You are on page 1of 10

Journal of Banking & Finance 37 (2013) 21732182

Contents lists available at SciVerse ScienceDirect

Journal of Banking & Finance


journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/jbf

Funding liquidity risk: Definition and measurement


Mathias Drehmann a,, Kleopatra Nikolaou b
a
Bank for International Settlements, Centralbahnplatz 2, 4002 Basel, Switzerland
b
European Central Bank, Kaiserstrasse 29, 60311 Frankfurt am Main, Germany

a r t i c l e i n f o a b s t r a c t

Article history: Funding liquidity risk has played a key role in all historical banking crises. Nevertheless, a measure for
Available online 8 January 2012 funding liquidity risk based on publicly available data remains so far elusive. We address this gap by
showing that aggressive bidding at central bank auctions reveals funding liquidity risk. We can extract
JEL classification: an insurance premium from banks bids which we propose as a measure of funding liquidity risk. Using
E58 a unique data set consisting of all bids in all auctions for the main refinancing operation conducted at the
G21 ECB between June 2005 and October 2008 we find that funding liquidity risk is typically stable and low,
Keywords:
with occasional spikes especially around key events during the recent crisis. We also document down-
Funding liquidity ward spirals between funding liquidity risk and market liquidity. As measurement without clear defini-
Liquidity risk tions is impossible, we initially provide definitions of funding liquidity and funding liquidity risk.
Bidding behaviour ! 2012 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.
Central bank auctions

1. Introduction Ideally and in line with other risks, we would want to measure
funding liquidity risk by the distribution summarising the stochas-
Funding liquidity risk has played a key role in all historical tic nature of the underlying risk factors. This is impossible as these
banking crises. Recent events are not different. The global credit distributions cannot be estimated because of a lack of data, even
crisis bore all the hallmarks of a funding liquidity crisis as inter- for banks with access to more (confidential) information. Against
bank markets collapsed and central banks around the globe had this drawback, we propose a new approach for measuring funding
to intervene in money markets at unprecedented levels. Nonethe- liquidity risk. We extract funding liquidity risk from observing the
less, a concrete measure of funding liquidity risk based on readily costs that banks are willing to pay in order to secure liquidity from
available data remains so far elusive. This paper addresses this gap the central bank. The underlying trade-off at the central bank auc-
by showing that banks bids during open market operations reveal tion is whether to obtain liquidity from the central bank directly or
funding liquidity risk. rely on other markets for liquidity. By submitting aggressive bids
Measurement without definition is, however, difficult if not above the expected marginal rate (i.e. the rate which equates the
impossible. In this paper we define funding liquidity as the ability aggregate demand for central bank money with its supply), the
to settle obligations with immediacy. It follows that, a bank is illiquid bank is very likely to obtain funds from the central bank. Thereby
if it is unable to settle obligations in time. Consequently, we define it can insure against becoming illiquid. This is intuitive. But it can
funding liquidity risk as the possibility that over a specific horizon the also be shown theoretically that banks bid more at higher prices,
bank will become unable to settle obligations with immediacy. In con- the greater their funding liquidity risk (Nyborg and Strebulaev,
trast to other definitions used by academics and practitioners, our 2004; Valimaki, 2006).
definitions have important properties, shared by definitions of Putting it differently, a banks bid reveals its funding liquidity
other types of risk. First, like solvency, funding liquidity is a risk. This is highly useful information, as it is a real time measure
point-in-time and a binary concept as a bank is either able to settle of bank specific funding liquidity risk, which is otherwise hardly
obligations or not. Funding liquidity risk, on the other hand, can available. For confidentiality reasons, we cannot show bank specific
take infinitely many values depending on the underlying funding bids. But using this insight, we demonstrate that aggregate funding
position of the bank. As any other risk, it is forward looking and liquidity risk can be measured by the sum of the premia banks are
measured over a specific horizon. willing to pay above the expected marginal rate (i.e. the expected
interest rate which will clear the auction) times the volume they
Corresponding author. Tel.: +41 61 280 8089; fax: +41 61 280 9100. bid, normalised by the expected amount of money supplied by the
E-mail addresses: mathias.drehmann@bis.org (M. Drehmann), kleopatra.niko central bank. This measure can be interpreted as the weighted aver-
laou@ecb.int (K. Nikolaou). age insurance premium against funding liquidity risk.

0378-4266/$ - see front matter ! 2012 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.
doi:10.1016/j.jbankfin.2012.01.002
2174 M. Drehmann, K. Nikolaou / Journal of Banking & Finance 37 (2013) 21732182

We construct our measure with the help of a unique data set of liquidity risk as the possibility that over a specific horizon the bank will
171 main refinancing operation (MRO) auctions, conducted be- become unable to settle obligations with immediacy.
tween June 2005 and October 2008 in the euro area, involving It is worth to highlight important differences between funding
more than 1000 different banks. Expected marginal rates are taken liquidity and funding liquidity risk: Funding liquidity is essentially
from a new survey dataset from Reuters. To the best of our knowl- a binary concept, i.e. a bank can either settle obligations or not.
edge, this is the first time that this kind of data set has been used. Funding liquidity risk on the other hand can take infinitely many
We find that our proposed measure has intuitive properties. Prior values as it is related to the distribution of future outcomes. Impli-
to the crisis, the average insurance premium was less than one basis cit in this distinction is also a different time horizon. Funding
point. Funding liquidity risk increased rapidly after August 2007 and liquidity is associated with one particular point in time. Funding
spiked after the rescue of Northern Rock. Following the failure of liquidity risk on the other hand is always forward looking and mea-
Bear Sterns liquidity risk rose sharply again, even though to less ele- sured over a specific horizon. In this respect, concerns about the fu-
vated levels. Unsurprisingly, our measure identifies record pres- ture ability to settle obligations, i.e. future funding liquidity, will
sures in October 2008 after Lehman failed, when the average impact on current funding liquidity risk. Therefore, the distinction
insurance premium rose to over 40 basis points. More generally, between liquidity and liquidity risk is straightforward and analo-
our measure shares characteristics such as a high degree of persis- gous to other risks. For example, a similar distinction can be made
tence with occasional spikes, which have been documented by mar- between credit risk and default. Whilst default either occurs or
ket participants using banks own models (e.g., Matz and Neu, 2007; does not, credit risk is associated with the likelihood that the bor-
Banks, 2005). Moreover, these properties are also shared by mea- rower will default over a particular horizon.1
sures for market liquidity (e.g., Amihud, 2002; Chordia et al., 2005). Surprisingly, a distinction in the definition of funding liquidity and
Our measure also allows us to assess the interactions of market funding liquidity risk has not been made by practitioners and academ-
liquidity and funding liquidity risk. Whilst this has been shown ics so far. Borio (2000), Strahan (2008) or Brunnermeier and Pedersen
theoretically (e.g., Brunnermeier and Pedersen, 2009) and anec- (2009) for example, define funding liquidity as the ability to raise cash
dotal evidence points to these effects in the recent crisis, the inter- at short notice either via asset sales or new borrowing. Whilst it is the
action between both liquidity measures has not been shown case that banks can settle all their obligations in a timely fashion if they
empirically due to a lack of measures for funding liquidity risk. can raise (sufficient) cash at short notice, the reverse is not true as a
Using our measure, we are able to show that there are strong neg- bank may well be able to settle its obligations as long as its current
ative interrelationships between funding liquidity risk and a mea- stock of cash is large enough to cover all outflows. As the ability to raise
sure for market liquidity. In this sense, higher funding liquidity risk cash can vanish (Borio, 2000) this definition is implicitly forward look-
implies lower market liquidity. ing and therefore associated to funding liquidity risk. The IMF defines
Finally, our measure significantly improves on other risk mea- funding liquidity as the ability of a solvent institution to make
sures. For example, money market spreads have been a common agreed-upon payments in a timely fashion (p. xi, IMF, 2008). This def-
reference point for practitioners, policy makers and academics to inition carries the notion that liquidity is related to the ability to settle
describe tensions prevailing during the current financial crisis. obligations. However, it is crucial to distinguish liquidity and solvency
We show that the EURIBOR-OIS spread is much higher than our as welfare losses associated with illiquidity arise precisely when sol-
proposed measure. This is not unsurprising as the former is af- vent institutions become illiquid. The definition of the Basel Commit-
fected by a host of other risk factors and therefore is not a clean tee of Banking Supervision is close to our definition even though it
measure of funding liquidity risk (e.g., Gyntelberg and Wooldridge, mixes the concepts of funding liquidity and funding liquidity risk.
2008). Moreover, although no direct comparison is provided be- In their view liquidity is the ability to fund increases in assets and
tween our measure and banks own measures of funding liquidity meet obligations as they come due, without incurring unacceptable
risk as data are unavailable, the latter are also not useful to mea- losses (BCBS, 2008, p. 1). The first part of this definition is essen-
sure funding liquidity risk on an aggregate basis. They rely entirely tially equivalent to ours. However, it is unclear what unacceptable
on confidential information and contain a lot of judgement (e.g., losses really means.
Matz and Neu, 2007), thereby preventing appropriate aggregation. Our definition raises the question how banks settle obligations.
The remainder of the paper is structured as follows. In Section 2 Most transactions, especially those involving private agents, are
we introduce our definition of funding and funding liquidity risk settled in commercial bank money. However, central bank money
and discuss how this relates to other definitions in the literature. plays a crucial role for transactions between banks. In the Eurosys-
After providing a short overview of OMOs in the euro areas in Sec- tem, but also in most other economies, large value payment and
tion 3, we show that higher funding liquidity risk will result in higher settlement systems rely on central bank money as the ultimate set-
bids during OMOs in Section 4. Section 5 introduces our measure and tlement asset (CPSS, 2003).2 While banks can create commercial
Section 6 presents data used. In Section 7 we present the results. Fur- bank money, the volume of central bank money is determined by
ther discussion is provided in Section 8. Finally, Section 9 concludes. central banks. Therefore, the ability to settle obligations, and hence
funding liquidity risk, is determined by the ability to satisfy the de-
mand for central bank money.3

2. Definition of funding liquidity and funding liquidity risk 2.2. Funding liquidity as a stock-flow concept

2.1. Funding liquidity and funding liquidity risk Based on our definition, it is easy to see that a bank is able to
satisfy the demand for (central bank) money, and hence is liquid,
Liquidity risk arises because revenues and outlays are not syn-
chronised (Holmstrm and Tirole, 1998). This would not matter if 1
A broader definition of credit risk also accounts for the stochastic nature of loss
agents could issue financial contracts to third parties, pledging their given default, changes in the underlying credit quality and changes in the exposure at
future income as collateral. Given frictions, this is not always possi- default.
2
Central bank money consists mainly of deposits held by commercial banks with
ble in reality and agents may become illiquid. We define funding
the central bank. Central bank money has also been labelled high powered money in
liquidity as the ability to settle obligations with immediacy. Conse- the monetary economics literature.
quently, a bank is illiquid if it is unable to settle obligations. Legally, 3
The role of central bank money as a settlement asset is elaborated further in the
a bank is then in default. Given this definition we define funding working paper version (Drehmann and Nikolaou, 2010).
M. Drehmann, K. Nikolaou / Journal of Banking & Finance 37 (2013) 21732182 2175

as long as at each point in time outflows of (central bank) money euro area.5 Additionally, the ECB can undertake fine-tuning opera-
are smaller or equal to inflows plus the stock of (central bank) tions in case of a need for an additional and extraordinary injection
money held by the bank:4 or absorption of central bank money.
MROs form the basis of our measure. Note that this means that
Outflowst 6 Inflowst Stock of Moneyt 1
we measure funding liquidity risk over a one week horizon. In our
We focus on the net volume of money needed to avoid illiquidity. sample, MROs are conducted as variable rate tenders.6 The auction
We construct the net-liquidity demand (NLD) from the stock flow set-up is as follows: Eligible banks can submit bids (volume and
constraint above. Namely, we take the difference between all out- price) at up to ten different bid rates at the precision of one basis
flows (Outflows) and contractual (i.e. known) inflows (Inflowsdue) point (0.01%). Prices and volumes are unconstrained, except for the
net of the stock of central bank money (M): minimum bid rate, which equals the policy rate set by the Governing
Council. The aggregate supply of liquidity also called total allot-
due
NLDt Outflowst % Inflowst % Mt ment is determined by the ECB. The auction is price-discriminat-
ing, i.e. every successful bidder has to pay her bid. The marginal
6 pDt LDnew;t pIB IB A CB
t Lnew;t pt Asold;t pt CBnew;t 2
rate is the interest rate when aggregate demand equals supply. At
In case of a deficit (i.e. outflows are larger than inflows and the the marginal rate, depending on the aggregate bid schedule, bids
stock of money), the inequality highlights that NLDt has to be fi- may be rationed, so that everyone takes the same pro rata amount
nanced either by new borrowing from depositors (LDnew ), from the of the remaining liquidity. Banks are only required to submit suffi-
interbank market (LIBnew ), selling assets (Asold) or accessing the central
cient collateral for the allotted liquidity.
bank (CBnew). All these sources have different prices p. If there is a Under normal conditions, the total allotment in the weekly
positive net liquidity demand which cannot be funded with new in- MROs is determined by the benchmark allotment. This is the vol-
flows, the bank will become illiquid and default. Conversely, if the ume that satisfies exactly these needs for central bank money in
bank has an excess supply of liquidity, no borrowing is necessary aggregate and is calculated as the sum of the autonomous factor
and the bank can sell the excess liquidity on the market. Note that forecasts (such as banknotes, government deposits and net foreign
this means that ex-post inflows always equal outflows, as long as assets) and banks reserve requirements.7 This forecast, technically
the bank does not fail. called benchmark at announcement, is published prior to the auc-
Ex-ante, Eq. (2) highlights that funding liquidity risk is driven tion. The ECB can deviate from the forecast and provide more or less
by two stochastic components: future developments of NLD (i.e. liquidity after it received all the bids, even though the distribution of
volumes) and future prices of liquidity in different markets. And deviations is skewed towards the positive side. As central bank oper-
in this sense, funding liquidity risk is not independent of other ations are primarily monetary policy operations with a purpose to
risks. For instance, market liquidity risk affects prices in asset mar- steer market rates close to the policy rate, the ECB made use of this
kets (pA) highlighting the potential interactions between market option to a larger extent after the beginning of the crisis. During this
and funding liquidity risk (as shown by Brunnermeier and Peder- period the ECB front-loaded liquidity requirements. Front loading
sen, 2009), something we will explore empirically in Section 7.3. is an allotment practice, where the central bank provides liquidity
Equally, the price of borrowing in the interbank market (pIB) may above the benchmark in the beginning of the maintenance period,
depend on the credit risk of the institution. and close to or just below the benchmark towards the end of the
The question for this paper is how to measure funding liquidity maintenance period, possibly in combination with liquidity absorb-
risk. Ideally, and in line with other risks, we would want to mea- ing operations. In doing so, the central bank makes sure that banks
sure funding liquidity risk by the distribution jointly summarising fulfil their reserve requirements early in the maintenance period.
the stochastic nature of in- and outflows as well as prices. But, even In times of crisis this helps to stabilise the overnight rate. Clearly,
banks with access to far more data are unable to construct such a market participants try to anticipate the ECB behaviour when sub-
distribution. For example, it is impossible to estimate prices of, and mitting bids. We take this endogeneity into account when construct-
access to, liquidity in different markets in stressed conditions, as ing our measure (see Section 5).
crises occur too rarely to use standard statistical tools.
We propose a different approach to measure funding liquidity 4. Funding liquidity risk and bidding behaviour at OMOs
risk, which incorporates information on both volumes and the
price of liquidity. We observe banks bids (rates and volumes) dur- In this section we show that funding liquidity risk is revealed by
ing central bank operations (or pCB t CBnew;t in the language of Eq. (2)). the price banks are willing to pay during open market operations. In
In Section 4 we explain that banks with higher funding liquidity particular we show that aggregate liquidity risk can be measured by
risk will bid more aggressively and the more so the higher their the sum of the premia banks are willing to pay above the expected
funding liquidity risk. A short overview over the institutional back- marginal rate times the volume they bid, normalised by the ex-
ground of open market operations (OMOs) in the euro area may be pected total allotment. This measure can be interpreted as the
useful in that respect. weighted average insurance premium against funding liquidity risk.

3. Open market operations in the euro area 6


In October 2008 the ECB changed the tender procedure to full allotment at the
fixed rate prevailing at the MRO. Under the new framework, only the volumes of
liquidity demand are revealed but not the price. As a result, our measure as presented
We use data from 1 June 2005 until 7 October 2008. During this
here does not apply on the new auction design after October 2008. However, we
time OMOs are mainly conducted as short-term main refinancing conjecture that volumes bid still reveal funding pressures as the rates in the interbank
operations (MROs) or longer-term refinancing operations (LTROs). markets for good banks are below the policy rate.
MROs are carried out weekly and have a maturity of one week. Tra- 7
In the euro area individual banks have to fulfil reserve requirements. Banks are
ditionally MROs have provided the main bulk of liquidity to the allowed to hold positive or negative (relative) reserve balances with the CB within a
specified period; i.e. relative to their requirements banks can hold more or less.
Negative current accounts, so-called intraday credit, have to be collateralised and will
4
This section draws on earlier unpublished work by Drehmann, Elliot and Kapadia, be referred to the marginal lending facility at the end of the day. Reserve
which is now incorporated in Kapadia et al. (forthcoming). requirements have to be fulfilled on average across the maintenance period (usually
5
This has changed with the onset of the crisis in August 2007, when the between 28 and 35 days). At the start of the maintenance period the reserve
heightened uncertainties lead to an increase in the liquidity demand for longer requirements are determined by the Eurosystem for each bank and remain fixed
horizons. during the period.
2176 M. Drehmann, K. Nikolaou / Journal of Banking & Finance 37 (2013) 21732182

Period 1 Primary market: Auction conducted by the central bank


marginal facilities are fixed, the interest rate in period 2 purely re-
flects the expectations of the amount and likelihood of accessing
Liquidity shocks either facility in period 3. But at time 1, banks expect that the inter-
est rate in the interbank market equals the policy rate, as the cen-
Period 2 Secondary market: Trading in the interbank market tral bank is assumed to provide the right expected amount of
aggregate liquidity. Given risk neutrality, all banks therefore bid
Period 3 Final settlement: Banks can access marginal facilities at the central bank at the minimum bid rate as they are indifferent between obtaining
liquidity in the primary auction or from the interbank markets.
Fig. 1. Stylised time line.
Hence, our proposed measure would indicate no risk. However,
the assumption of risk neutral banks and frictionless interbank
The theoretical literature assessing the bidding behaviour of markets is unrealistic, particularly during times of stress. If we re-
banks during open market operations started with Poole (1968). lax these assumptions, higher bids reveal higher liquidity risk.
It generally considers a stylised time line. In the simplest case, it
consists of three periods (see Fig. 1). In period 1, banks can acquire
liquidity in the primary market by participating in the auction con- 4.2. Bidding with interbank market frictions
ducted by the central bank. Afterwards, liquidity shocks material-
ise. In period 2, banks trade in the interbank market. After It has been theoretically shown that asymmetric information
interbank markets close in period 3, all obligations are settled (e.g., Flannery, 1996), co-ordination failures (e.g., Rochet and Vives,
and banks have to fulfil their reserve requirements set by the cen- 2004), uncertainly about future liquidity needs (e.g., Holmstrm
tral bank.8 At this point, the market in aggregate may be short (or and Tirole, 2001) or incomplete markets (e.g., Allen and Gale,
long) of liquidity and hence some banks may have to access the mar- 2000) are all frictions which lead to funding liquidity risk. Such
ginal lending (deposit) facility. Prices for the marginal facilities are frictions imply that a bank which has to raise liquidity in the inter-
considered key policy rates and are determined by the central bank. bank market may have to pay more than the market rate to obtain
Therefore, they are already known in period 1. At the same time, it. In the extreme, prices may even be infinite if a bank is rationed
these prices constitute an upper and lower bound for the interest (e.g., Stiglitz and Weiss, 1981) or markets break down completely
rate in the interbank market in period 2, given that a bank with suf- (e.g., Heider et al., 2009).9
ficient collateral can always recourse to the standing facilities at per- Banks with high liquidity risk anticipate this before they submit
iod 3 to settle any liquidity imbalances. For our sample period, banks their bids. The underlying trade-off is whether to obtain liquidity
paid 100 bp on top of (below) the policy rate to access the marginal from the central bank (period 1 in Fig. 1) or rely on other markets
lending (deposit) facility. for liquidity (period 2), which may be very costly. By submitting
To assess the bidding behaviour of banks and how this relates to aggressive bids at the central bank auction, the bank is very likely
liquidity risk, it is important to distinguish interbank markets with to obtain funds from the central bank. Thereby it can insure itself
and without frictions. Note, that throughout the discussion we only against becoming illiquid. It is intuitive that a bank with higher risk
consider price discriminating auctions, which is the auction design is willing to pay a higher premium. Nyborg and Strebulaev (2004)
used by the ECB. Moreover, we follow the literature and assume show formally that, short banks (i.e. banks which do need to
throughout the theoretical discussion that the central bank accu- raise cash from the central bank or the interbank market to settle
rately provides the necessary and known (expected) amount of all obligations) will bid more aggressively than long banks (i.e.
central bank money, independent of the bids it receives. banks which have excess funds), even if all banks are risk neutral.10
In particular, Nyborg and Strebulaev analyse the case where long
banks have some market power during trading in the secondary
4.1. Bidding with frictionless interbank markets
market, so that they can squeeze short banks and demand higher
interest rates.11 Short banks can avoid being squeezed if they obtain
If interbank markets are frictionless and banks are risk neutral,
sufficient funds from the central bank during the OMO. And to en-
it is optimal for banks to only bid at the minimum bid rate (e.g.,
sure that they get the required funds, they have to bid above the ex-
Ayuso and Repullo, 2003). No bank is, therefore, willing to pay a
pected marginal rate. Nyborg and Strebulaev show that in
premium above the minimum bid rate.
equilibrium the threat of a squeeze induces short banks to submit
This result is intuitive. First, consider the case where banks are
on average bids above the minimum bid rate with a higher expected
only subject to idiosyncratic liquidity shocks so that there is no
mean rate than the bids submitted by banks which are long. The
aggregate liquidity surplus or deficit in period 2 or 3. As long as
authors also show, that the larger the short position, the larger are
banks are solvent, banks can always obtain the required funding
the volumes bid at higher prices.12 Or putting it simply: banks bid
in the secondary market as the (frictionless) interbank market allo-
more at higher prices, the greater their funding liquidity risk.
cates liquidity from those with a surplus to those with a deficit. Gi-
ven the central bank provides the right amount of liquidity, the 9
Nikolaou (2009) provides an overview over the literature describing the role of
interest rate in the interbank market equals the minimum bid rate.
interbank markets and funding liquidity risk.
With no uncertainty in period 2, bidding at the minimum bid rate 10
Formally, the results from Nyborg and Strebulaev will only carry over to a setting
in period 1 is the only rational strategy. Hence, our suggested mea- with a different interbank market frictions, if the friction implies that long players can
sure would indicate zero liquidity risk, which is exactly what it charge a higher interest rate if short banks are sufficiently illiquid. If the interbank
should do. Theory has shown that funding liquidity risk is zero, market is closed and only banks can trade in the interbank market this is the case.
Nyborg and Strebulaev also assume that agents have full information on short and
when interbank markets are frictionless and no aggregate shocks
long positions prior to the OMO. However, imperfections in the interbank market are
occur (e.g., Allen and Gale, 2000). often associated with imperfect information. Nyborg and Strebulaev conjecture that
Even with frictionless interbank markets, however, trading can- with private information about positions, long players will aim to exploit their
not eliminate the risk that the market on aggregate may be long or informational advantage. But in equilibrium short banks would still bid on average at
higher rates to prevent the squeeze.
short of central bank money in period 3. As prices for accessing the 11
Acharya et al. (forthcoming) document several banking crises where this effect
seems to have played an important role.
8 12
Most countries have positive reserve requirements for banks. However, theoret- Fecht et al. (2011) find empirical support for this by analysing OMOs for German
ically it is only necessary that there is a threshold (e.g. zero) and that banks would be banks. They document that banks, which are below their reserve requirements, bid
penalised if their balances with the central bank would drop below this level. more aggressively especially in times when the imbalance across banks is large.
M. Drehmann, K. Nikolaou / Journal of Banking & Finance 37 (2013) 21732182 2177

Aggressive bidding may also occur because banks may not be periods like the LTCM crises (e.g., Furfine, 2002). However, a banks
risk neutral. Once a bank becomes illiquid, it will default. It is financial health did influence the interbank market rates it had to
therefore likely that is some circumstances the bank will act as if pay during the recent crisis, in particular after the Lehman failure
it is risk averse. Obviously, risk aversion implies that banks with (e.g., Angelini et al., 2009). As a consequence, term money markets
high liquidity risk will pay a higher premium to insure against this almost dried up and money market activity focused in the short-
risk. During normal times the effects of risk aversion should not be term segment. In this segment, credit risk concerns are generally
material as interbank markets are nearly frictionless and banks can minimal. Even during the recent crisis, Angelini et al. (2009) show
obtain any required amount of funding in the secondary market. that lower capital ratios one observable proxy for credit risk - did
The only risk banks face are small price changes for unsecured not significantly increase funding spreads for one week maturities,
lending due to small aggregate shocks.13 However, in stressed con- in contrast to longer ones. Therefore, while liquidity risk may not
ditions the risk of becoming illiquid or having to pay high costs to be completely orthogonal to credit risk, by focusing on one week
obtain funds in the secondary market increases, so the effects of risk maturities, our measure should to a very large extend reflect fund-
aversion on bid behaviour are more important. ing liquidity risk.
Valimaki (2006) explores a model with risk averse banks, where Second, there could be collateral effects as the ECB accepts a lar-
deviations from a target level of central bank balances prior to ger pool of collateral than can be used in the securitised interbank
trading in the interbank market are costly. Such a target level could markets. We do not expect this to bias our results in a significant
be the result of frictions. For example, banks know that the desire fashion, as interbank markets work to a large extend on an uncol-
to obtain very large amounts of money would be penalised by rates lateralised basis.15
above the market rate or it may even be impossible to raise the Third, it has been shown that at year-ends, banks bid more
necessary amount of funds because of rationing. In line with Ny- aggressively to engage in window-dressing and establish favour-
borg and Strebulaev, Valimaki shows that banks with a higher tar- able end of year balances (Bindseil et al., 2003). Clearly, such sea-
get level, or equivalently with a higher NLD, bid more aggressively sonality effects are unrelated to liquidity risk as they are not
during the central bank auction. Again, the more banks bid at rates driven by a reaction to funding pressures. This, however, affects
above the expected marginal rate, the greater their funding liquid- primarily year-end auctions, which we therefore drop.
ity risk. Last, bidding behaviour may also be influenced by the well-
known winners curse problem which results in underbidding
4.3. Bidding when considering all available sources of liquidity (e.g., Milgrom and Weber, 1982). For this problem, however, to
be material it is necessary that market participants have asymmet-
No model in the literature on bidding behaviour in OMOs takes ric information about the value of the good in the secondary mar-
account of all sources of funding liquidity shown in Eq. (2). In real- ket. Bindseil et al. (2009) find no evidence that this is the case for
ity, banks can trade in the interbank market but also obtain liquid- OMOs in the euro area. Hence, the winners curse problem should
ity from depositors or from selling assets. However, within the one not impact on our measures.
week horizon we consider here, banks cannot expect to rely on
new customer deposits to weather unexpected liquidity shocks. 5. Measuring funding liquidity risk
In the short run, banks have a limited ability to attract a significant
amount of new customer deposits (for example by raising rates) 5.1. The Liquidity Risk Premium (LRP)
because of sluggish depositors behaviour (Gondat-Larralde and
Nier, 2004). In Section 4 we have shown that large bid volumes at prices
Asset sales are therefore the only other alternative source of above the expected marginal rate reveal funding liquidity risk as
liquidity in the short run. Without frictions in any market, the costs a bidder can be relatively certain that she will get the liquidity re-
of obtaining liquidity from the interbank market or from selling as- quested without being rationed16. Our measure is, therefore, simply
sets are equal as all price differentials are arbitraged away. In such based on the volume banks bid at rates above the expected marginal
an environment, the results from Section 4.1 apply and banks only rate.
bid at the policy rate. But as in the case of interbank market, fric- We define the adjusted bid (AB) as
tions in asset markets are central in theories of market liquidity
risk (for an overview see e.g. Biais et al., 2005). A drying-up of mar- ABb;i;t bid rateb;i;t % Emarginal ratet & v olumeb;i;t
3
ket liquidity depresses the value of assets which can be sold to if bid rateb;i;t > Emarginal ratet
raise funds. As can be seen from Eq. (2) this raises the funding
liquidity risk of banks. Banks with high liquidity risk will expect where bid rateb;i;t and volumeb,i,t are the rate and volume of bank i
this. Therefore, they will bid more aggressively in the primary auc- (from 1 to N), which submits b bids (from 1 to B) at time (auction)
tion to obtain the required funds.14 t. Emarginal ratet is the expected marginal rate. ABb,i,t are the total
Before we turn to the empirical analysis we should point out costs a bank is willing to pay to ensure that it obtains the volumeb,i,t
that our measure of funding liquidity risk may also be influenced of cash from the central bank. In this sense, it is an insurance cost
by other factors. First, credit risk can potentially affect the price against funding liquidity risk and thus provides a bank specific mea-
banks have to pay to obtain funds in the interbank market. Given sure of funding liquidity risk.
the short duration of the MROs the theoretical literature assumes
that this is negligible. Empirical evidence indeed shows that this 15
The broad collateral framework of the ECB may render the ECB auctions relatively
is the case during normal times but also during somewhat stressed more attractive than the secured money market. Ewerhart et al. (2010) show
theoretically that this may lead banks to bid more aggressively. During normal times
this effect should not be large as liquidity is readily available in all money market
13
As long as all banks lend freely in the interbank market, aggregate liquidity segments. In crisis the may be different. However, during the recent crisis, the ECB has
shocks in the market for central bank money are technically only driven by changes in broadened its collateral eligibility rules to accommodate the large liquidity demand of
autonomous factors. Autonomous factors constitute (nearly completely) of bank- the banking system, given the breakdown of several money market segments.
notes, government deposits and net foreign assets. These factors can and do change Therefore, it is unclear what the net-effect is on our measure during the crisis.
16
between OMOs even though these fluctuations are generally not large. In theory, the expected marginal rate equals the minimum bid rate. However, the
14
As shown by e.g. Brunnermeier and Pedersen (2009), there is a potential feedback marginal rate has been on average 6 bps above the policy rate even in normal times.
loop between market and funding liquidity risk, something we discuss in more detail In section 5.1 we will explain in detail how we measure the expected marginal rate as
in Section 7.3. well as the expected total allotment empirically.
2178 M. Drehmann, K. Nikolaou / Journal of Banking & Finance 37 (2013) 21732182

Given AB it is easy to construct an aggregate liquidity risk insur-

.5
Actual
ance premia (LRP) by summing across all adjusted bids of all banks. Expected

PN PB

.4
i1 b1 ABb;i;t
LRPt & 100 4
Eallotmentt

.3
We normalise the sum of the adjusted bid rates by the volume

Spread
banks expect the central bank to provide. The normalisation is nec-
essary to ensure consistency across auctions which differ in size.

.2
This will also ensure that our measure is unaffected by frontload-
ing practices after August 2007 as discussed in Section 3. Further-
more, the normalisation implies that LRP is the value weighted

.1
average spread banks are willing to pay to ensure that they obtain
liquidity from the central bank. Or putting it simply, LRP is the aver-

0
age insurance premium of banks against funding liquidity risk. The
multiplication by 100 implies that it is measured in basis points. An 01jul2005 01jul2006 01jul2007 01jul2008

alternative interpretation is shown in Fig. A2.1 in the Annex using Date

one auction as an example. As can be seen LRP is simply the norma- Fig. 2. Spread between the marginal and policy rate actual versus expected. Note:
lised area under the aggregate demand curve. Expected rates are taken from the Reuters poll. The solid vertical line indicates the
Finally, it should be noted that although the reasoning underly- beginning of the crisis (7 August 2007). The dotted vertical lines indicate dates of
ing the construction of LRP requires access to data that are not important events, the failure of Northern Rock (13 September 2007), the failure of
Bear Sterns (16 March 2008) and the failure of Lehman Brothers (15 September 2008).
publicly available, a proxy measure can be constructed from public
data. Under the assumption that expected values are close to actual
volume is different, as the excess liquidity has to be balanced out.
values, expected variables can be substituted by actual values. This
To account for this we insert a dummy variable end which equals
in turn means that LRP can be proxied by the weighted average bid
1 on the last auction of each maintenance period.
rate, a variable routinely published by the ECB.17
We use a 30-day rolling window estimation procedure. Rolling
windows estimation is ideal in case of structural breaks in the data,
5.2. Estimating the expected marginal rate and allotment volume which are likely to exist given the outbreak of the crisis.20 We
choose a 30 day window as this provides us with the necessary
As we discussed previously, the central bank can adjust the sup- amount of data in order to achieve efficient asymptotic estimates,
ply of liquidity after all bids have been received. The market will while at the same time it minimises the effects of changes which oc-
anticipate this when forming their expectations about the marginal curred during the crisis, for which we only have 59 observations.
rate and the total allotment volume, which we require as inputs for
our measure. Gauging market expectations is a non-trivial task. 6. Data
The problem is further complicated by the endogeneity between
the aggregate bids and the total allotment. For this reason we rely Our analysis benefits from a unique data set of 175 MROs con-
on a new survey dataset from Reuters, where market expectations ducted by the ECB from June 2005 to 7 October 2008. To avoid the
about the marginal rate of each auction are revealed (these data contamination of our measure by window-dressing, we drop the
are described in detail in Section 6). Using this data set we can treat last operation in each year. We also do not consider the operation
the expected marginal rate as an exogenous variable to determine conducted on 18 Dec 2007 as this had a maturity of 2 weeks. In to-
the expected total allotment (TA) by a simple OLS regression:18 tal we have therefore 171 MROs in our sample.
Overall, 1068 banks took part at least once in any of these auc-
TAt a0 a1 & Espreadt a2 & benchmark a4 & end et 5 tions. We have information on an anonymous but unique code for
each bidder, the submitted bid schedule (bid rate and bid volume)
All the regressors in Eq. (5) are known when bids are submitted. of each bank and the allotted volume. These data are not publicly
E(spread) is the expected spread between the expected marginal available. However, data on the policy rate (minimum bid rate),
rate and the policy rate, which is known in advance of bidding.19 the marginal rate, the maintenance periods, the benchmark and
benchmark is the benchmark at announcement. At the end of the the settlement dates of the auctions are publicly available and ta-
maintenance period it is likely that the behaviour of the allotment ken from the ECBs internet site.21
We combine this information with data from a Reuters poll sur-
17
For the interested reader, an exposition of LRP measures using public data and veying expectations of the marginal rate. To our knowledge, this is
comparisons with the LRP measure can be found in Drehmann and Nikolaou (2010). the first time these data are used. The poll is conducted on a weekly
The authors find that proxies based on public data give an adequate result. But at
periods of high intensity during the crisis, the divergences between expected and
basis. Reuters asks a number of banks (usually the same panel of 25
actual values lead to significant differences in the measures. 30) every week about their expectations about the marginal rate.
18
In the absence of the Reuters poll data we would need a simultaneous equations These banks represent the largest banks in the euro area as well as
setting to jointly estimate the expected rate and the expected allotment rate. Indeed, some mid-size dealers. The number of banks may vary slightly per
using 3SLS, we estimated the spread between the marginal rate and the policy rate
week depending on availability. We use the mean of this survey as
and the total allotment jointly, using the allotment at announcement, the lagged
spread, the lagged difference between the announced and actual allotment and a the expected marginal rate. Fig. 2 shows that before the crisis, the
dummy which is one in the last auction of the maintenance period as explanatory market anticipated the marginal rate well. Afterwards a gap
variables. The regression results for the spread match the Reuters expectations very emerges. Interestingly, the market seems to consistently underesti-
closely. mate the marginal rate in the early stages of the crisis.
19
The policy rate is set on the monthly meetings of the Governing Council of the
ECB. It is announced on the first Thursday of every month and is valid for the
20
maintenance period that spans the period during two consecutive announcements. It Windows of length 24, 40, 50, 52 and 60 observations were also tried. Results are
is effective from the MRO immediately following the announcement and for all broadly similar and available on request.
21
consequent MROs within the same maintenance period. http://www.ecb.eu/mopo/implement/omo/html/index.en.html.
M. Drehmann, K. Nikolaou / Journal of Banking & Finance 37 (2013) 21732182 2179

Figs. A2.2 and A2.3 in the Annex provides an overview over the
components of the individual bids. Fig. A2.2 shows the individual

40
bid rates as spreads above the minimum bid rate. Each data point
corresponds to a single dot in the figure. It is apparent that the cri-
sis period is associated with a larger variability in bid rates and

30
more aggressive bidding as suggested by the amount and extent
of bids above the expected marginal rate. Fig. A2.3 shows the vol-

LRP
umes bid for bid rates above the expected marginal rate. In line

20
with Eq. (4), we normalise each submitted bid volume by the ex-
pected total allotment. In contrast to the rates, volume bids do
not change dramatically before and during the crisis, even though
some increase is apparent.

10
Fig. A2.4 presents the evolution of the total allotment and the
benchmark at announcement. Prior to August 2007 the benchmark
is a very good predictor for the actual allotment. On average, the

0
difference during this period is only 0.4%. This changed with the 01jul2005 01jul2006 01jul2007 01jul2008
the crisis, when the ECB started the frontloading practices de- Date
scribed in Section 3.
Fig. 4. LRP. Note: The solid vertical line indicates the beginning of the crisis (7
August 2007). The dotted vertical lines indicate the failure of Northern Rock (13
7. Results September 2007), the failure of Bear Sterns (16 March 2008) and the failure of
Lehman Brothers (15 September 2008). In basis points.
7.1. Regression results
Table 1
Before presenting LRP we briefly discuss the results of the Statistics of the liquidity risk.
regression determining the expected allotment as described in
LRP
Eq. (5). Fig. 3 below shows the actual versus fitted values and the
R2. Normal Crisis Ratio
As a general result the fit is rather good. Before the crisis the to- Observations 112 59
tal allotment can be nearly perfectly forecasted as the benchmark Mean 0.9 7.6 8.7
Std. 0.4 7.1 19.1
at announcement is very close to the actual allotment. During the
Min 0.1 2.7 20.0
crisis the fit continues to be quite good (around 80%), with the Max 2.2 44.1 19.9
notable exceptions of the outbreak of the turmoil in August 2007
and the incident of the Lehman collapse at the end of our sample. Note: Normal indicates the period from June 2005 until 7 August 2007. Crisis is the
remaining period until 7 October 2008. Ratio equals crisis/normal. LRP is measured
These two exceptions are technically grounded, given the struc- in basis points.
tural breaks in the data (validated by appropriate Chow tests)
and are also economically reasonable, given that both incidents oc-
curred suddenly and therefore expectations about volumes would greater and has much more pronounced spikes towards the end of
consider only the pre-crisis information set. our sample. The change in level coincides perfectly with the begin-
ning of the crisis. Prior to the crisis, banks on average paid below 1
basis point to insure against funding liquidity risk (see Table 1).
7.2. The LRP measure
The average insurance premium increased rapidly after August
2007, and reached a first peak of more than 16 basis points after
Our aggregate measure of funding liquidity risk is presented
Northern Rock had to be rescued by the UK government. A relative
in Fig. 4. Unsurprising, LRP reveals that liquidity risk is much
tranquil period followed, but liquidity risk rose again at the end of
the year. The failure of Bear Sterns, was also followed by a pro-
350000

nounced spike, even though this was less significant than the spike
1

following the failure of Northern Rock. Tensions subsequently sub-


sided but rose towards the end of June 2008. To some extent this
300000

may reveal window-dressing effects and uncertainties about half


.8

year results. The largest spike in funding liquidity risk occurs at


the beginning of October 2008, when money markets broke down
Total allotment
250000

completely following the failure of Lehman Brothers. At this point,


the average insurance premium was more than 44 basis points
R2
.6

(see Table 1).


200000

The graph clearly shows that funding liquidity risk is time vary-
ing and persistent, but subject to occasional spikes. These charac-
.4

teristics have been documented by market participants using


150000

Actual banks own models (e.g., Matz and Neu, 2007; Banks, 2005), but
Fitted are also common for measures of market liquidity (e.g., Amihud,
R2 (right axis)
2002; Chordia et al., 2005).
.2

01jul2005 01jul2006 01jul2007 01jul2008


Date
7.3. Funding liquidity risk and market liquidity
Fig. 3. Total allotment actual versus expected. Note: Regressions are based on 30
observations rolling window. For each rolling regression, we show the last
predicted value, except for the beginning of the sample where we use the first Market and funding liquidity are strongly interrelated. Eq. (2)
regression to derive the predicted values. clearly shows that depressed asset values due to a lack of market
2180 M. Drehmann, K. Nikolaou / Journal of Banking & Finance 37 (2013) 21732182

liquidity may raise funding liquidity risk. But market liquidity is in Normal

turn not exogenous from funding liquidity risk. Brunnermeier and Crisis

40
Normal: Fitted values
Crisis: Fitted values
Pedersen (2009), show that downward spirals between increased
market and funding liquidity risk can emerge. Such a downward
liquidity spiral can, for instance, start with a bank (or brokers in

30
the Brunnermeier and Pedersen model), which is short of funding
liquidity and cannot obtain it from the interbank market. In the

LRP
model it, therefore, has to sell assets. If asset markets are charac-

20
terised by frictions, (large) asset sales induce a fall in asset prices.
These in turn imply that the bank has to post higher margins,
which increases liquidity outflows. To remain liquid banks have
to sell even more assets, which depresses market prices even fur-

10
ther (because of a lack of market liquidity). Whilst the theoretical
expositions are clear and anecdotal evidence points to these effects
in the recent crisis, the interaction between both liquidity mea-

0
sures has not been shown empirically due to a lack of measures -3 -2 -1 0 1
for funding liquidity risk. Market liquidity index
Using our measure we are able to assess this question in a more
Fig. 5. Interactions between funding liquidity risk and market liquidity. Note:
robust fashion. We use a broad measure of market liquidity for the
Normal indicates the period from June 2005 until 7 August 2007. Crisis is the
euro area (see ECB, 2007) which is shown in Fig. A2.5 in the Annex. remaining period until 7 October 2007. Fitted values are based on the regression
This index of market liquidity is a weighted average of different using the specified sub-samples.
market liquidity measures such as bid-ask spreads in FX, equity,
bond and money markets.22 Table 2
Fig. 5 shows a scatter plot of LRP and the market liquidity index. Regression results of LRP on the market liquidity index.
A clear negative relationship can be seen, i.e. when market liquid- Coefficient R-squared Observations
ity is drying up (i.e. is low), funding liquidity risk is high (which
Full sample
would be equivalent to saying that high funding liquidity risk is Market liquidity %5.7*** 0.48 171
associated with high market liquidity risk). The dotted and solid Constant 2.5***
lines show the predicted values based on a simple regression of Normal
the index on LRP during normal times and the crisis. Market liquidity %0.4 0.003 112
The regression results are shown in Table 2. The scatter plot al- Constant 1.0***
ready suggests that the negative relationship only emerges during Crisis
the crisis. The econometric analysis supports this, as there is no sig- Market liquidity %5.3*** 0.17 59
nificant relationship between our measure of funding liquidity risk Constant 2.9*
and market liquidity prior to the crisis.23 However, once the crisis un- Note: The independent variable is LRP for all regressions. Normal indicates the
folds a significant negative relationship emerges. This is exactly what period from June 2005 until 7 August 2007. Crisis is the remaining period until 7
the theory predicts, as these interactions should only emerge once October 2008.
***
Significant at the 1% level.
banks become funding constraint. The relationship during the crisis *
Significant at the 10% level.
is also economically significant. The estimates imply that, for example,
a fall of the market liquidity index by three standard deviations is
associated with a 14 basis points increase in the average liquidity our results hold even when we focus solely on the composite index
insurance premium. This is approximately the difference between of FX, equity and bonds markets (see Table A1.1 in the Annex).
levels of LRP after the failures of Northern Rock or Bear Stearns and
pre-crisis levels. Note that we do not want to imply any causal 8. Comparison with money market spreads
relationships with this thought experiment, as market and funding
liquidity risk are determined simultaneously in equilibrium. Ideally, we would provide a comparison with banks own mea-
The market liquidity index used above combines different sures of funding liquidity risk and how this relates to their bidding
liquidity measures, which we can separate into two main compos- behaviour. However, this information is unavailable. A typical
ite indices, namely FX, equity and bond markets, and a money mar- measure commonly used by central banks, academics and practi-
ket index. Given the nature of the crisis, it is plausible that our tioners to assess money market conditions is the spread between
results are driven by developments in money markets. However, unsecured interbank rates and the overnight index swap rate
(e.g., IMF, 2008).
Spreads are, however, not a clean measure of funding liquidity
22
As discussed in ECB (2007) (Box 9), ...the financial market liquidity indicator risk because of several reasons. First, interbank market rates may
combines eight individual liquidity measures. Three of them cover bid-ask spreads: not be representative of actual funding conditions during a crisis
(1) on the EUR/USD, EUR/JPY and EUR/GBP exchange rates; (2) on the 50 individual period because of increased uncertainty, dispersion in the credit
stocks which form the Dow Jones EURO STOXX 50 index and; (3) on EONIA one month
quality across banks and greater incentives to strategically misre-
and 3 month swap rates. Three others are return-to-turnover ratios calculated for: (4)
the 50 individual stocks which make up the Dow Jones EURO STOXX 50 index; (5) port funding costs (e.g., Gyntelberg and Wooldridge, 2008). By con-
euro bond markets and; (6) the equity options market. The last two components struction interbank rates such as Euribor are not a transaction
which measure the liquidity premium are gauged by: (7) spreads on euro area high- based price measure but an index based on a daily survey amongst
yield corporate bonds which are adjusted to take account of the credit risk implied in a large number of panel banks.24 There is now clear evidence that
these spreads by expected default frequencies (EDFs) and; (8) euro area spreads
between interbank deposit and repo interest rates. The composite indicator is a
24
simple average of all the liquidity measures normalised on the period 19992006. For example, for the construction of Euribor banks are asked to quote the
23
To see whether the results are driven by outliers, we dropped the 5% highest LRP rate. . .that each panel bank believes one prime bank is quoting to another prime bank
values in the sample as a robustness check. We continue to find the same qualitative for inter-bank term deposits within the euro zone, see http://www.euribor.org/html/
results. content/euribor_tech.html.
M. Drehmann, K. Nikolaou / Journal of Banking & Finance 37 (2013) 21732182 2181

can insure itself against becoming illiquid and thereby reveals its
LRP
EURIBOR-OIS spread liquidity risk.
100

Using information from a data set of 171 main refinancing oper-


ations conducted by the ECB from June 2005 to October 2008, we
find that funding liquidity risk increased rapidly after August
2007 and spiked after the rescue of Northern Rock. Following the
failure of Bear Sterns liquidity risk rose sharply again, even though
Spreads

to less elevated levels. Unsurprisingly, our measure identifies re-


50

cord pressures in October 2008 after Lehman failed. More gener-


ally, we find that our measure has similar properties as market
liquidity such as low levels, persistence and occasional spikes.
We are able to find evidence that there is indeed an inverse rela-
tionship between funding liquidity risk and market liquidity.
Our analysis is only a starting point in using bidding data to assess
funding liquidity risk. It would certainly be interesting to implement
0

01jul2005 01jul2006 01jul2007 01jul2008 our measure for horizons beyond one week or for different jurisdic-
Date tions. This is certainly possible as the same auction design was also
used for long term refinancing operations in the euro area prior to
Fig. 6. LRP and the Euribor-OIS spread. Note: In basis points. The solid vertical line
indicates the beginning of the crisis (7 August 2007). The dotted vertical lines October 2008. It is also the case that a broad range of other countries
indicate dates of important events, the failure of Northern Rock (13 September such as the Canada, Mexico, or the UK have similar auction set-ups at
2007), the failure of Bear Sterns (16 March 2008) and the failure of Lehman Brothers least for some of their money market operations. Whilst daily OMOs
(15 September 2008). in the United States are conducted with a narrow set of broker deal-
some panel members tried to manipulate interbank lending rate ers, the auctions design of the newly introduced Term Auction Facil-
during the crisis.25 But even before this was officially acknowledged, ity is similar to the one necessary to construct our measure.26 Even
academics and market participants considered such indexes (Euribor though the auction is conducted as a single-price auction format it
or Libor) void of essential information, as term markets dried out should be possible to use bids as a measure for funding liquidity risk
during the crisis, and therefore not really suggestive of the reality based on our approach.
in markets (e.g., Brousseau et al., 2009). It would also be interesting to strip out collateral effects, which
Second, spreads between unsecured interbank rates and the may impact on banks bidding behaviour. Conceptually, this is pos-
overnight index swap rate do not reveal any information about sible. However, we do not have access to the relevant information.
the volume banks need to obtain to remain liquid. As discussed Nonetheless, we argue that our approach provides a very useful
in Section 2.2, this is a key component of funding liquidity risk. tool not only because it opens up ways of further empirical re-
Our measure also has an additional benefit in that it allows policy search on liquidity, an area of research hindered by the unavail-
makers to obtain bank specific measures of funding liquidity risk ability of proxies, but also because it can be an efficient tool for
by looking at the adjusted bids bank by bank (Eq. (3)). By construc- policy analysis and monitoring.
tion spreads between unsecured interbank rates and the overnight
index swap rate cannot be disaggregated and only reveal aggregate Acknowledgments
funding conditions.
Fig. 6 plots our measure of funding liquidity risk against the The views expressed in the paper do not represent the views of
spread between unsecured interbank rates and the overnight index the BIS or the ECB. We would like to thank the editors and an anon-
swap rate. Given that we look at a one week measure for the euro ymous referee for helpful comments. We are also indebted to Gus-
area, the relevant spread is the 1 week Euribor-OIS spread. The graph tavo S. Arajo, Claudio Borio, Markus Brunnermeier, Ben Craig,
shows that the Euribor-OIS spread is much higher than LRP. On aver- Charles Goodhart, Philipp Hartmann, Bill Nelson, Kjell Nyborg, Kos-
age the difference is around 3 basis points in normal times but in- tas Tsatsaronis, Christian Upper and Gtz von Peter as well as par-
creases to more than 20 basis points during the crisis. This is not ticipants at the Annual Seminar on Banking, Financial Stability and
unsurprising, given that LRP reflects funding liquidity risk more Risk, hosted by the Central Bank of Brazil and Journal of Banking
cleanly and the Euribor includes possible measurement biases. and Finance; the European Economic Association Meeting 2009;
the Money, Market and Finance conference 2007; the conference
on Central Bank Liquidity Tools hosted by the Federal Reserve
9. Conclusion Bank of New York; the conference on Liquidity hosted by the
CESifo and Deutsche Bundesbank; and seminars at the Bank of Eng-
In this paper we propose a measure of funding liquidity risk, land, the Monetary Authority of Hong Kong, the Bank of Canada,
using readily available information. As measurement without clear the Norges Bank, and the University of Pireus.
definitions is impossible, we also provide definitions of funding
liquidity and funding liquidity risk. We define funding liquidity as
the ability to settle obligations with immediacy. Accordingly, funding Appendix A. Supplementary material
liquidity risk is driven by the possibility that over a specific horizon the
bank will become unable to settle obligations with immediacy. Ideally Supplementary data associated with this article can be found, in
and in line with other risks, we would want to measure funding the online version, at doi:10.1016/j.jbankfin.2012.01.002.
liquidity risk by the distribution summarising the stochastic nature
of the underlying risk factors. Such distributions cannot be esti- References
mated because of a lack of data. However, we observe how much
Acharya, V.A., Gromb, D., Yorulmazer, T., forthcoming. Imperfect competition in the
banks are willing to pay to obtain liquidity from the central bank. interbank market for liquidity as a rational for the central bank. American
By submitting aggressive bids at the central bank auction, the bank Economic Journal: Macroeconomics.

25 26
See e.g. US eyes criminal route over Libor, Financial Times, 8.Sep. 2011. For further details see http://www.federalreserve.gov/monetarypolicy/taf.htm.
2182 M. Drehmann, K. Nikolaou / Journal of Banking & Finance 37 (2013) 21732182

Allen, F., Gale, D., 2000. Financial contagion. Journal of Political Economy 108, 133. Flannery, M.J., 1996. Financial crises, payment system problems, and discount
Amihud, Y., 2002. Illiquidity and stock returns: cross-section and time-series window lending. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 28, 804824.
effects. Journal of Financial Markets 5, 3156. Furfine, C., 2002. The interbank market during a crisis. European Economic Review
Angelini, P., Nobili, A., Picillo, C., 2009. The interbank market after August 2007. 46, 809820.
What has changed, and why? Banca DItalia Working Paper 731. Gondat-Larralde, C., Nier, E., 2004. The economics of retail banking an empirical
Ayuso, J., Repullo, R., 2003. A model of the open market operations of the European analysis of the UK market for personal current accounts. Bank of England
Central Bank. Economic Journal 113, 883902. Quarterly Bulletin Spring, 153159.
Banks, E., 2005. Liquidity Risk: Managing Asset and Funding Risk. Palgrave Gyntelberg, J., Wooldridge, P., 2008. Interbank rate fixings during the recent
Macmillan, New York. turmoil. BIS Quarterly Review March, 5972.
Basel Committee on Banking Supervision (BCBS), 2008. Principles for Sound Heider, F., Hoerova, M., Holthausen, C., 2009. Liquidity hoarding and interbank
Liquidity Risk Management and Supervision. Bank for International market spreads: the role of counterparty risk. ECB Working Paper 1126.
Settlements, Basel. Holmstrm, B., Tirole, J., 1998. Private and public supply of liquidity. Journal of
Biais, B., Glosten, L., Spatt, C., 2005. Market microstructure: a survey of Political Economy 106, 140.
microfoundations, empirical results and policy implications. Journal of Holmstrm, B., Tirole, J., 2001. LAPM: a liquidity-based asset pricing model. The
Financial Markets 8, 217264. Journal of Finance 56, 18371867.
Bindseil, U., Nyborg, K.G., Strebulaev, I.A., 2009. Repo auctions and the market for International Monetary Fund (IMF), 2008. Global Financial Stability Report, April.
liquidity. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 41, 13911421. International Monetary Fund, Washington.
Bindseil, U., Weller, B., Wuertz, F., 2003. Central banks and commercial banks Kapadia, S., Drehmann, M., Elliot, J., Stern, G., forthcoming. Liquidity risk, cash flow
liquidity risk management what is the relationship? Economic Notes 32, 37 constraints and systemic feedbacks. In: Haubrich, J., Lo, A.W. (Eds.), Quantifying
66. Systemic Risk. National Bureau of Economic Research, Boston.
Borio, C., 2000. Market liquidity and stress: selected issues and policy implications. Matz, L., Neu, P., 2007. Liquidity Risk: Measurement and Management. Wiley,
BIS Quarterly Review November, 3851. Hoboken.
Brunnermeier, M.K., Pedersen, L.H., 2009. Market liquidity and funding liquidity. Milgrom, P.R., Weber, R.J., 1982. A theory of auctions and competitive bidding.
Review of Financial Studies 22, 22012238. Econometrica 50, 10891122.
Brousseau, V., Chailloux, A., Durre, A., 2009. Interbank offered rate: effects of the Nikolaou, K., 2009. Liquidity (risk) concepts: definitions and interactions. ECB
financial crisis on the information content of the fixing. LEM Working Paper Working Paper 1008.
2009-17. Nyborg, K.G., Strebulaev, I.A., 2004. Multiple unit auctions and short squeezes. The
Chordia, T., Sarkar, A., Subrahmanyam, A., 2005. An empirical analysis of stock and Review of Financial Studies 17, 545580.
bond market liquidity. The Review of Financial Studies 18, 85128. Poole, W., 1968. Commercial bank reserve management in a stochastic model:
Committee on Payment and Settlement Systems (CPSS), 2003. The Role of Central implications for monetary policy. Journal of Finance 23, 769791.
Bank Money in Payment Systems. Bank for International Settlements, Basel. Rochet, J.C., Vives, X., 2004. Coordination failures and the lender of last resort: was
Drehmann, M., Nikolaou, K., 2010. Funding liquidity risk: definition and Bagehot right after all? Journal of the European Economic Association 2, 1116
measurement. BIS Working Paper 316. 1147.
European Central Bank (ECB), 2007. Financial Stability Review, June. European Strahan, P.E., 2008. Liquidity production in 21st century banking. NBER Working
Central Bank, Frankfurt. Paper 13798.
Ewerhart, C., Cassola, N., Valla, N., 2010. Declining valuations and equilibrium Stiglitz, J., Weiss, A., 1981. Credit rationing in markets with imperfect information.
bidding in central bank refinancing operations. International Journal of American Economic Review 71, 393410.
Industrial Organisations 28, 3043. Valimaki, T., 2006. Why the marginal MRO rate exceeds the ECB policy rate? Bank of
Fecht, F., Nyborg, K.G., Rocholl, J., 2011. The price of liquidity: the effects of market Finland Research Discussion Papers 200/2006.
conditions and bank characteristics. Journal of Financial Economics 102, 344
362.

You might also like