You are on page 1of 16

Booher &Power

Network Innesin Collaborative Planning

Network Power in Collaborative Planning

David E. Booher & Judith E. Innes

Power is everywhere and nowhere: it is in mass production, in financial flows, in lifestyles, in Abstract
the hospital, in the school, in television, in images, in messages, in technologies . . . our identity
This article makes a case that collaborative
is no longer defined by what we do but by what we are. . . . Such is the central question to which
planning is becoming more important be-
political thought and action must respond. . . . The fundamental matter is not seizing power, cause it can result in network power. Col-
but to recreate society, to invent politics anew, to avoid the blind conflict between open markets laborative policy processes are increas-
and closed communities, to overcome the breaking down of societies where the distance increases ingly in use as ways of achieving results in
between the included and the excluded, those in and those out. an era distinguished by rapid change, so-
cial and political fragmentation, rapid
Alain Touraine, as translated by Castells
high volume information flow, global in-
(1997, 309)
terdependence, and conflicting values.
Network power can be thought of as a flow
of power in which participants all share. It
Rethinking Power for the Informational Age comes into being most effectively when
three conditions govern the relationship
of agents in a collaborative network: diver-
Power is an elusive concept. When people use the term, they typically assume others sity, interdependence, and authentic dia-
know what they mean. When they try to define it, it becomes clear there is no agree- logue (DIAD). Like a complex adaptive
ment on even the most generic definition. Nowhere has dealing with the concept of system, the DIAD network as a whole is
more capable of learning and adaptation
power been more challenging than in the field of planning. It is a commonplace
in the face of fragmentation and rapid
assumption that whatever power is, planners do not have it. Planning as a professional change than a set of disconnected agents.
activity, particularly in the United States, is typically thought to be subject to power and Planners have many roles in such net-
not part of it. Though a few planning theorists argue otherwise, saying that what plan- works, and planning education needs to
incorporate new subject matter to better
ners do is part and parcel of what constitutes power in a society (Forester 1989; Hoch
prepare planners for these roles.
1994; Throgmorton 1996; Bryson and Crosby 1993), overall as a field we have not sys-
tematically made this case. The predominant view in many circles is still that planning is
either the handmaiden of power (Weiss 1987; Harvey 1989) or the dupe, or even the
victim of power (Altshuler 1965; Flyvbjerg 1998).1 Most often, those who write about
planning ignore power all together, as if it did not matter, or, more ominously, as if it
mattered so much that they dared not even raise the question.
Recently, the issue of power has moved more to the forefront in planning thought,
in part because of the growth of collaborative planning and consensus building. These David E. Booher, AICP, is a public policy
sets of practices involve a variety of stakeholders in long-term, face-to-face discussions to consultant at the California Center for
Public Dispute Resolution, California
produce plans and policies on controversial public issues.2 When we speak about our
State University, Sacramento.
research and practice in consensus building to academic audiences, some dubious lis-
Judith E. Innes is a professor of city and re-
teners always ask us how such efforts can make any real difference, given that power is
gional planning and director of the Insti-
unequally distributed and some stakeholders have fewer resources and influence out- tute of Urban and Regional Development
side the dialogue than others do. Is this just a more elaborate form of co-optation? How at the University of California, Berkeley.

Journal of Planning Education and Research 21:221-236


2002 Association of Collegiate Schools of Planning

221
222 Booher & Innes

can talking among a group make any real difference when the although we do not claim to prove its truth. What we offer is a
material sources of power, such as money, formal authority, or way of understanding a phenomenon we are witnessing in
the access to force, remain and when the group represents practice. What we hope is that these ideas will help generate
only a small subset of the players?3 discussion about power and planning.
This skepticism is largely based on a view of power as the
ability of one player, organization, or class to make another
person or group do something they would otherwise not do The Angst of Planners
(Galbraith 1983). While we do not disagree that this ability is a
form of power and is relevant to planning practice, we also find Planners in the United States seem always to be complain-
it to be a limiting concept for contemporary times. Often the ing because they feel powerless.5 They cannot make political
powerful player gets acquiescence but not results, or even leaders act on their analyses (Vasu 1979). They often have to
results contrary to his intentions. The world is too complex, work for agencies or clients they do not agree with, and they
too rapidly changing, and too full of ambiguities for this sort of sometimes feel they have to choose between their integrity and
mechanical power to produce consistently what the player their livelihood (Howe 1980, 1994). They want to do compre-
wanted or to produce sustainable results. hensive planning in the public interest, but more often they
The purpose of this article is to develop theory about net- work piecemeal on whatever their agency doeshousing,
work power, an alternative form of power that, we argue, community development, or transportation. They are frus-
emerges from consensus building and other forms of collabo- trated by the lack of opportunity to link these together and the
rative planning. We will outline the conditions under which inability to get at the sources of the problems instead of merely
such power comes into being, along with its consequences. the symptoms. Planners in the United States are not featured
This effort is inspired by our attempts to understand the emer- in the news. They do not make big salaries. They are not the
gence, growing popularity, and impact of many types of collab- subjects of prime-time television series nor even interviewed
oration today, from consensus building for resource manage- on national television. They are practically invisible.
ment or controversial public investment, to university The academy mostly feeds the planner angst. A recent
community partnerships for community development, to com- example is Flyvbjergs (1998) account of how the leaders in the
petitive businesses working together. It is also motivated by our city of Aalborg willfully ignored the rational analyses of plan-
observation that planners and others who assist policy-making ners for the sake of politics. This account is just the latest in a
processes typically do not recognize the power they do have or long tradition, especially in the United States. Banfield (1961)
the ways they can play significant parts in producing valued made the same case in the 1950s in his classic Political Influence,
outcomes for society. in which he explained the strategy of Chicagos powerful
Our proposal for how power and collaboration are linked mayor Richard Daley, who accumulated political capital by get-
grows out of our research and practice, particularly in consen- ting projects funded for powerful players. Daley did not have a
sus building, but also in community development and other vision of a good city, other than a place where a lot was getting
practices of cooperative deliberation and action. We have seen done. He used the planners to support and legitimize what he
results in some of these cases in which beforehand there was had already decided to do (Banfield 1961).6 Altshuler (1965),
only paralysis, results that other methods of planning and in his classic study of comprehensive planning, argued that
deciding had not been able to achieve.4 These ideas also grow planners simply could not serve the public interest because
out of literatures on collaboration and on rational choice the- this could only be accomplished through political means,
ory, and they build on the conceptual work of one of the which he said were contrary to the planners professional skills
authors (Booher 1974) in his analysis of public participation in and norms. This argument was to help dash many aspirations
planning. Many others have written about networks from vari- of the profession, which had at the time no real answer for
ous related perspectives, including most notably Roland War- Altshuler.7
ren (1967), Emery and Trist (1965), and Friend, Power, and The planning academy instead largely bought into the pol-
Yewlett (1974) on interorganizational networks and Norton icy analysis model of planning, with its emphasis on quantita-
Long (1958), who described the local community as an ecol- tive and economic analysis involving not the engaged, compre-
ogy of games. While our argument is consistent with these, our hensive planner dealing with community values but the
emphasis is on planning and policy-making processes and on rational, neutral analyst working for a client. The advocacy/
the implications for the professionals who serve those pro- organizing model of planner as representative of the poor was
cesses. We offer brief examples to illustrate our argument, an extension of this analyst conception as it too was built on the
Network Power in Collaborative Planning 223

idea of planner as expert working for a client. A whole genera- to focus on collaborative methods and consensus building as a
tion of armchair planning theorists in the 1960s and 1970s mode of planning and policy making (Healey 1997; Innes and
spent their time hypothesizing and prescribing what planning Booher 1999b; Kolb and Associates 1994; Innes 1996; Innes
would be like if it were done properly, most often in the ratio- et al. 1994; Susskind and Cruikshank 1987). They found that
nal analytic mode. In this model, a planner was not really sup- these could be creative and effective processes in which plan-
posed to be concerned about power. A planner who accepted ners played substantial roles. Communicative planning
this rational model would despair in practice of getting past became a focus for planning theory but for the most part
politics and power to get people to do the right thing. ignored the issue of power (Mandelbaum, Mazza, and
Even more depressing could be the work of the political Burchell 1996; Sager 1994).
economists, whose accounts of planning emphasized the We intend this article to play a part in the discourse that the
power and importance of capital in shaping the world in which field requires to develop a realistic sense of the power planners
planners operate. Weiss (1987), for example, made the case can have in shaping policy and places when they manage or
that planners in the 1950s and 1960s had served as enablers of engage in collaborative planning dialogues. Planners are far
development and responded above all to the interests of devel- from powerless, we argue, but their power is not in a form they
opers and the business community. David Harvey (1989) con- have typically recognized. They help to shape the flow of
tended that planning education was devoted to encouraging power, to mobilize it and to focus it. They are a part of it but not
balancing all values so that planning as a field could maintain in control. But then, no one today is in control.
the capitalist structure against the dangers of overaccumulation
or underaccumulation. The political economists are persua-
sive, and their large-scale social analysis seems to us in the main The Informational Age as a
fair and on target. It typically assumes, however, that powerful Context for Network Power
elites will inevitably dominate, if not decide, the outcomes, and
it assumes away the power of individual agency of professionals We have entered an era that Castells (1996) has labeled the
or other players. All too often this literature leaps to the con- informational age or the network society. He makes the
clusion, or even builds on the assumption, that the forces of case that
capital have far more capacity to ensure that outcomes and
a technological revolution, centered around information
actions are supportive to them than we believe these forces technologies, is reshaping, at an accelerated pace, the
have in reality. material basis of society. Economies around the world have
In the past decade or two, the planning academy has begun become globally interdependent, introducing a new form
of relationship between economy, state, and society. . . .
to move away from the idea that analysts can figure out how to
Capitalism itself has undergone a process of profound
design programs and make outcomes turn out as planned to restructuring characterized by greater flexibility in man-
the idea that planners have to work with the market. Most U.S. agement; decentralization and networking of firms both
planning theorists and some Europeans have turned away internally and in their relationships to other firms. (P. 1)
from the primarily normative and hypothetical exercises of the This, Castells (1996) says, has resulted in accentuation of
previous generation and have begun to study actual planning uneven development, separating the rich from the poor. The
practice (Innes 1995). One of the pioneers in this work, John new global, interactive communication system integrates glob-
Forester (1989), on the basis of his observations of planners in ally the production and distribution of words, sounds, and
the San Francisco City Planning Department, showed us that images of our culture and customizes them to the tastes of
planners every day were exercising power through their com- identities and moods of individuals (p. 2). One of the major
munications with planning commissioners, citizens, develop- consequences of such technological and economic changes is
ers, and others. These communications were empowering or social turmoil and change. He notes that
disempowering to the listener, depending on how they were
done. Planners had the power to organize attention and get social movements tend to be fragmented, localistic, single-
issue oriented and ephemeral. . . . In a world of uncon-
people to focus on some issues and away from others. Planning
trolled, confusing change, people tend to re-group around
scholars also studied other aspects of communication (Healey primary identities, religious, ethnic, territorial and
1993; Schon 1983; Sager 1994), often relating it directly to national. . . . In a world of global flows of wealth, power, and
power. The political economists began a debate with the com- images, the search for identity, collective or individual,
ascribed or constructed, becomes the fundamental source
municative theorists, which may result in some useful mutual
of social meaning. . . . In this condition of structural schizo-
learning about power.8 Other theorists and researchers began phrenia between function and meaning, patterns of social
224 Booher & Innes

communication become increasingly under stress . . . social particularly all-channel networks in which every node can com-
groups and individuals become alienated from each
municate with every other nodeis one of the single most
other . . . social fragmentation spreads and identities
become more specific and increasingly difficult to share. important effects of the information revolution for all realms
(P. 3) (p. 5). According to the authors, whoever masters the network
form stands to gain major advantages in the new epoch. Mili-
Castells (1996) argues that these changes amount to a revo- tary thinkers in the United States are actively using models of
lution, a dramatic change in the nature of both society and the self-organizing networks to develop new strategies and tactics
self. This emergent global economy is driven by and depends for the battlefield (Mitchell 1998).
on the flows of information. Those who are successful in the Likewise, leaders in business and management have for
knowledge-based, fast-evolving societies are those who keep years applied a similar insight in the organization and opera-
their feelers out constantly, learning and adapting. The value tion of the firm (Kotter 1985; Schrage 1990; Moore 1996; Davis
added of the most successful companies is in the ways they pro- and Meyer 1998; Brown and Eisenhardt 1998). An eminent
cess or provide information or offer smarter products and ser- management analyst has documented how ineffective tradi-
vices that take advantage of information technology. The new tional forms of power such as authority, wealth, force, or even
society is one where virtually nothing is a given any more, it is simple persuasion have increasingly become (Kotter 1985).
no longer obvious who are ones friends and allies and who are According to Kotter (1985), the prevalence of diversity and
not, and little is shared in values and ideology. Castells terms it interdependence among groups and individuals within firms
the informational society because it is organized around has rendered the old view of centralized, rational economic
information generation, processing, and transmission and decision making obsolete. What is emerging instead is an adap-
these are its fundamental sources of power and productivity. tive organization based on teams engaged in dialogue, collabo-
The nature of the new society has profound implications ration, and the development of shared meaning across the
for the phenomenon of power. Castells (1997) shows that organization (Schrage 1990; Huberman 1998; Stacey 1998).
power is no longer concentrated in institutions, organizations, This form of planning and decision making is made more
or even symbolic controllers such as the church or media. important because of the rapid change described by Castells
Instead power is diffused throughout global networks of (1996, 1997). As Xeroxs John Seely Brown (cited in Schrage
wealth, information, and images. Power does not disappear. It 1990) has observed, conversation enables us to rapidly build
still shapes society. But the old forms of power are fading away shared contexts. If the world is not changing very much, then
because they are comparatively less effective than the new the shared context we had a year ago can be evoked easily. But
forms. The new power lies in the codes of information and in the to interpret rapidly changing phenomena or act effectively in a
images of representation around which societies organize their institu- radical changing environment, players have to rapidly create
tions, and people build their lives and decide their behavior. The sites of new, shared contexts (Schrage 1990, 83).
this power are peoples minds (Castells 1997, 359, emphasis A parallel collaborative, communicative process is occur-
added). Whoever wins the battle of peoples minds will rule ring across firms within various industrial sectors in which new
because rigid apparatuses will not be a match, in any reason- forms of collaboration have emerged. Saxenian (1994) has
able time span, for the minds mobilized around the power of documented the flexible linkages and personal and profes-
flexible, alternative networks (Castells 1997, 360). Constant sional networks that permitted Silicon Valley to grow the most
change in information flows means values are constantly successful and innovative high-technology industry in the
changing. As a result, the search for identity and meaning for world and to prosper across more than four decades. In Blur:
individuals, groups, and communities becomes a central and The Speed of Change in the Connected Economy, Davis and Meyer
continuing task. (1998) argue that familiar distinctions no longer obtain
Even the most ancient and traditional form of power, between products and services, buyers and sellers, structure
armed combat led by a military hierarchy, has been changed by and process, owning and using, or knowing and learning.
the informational society. Sheer brute force and chain-of- Things one cannot see or touch, like customer service and rep-
command-style organization is increasingly less crucial to mili- utation, are more valuable than tangible assets. Business prac-
tary success, while networks and multiuser communication tices are, as a result, undergoing radical change. A company
play an ever-growing role. Researchers at RAND, in a study for like Netscape or Adobe might give away its product to get peo-
the U.S. secretary of defense (Arquilla and Ronfeldt 1997), ple to subscribe to the services, or simply read the advertising
found that the informational age favors and strengthens net- attached, so they can get information about users to build the
work forms of organization, while making life difficult for hier- business. Thus, buyer and seller somehow keep constantly
archical forms. The rise of network forms of organization trading places. There is an exchangea new kind of
Network Power in Collaborative Planning 225

collaboration taking place that involves much more than do the nodes in a neural networkbut collectively they have a
money and material products. substantial intelligence. Connectionist networks are self- orga-
While new kinds of collaboration have emerged in the pub- nizing systems capable of adapting to environmental stress or
lic sector and among the public agencies and private players in change and evolving to greater levels of performance without
recent years, this arena has lagged behind the private sector in central guidance (Epstein 1999; Epstein and Axtell 1996;
developing the potential of networked relationships. More- Cilliers 1998).
over, there remains much less scholarly documentation or Power in a connectionist network is not a weapon that an
analysis of these efforts than there is of business management.9 individual can hold and use at will, nor is it the result of an
This article is intended to develop the concepts that can frame unequal relationship between players. Instead, it is a jointly
future research on the impact of collaboration in planning. held resource enabling networked agencies or individuals to
accomplish things they could not otherwise. Participants
(community-based organizations, individuals), for example,
in a highly networked community sector are able to influence
The Network Power Concept
city agencies and change city policy through myriad individual
Nothing under Heaven is as soft and yielding as water. actions (Morris 1998). This notion of power makes sense if we
Yet for attacking the hard and strong, nothing can think of the world as a complex adaptive system within which
compare with it. individuals work, communicate, and learn, rather than as a
The weak overcomes the strong. The soft overcomes machine that we can manage and control with the right knowl-
the hard. edge.11 Thinking of power this way requires us to set aside
Everyone knows this, but none have the ability to practice it. some of our familiar notions. Lao Tzus (1995) paradoxical
Lao Tzu (1995, 78) concept of power as soft and yielding like water may help us to
understand that network power can be significant while
appearing not to be.
In the informational age, network power is what works most This idea of network power is consistent with Giddens
effectively. Network power is a shared ability of linked agents to (1984) perspective that contends that there are three types of
alter their environment in ways advantageous to these agents powerthe power of action; the power of ideas, modes, and
individually and collectively. Network power emerges from methods; and the power of deep structureand with Bryson
communication and collaboration among individuals, public and Crosbys (1992) view of leadership in a shared power
and private agencies, and businesses in a society. Network world. Network power depends on the flow of ideas through
power emerges as diverse participants in a network focus on a networks and on the power of action of each of the agents
common task and develop shared meanings and common within networks. While the emergence of network power does
heuristics that guide their action. The power grows as these not affect deep structure in the short term, we share with
players identify and build on their interdependencies to create Giddens (1984) the idea that agents enact structure within
new potential. In the process, innovations and novel responses constraints and agency gradually can change structure. The
to environmental stresses can emerge.10 These innovations in networked patterns of action in an informational society, with
turn make possible adaptive change and constructive joint the rapid communication and change that are the norm today,
action. suggest that deep structure may change more quickly now than
Our concept of network power uses the connectionist at other points in history. The idea of network power is, we
model of neural networks developed by cognitive scientists as a believe, consistent with a number of other approaches to
basic model. A connectionist network, like the neural network power in the literature (Blau 1964; Galbraith 1983; Fisher
of the brain, is composed of individual agents connected 1983) that recognize that power is both enabled and limited by
together with information exchange links with no central or an interactive process among individuals, interests, or nations.
top-down control over information flow or individual behav- According to researchers and practitioners at the Harvard
ior. Actions take place in a limited physical space, around a Negotiation Project (Fisher and Ury 1981; Raiffa 1982), agents
common resource, or within localized social and political con- can meet their needs with interest-based negotiations by creat-
texts. Information in a connectionist network is distributed ing new options that were not available to them individually or
rather than centralized, and much of it is in the form of shared when they were in a conflict mode with others.
heuristics or encoded responses used by the agents. These Clearly, many other types of power exist, such as, for exam-
agents do not have global information, and they do not indi- ple, power associated with personality, property, or degree of
vidually have infinite computational powerany more than organization, as John Galbraith (1983) has argued. These are
226 Booher & Innes

all important as part of the environment within which collabo- Whelan, and Murin 1986). For example, Warren, Rose, and
ration and network power must be understood. These forms of Bergunder (1974) documented elements of what we call net-
power come into play in the design and implementation of col- work power in their study of community decision organizations
laboration. The traditional ways of thinking about power are and Sarason and Lorentz (1979) documented similar ele-
not, however, very useful in understanding the overall dynam- ments in their study of resource exchange networks. The ter-
ics of collaboration itself. rorist attacks on 11 September 2001 provided a vivid and trau-
Probably the most important aspect of network power is the matic illustration of the power of networks in contemporary
ability of networked agents to improve the choices available to global society (Arquilla and Ronfeldt 2001).
all of them as a result of collectively developed innovative
ideas. We have described elsewhere how innovative options for
a group of competing interests can emerge through a process
The Conditions Enabling Network Power
of collective intellectual bricolage and role-playing (Innes and
Booher 1999b). For example, a consensus-building group We recommend that you should try to get what it is feasible for you to
invented a way to not only share a limited water resource but get, holding in view the real sentiments of us both; since you know
also to increase the effective quantity of water available to all as well as we do that right, as the world goes, is only in question
through this sort of creative discussion. In turn, the power of between equals in power, while the strong do what they can and the
the network enables the participants to, independently and weak suffer what they must.
cooperatively, implement the strategy and adapt it as condi- Athenians to the Melians
tions evolve, for example, in drought years. They can do this (Thucydides 1952, 505)
without the need for central direction. Hence, a cooperative
monitoring system among stakeholders spread out across the
rivers and wetlands in Northern California has allowed a real- For network power to emerge in a significant way, we con-
time response to changing water conditions and saved hun- tend, three basic conditions must be in place. The first is that
dreds of thousands of acre feet of water as a result of the collab- the agents in the network (stakeholders, agencies, and citi-
orative process among federal and state agencies and interests, zens) should be diverse in a way that is consistent with the full
known as CALFED (Connick forthcoming). The choices avail- range of interests and knowledge relevant to the issues at hand.
able to individual agencies or interest groups as a result of par- This would include, for example, diversity of values, resources,
ticipating in such collaborations can be wider and often more experience, and information. It might also include diversity of
attractive than what they can gain through more traditional race, gender, geographic roots, and other factors, depending
power struggles or maneuvering. For example, in the Califor- on the task. The second condition is that agents must be in a sit-
nia Governance Consensus Project, many of the most powerful uation in which their ability to fulfill their interests depends on
political interests in California developed collaborative pro- each others actions and in which they recognize this interde-
cesses to work on fiscal and governance reforms and to reduce pendence. This interdependence involves each players hav-
the reliance on more conflict-oriented ballot initiatives and ing something to offer that others want and something they
legislative conflicts they had traditionally used. This collabora- want from the others. The third condition is authentic dia-
tion continued even after the project had ended (Innes and logue. The communication flowing through the network must
Booher 1999b, 2000) and has been used to create joint initia- be both accurate and trusted by participants to allow the full
tives on schools, labor issues, and housing. The principal rea- advantage to be taken of the agents diversity and interdepen-
son such powerful players collaborate is to greatly increase dence. In particular, it is critical that the participants in the net-
their options. work have discourse in which all are empowered and informed
Network power is not a new phenomenon. On the contrary, and in which sincerity, legitimacy, and accuracy of what people
it proliferates in nature (Kauffman 1995; Holland 1998). In say can be judged (Innes and Booher 1999a, 1999b). We use
social settings, network power has probably always existed, the acronym DIAD to designate collaborative networks in
although it has not been labeled as such nor extensively docu- which diversity, interdependence, and authentic dialogue are
13
mented. Very often, the conditions for it were not in place.12 present (see Figure 1). While no real situation will have ideal
Organizational researchers have long recognized the impor- conditions in all these dimensions, these are directly related to
tance of relations among organizations as an issue worthy of the flow and effectiveness of network power.
research beyond the characteristics of the individual organiza- If we think of a collaborative network as an organic system,
tions or even their aggregate characteristics (Emery and Trist diversity is the source of raw material as it brings together the
1965; Warren 1967; Friend, Power, and Yewlett 1974; Stone, ideas, values, interests, and knowledge into a new fabric.
Network Power in Collaborative Planning 227

interests to get the legitimacy and ultimately political support


Characteristics Diversity Interdependence
of Agents of Agents they would need to pass legislation (Innes et al. 1994).
of Participants
The diversity of interests in turn provides the opportunity
for creative solutions to satisfy different concerns and helps
Reciprocity
Relationships
ensure that strategies are robust and feasible. Moreover, this
Results of
Authentic Dialogue Learning diversity provides a wide range of resources, information, per-
Creativity
sonalities, experiences, and points of view that become the
materials for innovation and learning. Fishermen, for exam-
Shared Identities
ple, provided critical information in the San Francisco Estuary
Adaptations Shared Meanings
of the System
Project (Innes and Connick 1999) because they were aware
New Heuristics
Innovation long before scientists or others of the deterioration in
biodiversity. A sense of authenticity of the communication is,
Figure 1. Diversity, interdependence, and authentic dialogue network in addition, essential for players to make self-interested, ratio-
dynamics. nal decisions about participating in discussion or cooperating
in action. They have to trust what each other says if they are
going to act on it.

Interdependence among the participants is the source of


energy as it brings agents together and holds them in this sys- Diversity
tem. Authentic dialogue is the genetic code, providing struc-
ture within which agents can process their diversity and inter- Diversity is a hallmark of the informational age. The wide
dependence. Network power is the resulting life force of range of life experiences, interests, values, knowledge, and
patterned action, learning, adaptation, and reproduction. We resources in society is a challenge for planning and for the
offer this analogy because we and others have argued that a effort to produce agreements and collective action. In a social
new biological metaphor is needed for the informational age system, as in a biological one, it is the diversity in the environ-
to replace the mechanical metaphor we have used for so long ment that permits innovation. The various elements of the
to understand human organization as well as nature (Innes environment interact and adaptively change as a result of the
and Booher 1999c; Petzinger 1999). We have also argued that interactions. Diversity provides the building blocks for a net-
complex adaptive systems theory is a useful model to frame the work to create new conditions and solutions.
study of collaborative planning (Innes and Booher 1999c).14 What happens in diverse networks in which participants
Self-interest and rational choice drive network power. engage in authentic dialogue is that they can jointly construct a
Stakeholders very rarely participate in collaborative efforts way of seeing the problem that they can agree on instead of
because they are selfless altruists or because they are searching speaking in different languages within different frames of ref-
for the common good. Participants become involved because erence.15 They can develop agreement on the problems tech-
they have learned their interests are interdependent in some nical characteristics and political, economic, and social dimen-
way on the actions of others. Otherwise, they would pursue sions and the implications for them individually and as a
their interests outside the collaborative process. They hope to group. Participants start with diverse views of the world and the
achieve something together that they cannot achieve alone. problems they face. As they try to understand the problem and
Frequently, collaborations start because players all have incen- each others interests, they develop a more nuanced and com-
tives to change the status quo or head off anticipated change. plex understanding of the problems from various perspectives.
For example, in San Diego, an unusual collaboration of local While they each bring to the dialogue their identities as stake-
governments on regional growth management started in order holders or agency representatives, in the process of discussing
to head off anticipated state legislation that might have im- a problem such as, for example, the management of a water
posed conditions they would find unacceptable (Gruber 1994). resource they can begin to develop shared and complemen-
In many cases, participants make rational, self-interested deci- tary identities as users and producers of a supply of water. They
sions to include a wide range of interests in their negotiations can develop agreed-on meanings for such concepts as
to ensure they get the knowledge, support, and legitimacy they biodiversity or adequacy of water flows. This comes from build-
need for a successful outcome. In the statewide California ing a shared understanding of the larger system and from how
Growth Management Consensus Project, powerful business stakeholders, whether they are developers, farmers, or envi-
and environmental interests decided to include social equity ronmentalists, plays a part in it in the management of the
228 Booher & Innes

Figure 2. Altruism begins at home.


Source: CALVIN AND HOBBES Watterson. Reprinted with permission of UNIVERSAL PRESS SYNDICATE. All rights reserved.

resource. Participants in such dialogue can come to recognize emerge that not only represents practical rationality but also
they are a part of a community of interest, with a common fate emancipatory rationality.18 Such a dialogue among diverse
based on the behavior of other participants in the network. stakeholders is more likely to produce practical results as well
Ostroms (1990) studies of long-term, effective collective man- as see beyond the accepted rationalizations in a society and the
agement of common resources such as grazing lands, fisheries, assumptions that interfere with insights. The international
and water resources provide powerful examples of how com- society of professional mediators and facilitators has, on the
munities can build this sort of understanding and practice. If a basis of experience with thousands of disputes, reached a simi-
network of agents achieve such shared meaning, they acquire a lar conclusion and recommends including all key stakeholders
new power to act and accomplish, whether through joint or in an issue in mediation processes (Society of Professionals in
individual action. They have created a sort of community with Dispute Resolution 1997; see Figure 2).
common purpose and heuristics to guide future action.16 They
are no longer isolated players working at cross-purposes often
without a clear idea of what makes sense for themselves, much Interdependence
less for the resource on which they depend. They can move on
to develop ways to address the problem that they could not do Interdependence based on self-interest and reciprocity
individually given their more narrow perspectives or resources among diverse participants fuels network power. Participants
or the assumption that they have to operate alone.17 For exam- must each have something others want and need something
ple, in the consensus-building process around the water supply others can offer them. This exchange may involve one agent
in the Sacramento region of California, the participants had having authority or resources and another, perhaps weaker
built trust and new methods of working together that held the agent in conventional terms, having legitimacy or many sup-
group together when a local congressman put forward legisla- porters as did the social equity groups in the Growth Manage-
tion for a major dam that environmentalists had long opposed. ment Consensus Project. One agent, such as an environmental
He packaged his proposal with flood control funding for the representative or a local neighborhood organization, may
whole region, making it impossible for other important players have firsthand knowledge of the issues, whereas another, con-
in the group to oppose the bill. Members talked and found ventionally more powerful agent, such as a developer, suffers
ways to maintain constructive working relationships despite the most expensive impacts from not resolving the problem.
the way this divisive act had undermined their efforts to col- Interdependence means that each agent needs something
laboratively manage the water resources of the region (Innes from the others. Reciprocity exists when agents realize they
and Booher 1999b). can gain and create new opportunities by sharing what each
Habermas (1981) argues in a parallel way that to achieve uniquely can offer and when they can expect the other players
communicative rationality, a diverse set of interests must par- to contribute. Once participants recognize the reciprocal
ticipate in a dialogue. Each individual brings not only his or nature of their relationship, they can come to understand, or
her interest but also praxis, experience, and knowledge. even cultivate, their interdependence. For example, in the
Through a face-to-face dialogical process, understanding can Governance Consensus Project referenced above, the business
Network Power in Collaborative Planning 229

community began to understand that they needed better Axelrod has also shown that strategies based on reciprocity
schools to supply more knowledgeable labor and the Califor- and cooperation can be very robust (Axelrod 1984; Bendor
nia Teachers Association learned that they needed the support and Swistak 1997; Axelrod 1997). Using the game of the Pris-
of the conservative business community if they were to be able oners Dilemma, he shows that players involved in repeated
to increase revenues to support schools. Reciprocity is the basis games with each other will choose to cooperate rather than to
of trust. The existence of trust and reciprocity in turn means minimize their own risk by turning on the other player because
agents will have a reason to continue to work together. It is in a cooperative strategy produces more benefits over time than
this sense that interdependence and reciprocity provide the an uncooperative one. In repeated games, a pattern develops
energy that holds a collaborative network together. in which each player discovers this independently and volun-
The concept of rational choice is important to understand- tarily cooperates with the other. Axelrods analysis also shows
ing interdependence in collaborative processes because self- that for cooperation to be a beneficial strategy, it requires
interest and recognition that the cooperation of others is the three conditions: the existence of reciprocity, sufficient stake
means to achieve a desirable outcome are the motivating fac- in the outcomes for both players so the reciprocity can be sta-
tors for agents (Downs 1957; Olson 1965; Arrow 1963; ble, and knowledge the game will continue. Whether the play-
Buchanan and Tullock 1967). Riker (1962) describes rational ers initially trust each other is less important than the existence
choice as follows: of these conditions. Also important to long-term stability of
cooperative modes is the ability of agents to monitor conduct
Given social situations within certain kinds of decision- by others so that defections can be punished and the incentive
making institutions (of which parlor games, the market,
elections, and warfare are notable examples) and in which to participate does not evaporate (Ostrom 1990). Once coop-
exist two alternative courses of action with differing out- eration is established in a system, both theory and practice
comes in money or power or success, some participants will demonstrate that uncooperative strategies or co-optation
choose the alternative leading to the larger payoff. Such a (Selznick 1966) cannot easily supplant the pattern.
choice is rational behavior and it will be accepted as defini-
tive while the behavior of participants who do not so choose
will not necessarily be so accepted. (P. 23)
Authentic Dialogue
Rational choice is always about means, not ends. The term
rational is never applied to an agents ends but only to her or his Few of these benefits of diversity and interdependence can
means. This follows from the definition of rational as efficient, occur without authentic dialogue among the agents, that is,
that is, maximizing output for a given input or minimizing without dialogue that allows all agents to speak openly and in
input for a given output (Downs 1957, 5; Arrow 1963). Indeed, an informed way about their interests and understandings and
as Arrow (1963) has shown, the choice is never between just ensures that all are listened to and taken seriously by the oth-
two alternative strategies because if there is more than one pos- ers. Without this kind of dialogue, meanings will not become
sible strategy, there is the possibility for an infinite number of truly shared, nor will group members identify with a common
means to reach a rational choice.19 A prominent business theo- system or community. Without such dialogue, opportunities
rist has suggested that this search for economizing action strat- for reciprocity will be missed, important information about the
egies is a fundamental propensity of nature as well as rational problem will not surface, and creative solutions are far less
man (Frederick 1995). likely to emerge, as both empirical research and theory suggest
From a rational choice perspective, an individual con- (Johnson and Johnson 1997). Connectionist and neural net-
stantly searches for more efficient means to achieve her or his works require information to flow among the agents of the net-
ends. Where cooperation can lead to more efficient means, work if they are to carry on their activities in a way that is suit-
cooperation becomes the more rational strategy. But this able to the needs of the network (Cilliers 1998). In the case of
requires some degree of certainty in the cooperation. Each collaborative planning, the information flow must allow the
agent must have a sense that the other agents self-interest also agents to fully utilize the diversity of the network if they are to
requires their continued cooperation. Ostrom (1998) has create innovative choices. This flow also is necessary for the
shown empirically that building conditions of reciprocity, rep- survival of the collaborative network and for the emergence
utation, and trust can help to overcome strong temptations for out of interdependence and reciprocity of shared norms and
individuals to work only toward their short-term self-interest. heuristics. For example, in the governance consensus process,
The results of working collaboratively on problems are more participants developed the shared heuristic that they would
beneficial to participants than action based on noncollabora- communicate and collaborate with each other rather than
tive choice methods (Ostrom 1998). return to conflict as usual. An out-of-state interest placed an
230 Booher & Innes

initiative on the California ballot that would have harmed overestimated by hundreds of thousands of acre feet the
labor but in the process created a statewide war between busi- amount of water that would be available. At first it seemed this
ness and labor, harming business as well. The powerful mem- enormous error would undo the agreement because so much
bers of this project, which included leaders of the major state would have to be changed. But instead, because of their confi-
unions, the chamber of commerce, and other business groups, dence in their joint fact-finding capabilities, they were able to
got together and agreed on a strategy that ultimately suc- get the agency to revise its figures and to alter their agreement
ceeded in defeating the initiative (Innes and Booher 1999b, to take into account the new and correct data. Innes earlier
2000). Availability of information about the behavior of the research has demonstrated that agreement on the accuracy of
other agents in the network is also necessary to maintain inter- statistics and indicators, for example, can be an essential part
dependence. To make this kind of joint action work among of achieving agreement on controversial policy (de Neufville
competing stakeholders, they must have confidence that oth- 1975). Third, statements participants make must be compre-
ers are not defecting. In the above example, the ballot initia- hensible to each other. In facilitated processes, comprehensi-
tive, campaign and finance disclosure laws, daily communica- bility across diverse agents is typically achieved as they and the
tions, and media reports assured the participants that they facilitator place statements in the context of their experience,
would know if other participants defected from the strategy. as they engage in role-playing and storytelling (Innes and
Our research and practice in consensus building, the prac- Booher 1999b), or in questions directed at the speaker about
tice of mediators and facilitators doing dispute resolution the meaning and implications of what they say. For example,
(Society of Professionals in Dispute Resolution 1997), and the the meaning of pollution and of biodiversity were the subject of
work of Habermas (1981) and others who write about dialogue extensive conversation in the San Francisco Estuary Project
(e.g., Fox and Miller 1996) all converge on four key conditions (Innes and Connick 1999). Finally, for authentic dialogue,
for authentic dialogue. In authentic dialogue of the ideal speakers must have legitimacy to say what they do. That is, they
form, participants speak with sincerity, accuracy, comprehensi- must have expertise, experience, or some other basis for their
bility, and legitimacy. Moreover, they can evaluate each others statements, and the other participants in the discourse must be
statements in these terms. Skilled facilitators in dispute resolu- able to inquire into that legitimacy. Thus, someone speaking
tion and consensus building can create conditions for such for the business community must be representative of a sub-
dialogue, and participants who get to know each other over stantial organization of businesses and must confer regularly
time can develop these conditions with or without such facilita- with them. A farming representative who wants to make the
tors if they understand their importance (Susskind, McKearnon, case that water regulations will harm farming operations needs
and Carpenter 1999). to be able to speak knowledgeably and often experientially of
Dialogues must be face-to-face and take place over time if those operations.
participants are to assess each others sincerity. They must get It is crucial during a dialogue that participants be able to
to know each other sufficiently to make such assessments. suspend judgment and share the meaning being presented by
Thus, an authentic dialogue takes time to develop and another participant without necessarily accepting it, if they are
requires both formal and informal interactions. Participants to be able to uncover the rationalizations and get beyond the
must feel comfortable and safe in expressing their honest views taken-for-granted ideas that may be hindering a solution.
and feelings. They cannot feel pressured to conceal them Thus, participants can uncover the intellectual content of a rig-
because those hidden views hamper the development of genu- idly held assumption while defusing the emotional content
ine reciprocity and robust collaboration. Individuals must be that accompanies it (Bohm 1992; Innes and Booher 1999b).
able to pursue their interests without disguising them if collab- Bohm (1992) calls this a vision of dialogue, and it is equally
oration is to work (Arrow 1963). Second, dialogues and indi- important in scientific discourse as in planning discourse. He
viduals within them must be fully and equally informed about says the following about scientific discourse:
the issues and the problems if they are to effectively assess their
We can see that we all have these assumptions, and we look
own interests and the accuracy of others statements and if they at all the assumptions. Im looking at your assumptions and
are to reach shared and durable understandings. Joint fact my assumptions. Theyre all suspended. Im not deciding
finding, often used in consensus building, is an important they are right or wrong. Or, if I think I prefer mine, well,
thats OK. But still Im looking at the meaning of what you
component of the exercise. For example, in the case of the Sac-
say. And therefore we are sharing a common meaning.
ramento Water Forum cited above, when the participants were Then, if somebody else comes up with another assumption
finalizing their agreement, they discovered a flaw in the model we all listen to that; we share that meaning. Now that would
used by a federal water agency, which meant the agency had be the vision of dialogue. (P. 205)
Network Power in Collaborative Planning 231

Building shared meaning requires players not just to say understanding what others are contributing, as well as paying
their pieces but also to listen. Thus power, paradoxically, attention to the emerging meanings the group is creating. One
depends on listening. Facilitators teach listening skills, and can imagine the discussion as being like a group jointly paint-
Habermas (1981) implies they are part of the conditions for ing a canvas. They use language as a painter uses his or her
communicative rationality and authentic dialogue. Listening mediumto evoke images, impressions, memories, and
can make deliberative space both for the groups that are thoughts and to help others connect emotionally to what they
marginalized by the dominant dialogue in a society or issue are saying.21 Language is not simply a means to exchange
area and for individuals marginalized within the dialogue of information or a set of tools to argue with. Language is a
their own group. Listening is an important aspect of reflexivity medium for working together, creating relationships and
and is essential to seeking understanding (Bickford 1996). Lis- understanding (Schrage 1990). Persuasion is about relevance
tening productively means that one maintains ones own per- and fitting ideas together in a way that works collectively.
spective as background while focusing on the situation and A central outcome in the generation of network power is
opinions of another. The point is not to add up the voices and that participants in dialogue build a sense of shared identity as
seek the lowest common denominator but to hear and main- part of a system or community, and perhaps a changed identity
tain divergent perspectives in relation to each other.20 This is a of their own in the process. We do not build our identities as
crucial part of the effort to build on diversity. Awareness of the isolated individuals but as people or groups in a context and a
dissonance can also clarify the nature of conflicts that often community. A lone person on a desert island does not need an
may not be what they seem at first. Stakeholders may, for exam- identity, but once others arrive the issue of identity arises.
ple, take different positions on what strategy to take to clean up Building identity is done through conversation, as people try
an estuary or on how urgent it is to do so. But as they come to out various ways of thinking about themselves and ways of mak-
recognize each has valid reasons for differing positions, they ing sense of their experience and the world in which they live.
may recognize, for example, that the conflict is more over tim- The conversation may be real with other people, or imagined
ing or who pays rather than whether the estuary should be as we make assumptions about what others would say or how
cleaned up. Such a new problem frame for the conflict may others would see us. We need feedback from others, reassur-
allow new solutions to be developed. A group in which mem- ance or disagreement, to build identities as individuals,
bers recognize and accept divergent perspectives can take joint groups, or communities. More than at other times in history, as
action on some things while committing themselves to contin- Castells (1997) has contended, many people are preoccupied
uing to explore and address differences. This is effectively what with their identities. People today are less likely to know what
happened in the example of the Sacramento Water Forum. group to identify with, what values they want to adopt, or who
The environmentalist participants worked outside the Forum they want to be because they have so many choices. In authen-
to oppose the proposed federal legislation, while continuing tic dialogue, people get the opportunity to talk with others who
to explore possible resolutions of their differences with the are different but who also share an environment and context.
water agency participants who did not oppose the legislation. They can find what aspects of identity they share as well as
In the end, the legislation was defeated and the water agencies agree on how the identities of each can be articulated and dif-
found they could obtain what they needed through the Water ferentiated. They can in turn learn how they may be interde-
Forum process without the new dam. It is this continuing pendent and build new strategies using flexible linkages
exploration and search for ways to overcome or to build on dif- among themselves. For example, the environmentalists and
ference that gives a network its innovative power and generates the developers in the Sacramento Water Forum came to share
a potentially infinite range of possible choices. their identity as stakeholders who care about the water
In this context, we can see persuasion in a different light resources of the American and Sacramento Rivers, while
than we do when we are thinking in terms of the more conven- understanding how each other had different ways of depend-
tional notions of power. While persuasion is part of collabora- ing on that resource and different contributions to make to its
tion and building shared meaning, it is not, as is often protection. This combination of collaboration among diverse,
assumed, about having the power to get everyone to buy into interdependent stakeholders, dialogue, building shared
ones own version of the world or ones own answer (Conger meaning, and developing new heuristics feeds back into more
1998). Instead, it is about working collaboratively to develop cooperative action and more discovery of interdependence. It
ones own contribution and find the place for it in the total pic- is this process that generates the cumulative and growing effect
ture. Effective persuasion in this sense requires listening and of network power (see Figure 3).
232 Booher & Innes

Figure 3. Network power model.

The Roles of Planners values of the planning profession and able to communicate
with others who work on the issues. They are part of the flow of
As we explore the phenomenon of network power, it network power and help to shape how that power works and
becomes evident that planners play many key roles in making it what it produces.
possible, participating in it, shaping its form and direction,
influencing its outcomes, providing the opportunities for it,
and helping other agents to create and use it. The network Planning Education
model of power dissolves the dilemma that has made many
planners feel trapped in a no-win choice between serving For planning education to help its graduates to meet these
power or challenging it. Planning and policy professionals challenges, significant rethinking of what is taught will be
instead can be a key part of a self-organizing process that brings required. Planning students in the United States will need to
together agents, enables information to flow, builds trust and be far more sophisticated about politics and power than they
reciprocity, represents interests, connects networks, and mobi- are today. Most professional planning programs skim lightly
lizes action (see Figure 3). They have power of their own as over the political setting, if they deal with it at all. The word
nodes of this system and as agents who help build the network power is almost taboo in some curricula. Students of planning
of relationships and frame the communication flows. It is not and planners will need to spend more time developing collab-
up to planners to challenge or to acquiesce. Instead, they pro- oration skills. Learning to work with teams of other planners
vide informational power in shaping the procedures, pro- on projects is not nearly enough. They need to develop skills in
cesses, and agendas that may allow network power to emerge meeting design and management, facilitation, mediation, and
(Bryson and Crosby 1993; Innes and Booher 2000). They play a negotiation. They need to learn how to listen and how to com-
part in convening stakeholders and in making sure that pro- municate in ways that allow others to hear and enable others to
cesses can meet the conditions of network collaboration. They speak for themselves. They need to communicate in authentic
may serve as participants, technical or support staff, facilita- rather than formalistic ways, while maintaining their profes-
tors, or advocates. They are voices themselves speaking for the sionalism, and they need to enable others to communicate
Network Power in Collaborative Planning 233

authentically. They need to develop greater awareness of their 7. Innes (1996) has argued that this collaborative, consensus-
building model permits genuine comprehensive planning to be
own roles in shaping community or public attention, in estab-
done in the mode suggested by Kent (1964) in his Urban General
lishing rules and procedures, setting agendas, and framing Plan, whereas the rational-technical analyst model of planning was
issues. They need to become more reflective on these efforts so indeed at odds with comprehensive planning as Altshuler (1965)
they can use this power in a responsible and ethical way. Those suggested.
8. This debate has taken place at the meetings of the Associa-
who are primarily analysts need to learn to work with collabora-
tion of Collegiate Schools of Planning, the Association of Euro-
tive groups, providing information organized and designed in pean Schools of Planning, several conferences on planning theory
the way that makes sense to the group. They need to be willing at Oxford Brookes University, and in the Journal Planning Theory
and able to accept that there is no one best way to do an analy- (volumes 14 and 17, 1995 and 1997).
9. Some exceptions to this include Managing Complex Networks
sis. They need to be prepared to be quickly and respectfully
(Kickert, Klijn, and Koppenjan 1997), Collaborating (Gray 1991),
responsive to others. They also need to learn neither to be and The Consensus Building Handbook (Susskind, McKearnon, and
afraid of conflict nor to try to avoid it, but rather to work with Carpenter 1999).
differences constructively. They need to learn about and 10. Emery and Trist (1965), in their classic article, argue simi-
larly that in a turbulent environment cooperation between organi-
develop new ways of thinking about leadership in an informa-
zations in an organizational matrix becomes critical.
tional, networked age, when the effective processes are collab- 11. We have elsewhere explored this notion of complex adap-
orative rather than hierarchical. Most of all, planners and edu- tive systems as a productive metaphor for understanding change
cators need to embrace rather than shrink from what is new and action in planning and for evaluating collaborations (Innes
and Booher 1999a).
and experimental. That is what planning is about after all. It is
12. One historical example is the evolution of the Community
what planning has to be about at the threshold of the new Action Program that was part of the War on Poverty in the United
millennium. States in the late 1960s. Local community action boards were often
composed of representatives of stakeholders. However, in many
cases, these turned out to be primarily examples of co-optation
because the conditions for collaborative networks did not exist
Notes (Booher 1974; Moynihan 1969).
13. We should note that, like any model, these are ideal condi-
1. For a good review of power as it has been thought about in tions. In the real world of collaborative planning, they are present
planning, see Sager (1994). in less than a complete pattern. The extent to which they are pres-
2. More detail on the kinds of processes we are talking about ent will determine the extent and range of network power.
can be found in some of our work (Innes et al. 1994; Innes 1996; 14. Complexity theory first appeared in the physical sciences
Innes 1998a; Innes and Booher 1999b, 1999c) and that of a hand- (Prigogine and Stenger 1984; Nicolis and Prigogine 1989; Lewin
ful of others (Healey 1997). A definitive guidebook for consensus 1992; Waldrop 1992; Kauffman 1995). Increasingly, some scholars
building has also recently been published (Susskind, McKearnon, are arguing that this set of ideas can be powerful in understanding
and Carpenter 1999). the functioning of social systems (Kiel 1991; Wheatley 1992;
3. Curiously, these questions do not come up when we present Kauffman 1995; Hwang 1996). Key features relevant to collabora-
the ideas to those in the practice of policy making and planning. tive planning have been developed (Innes and Booher 1999a,
They nod assent as if this makes good sense to them. 1999c).
4. A study of 13 cases of growth and environmental manage- 15. For example, in the San Francisco Estuary Project, partici-
ment offers one example of what can be accomplished (Innes et al. pants from agriculture, the development community, environ-
1994). A comprehensive handbook on consensus building mental advocacy organizations, regulatory agencies, and local gov-
(Susskind, McKearnon, and Carpenter 1999) offers seventeen ernments were able, after extended dialogue, to agree on a status
detailed case examples in many realms of public policy. An emerg- and trends report on the condition of the estuary, which provided
ing movement to create partnerships among universities and their the basis for a comprehensive management plan (Innes and
surrounding communities is beginning to be documented in a Connick 1999).
series of articles in such journals as Metropolitan Universities and the 16. Our notion of heuristics is of a set of rules of thumb and
Journal of Planning Education and Research. Although the impacts of ideas that tacitly guide actions of individuals and groups. An exam-
these activities remain to be fully documented, what is clear is that ple is when individual representatives of business and environmen-
they are steadily growing in popularity and have been for the past tal interests would articulate the interest of the other when they
decade or more and substantial amounts of time and energy are were not present rather than allow a dialogue to go forward that
being put into them. did not recognize the absent agents interest (Innes et al. 1994).
5. This case has been made in more detail in two other articles Another form of shared heuristic is found in discourse coalitions
(Innes 1994, 1998b). (Hajer 1995), in which the participants share a set of meanings and
6. An extensive literature has explored the nature of power in therefore reactions to policy ideas and types of solutions they seek,
local communities. Several of the classics include Agger, Goldrich, without necessarily discussing the ideas among themselves. The
and Swanson (1964); Bachrach and Baratz (1970); Dahl (1961); concept of a heuristic may also include the notion of planning doc-
and Presthus (1964). All of these authors similarly seem to attest to trine (Alexander and Faludi 1996), a concept that guides planning
the apparent impotence of planners in local politics. so that many players incorporate the idea into their thinking, like
234 Booher & Innes

the Green Heart in the Netherlands or the Green Belt around Lon- . 1997. The complexity of cooperation: Agent-based models of com-
don. The concept of a heuristic includes flocking programs that petition and collaboration. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University
can produce birdlike flocking behaviors with computers using sim- Press.
ple rules encoded into an algorithm such as dont bump into each Bachrach, P., and M. S. Baratz. 1970. Power and poverty: Theory and
other, but keep up with your neighbors, and dont stray too far. practice. New York: Oxford University Press.
One of these was used to create the bats flying through the tunnels Banfield, E. C. 1961. Political influence: A new theory of urban politics.
in the movie Batman Returns (Kelly 1994). New York: Free Press.
17. This dynamic occurs in part as a result of a well-managed Bendor, J., and P. Swistak. 1997. The evolutionary stability of coop-
group process itself (Johnson and Johnson 1997). The diversity of eration. American Political Science Review 91 (2): 290-307.
the group contributes to the potential for innovation, although it Bickford, S. 1996. The dissonance of democracy: Listening, conflict and
can also contribute to the challenge of developing a constructive citizenship. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press.
dialogue to begin with. Blau, P. 1964. Exchange and power in social life. New York: John Wiley
18. Habermas (1981) and the other critical theorists would also and Sons.
add that emancipatory knowledge requires the knower to side with Bohm, D. 1992. Thought as a system. London: Routledge.
the oppressed and challenge the status quo. But if all stakeholders Booher, D. E. 1974. A theory of participatory planning. Masters
are at the table, inevitably some will be those who are oppressed. If thesis in planning, University of Tennessee, Knoxville.
they are given the ability to speak for themselves, the dialogue will Brown, S. L., and K. M. Eisenhardt. 1998. Competing on the edge:
involve challenges to the status quo. Strategy as structured chaos. Boston: Harvard Business School
19. There are other aspects of rational choice theory that are Press.
potentially relevant to collaborative planning. For example, Olson Bryson, J. M., and B. C. Crosby. 1992. Leadership for the common good:
(1965) has shown that large groups organized for collective eco- Tackling public problems in a shared power world. San Francisco:
nomic purpose cannot be maintained solely by pursuit of that pur- Jossey-Bass.
pose. There must be other benefits of continued participation . 1993. Policy planning the design and use of forums, are-
(Olson 1965). On the other hand, rational choice theories have nas, and courts. Environment and Planning B: Planning and
their limitations. For example, the model proposed by Riker Design 20:175-94.
(1962) relies fundamentally on complete and perfect informa- Buchanan, J. M., and G. Tullock. 1967. The calculus of consent. Ann
tion, a condition far from the reality of the informational age. A Arbor: University of Michigan Press.
fair reading of his predictions for world affairs in chapter 10 com- Castells, M. 1996. The rise of the network society. The Information Age:
pared to the actual unfolding of world affairs over the past thirty Economy, society and culture. Vol 1. Cambridge, MA: Blackwell.
years support the limitations of the model (Riker 1962). For other . 1997. The power of identity. The Information Age: Economy, soci-
critiques of rational choice theory compared to agent-based net- ety and culture. Vol. 2. Malden, MA: Blackwell.
works, see Epstein (1999). We leave an exploration of such inter- Cilliers, P. 1998. Complexity and postmodernism: Understanding com-
esting topics for another time. plex systems. London: Routledge.
20. For example, in a case in which an impasse had been Conger, J. A. 1998. The necessary art of persuasion. Harvard Busi-
reached among environmental and neighborhood groups and ness Review 76 (3): 84-107.
transportation providers, a creative solution emerged that pro- Connick, Sarah. Forthcoming. The use of collaborative processes in the
vided new environmental protections and access for the neighbor- making of California water policy: The San Francisco Estuary Project,
hoods along with the new transit station that the state agency CALFED Bay Delta Program and the Sacramento Area Water Forum.
wanted to build (Susskind 1981). Dissertation, University of California, Berkeley.
21. Throgmorton (1996) has written about the importance of Dahl, R. 1961. Who governs: Democracy and power in an American city.
planning as persuasive storytelling in planning debates. Our own New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.
research also suggests that stories and images play a crucial part in Davis, S., and C. Meyer. 1998. Blur: The speed of change in the connected
the emerging understanding, commitment, and creativity of suc- economy. Reading, MA: Addison-Wesley.
cessful consensus building (Innes and Booher 1999b). de Neufville, J. I. 1975. Social indicators and public policy: Interactive
processes of design and application. Amsterdam: Elsevier.
Downs, A. 1957. An economic theory of democracy. New York: Harper &
Row.
References Emery, F. E., and E. L. Trist. 1965. The causal texture of organiza-
tional environments. Human Relations 18:21-32.
Agger, R., D. Goldrich, and B. E. Swanson. 1964. The rulers and the Epstein, J. M. 1999. Agent-based computational models and gener-
ruled: Political power and impotence in American communities. New ative social science. Complexity 4 (5): 41-60.
York: John Wiley and Sons. Epstein, J. M., and R. Axtell. 1996. Growing artificial societies: Social
Alexander, E. R., and A. Faludi. 1996. Planning doctrine: Its uses science from the bottom up. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution
and implications. Planning Theory 16 (winter): 11-61. Press.
Altshuler, A. 1965. The city planning process: A political analysis. Fisher, R. 1983. Negotiating power: Getting and using influence.
Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press. American Behavioral Scientist 27 (2): 149-66.
Arquilla, J., and D. Ronfeldt. 1997. In Athenas camp. Santa Monica, Fisher, R., and W. Ury. 1981. Getting to yes: Negotiating agreement with-
CA: RAND. out giving in. Boston: Houghton Mifflin.
Arrow, K. 1963. Social choice and individual values. New Haven, CT: Flyvbjerg, B. 1998. Rationality and power: Democracy in practice. Chi-
Yale University Press. cago: University of Chicago Press.
Axelrod, R. 1984. The evolution of cooperation. New York: Basic Forester, J. 1989. Planning in the face of power. Berkeley: University of
Books. California Press.
Network Power in Collaborative Planning 235

Fox, C. J., and H. T. Miller. 1996. Postmodern public administration: tive planning. Journal of the American Planning Association 65 (4):
Toward discourse. Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage. 412-23.
Frederick, W. C. 1995. Values, nature, and culture in the American cor- . 1999b. Consensus building as role playing and bricolage:
poration. New York: Oxford University Press. Toward a theory of collaborative planning. Journal of the Ameri-
Friend, J. K., J. M. Power, and C.J.L. Yewlett. 1974. Public planning: can Planning Association 66 (1): 9-26.
The inter-corporate dimension. London: Tavistock. . 1999c. Metropolitan development as a complex system: A
Galbraith, J. K. 1983. The anatomy of power. Boston: Houghton new approach to sustainability. Economic Development Quarterly
Mifflin. 13 (2): 141-56.
Giddens, A. 1984. The constitution of society: Outline of the theory of . 2000. Planning institutions in the network society: Theory
structuration. Berkeley: University of California Press. for collaborative planning. In The revival of strategic spatial plan-
Gray, Barbara. 1991. Collaborating: Finding common ground for multi- ning, edited by Willem Salet and Andreas Faludi, 175-89.
party problems. San Francisco: Jossey-Bass. Amsterdam: Royal Amsterdam Academy of Arts and Science.
Gruber, J. 1994. Coordinating growth management through consensus- Innes, J. E., and S. Connick. 1999. The San Francisco Estuary
building: Incentives and the generation of social, intellectual, and Project: Case 5. In The consensus building handbook, edited by
political capital. IURD Working Paper Series, No. 617. Berkeley: L. Susskind, S. McKearnon, S. Thomas, and J. T. Larmer. Thou-
Institute of Urban and Regional Development, University of sand Oaks, CA: Sage.
California. Innes, J. E., J. Gruber, M. Neuman, and R. Thompson. 1994. Coordi-
Habermas, J. 1981. The theory of communicative action: Reason and the nating growth and environmental management through consensus
rationalization of society. Vol. 1. Translated by Thomas McCarthy. building. CPS Report: A Policy Research Program report. Berkeley:
Boston: Beacon. California Policy Seminar.
Hajer, M. A. 1995. The politics of environmental discourse: Ecological Johnson, D. W., and F. P. Johnson. 1997. Joining together: Group theory
modernization and the policy process. Oxford, UK: Oxford Univer- and group skills. 6th ed. Boston: Allyn & Bacon.
sity Press. Kauffman, S. 1995. At home in the universe. London: Viking.
Harvey, D. 1989. The urban experience. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins Kelly, K. 1994. Out of control: The rise of the neobiological civilization.
University Press. Reading, MA: Addison-Wesley.
Healey, P. 1993. Planning through debate: The communicative Kent, T. 1964. The urban general plan. San Francisco: Chandler.
turn in planning theory. In The argumentative turn in policy analy- Kickert, J.M.W., E. H. Klijn, and J.F.M. Koppenjan. 1997. Managing
sis and planning, edited by F. Fischer and J. Forester, 233-53. complex networks: Strategies for the public sector. London: Sage.
Durham, NC: Duke University Press. Kiel, D. L. 1991. Lessons from the nonlinear paradigm: Applica-
. 1997. Collaborative planning: Shaping places in fragmented soci- tions of the theory of dissipative structures in the social sci-
eties. Planning-environment-cities. London: Macmillan. ences. Social Sciences Quarterly 7:431-42.
Hoch, C. 1994. What planners do: Power, politics and persuasion. Chi- Kolb, D., and Associates, eds. 1994. When talk works: Profiles of media-
cago: Planners. tors. San Francisco: Jossey-Bass.
Holland, J. 1998. Emergence: From chaos to order. Reading, MA: Kotter, J. P. 1985. Power and influence: Beyond formal authority. New
Addison-Wesley. York: Free Press.
Howe, E. 1980. Role choices of urban planners. Journal of the Ameri- Lao Tzu. 1995. The Tao Te Ching. Translated by B. B. Walker. New
can Planning Association 46 (4): 398-409. York: St. Martins Griffin.
. 1994. Acting on ethics in city planning. New Brunswick: Cen- Lewin, R. 1992. Complexity: Life at the edge of chaos. New York:
ter for Urban Policy Research, Rutgers, the State University of Macmillan.
New Jersey. Long, N. E. 1958. The local community as an ecology of games.
Huberman, B. 1998. Collective problem-solving. Embracing complexity: American Journal of Sociology 64:251-61.
A colloquium on the application of complex adaptive systems to busi- Mandelbaum, Seymour J., Luigi Mazza, and Robert W. Burchell,
ness. Cambridge, MA: Ernst & Young Center for Business eds. 1996. Explorations in planning theory. New Brunswick, NJ:
Innovation. Center for Urban Policy Research, Rutgers, State University of
Hwang, S. W. 1996. The implications of the nonlinear paradigm New Jersey.
for integrated environmental design and planning. Journal of Mitchell, J. H. 1998. Complexity and battle management. Embracing
Planning Literature 11:167-80. complexity: A colloquium on the application of complex adaptive sys-
Innes, J. E. 1994. Planning institutions in crisis. Planning Theory 10/ tems to business. Cambridge, MA: Ernst & Young Center for Busi-
11:81-96. ness Innovation.
. 1995. Planning theorys emerging paradigm: Communica- Moore, J. F. 1996. The death of competition: Leadership and strategy in
tive action and interactive practice. Journal of Planning Educa- the age of business ecosystems. New York: Harper Business.
tion and Research 14 (3): 183-89. Morris, Elizabeth. 1998. Urban redevelopment and the emerging
. 1996. Planning through consensus building: A new view of community sector. Dissertation, Department of City and
the comprehensive planning ideal. Journal of the American Regional Planning, University of California, Berkeley.
Planning Association 62 (4): 460-72. Moynihan, P. 1969. Maximum feasible misunderstanding. New York:
. 1998a. Information in communicative planning. Journal of Free Press.
the American Planning Association 64 (1): 52-63. Nicolis, G., and I. Prigogine. 1989. Exploring complexity. New York:
. 1998b. Viewpoint: Challenge and creativity in postmodern Freeman.
planning. Town Planning Review April:v-ix. Olson, M. 1965. The logic of collective action: Public goods and the theory
Innes, J. E., and D. E. Booher. 1999a. Consensus building and com- of groups. New York: Schocken.
plex adaptive systems: A framework for evaluating collabora-
236 Booher & Innes

Ostrom, Elinor. 1990. Governing the commons: The evolution of institu- Stacey, R. 1998. Complexity and creativity in organizations. Embracing
tions for collective action. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University complexity: A colloquium on the application of complex adaptive sys-
Press. tems to business. Cambridge, MA: Ernst & Young Center for Busi-
. 1998. A behavioral approach to the rational choice theory ness Innovation.
of collective action. American Political Science Review 92 (1): 1-22. Stone, C. N., R. K. Whelan, and W. J. Murin. 1986. Urban policy and
Petzinger, T. 1999. The new pioneers: The men and women who are trans- politics in a bureaucratic age. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice Hall.
forming the workplace and marketplace. New York: Simon & Susskind, L. 1981. Citizen participation and consensus building in
Schuster. land use planning: A case study. In The land use policy debate in the
Presthus, R. 1964. Men at the top: A study in community power. New United States, edited by J. I. de Neufville, chap. 14. New York:
York: Oxford University Press. Plenum.
Prigogine, I., and I. Stenger. 1984. Order out of chaos. New York: Susskind, L., and J. Cruikshank. 1987. Breaking the impasse: Consen-
Bantam. sual approaches to resolving public disputes. New York: Basic Books.
Raiffa, H. 1982. The art and science of negotiation. Cambridge, MA: Susskind, L., S. McKearnon, and S. Carpenter. 1999. The consensus
Harvard University Press. building handbook. Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage.
Riker, W. H. 1962. The theory of political coalitions. New Haven, CT: Throgmorton, J. A. 1996. Planning as persuasive storytelling: The rhe-
Yale University Press. torical construction of Chicagos electric future. Chicago: University
Sager, T. 1994. Communicative planning theory. Aldershot, UK: of Chicago Press.
Avebury. Thucydides. 1952. History of the Peloponnesian War. Chicago:
Sarason, S. B., and E. Lorentz. 1979. The challenge of the resource Encyclopaedia Britannica.
exchange network. San Francisco: Jossey-Bass. Vasu, M. L. 1979. Politics and planning: A national study of American
Saxenian, A. 1994. Regional advantage: Culture and competition in Sili- planners. Chapel Hill: University of North Carolina Press.
con Valley and Route 128. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Waldrop, M. M. 1992. Complexity: The emerging science at the edge of
Press. chaos. New York: Simon & Schuster.
Schon, D. A. 1983. The reflective practitioner: How professionals think in Warren, R. L. 1967. The interorganization field as a focus for inves-
action. New York: Basic Books. tigation. Administrative Science Quarterly 12:396-419.
Schrage, M. 1990. Shared minds: The new technologies of collaboration. Warren, R. L., S. M. Rose, and A. F. Bergunder. 1974. The structure of
New York: Random House. urban reform: Community decision organizations in stability and
Selznick, P. 1966. TVA and the grass roots: A study in the sociology of for- change. Lexington, MA: DC Heath & Co.
mal organizations. New York: Harper & Row. Weiss, M. 1987. The rise of the community builders: The American real
Society of Professionals in Dispute Resolution. 1997. Best practices estate industry and urban land planning. New York: Columbia
for government agencies: Guidelines for using collaborative agreement- University Press.
seeking processes. Washington, DC: Society of Dispute Resolution Wheatley, M. 1992. Leadership and the new science. San Francisco:
Professionals. Berret-Koehler.

You might also like