instruments have
Financial services is among the industries that permitted banks to offer their deposit customers un-
have been most transformed by technological change. precedented levels of convenience, often at lower
Advances in information flows, communications in- costs. For example, today about 34 percent of house-
frastructure, and financial markets have dramatically hold payments are made using electronic channels
altered the way in which banks assess the creditworthi- like debit cards, credit cards, and automated bill pay;
ness of their loan customers, service their deposit cus- as recently as 1990 only about 15 percent of house-
tomers, process payments, and produce and distribute hold transactions were electronic, with the remaining
nearly all of their other products and services. Coupled 85 percent made with cash and checks (HSN Consult-
with the effects of industry deregulation, technologi- ants, Inc., 2002).
cal advances have led to substantially increased com- The reduction in use of the physical paycheck is
petition in the financial marketplace as both banks testimony to the important role of transactions made

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago 57


through the Automated Clearing House (ACH). ACH has changed, in some cases dramatically, the roles
not only makes direct deposit of household wages that banks play in credit markets.
possible, but it facilitates automated online bill pay On the consumer lending side, the advent of credit
for households and businesses, in addition to other scoring models that use hard (that is, quantifiable)
recurring transactions. Retail business customers information to evaluate creditworthiness, together
benefit from electronic lockbox services and check with the development of secondary markets for secu-
truncation, and the recently passed Check 21 legisla- ritized loans, has changed the way that banks and
tion will accelerate these changes in our financial in- other financial institutions provide credit to households
frastructure by requiring banks to accept substitute (Stein, 2002). Instead of earning interest margins from
checks, which can be transmitted as electronic images. holding mortgage, auto, or credit card loans in their
And for those who wish to make old-fashioned cash loan portfolios, banks can earn separate fees for orig-
transactions, financial information that flows through inating the loans, securitizing the loans, and servic-
ATM (automated teller machine) networks has made ing the loans, while the interest income flows to the
access to cash more convenient, while generating fee investors that purchase the securities backed by these
income for banks and creating an entirely new finan- loans. New financial institutionssuch as brokers
cial service sector for nonbank owners of ATMs. that originate and immediately securitize home mort-
gages and monoline credit card and finance companies
Online brokerage that take advantage of huge scale economies in the
A more specialized application of financial infor- production, distribution, and servicing of consumer
mation technology is online discount brokerage. On- credithave emerged to service much of the market
line brokerage of any sort was obviously not possible share in consumer credit that traditionally belonged
prior to the invention of the internet, and the discount to depository institutions like banks.
brokerage model fits well with this distribution channel. On the business lending side, the introduction of
This application reduces production costs two differ- high-yield (junk) bonds, increased access to com-
ent ways: potential scale economies from operating mercial paper, and other financial market developments
on a nationwide basis and potential reductions in over- have allowed large commercial borrowers to bypass
head expenses by targeting do-it-yourself customers. banks in favor of direct finance. While commercial
(For these customers, less personal service ironically banks have lost considerable market share in com-
translates into greater convenience.) Because this prod- mercial lending, one way that they continue to play a
uct is offered in a very competitive marketplace, on- role in commercial finance is by charging a fee in ex-
line discount brokerage firms like Charles Schwab and change for providing the back-up lines of credit that
E*Trade must pass a large portion of these savings on firms need to float commercial paper. In this new tech-
to their customers in the form of lower transaction fees. nological environment, loans to small and moderate-
Along with other changes in the retail financial sized businesses based on private, information-rich
landscapelike the widespread adoption of mutual relationships between business people and their com-
fund investing and the shift to defined contribution mercial bankers stand out as one of the last types of
pension plansthe emergence of discount brokerage loans that are still produced in the traditional inter-
firms has increased the competition for household mediation fashion.
savings and investments. In response, most large re-
tail banks now offer some version of online brokerage Business strategies at banking companies
to help retain retail depositors. A simple and often-employed method for com-
Intermediation paring the performance of different banking strategies
Banks have traditionally earned most of their prof- is to separate banking companies by size. As we have
its by intermediating between parties that have excess seen, scale is clearly important: The scale of a large
liquidity (depositors) and parties that need additional banking company gives it access to low-unit-cost mar-
liquidity (borrowers). For a variety of reasons, banks keting and production techniques, while the scale of
historically have been better than other institutions at a small banking company allows it to build person-
mitigating the informational asymmetries and other lo- to-person relationships with its customers. But econ-
gistical problems that prevent direct finance between these omies of scale is not the only dimension across which
parties.2 But advances in information processing and banking companies vary strategically. Moreover, we
financial markets have greatly reduced banks compara- assume that achieving a large scale, a medium scale,
tive advantages, and the resulting disintermediation or a small scale is not the main objective of a banking

58 4Q/2004, Economic Perspectives


company; rather, it is to earn a rate of return commen- The eight business strategies are not meant to be
surate with the risk to which owners of the bank are fully exhaustive of all the competitive strategies being
exposed. In pursuit of high risk-adjusted earnings, used by banking companies today. Moreover, we de-
banking companies choose from among many bank- fined the strategy groups tightly: Over half (758 out
ing strategies, some of which can be practiced by of 1,281) of the eligible banking companies were not
small banks as well as large banks. assigned to any strategy group. Although we did not
For the purposes of this study, we define eight design the strategy groups to be mutually exclusive,
distinct banking business strategies based on differ- only about 10 percent (123) of the 1,281 banking com-
ences in product mix, location, production techniques, panies fell into more than a single group; of these,
and other characteristics across U.S. banking compa- just 28 banking companies were assigned to three or
nies: traditional banking, nontraditional banking, pri- more strategy groups, and just two banking compa-
vate banking, agricultural banking, corporate banking, nies were assigned to four strategy groups.
local community focus, payment transactions, and a The traditional banking group contains 117 bank-
diversified banking strategy. The procedures we use ing companies; 2003 assets averaged about $242 mil-
to define these strategy groups, and to assign banking lion and ranged from $10 million to $1.7 billion. To
companies to these groups, are presented below and be included in this strategy group, banking companies
are not highly scientific. We used our informed judg- had to be portfolio lenders that did not securitize any
ment to select a short list of characteristics that one assets in either 1993 or 2003, and their ratios of core
would expect to find at banks that used each of these deposits to assets, loans to assets, and net interest in-
business strategies and we set arbitrary numerical come to operating income all had to rank higher than
thresholds for each of those characteristics above or the 25th percentile among our sample of 1,281 bank-
below which banking companies would be included ing companies in both 1993 and 2003.
in, or excluded from, each strategy group. It is impor- The nontraditional banking group contains 29
tant to note that we did not use bank size to define any banking companies; 2003 assets averaged about $140
of these eight strategy groups and, as a result, each billion and ranged from $590 million to $771 billion.
strategy group includes banking companies of differ- To be included in this strategy group, banking com-
ent sizes. (For comparative purposes, we also define panies had to securitize at least some assets in both
a number of groups based purely on bank size and 1993 and 2003; rank lower than the 25th percentile
bank growth rates.) in our sample in terms of both deposits to assets and
Banking companies were eligible for assignment net interest income to operating income; and rank
to one or more of these strategy groups if they were above the 75th percentile in terms of the asset value
at least ten years old in 1993,3 were still operating in of letters of credit issued to assets. This group includes
2003, were domestically owned, and had positive many of the nationally recognized commercial bank-
amounts of loans, transaction deposits, deposits in- ing companies (for example, Bank of America, J. P.
sured by the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation MorganChase, Wachovia, Wells Fargo), as well as a
(FDIC), and equity capital in both 1993 and 2003. number of superregional (for example, Fifth Third,
A total of 1,281 banking companies met these eligi- National City, Suntrust) and regional commercial
bility conditions. We selected the 19932003 period banks (for example, First Tennessee, Marshall &
because it began after the passage of the Federal Ilsley, Regions Financial).
Deposit Insurance Corporation Improvement Act The private banking group contains 11 banking
(FDICIA) of 1991 and because it was long enough companies; 2003 assets averaged about $25 billion
to adequately observe the variability of banking com- and ranged from $550 million to $92 billion. To be
pany returns over an entire business cycle. We drew included in this strategy group, banking companies
the data for our analysis chiefly from the Reports of had to rank above the 99th percentile in terms of fi-
Condition and Income (call reports), Federal Reserve duciary income to operating income in 1993 and 2003.
Board FR Y-9C reports, the Federal Reserve Board Some of the better known companies in this group
National Information Centers (NIC) structure data- are Northern Trust, State Street, Bank of New York,
base, the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporations and Mellon Financial.
Summary of Deposits database, and the Center for The agricultural banking group contains 96 bank-
Research on Stock Prices (CRSP) database. We ex- ing companies; 2003 assets averaged $108 million and
press all data in thousands of year 2003 dollars, un- ranged from $4 million to $1.2 billion. To be included
less otherwise indicated. in this strategy group, banking companies had to rank

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago 59


above the top 90th percentile in terms of agricultural to total loans and below the 90th percentile in agri-
production loans to total loans in both 1993 and 2003. cultural production loans to total loans, in both years.
The corporate banking group contains 14 banking In addition to these eight largely activities-based
companies; 2003 assets averaged about $74 billion strategy groups, we defined five purely size-based strate-
and ranged from $729 million to $327 billion. To be gy groups: assets less than $100 million (541 banks);
included in this strategy group, investment banking assets between $100 million and $500 million (303
activities had to generate at least 1 percent of a banks banks); assets between $500 million and $1 billion
operating income in 2003; the bank had to rank above (59 banks); assets between $1 billion and $10 billion
the 75th percentile in commercial loans to total loans (89 banks); and assets greater than $10 billion (29
in both 1993 and 2003; and the bank had to rank above banks). We applied these size thresholds to the assets
the 50th percentile of the sample in terms of demand of each banking company twice: In 2003 we applied
deposits to total deposits and the asset value of letters them to actual 2003 asset values, and in 1993 we ap-
of credit issued to assets in both 1993 and 2003. Some plied them to 1993 asset values that had been adjust-
of the companies included in this group are Bank One ed upward to account for industry asset growth and
(before its acquisition by J. P. MorganChase), Com- inflation between 1993 and 2003. We also defined
merce Bancshares, FleetBoston (before its acquisi- two strategy groups based on the asset growth rates.
tion by Bank of America), Huntington Bancshares, The geographic deregulation of U.S. banking markets
Mellon Financial, PNC Financial, and U.S. Bancorp. in the late 1980s and 1990s created unparalleled op-
The community focus group contains 151 banking portunities for U.S. banking companies to grow, ei-
companies; 2003 assets averaged about $268 million ther by making acquisitions or by growing internally.
and ranged from $8 million to $4.1 billion. Companies The mergers (external growth) group contains 17
in this strategy group generated at least half of their banking companies, with 2003 assets averaging $143
deposits from a one-county area and ranked above the billion in a range from $514 million to $771 billion.
50th percentile in core deposits to assets and loans to These banking companies grew at an inflation-adjusted
assets, in both 1993 and 2003. rate of 250 percent or more between 1993 and 2003,
The transaction services group contains 96 banking and at least 25 percent of this increased size was at-
companies; 2003 assets averaged about $1.6 billion tributable to assets acquired in mergers. The growers
and ranged from $8 million to $46 billion. Banking (internal growth) group contains 85 banking compa-
companies in this strategy group ranked above the nies, with 2003 assets averaging $2.8 billion and
top 75 percent of banking companies in terms of both ranging from $47 million to $88 billion. These bank-
payment-related income associated largely with checking ing companies grew at an inflation-adjusted rate of
transactions (service charges on deposits plus foregone 250 percent or more between 1993 and 2003 without
interest revenue on deposits) and payment-related in- making any major acquisitions.
come not necessarily associated with checking trans- Finally, we defined a no-strategy group. This
actions (estimated payment-related fees from ATM, group contains 113 banking companies that did not
fiduciary, and credit card activities) as a percentage qualify for any of the eight main strategy groups in
of operating income in 2003. both 1993 and 2003. (Note that the no-strategy group
The diversified banking group contains 97 banking does not include banking companies that switched
companies; 2003 assets averaged about $1.6 billion strategies, that is, banks that qualified for one of the
and ranged from $160 million to $26 billion. This eight main strategy groups in 1993 and qualified for
strategy group includes banking companies that do a different strategy group in 2003. The financial per-
not specialize in any of the areas described above but formance of these banks would likely have been im-
participate to at least some extent in each of those areas. pacted by the costs of transitioning from one
To be included in this strategy group, banks had to business strategy to another.)
rank between the 10th and 90th percentiles among the
1,281 eligible banks in terms of service charges to Financial performance of different
assets, other (non-service charge) noninterest income business strategies
to assets, net interest income to assets, home mortgage We used quarterly accounting data to calculate
loans to total loans, commercial real estate loans to three financial performance measures for each of the
total loans, and consumer loans to total loans in both 1,281 banking companies in our 19932003 dataset:
1993 and 2003. Moreover, these banks had to rank The profitability of each bank is the annualized aver-
above the 90th percentile in terms of commercial loans age return on equity (ROE) over the 44 quarters from
1993 through 2003. The riskiness of each bank is the

60 4Q/2004, Economic Perspectives


annualized standard deviation of quarterly ROE over TABLE 1
that period. The risk-adjusted return of each bank, also Accounting-based and market-based financial
known as the Sharpe ratio, is the annualized quarter- performance measures
ly ROE minus the annualized interest rate on 90-day
Treasury bills, divided by the annualized standard Quarterly Weekly stock
accounting ROE market returns
deviation of quarterly ROE.4 In addition, for the 157 1,281 companies 157 companies
banking companies in our dataset that were publicly mean (standard deviation)
traded, we used weekly stock prices to calculate mar-
Return 0.1199 0.1726
ket-based analogs of these three financial performance
(0.0785) (0.0708)
measures.
Table 1 displays summary statistics (means and Risk 0.0337 0.2813
standard deviations) for all of our performance mea- (0.0413) (0.0721)
sures. We note that our performance measures are Risk-adjusted 4.0646 0.4636
observed ex postthat is, they reflect actual rather return (3.5873) (0.2094)
than expected revenues and expensesand as such Notes: ROE is return on equity. Performance measures are observed
they are just proxies for investors expectations of fu- ex post. Banking companies that were acquired or failed are not
included. Measures are not comparable across columns.
ture returns, upon which finance theory is based. We
also note that our dataset excludes banking compa-
nies that were acquired or failed between 1993 and with the fundamental principle of finance that markets
2003, and as a result the performance measures for reward risk-taking with higher returns, but that the
the surviving companies that populate our dataset returns to risk-taking are diminishing. (This arc is not
may be biased. For example, banks that practice es- a representation of the efficient risk-return frontier,
pecially risky strategies will be more likely to fail, all because we have plotted it based on the average risks
else being equal, so the average ROE for a high-risk and average returns of the banks in each strategy
strategy group may be biased upward. group.)6 Moving from left to right on the graphfrom
The quarterly accounting-based returns exhibit low-risklow-return strategies to higher-riskhigher-
considerably less variation over timeand as a re- return strategiesthese strategy groups line up in an
sult, substantially higher risk-adjusted profitsthan economically sensible order. Not surprisingly, the di-
the weekly stock market returns. This difference is versified strategy has the lowest (ex post) risk position.
likely due to three factors: accounting conventions The corporate, nontraditional, and private banking
that affect the valuation of assets and the way that groups come next, with increasingly higher levels of
expenditures are recognized over time; changes in risk (and associated higher returns) that are roughly
relevant information and investor expectations that consistent with the increasing reliance of the banks
are priced by the stock market but not included in in these groups on noninterest income (DeYoung and
backward-looking accounting statements; and the Roland, 2001).
different frequencies over which we observe the ac- The highest risks and the highest returns, on aver-
counting data and the market data (quarters versus age, are generated by banking companies that grew
weeks).5 Also note that the accounting-based returns quickly during the sample period by either external
are substantially lower on average than the stock means (the mergers group) or internal means (the
market-based returns. The most likely explanation is growers group). For the merging banks, accounting
that publicly traded companies with low returns are earnings are likely to be volatile because of accounting
likely to become takeover targets and drop out of our charges taken during the post-merger transition peri-
sample, while closely held private companies (often od. For the growing banks, this volatility is likely re-
small banks) with low returns are more likely to con- lated to several different phenomena: the temporary
tinue to operate independently. excess capacity in physical plant necessary to grow a
Accounting-based financial performance bank by opening new branch locations; a slippage in
Figure 4 plots the average accounting-based re- credit quality that often occurs when banks attempt
turn and risk measures for each of the strategy groups. to grow their loan portfolios quickly; and the purchase
These average risk-return profiles fall into two clus- of expensive time deposit funding to which these banks
ters. One cluster of strategies (diversified, corporate, often must resort to finance fast asset growth. The
nontraditional, private banking, mergers, and growers) high accounting earnings also have a number of
forms an arc of riskreturn combinations consistent plausible explanations. On the one hand, profitable

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago 61


FIGURE 4 of our five purely sized-based groups. As
Average book returns and risk for strategy groups
shown in figure 5, for banking companies
with assets less than $500 million in-
return (mean ROE) creased size unambiguously improves (ex
0.20
post) financial performancethat is, re-
turns increase without having to accept
0.16 more riskwhile for banking companies
larger than $500 million increased returns
0.12 are attainable on average only by accept-
ing increased risk. This crude analysis is
consistent with several findings in the
0.08
bank scale economy literature. In general,
this literature finds that even relatively
0.04 large banking companies can expect to re-
duce per-unit costs by growing larger.
0.00 Berger, Demsetz, and Strahan (1999) pro-
0 0.01 0.02 0.03 0.04 0.05 0.06 vide a relatively recent review of this lit-
risk (standard deviation of ROE) erature. However, Evanoff and Israilevich
nontraditional mergers traditional community (1991) and Berger and Humphrey (1991)
private growers agricultural transactions demonstrated that the bulk of these per-
diversified corporate no strategy unit cost improvements are captured at
relatively small bank sizethat is, aver-
age costs decrease with bank size but at a
banks are better able to generate the large amounts of rapidly diminishing rate. Other studies have found
internal funds to make the repeated purchases or in- that banking companies that grow larger tend to take
vestments necessary to expand rapidly. On the other on increased risk (for example, Demsetz and Strahan,
hand, the data simply may indicate that merger-based 1997; Hughes, Lang, Mester, and Moon, 1996), con-
and growth-based strategies tended to pay off during sistent with the patterns for the larger banking com-
the 1990s (Calomiris and Karceski, 1998). Finally, panies in figure 5.
the returns for the high-risk growers strategy may be Although this demonstration of the riskreturn
biased upward to the extent that unsuccessful fast- effects of increased banking company scale is admit-
growing banks that failed are not in our dataset. tedly crude, applying these findings to our analysis
A second cluster of strategies (traditional, com- produces stark and economically sensible results. In
munity focus, transactions, agricultural, and no strat- figure 6 we re-plot the average risk profiles of the
egy) lies well below the risk-return arc. The returns banking strategy groups after removing companies
generated by the banks using these strategies do not with assets less than $500 million. The result is a rel-
appear to be high enough to compensate bank own- atively smooth arrangement of the strategy groups
ers for the risks they are takingin other words, the along the original riskreturn arc from figure 4. (The
data suggest that these are not economically viable average riskreturn tradeoff between these strategy
banking strategies, and these strategies and the bank- groups is illustrated by a quadratic ordinary least
ing companies that use them could disappear from squares trend line estimated for the 11 data points
the banking industry sometime in the future. But be- shown in the figure. Again, we note that this line is
fore writing off these banking strategies, we note that based on average financial performance, and is not an
there is a substantial size disparity between the two efficient riskreturn frontier.) The community focus,
clusters of banking companies: Those on the riskre- agricultural, and transactions strategy groups are now
turn arc tend to contain larger banks, while those in located on the imaginary riskreturn arc and exhibit
the lower cluster tend to contain small banks. Is the the relatively low levels of risk that are consistent
poor average financial performance of the banks in with business models that rely on close customer re-
the second cluster of strategy groups attributable to lationships.
untenable banking strategies, inefficiently small bank Although the riskreturn profiles of the traditional
size, or a combination of both? and no-strategy groups also improved after adjusting
To investigate this possibility, we plotted the aver- for scale effects, these two groups still fall somewhat
age accounting-based return and risk measures for each short of the other strategy groups. For the no-strategy

62 4Q/2004, Economic Perspectives


FIGURE 5 ratios ranging from 6.0 to 6.7 on average.
Average book returns and risk for size groups
We discussed the potential shortcomings
of the traditional strategy and the no-strat-
return (ROE) egy groups above. The relatively poor
0.25
performance of the private banking strate-
gy group is likely explained by the large
0.20 fluctuations in the stock market during the
latter half of our sample period, while the
0.15 small number (five) of agricultural banks
in this analysis makes the poor average
performance of this group difficult to in-
0.10
terpret. The third subgroup includes the
community, corporate, mergers, diversi-
0.05 fied, transactions, and nontraditional strat-
egy groups, with Sharpe ratios ranging
0.00 from 7.3 percent to 8.1 on average. The
0 0.01 0.02 0.03 0.04 0.05 relatively good riskreturn performance
risk (standard deviation of ROE) of these six strategies is instructive: These
strategy groups are very different in terms
< $100 million $500 million$1 billion > $10 billion
of product mix, customer focus, produc-
$150500 million $110 billion tion processes, funding sources, and com-
pany size. Thus, the data in table 2
suggest that a broad range of different
types of banking strategies are financially
group, the explanation may be that firms that lack stra- viable, once banking companies have achieved at
tegic direction will naturally perform poorly (Porter, least a modicum of scale.
1980). For the traditional group, the explanation may We performed a complete set of pair-wise tests
be that recent advances in information flows, pricing to see which pairs of strategy groups had statistically
strategies, and production methods can enhance prof- different average Sharpe ratios and found only a few
itability, and banking companies that do not integrate of the pairs to be statistically different. One way to
these advances into their business model will operate interpret this result is that all of these strategic
at a disadvantage. groups can be, on average, economically viable.
However, it is more likely that the small number of
Transforming risk into return
observations in some of the strategy groups, along
Figure 6 provides reasonably compelling evi-
dence that changing strategies would require a bank-
ing company to accept more risk in exchange for
higher returns or lower returns in exchange for lower TABLE 2
risk, on average. However, the figure does not reveal Strategy groups by average accounting-based
directly whether any of these riskreturn tradeoffs Sharpe ratios
are superior to others. In table 2 we rank each of the Number Mean
strategy groups shown in figure 6 by their average risk- Rank Strategy of firms Sharpe ratio
adjusted returns, or Sharpe ratios. The Sharpe ratio 1 Nontraditional 29 8.0621
can be interpreted as a measure of how well a banking 2 Transactions 24 7.9124
company transforms risk-taking into profitability.7 3 Diversified 60 7.7869
4 Mergers 17 7.4915
This average performance measure divides the 5 Corporate 14 7.4682
strategies into three subgroups. The growers have by 6 Community 26 7.2875
far the worst Sharpe ratios, equal to just 5.3 on aver- 7 No strategy 113 6.6622
age. Despite the possible upward performance bias 8 Agricultural 5 6.4347
9 Private 11 6.3675
for this group (discussed above), banking companies 10 Traditional 17 6.0248
that experienced rapid internal growth tended to gen- 11 Growers 50 5.2830
erate low returns relative to the riskiness of this behav- Note: Calculations exclude banking companies with assets
ior. A second subgroup includes the traditional, private, greater than $500 million.

agricultural, and no-strategy banks, with Sharpe

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago 63


FIGURE 6 group once again defines the low-risk,
Average book returns and risk for strategy groups
low-return endpoint, and the growers
group once again defines the high-risk,
return (mean ROE) high-return endpoint. In between these
0.24 two endpoints, six other strategies
transactions, corporate, nontraditional,
0.20
private, mergers, and no-strategyare
arrayed in a riskreturn ordering some-
0.16
what similar to the accounting-based or-
dering plotted in figure 6. Thus, we have
0.12
some confidence that our accounting-
0.08
based risk and return measures are pro-
viding a roughly accurate ordering
0.04 of the relative risks and returns across
banking strategies.
0.00 Finally, to demonstrate the large
0 0.01 0.02 0.03 0.04 0.05 0.06 amount of variability in these data, we
risk (standard deviation of ROE) plotted the market-based performance
nontraditional mergers
measures for the individual banking
traditional community
private growers agricultural transactions companies from three strategy groups
diversified corporate no strategy with distinctively different riskreturn
profiles: the diversified strategy, the non-
Note: Excludes banking companies with assets below $500 million.
traditional strategy, and the grower strat-
egy. Figure 8 shows the resulting scatter
plot. Although the individual data points
with substantial noise in our estimated Sharpe ratios, overlap to a large extent, they do not overlap com-
is simply preventing us from finding statistical differ- pletely, and it is easy to see a rough, but positive, risk
ences between most of the strategy pairs.
FIGURE 7
Market-based financial performance
We re-plotted the riskreturn averages Average stock market returns and risk for strategy groups
once again, this time using stock market- percent return
based performance measures. Although 0.30
we have stock market returns for only
about 12 percent of the 1,281 banking 0.25
companies in our sample, using these
data to compare the riskreturn profiles 0.20
of the strategy groups provides a good
robustness check on our accounting-based 0.15
riskreturn analysis. Stock returns reflect
more information than accounting returns, 0.10
and the stock prices upon which they are
based are forward-looking valuations by 0.05
informed investors rather than backward-
looking records based on often arcane ac- 0.00
0.2 0.25 0.3 0.35
counting rules.
risk (standard deviation of percent returns)
Figure 7 displays the average market-
based return and risk measures for the nontraditional no strategy
strategy groups that contained at least five diversified transactions
publicly traded banking companies with corporate
mergers
assets greater than $500 million. The re-
growers private
sults are quite consistent with the account-
ing-based plots. The diversified strategy Note: Excludes banking companies with assets below $500 million.

64 4Q/2004, Economic Perspectives


FIGURE 8 focus on non-bank financial services. We
Stock market returns and risk for traded banking
find substantial differences in profitability
companies with assets > $500 million in three selected across these different strategic approach-
strategy groups esbut we also find that high-return
strategies tend to generate high amounts
percent return of risk, while relatively low-return strate-
0.6 gies tend to generate less risk. This sug-
gests a tradeoff between risk and return
0.5 that can leave the shareholders of high-
risk banks and the shareholders of low-
0.4 risk banks roughly equally compensated
on a risk-adjusted basis. In other words,
0.3 a variety of different banking strategies
from small, locally focused community
0.2
banking to large, economy-wide corporate
bankingappear to be financially viable
0.1
business models.
The major caveat to this conclusion is
0.0
0 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 that very small banks tend to operate at a
risk (standard deviation of percent returns) financial disadvantage, regardless of their
business model. In order to earn a market
growers diversified nontraditional return for their shareholders, banking
companies must capture at least some of
the scale economies that are available in
expected return tradeoff across these three strategies. banking production functions. Although we use an
The scatter plot also provides a good illustration of asset size threshold of $500 million to make this
why it can be difficult to find statistical differences in point in our analysis, we stress that the critical size
risk-adjusted returns across strategic groups, even for a banking company varies with its strategy, and
though the banking companies in these groups show even within a strategy group the critical size needed
a systematic riskreturn ordering. for financial viability likely varies with managerial
abilities, local market conditions, and other consider-
Conclusions and implications ations. Our analysis suggests that the number of very
We began this set of articles by asking the ques- small U.S. banking companies is likely to continue to
tion How do banks make money? In the course of decline in the future. Still, there are reasons to expect
our analysis we have discussed various trends and that hundreds of very small banking companies will
developments in the banking industry that provide continue to exist. For example, very small banks that
partial answers to this question. But we have also un- serve geographically isolated rural communities may
covered some broad themes regarding bank performance remain financially viable if the lack of competition in
and competitive strategies that make some banks these markets allows them to charge prices high
more profitable than others. enough to offset the cost disadvantages associated with
U.S. banking companies employ a wide variety very low scale. And, of course, very small banks whose
of business models. For example, some are special- owners are willing to operate at a relatively low rate
ized and some are very broad; some have a retail fo- of return in exchange for receiving personal satisfac-
cus and some have a wholesale focus; some are tion or providing a community service are also likely
nationwide in scope and some are purely local; some to survive in some numbers.
focus on traditional commercial banking and some

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago 65


NOTES
1 6
To check whether the shift in the distribution in figure 3 was We acknowledge that the average performance of banking com-
merely due to an increase in equity capital in most banks during panies that use a given strategy may not be a good comparative
this period, we also examined the distribution of transaction depos- indicator of the potential performance of that strategy. For ex-
its to liabilities. This distribution was nearly identical to figure 3. ample, it may be the case that some strategies are attempted only
by companies with very efficient management teams (in which
2
The function of banks as intermediaries lies at the core of a rich case the average performance will be representative of the best-
theoretical literature on why banks exist. See DeYoung and Rice practice performance), while other strategies are attempted by
(2004) for a short review of this literature. both well-managed and poorly managed banking companies (in
which case the average performance will not be representative of
3
For bank holding companies (BHCs) and financial holding com- the best-practice performance). We plan to pursue this issue in fu-
panies (FHCs), we based this threshold on the average age of the ture research.
commercial banking affiliates in these multi-bank companies.
7
A technical point: Each of the Sharpe ratios displayed in table 2
4
The quarterly ROE data were de-seasonalized prior to these cal- is calculated by taking the average of the individual Sharpe ratios
culations, and quarters in which banking companies made large for the banking companies in a given strategy group. These num-
acquisitions were excluded from the calculations. bers are analytically different from the Sharpe ratios implied for
each of the strategy groups in figure 6, which plots the averages
5
To explore the extent to which the scale of the accounting-based of the individual returns (vertical axis) and individual risks (hori-
and market-based risk and return measures differ, we recalculated zontal axis) for the banking companies in each strategy group. In
the market-based measures using quarterly data. The average the figure, the Sharpe ratio is implied by the slope of a line run-
market-based returns fell from 0.1726 to 0.1553 and the average ning from about 0.043 on the vertical axis (the average risk-free
standard deviation of market-based returns fell from 0.2813 to rate during the sample period) through the plotted points. The
0.2579. These changes only partially closed the gap between the two approaches are conceptually similar and result in similar
accounting-based and market-based measures reported in table 1. rankings of the strategy groups in terms of their riskreturn
Thus, we conclude that the primary difference between the scales tradeoffs. However, the Sharpe ratio averages displayed in table 2
of the market-based and accounting-based measures lies with ac- are superior because they directly link risk and return for each
counting conventions and not the frequency with which we ob- banking company, which is where the ex ante managerial deci-
serve the returns. sions to trade risk for return are made.

66 4Q/2004, Economic Perspectives


REFERENCES

Berger, Allen N., Rebecca S. Demsetz, and Philip Evanoff, Douglas D., and Philip R. Israilevich,
E. Strahan, 1999, The consolidation of the finan- 1991, Productive efficiency in banking: Econometric
cial services industry: Causes, consequences, and im- and linear programming evidence, Economic Per-
plications for the future, Journal of Banking and spectives, Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, Vol. 15,
Finance, Vol. 23, February, pp. 135194. July/August, pp. 1132.

Berger, Allen N., and David B. Humphrey, 1991, HSN Consultants, Inc., 2002, The Nilson Report,
The dominance of inefficiencies over scale and April, No. 761.
product mix economies in banking, Journal of Mon-
etary Economics, Vol. 28, pp. 117148. Hughes, Joseph P., William Lang, Loretta J.
Mester, and Choon-Geol Moon, 1999, The dollars
Calomiris, Charles W., and Jason Karceski, 1998, and sense of bank consolidation, Journal of Banking
Is the Bank Merger Wave of the 1990s Efficient? Les- and Finance, Vol. 23, pp. 291324.
sons from Nine Case Studies, American Enterprise
Institute. Kane, Edward J., 1996, De jure interstate banking:
Why only now?, Journal of Money, Credit, and
Demsetz, Rebecca S., and Philip E. Strahan, 1997, Banking, Vol. 28, No. 2, pp. 141161.
Diversification, size, and risk at bank holding com-
panies, Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking, Vol. Kroszner, Randall S., and Philip E. Strahan, 1999,
29, August, pp. 300313. What drives deregulation? Economics and politics
of the relaxation of bank branching restrictions,
DeYoung, Robert, Iftekhar Hasan, and Bruce Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 114, No. 4,
Kirchhoff, 1998, The impact of out-of-state entry pp. 14371467.
on the efficiency of local banks, Journal of Eco-
nomics and Business, Vol. 50, pp. 191204. , 1997, The political economy of dereg-
ulation: Evidence from the relaxation of bank
DeYoung, Robert, William C. Hunter, and Gregory F. branching restrictions in the United States, Federal
Udell, 2004, The past, present, and probable future Reserve Bank of New York, research paper, No. 9720.
for community banks, Journal of Financial Services
Research, Vol. 25, No. 2/3, pp. 85133. Porter, Michael E., 1980, Competitive Strategy:
Techniques for Analyzing Industries and Competi-
DeYoung, Robert, and Tara Rice, 2004, Noninter- tors, New York: Free Press.
est income and financial performance at U.S. com-
mercial banks, Financial Review, Vol. 39, No. 1, Spong, Kenneth, 2000, Banking Regulation: Its
pp. 101127. Purposes, Implementation, and Effects, Federal
Reserve Bank of Kansas City.
DeYoung, Robert, and Karin P. Roland, 2001,
Product mix and earnings volatility at commercial Stein, Jeremy C., 2002, Information production
banks: Evidence from a degree of leverage model, and capital allocation: Decentralized vs. hierarchical
Journal of Financial Intermediation, Vol. 10, pp. 5484. firms, Journal of Finance, Vol. 57, pp. 18911921.

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago 67


Index for 2004
Title & author Issue Pages

BANKING, CREDIT, AND FINANCE


FDIC losses in bank failures: Has FDICIA made a difference?
George G. Kaufman Third Quarter 1325
How do banks make money? The fallacies of fee income
Robert DeYoung and Tara Rice Fourth Quarter 3451
How do banks make money? A variety of business strategies
Robert DeYoung and Tara Rice Fourth Quarter 5267

ECONOMIC CONDITIONS
The acceleration in U.S. total factor productivity after 1995:
The role of information technology
John G. Fernald and Shanthi Ramnath First Quarter 5267
Assessing the jobless recovery
Daniel Aaronson, Ellen R. Rissman, and Daniel G. Sullivan Second Quarter 220
Is the official unemployment rate misleading?
A look at labor market statistics over the business cycle
Lisa Barrow Second Quarter 2135
Can sectoral reallocation explain the jobless recovery?
Daniel Aaronson, Ellen R. Rissman, and Daniel G. Sullivan Second Quarter 3649
The relationship between Hispanic residential location
and homeownership
Maude Toussaint-Comeau and Sherrie L. W. Rhine Third Quarter 212
You cant take it with you: Asset run-down at the end of the life cycle
Kate Anderson, Eric French, and Tina Lam Third Quarter 4054

REGIONAL ISSUES
The state of the state and local government sector:
Fiscal issues in the Seventh District
Richard H. Mattoon First Quarter 217
Creative destruction in local markets
Jaap H. Abbring and Jeffrey R. Campbell Second Quarter 5060
House prices and the proposed expansion of Chicagos OHare Airport
Daniel P. McMillen Third Quarter 2839

MONEY AND MONETARY POLICY


Cyclical implications of the Basel II capital standards
Anil K Kashyap and Jeremy C. Stein First Quarter 1831
Poor hand or poor play? The rise and fall of inflation in the U.S.
Franois R. Velde First Quarter 3451
Interest rates and the timing of new production
Boyan Jovanovic and Peter L. Rousseau Fourth Quarter 211
In search of a robust inflation forecast
Scott Brave and Jonas D. M. Fisher Fourth Quarter 1231

To order copies of any of these issues, or to receive a list of other publications, please telephone (312)322-5111
or write to: Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, Public Information Center, P.O. Box 834, Chicago, IL 60690-0834.
The articles are also available to download in PDF format from the Banks website at www.chicagofed.org/
economic_research_and_data/economic_perspectives.cfm

68 4Q/2004, Economic Perspectives

You might also like