You are on page 1of 14

World Development Vol. 33, No. 7, pp.

11011114, 2005
2005 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved
Printed in Great Britain
www.elsevier.com/locate/worlddev 0305-750X/$ - see front matter
doi:10.1016/j.worlddev.2005.04.009

Decentralization and Participation: The Governance


of Common Pool Resources in Nepals Terai
ARUN AGRAWAL
University of Michigan, Ann Arbor, USA

and

KRISHNA GUPTA *
Ministry of Commerce and Industry, New Delhi, India
Summary. Decentralization has emerged as an important instrument of environmental and
development policy in the last two decades. Presumed benets of environmental policy decentral-
ization depend in signicant measure on broad participation in the programs that governments cre-
ate to decentralize decision making related to resource management. This paper uses data from
protected areas in Nepals Terai to examine who participates in environmental decentralization
programs. On the basis of our statistical analysis, we highlight the fact that the likelihood of par-
ticipation in community-level user groups is greater for those who are economically and socially
better-o. We also nd that individuals who have greater access to and who visit government oces
related to decentralization policies more often are also more likely to participate in user groups cre-
ated by state ocials. Finally, we nd a negative correlation between education and levels of par-
ticipation. Our study and analysis support the argument that for decentralization policies to be
successful on equity issues, it is important to build institutional mechanisms that encourage poorer
and more marginal households to access government ocials, improve access to educational
opportunities, and create incentives to promote more interactions between less powerful rural res-
idents and government ocials.
2005 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.

Key words environment, protected areas, forests, resource management, Nepal, South Asia

* We would like to thank respondents in the surveyed


villages for their cooperation in our data collection
1. INTRODUCTION
eorts, and the UNDPKathmandu for providing the
Decentralization has emerged as an impor- funds necessary for the eld research. Colleagues at the
tant instrument of environmental and develop- Nepal Forestry Resources and Institutions Program, es-
ment policy in the last two decades. 1 pecially Birendra Karna and Mukunda Karmacharya,
Governments play a role in decentralizing deci- assisted in the data collection eort. Successive drafts of
sion making and policy implementation to the paper have beneted from comments by Ashwini
achieve diverse goals: among them social de- Chhatre, Clark Gibson, Elinor Ostrom, Kent Redford,
velopment, democratic participation, resource and Amy Poteete, and presentations to interested
management, and service provision (Agrawal audiences at Indiana University, Yale University, the
& Ostrom, 2001; De Vries, 2000; Willis, Chris- University of Michigan, and the fourth biennial meeting
topher da, & Haggard, 1999). Although decen- of the International Forestry Resources and Institutions
tralization is sometimes seen as a good in itself, Program in Nairobi, Kenya, in June 2002. Revisions of
decentralizers defend their policy choices more the paper were supported by grants from the National
often on grounds of increased eciency, greater Science Foundation (# SBR 9905443) and the Ford
equity, and higher responsiveness of govern- Foundation (# 950-1160-2). We gratefully acknowledge
ments to citizen demands. The presumed supe- the help we have received in dierent forms. Final revis-
riority of decentralized decision making stems ion accepted: January 24, 2005.
1101
1102 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

from the possibility that lower-level decision sponsored local user groups is greater for
makers are likely to have better access to infor- households who enjoy a greater level of eco-
mation, lower organization costs, and a greater nomic well being; who belong to the upper
willingness to compete (Fiszbein, 1997; Ribot, caste and have a higher level of education;
2002). Greater access to decision makers, who use more resources from protected areas,
higher levels of participation by various social and who have more interactions with govern-
groups in decision making, and the account- ment ocials. Testing these hypotheses helps
ability of decision makers are often the claimed explore whether existing power holders and
eects of participation. These are also impor- those who are wealthier may appropriate a
tant as justications (Andersson, Gibson, & Le- greater proportion of benets from decentral-
houcq, 2004; Wunsch & Olowu, 1997). ized control over resources. It also enhances
Where common pool resources (CPRs) 2 are the understanding of the nature of participation
concerned, the goal of decentralization policies, and its determinants so as to facilitate better
as for example in the case of Joint Forest Man- policy design and encourage participation from
agement in India and Community Forestry in groups that suer from a participation decit.
Nepal, has often been to increase participation Finally, results from the research can be re-
of rural households in decision making and viewed in relation to ndings from other parts
benets related to environmental resources. In of the world to gain a better sense of the factors
this paper, we contribute to the existing litera- that are important in promoting participation
ture on CPRs and decentralization by examin- in ongoing decentralization eorts.
ing the factors that help explain local To examine our research question and
participation in government eorts to decen- hypotheses in a concrete setting, we focus
tralize control over resources. The research is on the Parks and Peoples Program (PPP),
important in view of the widespread policy shift launched in 1994 in Nepals Terai region. This
toward decentralized control over natural re- program attempted to enhance local participa-
sources in many developing countries. It is also tion by employing both economic and social
important because many rural communities, incentives. We describe the main features of
especially in Nepals Terai and more generally the PPP and four of the ve protected areas
in South Asia, are highly dierentiated and in Nepals Terai that we studied. We then esti-
stratied in terms of power, income and wealth, mate a statistical model to test our hypotheses
and social status. In such circumstances, the regarding participation. The data for the empir-
question of dierential participation becomes ical test come from a survey of 240 households
especially important because the benets of that we conducted in 199899. 3 The house-
decentralization policies are seen to improve holds reside in four settlements in the buer
with greater participation. Presumably, those zones of the parks in the PPP in the Terai. 4
households that participate more in govern- The settlements were selected randomly from
ment eorts to devolve control over resources a list of all settlements in the buer zone.
are also the ones that gain greater benets from Within each settlement, we randomly selected
resources. Conversely, nonparticipating house- 60 households from a list of households. After
holds benet less from decentralization because discussing the results and their scope in light
they are unable to exercise their voice (Hirsch- of theoretical discussions on participation, we
man, 1970). Our paper attempts to examine conclude with a consideration of some of the
who participates in the governance of CPRs, implications of our research for future analyses
using a specic study to focus directly on fac- of participation in CPR management, and the
tors that shape the extent of participation in design of CPR-related decentralization policies.
government-sponsored decentralization initia-
tives.
More specically, we address the following 2. THE PPP AND THE STUDY AREA
research question: In CPR settings in Nepals
Terai region, what are the major factors inu- The PPP, sponsored jointly by His Majestys
encing participation in government-sponsored Government (HMG) of Nepal and the United
programs? To address this question, we exam- Nations Development Program, is an example
ine four hypotheses about participation that of the ongoing eort to involve communities
focus on economic, social, benets from CPRs, and local populations in the conservation of
and access issues. Briey, we hypothesize that forest resources. It is also an important step
the likelihood of participation in government- in the evolution of resource policy in Nepal.
DECENTRALIZATION AND PARTICIPATION 1103

As a leader among developing countries in set- estation, skill development, and income-genera-
ting conservation goals and priorities (Heinen tion programs (Budhathoki, 2003; UNDP,
& Kattel, 1992), the government of Nepal has 1994).
paid signicant attention to formal legislation The mechanics of the functioning of the PPP-
as a means to involve local rural residents in sponsored user groups are straightforward
environmental conservation. Serious formal (DNPWC, 1998). They exist at the settlement
preservation eorts began in Nepal from 1973 level. All households are eligible members. Vil-
after the passage of the National Parks and lagers meet regularly to contribute savings.
Wildlife Conservation Act and the establish- Their collective savings are the pool from which
ment of the Royal Chitwan National Park in eligible candidates draw loans at mutually
central Terai as Nepals rst protected area. decided interest rates. The loans are used to
Today, Nepal has an extensive network of na- encourage productive economic activities, often
tional parks, wildlife areas, hunting reserves, related to agriculture. PPPs mechanism for
and conservation areas covering nearly 15% investment is called the Internal Credit Fund.
of the countrys total area (Keiter, 1995). 5 A In addition, contributions from external actors
number of government agencies are involved such as the United Nations Development Pro-
in the protection eort including the Depart- gram toward a Village Credit Fund create a
ment of National Parks and Wildlife Conserva- corpus of money from which user group mem-
tion founded in 1980, the Ministry of Forestry, bers can borrow. Borrowers pay back their
the Ministry of Tourism, and the Royal Army loans to the user groups Internal Credit Fund.
whose contingents help enforce many park reg- Over time, the Village Credit Fund will be de-
ulations. pleted.
Increasingly, conservation areas and buer The total area for demarcation as the buer
zone management today have come to rely on zone for the ve protected areas is close to
user groups based in settlements located close 1,866 sq km. 8 The population of the buer
to or within protected area boundaries. The zone (for all ve parks) is estimated at
objective of management typically includes the 683,000. In its rst phase (199497), the PPP
provision of economic opportunities and sus- covered a relatively small proportion of the
tainable development of local populations buer zone. The details about the area covered
through user group activities. In Nepal, many during the rst phase are presented in Table 1. 9
donor agencies are facilitating the formation Two of the protected areas are contiguous
of local user groups, especially in buer zones Parsa and Suklaphanta Wildlife Reserves. We
around parks. 6 The PPP identied the main left out the smaller of these two contiguous
problem in the management of Nepals pro- protected areasThe Parsa Wildlife Re-
tected areas to be conicts between park man- servein selecting the settlements for our re-
agement authorities, and rural households and search.
their subsistence practices (Budhathoki, 2003;
UNDP, 2000). The most notable forms of these
conicts are poaching and encroachment 3. STUDIED VARIABLES, DATA, AND
on park resources, and crop damage and ANALYTICAL MODEL
human casualties from park animals. 7 To ad-
dress these conicts, the PPP aims to develop The eld research for this paper is part of a
alternatives to the use of park resources, pro- larger study conducted using methods devel-
vides compensation to local communities for oped by the International Forests Resources
their exclusion from parks, and creates incen- and Institutions (IFRI) Program. 10 A team
tives for local peoples to modify their resource of four researchers familiar with the IFRI re-
harvesting activities in the protected areas. Pro- search program administered the household
gram documents indicate that the PPP consid- instrument, spending between six and eight
ers higher levels of participation and lower weeks in each eld site. We collected informa-
rural poverty as critical ingredients of success tion on demographic characteristics and socio-
in conservation (UNDP, 2000). Creation of for- economic conditions of the households,
mal user groups is a key mechanism to enhance including information on land ownership,
participation and reduce poverty in the PPP wealth and income, educational level, caste,
strategy. These groups are involved in commu- household harvests of products from forests,
nity organization, savings and rotating credit access to the local government oce, institu-
schemes, and infrastructure construction, aor- tional membership, and occupational aspects.
1104 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

Table 1. Basic statistics on the ve protected areas in the Nepal Terai


Name Area Population Target Tourism
(sq km) (in 000s) number of revenues
user groups (million Rs.)
for PPP
Royal Suklaphanta Wildlife Reserve 155 74 153 0.23
Kosi Tappu Wildlife Reserve 175 172 136 0.54
Parsa Wildlife Reserve 499 126 167 0.17
Royal Bardia National Park 968 69 460 2.72
Royal Chitwan National Park 932 242 750 48.3
Source: UNDP (1994).

The choice of these variables is based on an can also exert a powerful inuence on willing-
extensive literature on determinants of partici- ness to participate in local user groups, even
pation, especially in the context of natural re- if the direction of this inuence is unclear. 11
source use. Caste is a commonly used indicator of social
Some of the earliest research on participa- status in much of South Asia. However, the
tion focused on politics, and suggested that exact status of numerous castes is highly con-
an individuals social status, education, and text specic (Lise, 2000). Education is similarly
organizational membership have a strong eect an important variable that can serve as an indi-
on the propensity to participate in political cator of both social status and economic oppor-
activities (Almond & Verba, 1963; Dahl, tunities (Adhikari et al., 2004; Stem, Lassoie,
1961). In general terms, research on participa- Lee, Deshler, & Schelhas, 2003). In addition,
tion has examined three broad sets of factors: household size can signicantly inuence social
incentives of individuals, socioeconomic and and economic status, including labor availabil-
structural factors, and normative and ideolog- ity, benets households derive from forests, and
ical forces (Verba, Schlozman, Brady, & Nie, ability to tolerate risks by smoothing income
1993). Analogous research on associations, uctuations over time (Naik, 1997).
interest groups, and collective action has also In the context of CPRs, levels of harvested
developed formal models of participation, products from forests are a useful indicator of
and emphasized the importance of taking costs the benets to households from their participa-
and benets of participation into account tion in state-sponsored user groups. They are
(Moe, 1980; Olson, 1965). This research sug- also a rough measure of the dependence of
gests that to explain participation it is impor- the household on forests. A number of scholars
tant to consider both economic and social have focused on benets to households and
variables at the participating household level, dependence as an important inuence on insti-
as also factors that aect benets and costs tutional durability and resource sustainability
to households. (Kant, 2000; Kaushal & Kala, 2004; Netting,
Studies of participation in natural resource 1981). The results of these studies indicate clear
management have tended to support the more dierences among scholars about whether
general arguments above, even as they have households that rely use more forest products
identied specic variables that should be taken are more or less likely to participate in gover-
into account. Many existing studies have also nance.
been highly concerned with questions of equity In addition to the above variables, it is neces-
and distribution in participation (Agarwal, sary also to assess another important aspect of
2001; Botchway, 2001; Teklu & Asefa, 1999). user organizations in the CPR settings upon
Land and livestock holding are commonly used which we focus: the role of the government.
as indicators of economic status and its varia- When governments facilitate the creation of
tions (Adhikari, Di Falco, & Lovett, 2004; organizations/groups to manage CPRs, a sig-
Kumar, 2002). In rural areas in Nepal, remit- nicant part of the agenda is designed by state
tances from outmigrants are common, and the agencies. Government ocials often decide
availability of such income can raise economic about the objectives of the community-level
status substantially. Thus sources of nonagri- groups, the obligations of members, and the
cultural contributions to the household income benets they receive. Careful initiatives can re-
DECENTRALIZATION AND PARTICIPATION 1105

duce costs of local collective action substan- able coded from 0 to 3. We have coded the
tially. Ill-designed interventions can undermine variable thus to reect the degree of participa-
all possibility of widespread participation. It is tion better. The criteria used in coding are as
important therefore to pay attention to the follows:
relationship between government ocials and A household is coded 0 if no household
residents in local communities, the extent to member participates in a state-sponsored
which government ocials are accessible to CPR-management group; (1) if one person
local residents, and how such accessibility af- of the household is a member of a state-
fects participation. sponsored CPR-management group; (2) if:
Given the multiplicity of factors that may (a) one person from the household holds
reasonably shape dierent levels of participa- an ocial position in a state-sponsored
tion, it is important to test the relative contribu- CPR-management group or (b) there are
tion of dierent theoretically relevant variables two household members in the CPR-man-
simultaneously. Doing so can minimize prob- agement group, either as ocials or as
lems related to multiple causation and omitted ordinary members; and (3) if three or more
variable bias. In the empirical context of the household members are in the CPR-man-
study, several of the independent variables agement group, either as ocials or as
may be correlated. Omitting theoretically ordinary members.
important variables can therefore bias the sta- The logic underlying the coding is straight-
tistical coecients of included variables (King, forward. Simple membership in a user group
Keohane, & Verba, 1994). Specically, the translates at best into attendance at meetings,
model we use to analyze our data includes vari- and following the decisions of the user group.
ables pertaining to the household economy, the However, ocial positions such as those of
social status of the households, benets to a chairman, secretary, treasurer, or account-
households from CPRs, and the accessibility keeper in a user group requires greater partici-
of state ocials (Knoke, 1988; Verba et al., pation from the household. Finally, if a
1993). We rely on some of the more commonly household has several individuals who are par-
discussed variables in the literature on gover- ticipating in the user group, then such a higher
nance of common pool forest resource in South level of participation should be reected in the
Asia to operationalize the following empirical data. Our attempt to represent dierent levels
model. of participation is an important part of our
Participation a b  Economic d  Social analysis, and a justication for the ordered pro-
bit statistical model we use.
c  CPRbenefits g  Access
kSize e; e  N 0; r2 ; (b) Independent variables

where: Our independent variables are classied into


Participation = Degree of participation in four categories corresponding to the various
the program; sources of motivation to participate in the
Economic = (Income, Land, Livestock); CPR-management groups created by the PPP.
Social = (Education, Caste); The size variable on the right-hand side of the
CPRbenets = (Firewood, Fodder); equation is a demographic variable referring
Access = (Member visits, Ocer visits); to household size.
Size = Household size. Economic condition: We use three dierent
variables to measure the economic condition
Our use of an ordered probit model is justi- of a household, namely income, land owner-
ed by the nature of our dependent variable: ship, and livestock ownership. These variables
it is neither continuous, nor normally distrib- correspond to the three main types of incomes
uted. The use of an OLS model would likely for households in the rural areas where the
lead to biased estimates for the variables. PPP is active. We constructed these variables
in the following manner.
(a) The dependent variable Income: This indicates whether the house-
hold gets any supplementary income in addi-
Our dependent variable measures house- tion to income from agriculture (e.g.,
hold-level participation in the user groups remittances from outmigrants or govern-
sponsored by the PPP. It is an ordered vari- ment pensions). Given serious problems in
1106 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

nding out exact incomes, we focused on Ocer Visit. The rst measures the frequency
identifying reliably whether sampled house- of members visits to the oces of the PPP
holds had any supplementary income at all. per year; the second measures the frequency
Land: This is the households land owner- of government and PPP ocers visits to house-
ship in kathas (1 katha = 0.034 ha). holds (per year) to encourage them to meet the
Livestock: This variable tells us the num- objectives of the program. A more rened way
ber of livestock units (LU) that a household to measure access would also include the nature
owns. We converted the cattle, sheep, and of these interactions. By only counting the
goats owned by the household into live- number of interactions, our data ignore the nat-
stock units using the following identities: ure of interactions. Our assumption is that
(a) 1.2 cows = 1 LU, (b) 1 bualo = 1 LU, since the period of data collection falls in the
(c) 5 sheep = 1 LU, (d) 4 goats = 1 LU, and initial years of the implementation of the PPP,
(e) two calves = 1 LU. 12 it is likely that visits by members and ocials
Social condition: In our analysis, two main are related primarily to group formation/bene-
variables describe the social condition of a t allocation, and problems in the process of
household: education and caste. We consider group formation/benet allocation.
education for the household by taking into ac- The basic information on the selected vari-
count the years of education for all adult mem- ables is presented in Table 2.
bers in a household (where adult is dened as The model and the variables we describe
15 years or older). Since the total number of above help us test the four participation-related
years of education is likely to be related to hypotheses we listed earlier in the introduction.
the number of household members, we also in- The hypotheses are each connected to the con-
clude household size as a variable in the analy- cern that decentralization programs attempting
sis. 13 The caste variable is simply a dummy to secure participation may not succeed in their
variable that identies whether a household be- objective owing to poor design or insucient
longs to a lower caste. There is a plethora of attention to household-level dierences.
caste categories in the Terai villages. 14 A com-
prehensive list of these categories is extremely
dicult to rank hierarchically. By dening 4. RESULTS AND DISCUSSION
caste as a dummy variable, we considerably
simplify the analysis. Table 3 reports the estimates for the model.
CPRbenets: Two of our variables pertain to The model is highly statistically signicant
the level of benets that surveyed households (p < 0.01), with a Chi-squared statistic of 62.
draw from the common pool resource. These Two of the three economic variables
are (a) the amount of rewood and (b) the income and landare statistically signicant.
amount of fodder that a household harvests Households with supplementary income in
from forests in the protected areas. Fodder addition to their income from agriculture are
and rewood constitute the most important more likely to participate in user groups created
benets for households from the Terai forests. by the PPP (coecient = 0.477, signicant at
In our research, we also collected data on addi- the 10% level). Similarly, households that own
tional products such as thatch grass, reeds for more land are more likely to participate to a
handicraft production, and green manure. greater extent in the groups created by the pro-
These benets were available only to a small gram (coecient = 0.004, signicant at the 5%
proportion of the sampled households, or are level). The livestock variable is not statistically
entirely unavailable to households in some of signicant. The explanation for the statistical
the buer zones. As a result, we focus on re- nonsignicance of the livestock variable might
wood and fodder. These commodities were lie in its positive and statistically signicant cor-
measured in bundles and headloads used annu- relation with three of our other independent
ally, based on observations and estimates pro- variables: land, household size, and income
vided by families. Using conversion values for (correlation = 0.13, 0.26 and 0.25, respectively;
bundles and headloads obtained during eld all signicant at the 10% level).
research, we later transformed the number of Both the social variables are statistically sig-
bundles and headloads into kilograms. nicant. The high statistical signicance of the
Access: We use two variables to indicate the caste variable conrms the hypothesis that
accessibility of government and PPP ocials lower-caste members participate relatively less
to community members: Member Visit and in the user groups created by the PPP
DECENTRALIZATION AND PARTICIPATION 1107

Table 2. Descriptive statistics for the variables used in the analysis


Name of variable Number of observations Mean Standard deviation Minimum Maximum
Participation 230 0.85 0.80 0 3
Size (number of persons) 230 7.82 3.50 1 20
Income 230 0.07 0.25 0 1
Land (kathas) 230 22.88 40.13 0 480
Livestock (units) 230 3.65 2.51 0 16.1
Education (years) 230 15.79 16.76 0 106
Caste 230 0.40 0.49 0 1
Fuelwood (tons/year) 230 1.45 1.59 0 11.35
Fodder (tons/year) 230 2.30 3.82 0 39.14
Ocer visit (per year) 230 2.87 0.65 0 4
Member visit (per year) 230 3.43 0.78 0 4
Source: Field Survey, 199899.

Table 3. The role of economic, social, benet, and access related variables in participation
Name of variable Coecient Standard error
Economic variables
Income 0.477* 0.298
Land 0.004** 0.002
Livestock 0.062 0.035
Social variables
Education 0.012** 0.006
Caste 0.554*** 0.167
CPRbenet variables
Firewood 0.100** 0.050
Fodder 0.038 0.025
Access variables
Ocer visit 0.058 0.133
Member visit 0.396*** 0.116
Size 0.139*** 0.029
Ancillary parameters
Cut 1 0.498 0.457
Cut 2 0.902** 0.459
Cut 3 2.067*** 0.492
LR Chi-squared (10) = 61.7; Prob (Chi-squared) = 0.000.
Pseudo-R-squared = 0.1190.
Note: The table presents the results of an ordered probit equation where the dependent variable is ordered from 0 to
3. The gures in the brackets are standard errors. For the coecients above, *, ** and *** indicate statistical
signicance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% levels, respectively. The ancillary parameters are the cuto points on the
standardized normal distribution used to calculate predicted probabilities for each category of the dependent vari-
able.

(coecient = 0.554, signicant at the 1% level). analysis. Some of the implications of this result
The education variable has a negative sign and are that higher education for the household
is statistically signicant (coecient = 0.012, may open up opportunities for educated indi-
signicant at the 5% level). This indicates that viduals outside the village, making them both
the higher the average number of years of edu- less available to participate in the PPP-spon-
cation of the adult members in a household, the sored user groups, and potentially less inter-
lower the likelihood of the household partici- ested in participating as well. Higher levels of
pating in the program. household education may even reduce the
The high statistical signicance and the nega- dependence of households on resources. This
tive sign of the education variable is an interest- result has important policy implications as well.
ing result, and needs further discussion and Better access to education and greater use of
1108 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

educational opportunities by households can In the reported model, the coecient of the
enhance the goal of resource conservation at household education variable is 0.012 (statis-
the same time as households have the possibil- tically signicant at the 5% level). In the three
ity to improve their socioeconomic status. This new models we tested, the coecients of mens
inference is especially likely if education indeed and womens education were statistically not
helps individuals become more interested in signicant, and varied between 0.001 and
seeking jobs outside the village. To examine 0.012. The coecients of nearly all the other
this issue in more detail, we looked at the cor- variables remained similar to those reported
relation between dierent economic variables in this paper. The data thus suggest that the
and education. We nd that education has a household education as a whole is correlated
weak and statistically nonsignicant but posi- better with levels of household participation
tive relationship with land ownership and non- than when disaggregated by gender, and that
agricultural income, but not caste. Although our results are not sensitive to a variety of dif-
this paper does not aim to investigate intra- ferent ways of operationalizing the education
household and gender issues related to partici- variable to take gender into account. However,
pation, we also examined the relationships of further research where participation is also
the dierent economic variables with the educa- disaggregated by gender might reveal new pat-
tion of men and women in the household. terns that our data do not indicate since we
When we disaggregated education levels by did not collect information on womens and
gender, the correlation of mens and womens mens participation separately.
education with land ownership and income re- Of the two variables related to benets
mained statistically nonsignicant at the 10% from the resource (rewood and fodder), re-
level with one exception: there is a weak but po- wood is statistically signicant. This means
sitive and statistically signicant relationship that as anticipated, households that use higher
between caste and womens educationupper amounts of rewood from the forest are also
caste women are better educated (correla- more likely to try to participate in the program
tion = 0.149, signicant at the 10% level). and to inuence decision making in local groups
We probed deeper into our data in light of through participation (coecient = 0.1, statisti-
the interesting result related to education. We cally signicant at the 5% level). Although we
know from our data that men are more edu- did not collect data on benets to households
cated than women (mean years of education as a proportion of their overall requirements
for adult men are twice those for adult women), of fodder and rewood, we estimated the per ca-
they are more likely to be in positions of pita benets from forests as a potentially better
authority in the PPP-sponsored user groups, measure of benets to households from the for-
and they are more likely to be employed in est. The coecient for both rewood and fodder
o-farm employment positions. If these condi- became smaller as expected, but the levels of sta-
tions hold, it may be the case that our model tistical signicance did not change appreciably
underestimates the correlation between educa- (the coecient for rewood benets per capita
tion and participation. If the assumptions sta- is 0.07, and it is statistically signicant at the
ted above are on the mark, we should expect 5% level; the coecient for fodder is statistically
the variable for mens education to have a nonsignicant). One reason fodder is not statis-
stronger positive relationship with participation tically signicant may be that households may
than the variable for total household education more commonly graze their animals in the open
or for womens education. To test the hypothe- rather than stall feed them. 15
sis, we reanalyzed the data after coding mens One of the access variables is also statistically
and womens education separately, and substi- signicant. Greater accessibility of the Parks
tuting the household-level education variable and Peoples oce to households increases par-
with (a) the two new variables for mens and ticipation in the program. The more visits
womens education; (b) mens education; and members of the user groups make to PPP o-
(c) womens education. The t of all the three ces, the more likely it is that they are participat-
tested models remained close to the results ing at a higher level in the user groups
reported in Table 3 (Chi-square value varied (coecient = 0.396, statistically signicant at
between 55 and 57, and the models were the 1% level). In contrast, visits by government
statistically signicant at p < 0.001). But the ocials do not have a statistically signicant
disaggregated education variables were not sta- correlation with variations in levels of partici-
tistically signicant in any of the three models. pation in user groups.
DECENTRALIZATION AND PARTICIPATION 1109

Finally, the size of the household is also Some of the greatest increases in the proba-
highly statistically signicant. A larger size of bility of participation stem from better access
the household bears a strong positive and sta- of the PPP oce to households, and dierences
tistically signicant relationship with levels of in household size. As the frequency of visits by
participation in PPP-sponsored user groups households to the PPP oces rises from a min-
(coecient = 0.139, statistically signicant at imum to a maximum, the probability of partic-
the 1% level). ipation increases by 0.310. Some reasons that
Table 4 presents the predicted probabilities may account for such a nding is that greater
that a household will participate to a substan- access to government oces and ocials helps
tial degree in the PPP-sponsored user groups disseminate greater information about avail-
(category 2 of the dependent variable), for the able program benets to villagers who are inter-
minimum and maximum values for each statis- ested in such information. Visiting government
tically signicant variable in Table 4, holding ocials can also provide the same information.
all other variables at their mean value. 16 The But unless households are interested in such
last column presents the dierence in the prob- information, it does not make much of a dier-
ability of participation as the variable changes ence to the likelihood of participation. Further,
from its minimum to maximum. it is likely that the well-o and the higher-caste
Among the economic variables, the probabil- households enjoy greater access to government
ity of participation increases from 0.094 to ocials and therefore undertake more visits.
0.191 if households have some supplementary However, in light of the fact that our data are
income. The eect on participation of variation from a single time period, we cannot discount
in land ownership from the lowest to the high- the possibility that there is reverse causality at
est observed value is also large: probability of work heregreater participation in the PPP-
participation increases from 0.080 to 0.341. sponsored user groups is what leads to more
Being from an upper caste increases the proba- visits by households to PPP oces. There is
bility of participation of a household by 0.111. one likely reason that may mitigate against
More education has a negative eect on the such an interpretationif it is participation
probability of participation. At the maximum that promotes interactions between households
value of education for a household, the proba- and government ocials, then households par-
bility of its participation in PPP-sponsored user ticipating more in the PPP should also receive
groups declines by 0.217. More benets to more visits from government ocials. But the
households from forests increase the likelihood coecient for ocials visits to participating
of participation. With other variables held con- households is both small and statistically non-
stant at their means and the dichotomous vari- signicant. We can cautiously infer that the
ables at 0, if rewood harvests increase from data provide some support for an argument
the minimum to the maximum value, the prob- to improve the ability of marginal and poorer
ability of participation increases by 0.226. households to access government oces and

Table 4. Change in probability of participation as statistically signicant variables vary from a minimum to a maximum
Name of variable At minimum value At maximum value Dierence between minimum and maximum
Economic variables
Income 0.094 0.191 0.097
Land 0.080 0.341 0.261
Social variables
Caste 0.094 0.205 0.111
Education 0.281 0.055 0.226
Dependence variables
Firewood 0.074 0.300 0.226
Access variables
Member visit 0.064 0.374 0.310
Size 0.015 0.417 0.402
Note: This table reports predicted probabilities of being in category 2 of the Participation variable. Probabilities are
reported at the minimum and maximum values of the statistically signicant variables in Table 3, holding other
variables at their mean values, and dummy variables at 0. The nal column reports the change in probability as the
independent variable changes from a minimum to a maximum.
1110 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

ocials if greater participation from such sourcestechnical, economic, political, social


households is desired as a part of decentraliza- serviceare distributed along lines of exist-
tion policy reforms. ing inequality and thus reinforce it unless
Finally, as the size of the household increases accompanied by radical, massive institutional
from a minimum to a maximum, the probabil- changes. . . (1978: p. 249). Our results are cer-
ity of participation also rises from 0.015 to tainly not as dramatic as the above assertion by
0.417. Schwartz. Indeed, the PPP attempts to create
The information in Table 4 is interesting both socioeconomic change mainly to improve the
because of its policy implications, and for its livelihood of participants, and reduce pressure
value as an indication of the social and eco- on park resources. But we nd that richer and
nomic relationships pertaining to participation. upper caste households have a higher probabil-
Obviously, it is not possible to use policy to ity of joining the user groups that the PPP has
help households make transitions across mini- created to decentralize environmental decision
mum to maximum values for several variables making and distribute benets from environ-
in Table 4. Individuals are born into a caste, mental resources. More specically, large land-
and changes are possible only over multiple ownership, having a high income, and being in
generations, if at all. Even the level of land an upper caste facilitate greater participation in
ownership is not really under the control of PPP-sponsored user groups. These results are
those framing environmental policies. But some relevant in the context of work by other schol-
of the other variables may reasonably be mod- ars that also shows how better-o and more
ied through policy measures. Two such vari- powerful local groups tend to appropriate
ables are education and visits by members. greater levels of benets from decentralized
Higher education levels are especially attractive community-level groups (Adhikari et al.,
as a policy option because of the important po- 2004; Crook, 2003; Ostrom, 2005; Weinberger
sitive impacts of education on other aspects of & Jutting, 2001).
rural livelihoods as well. Further, government- The results of our research are especially
sponsored user groups can improve the fre- important in the context of signicant political
quency of visits by poorer and socially less asymmetries in rural Nepal. Although decen-
powerful user group members by taking advan- tralization of environmental policy cannot ad-
tage of the likelihood that their opportunity dress or redress the political inequalities that
cost of time is lower than that of richer and so- are at least partially responsible for the violence
cially more powerful households. Locating the that has become an endemic feature of the rural
program oce closer to settlements, requiring Nepalese context, it can at least attempt not to
regular attendance at more frequent meetings exacerbate such inequalities. Indeed, this obser-
held at the program oce, and tying benets vation is relevant to the issue of elite domination
from the program to regular attendance may elsewhere as well. Whether it is bias in existing
make richer villagers less inclined to participate forms of program implementation that encour-
since they are likely to lose more by committing ages the economically and socially better-o to
greater amounts of time to program activities. participate more, or whether they are better able
Similarly, promoting income-generation activi- to participate because of microlevel social and
ties that do not depend on land ownership political connections with government ocials
but on education and training in nonagricul- and greater access to existing resources is an
tural occupations are also likely to benet those open question. Indeed, overt bias toward the
with a lesser amount of land. better-o rural residents is dicult to show in
the design and implementation structure of the
PPP. However, the more relevant point is that
5. CONCLUSION even without bias in favor of the richer, more
powerful rural residents, it is those with more
We began this paper by asking the question, land, more sources of income, and a higher-
Who participates in government-sponsored caste status who tend to participate more.
CPR-management programs? The results of Our results constitute a note of caution for
our analysis of an environmental policy decen- the way many decentralization programs are
tralization program are in broad agreement implemented in relation to environmental pol-
with what scholars of development have argued icy: in a relatively neutral fashion as far as
for long. As Schwartz pointed out for commu- securing the participation of the poor and so-
nity development, externally introduced re- cially marginal groups is concerned. If there is
DECENTRALIZATION AND PARTICIPATION 1111

a greater propensity on the part of the upper least for some poor households, the costs of
caste, the landed, and those who have more regular participation may be quite high. And
sources of income to participate more in for the really poor, programs such as the PPP
state-sponsored local organizations, then decen- may be ill suited to address poverty or secure
tralization programs that are neutral in their participation in resource conservation. Pro-
design as far as eliciting participation is con- grams explicitly aimed at addressing chronic
cerned will likely not aect equity at the local poverty may be the only mechanisms to sup-
level. Indeed, they may well exacerbate inequal- port such groups, although even such programs
ity. Those concerned with equity and democ- have not always worked well.
racy in common pool resource governance, The results related to household-level educa-
therefore, need to consider more carefully the tion also have direct implications for participa-
design and implementation of community-ori- tion as well as consumption of benets from
ented decentralization programs so that partic- park resources. Our data highlight the impor-
ipation can be biased in favor of the poor and tance of total household education on partici-
the marginal. pation: Higher education has a negative
Our statistical analysis points to two impor- relationship with participation in the user
tant policy-relevant ndings that are not new, groups of the PPP. The relationship is likely a
but directly concern the design of programs to result of declining interest in the PPP, and its
secure greater participation of the poorer and benets as higher levels of education make it
more marginal groups. The model suggests that possible to look for other sources of employ-
households initiating more interactions with ment and income, and possibly migrate out of
government ocials by visiting the oces of the settlement. The exact balance of the impact
the PPP are also more likely to be participants on participation as a result of greater educa-
in the user groups of PPP. There may be a natu- tion, and remittances from outmigrants to their
ral overlap between those who are better-o, homes needs further investigation.
and those with higher access to government o- To conclude, one way to enhance the partic-
ces. But since the participation-related eective- ipation of poor, lower-caste groups in local user
ness of decentralization programs can be groups is to take advantage of their lower
enhanced by improving the ability of house- opportunity cost of time, and tie program ben-
holds to contact and access government ocials, ets to greater commitment of time (frequent
the promotion of decentralization programs can local meetings, and regular attendance at these
be accompanied by specic steps to encourage meetings). Another way to do so, our data and
the economically and socially more marginal analysis indicate, is by creating greater access to
local residents to visit government oces. Such education among members of user groups.
encouragement may be achieved in two ways: Other scholars have pointed to mechanisms
by locating program oces closer to poorer set- for promoting equality that allow the poor to
tlements, and by requiring regular attendance at trade their shares of benets from the com-
frequent meetings and tying benets from the mons, require membership of lower-caste
program to regular attendance. groups in the decision-making committees of
Improving access of the poor and landless to local user groups, or argue for greater account-
local government oces and ocials through ability of decision makers (Adhikari et al.,
better information provision and greater dialog 2004; Crook, 2003; Nightingale, 2002). Only
can also have an important positive impact on when community-oriented decentralization
broadening participation. Indeed, such donor programs succeed in securing greater participa-
support has important bearing on the participa- tion from more vulnerable groups will it be
tion of the poor according to studies in other possible to meet the objectives of distributing
contexts as well (Weinberger & Jutting, 2001, benets more equitably and promoting local
p. 1402). It is important also to note that at democracy.

NOTES

1. Decentralization has seemingly become popular only See Agrawal and Ribot (1999) for a more general
since the mid-1980s. But earlier claims by governments statement about waves of decentralization in Africa and
that they are decentralizing decision-making authorities South Asia.
can be discerned in many areas of the developing world.
1112 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

2. See Ostrom (1990) and Ostrom, Gardner, and region: the Rara and the Khaptad National Parks. In the
Walker (1994) for a discussion of common pool second phase, there is also a shift in emphasis toward
resources and an analysis of the conceptual dierences community-based approaches and on development and
between common pool resources and common property self-reliant socioeconomic development.
regimes.
10. The International Forest Resources and Institu-
3. We interviewed 240 households in our eldwork. tions (IFRI) Program was initiated in 1992 at Indiana
But we discarded 10 responses because of incomplete University. The program comprises a network of
answers, or because of data reliability concerns. The Collaborating Research Centers in a number of coun-
nal statistical analysis was carried out on the remaining tries including Nepal, and aims to elucidate links
230 household responses. between institutional arrangements and forest manage-
ment. The chief means of data collection is a set of 10
4. The legal denition of buer zones is areas set aside research protocols focusing on biophysical, socioeco-
around a national park or reserve. . . for granting nomic, and institutional variables in a given site
opportunities to local people to use forest products on (Gibson, McKean, & Ostrom, 2000; Poteete & Ostrom,
a regular basis (UNDP, 1994, p. 3). An area of 2004). Collectively, these protocols include nearly 1,000
controlled land use, a buer zone, as the name suggests, variables.
separates a protected area from direct human or other
pressures and provides valued benets to neighboring 11. Availability of o-farm income to households is
rural communities (Nepal & Weber, 1994, p. 333). also an indirect measure of the articulation of a given
family with market opportunitiesanother relevant
5. For studies of biodiversity in the protected areas in variable aecting propensity to participate in local
Nepal and their economic signicance see Brown (1997) resource governance institutions (Beckley, 1998).
and Wells (1993). For their utility to subsistence users in
terms of products such as grass, fodder, and fuelwood,
12. Transformation of dierent types of animals into a
see Byers (1996) and Heinen and Yonzon (1994).
standardized livestock unit, based on the average weight
of dierent animals is common in the literature on
6. Even a partial list of agencies that have supported grazing systems (FAO, 2003, p. 2). Conversion into
environmental conservation activities in Nepal would standardized units is complicated, however, by varia-
include Action Aid, ADB (Asian Development Bank), tions in average animal weights across dierent contexts.
AusAID (Australian Governments Overseas Aid Pro- Tropical livestock units are typically taken to be 250 kg
gram), CARE International, DANIDA (Danish Agency of animal weight (Sidahmed, 1993). The more important
for Development Assistance), EuropeAid, FAO (Food element here is to take into account conversion ratios
and Agriculture Organization), GEF (Global Environ- across species (Thorton et al., 2002). We have relied on
ment Facility), GTZ (German Society for Technical the above publications to arrive at the conversion factors
Cooperation), SNV (Netherlands Development Organi- used in the analysis. To examine the robustness of our
zation), UNDP (United Nations Development Pro- results, we also conducted our analysis keeping browsers
gram), WWF (World Wildlife Fund), USAID (United (sheep and goats) and grazers (cows and bualoes)
States Agency for International Development), and the distinct, but this renement produced little dierence in
World Bank. the statistical signicance of livestock, or in the value of
the coecients of other variables.
7. Similar conicts are also present around protected
areas in other parts of the world (Hill, 2002; Vanderge-
13. As discussed earlier, household size is also an
est, 1996).
important variable for other reasons, including the
possibility that it reects labor availability within the
8. The buer zone area for the two parks (Chitwan and household, and the households ability to withstand
Bardia) has been identied and gazetted. For the three smooth income uctuations over time.
wildlife reserves (Suklaphanta, Parsa, and Kosi Tappu),
the area has been identied, but survey work for
14. The major groups coded as upper caste are
demarcation and ocial notication was still under
Brahman, Chhetri, and Thakuri. Lower castes included
way at the time of this study.
Biswakarma, Damai, Giri, Kami, Koiri, Lohar, Sanyasi/
Yogi, and Sunar. Dhami, Majhi, and Tharu are the
9. The objective of the PPP is the coverage of all tribal groups we encountered who strictly speaking do
protected areas in Nepal. In 1998, the project was not have a caste status. Given their low social status,
launched in two additional areas outside the Terai however, we coded them as low caste as well.
DECENTRALIZATION AND PARTICIPATION 1113

15. The gures in Table 2 support this inference. 16. We consider probabilities for the level of participa-
Sampled households own, on the average 3.5 livestock tion where a household has more than one member
units. Even if one takes a conservative estimate of 5 kg participating in the programs user groups, or a member as
of dry feed per animal, this would imply a total annual the ocial in the Program-sponsored user groups. This is
fodder requirement of approximately 6.4 tons per year. category 2 of the dependent variable. We did not examine
The mean fodder harvest level by sampled households, category 3 since there are very few households who have
however, is 2.3 tonsjust over 35% of what is individuals in ocial positions as well as multiple members
needed. in the program (only 7 our of 230 observations).

REFERENCES

Adhikari, B., Di Falco, S., & Lovett, J. C. (2004). De Vries, M. S. (2000). The rise and fall of decentral-
Household characteristics and forest dependency: ization: A comparative analysis of arguments and
Evidence from common property forest manage- practices in European countries. European Journal of
ment in Nepal. Ecological Economics, 48(2), 245 Political Research, 38(2), 193224.
257. DNPWC (Department of National Parks and Wildlife
Agarwal, B. (2001). Participatory exclusions, community Conservation) (1998). Guidelines for the preparation
forestry, and gender: An analysis for South Asia and of buer zone user group plan. Park and People
a conceptual framework. World Development, 29(10), Program (Nep/94/001). Park and People Program,
16231648. DNPWC, Kathmandu.
Agrawal, A., & Ostrom, E. (2001). Collective action, Fiszbein, A. (1997). The emergence of local capacity:
property rights and decentralization in resource use Lessons from Colombia. World Development, 25(7),
in India and Nepal. Politics and Society, 29(4), 10291043.
485514. FAO (Food and Agriculture Organization) (2003).
Agrawal, A., & Ribot, J. C. (1999). Accountability in Livestock sector brief: LAO PDR. Rome: FAO.
decentralization: A framework with South Asian and Gibson, Clark C., McKean, Margaret, & Ostrom, E.
West African cases. Journal of Developing Areas, 33, (Eds.) (2000). People and forests: Communities,
473502. institutions, and governance. Cambridge: MIT Press.
Almond, Garbriel A., & Verba, S. (1963). The civic Heinen, J. T., & Kattel, B. (1992). A review of
culture: Political attitudes and democracy in ve conservation legislation in Nepal: Past progress and
nations. Princeton: Princeton University Press. future needs. Environmental Management, 16(6),
Andersson, K. P., Gibson, C. C., & Lehoucq, F. (2004). 723733.
The politics of decentralized natural resource gover- Heinen, J. T., & Yonzon, P. B. (1994). A review of
nance. PSPolitical Science and Politics, 37(3), conservation issues and programs in Nepal: From a
421426. single species focus toward biodiversity protection.
Beckley, T. M. (1998). The nestedness of forest depen- Mountain Research and Development, 14, 6176.
dence: A conceptual framework and empirical explo- Hill, C. M. (2002). Primate conservation and local
ration. Society and Natural Resources, 11(2), communities: Ethical issues and debates. American
101120. Anthropologist, 104(4), 11841194.
Botchway, K. (2001). Paradox of empowerment: Reec- Hirschman, A. O. (1970). Exit, voice, and loyalty:
tions on a case study from Northern Ghana. World Responses to declines in rms, organizations, and
Development, 29(1), 135153. states. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.
Brown, K. (1997). Plain tales from the grasslands: Kant, S. (2000). A dynamic approach to forest regimes
Extraction, value and utilization of biomass in Royal in developing economies. Ecological Economics,
Bardia National Park, Nepal. Biodiversity and Con- 32(2), 287300.
servation, 6, 5974. Kaushal, K. K., & Kala, J. C. (2004). Applying the
Budhathoki, P. (2003). Buer zone initiatives in Nepal: sustainable livelihood approach to joint forest man-
Balancing the scales. Mimeo. http://www.protected- agement projects in India. International Forestry
landscapes.org/paper1.html. Accessed on September Review, 6(1), 1318.
12, 2004. Keiter, R. B. (1995). Preserving Nepals national parks:
Byers, A. C. (1996). Historical and contemporary Law and conservation in the developing world.
human disturbance in the Upper Barun Valley, Ecological Law Quarterly, 22, 591675.
Makalu-Barun National Park and Conservation King, G., Keohane, R., & Verba, S. (1994). Designing
Area, East Nepal. Mountain Research and Develop- social inquiry: Scientic inference in qualitative
ment, 16, 235247. research. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Crook, R. C. (2003). Decentralisation and poverty Knoke, D. (1988). Incentives in collective action orga-
reduction in Africa: The politics of local-central nizations. American Sociological Review, 53(3),
relations. Public Administration and Development, 311329.
23(1), 7788. Kumar, S. (2002). Does participation in common pool
Dahl, R. A. (1961). Who governs? New Haven: Yale resource management help the poor? A social cost
University Press. benet analysis of joint forest management in
1114 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

Jharkhand, India. World Development, 30(5), Stem, C. J., Lassoie, J. P., Lee, D. R., Deshler, D. D., &
763782. Schelhas, J. W. (2003). Community participation in
Lise, W. (2000). Factors inuencing peoples participa- ecotourism benets: The link to conservation prac-
tion in forest management in India. Ecological tices and perspectives. Society and Natural Resources,
Economics, 34(3), 379392. 16(5), 387413.
Moe, T. M. (1980). A calculus of group membership. Teklu, T., & Asefa, S. (1999). Who participates in labor
American Journal of Political Science, 24(4), 593 intensive public works in Sub-Saharan Africa: Evi-
632. dence from rural Botswana and Kenya. World
Naik, G. (1997). Joint forest management: Factors Development, 27(2), 431438.
inuencing household participation. Economic and Thorton, P. K, Kruska, R. L., Henninger, N., Krisjan-
Political Weekly, 32(48), 30843089. son, P. M., Reid, R. S., Atieno, F., Odero, A. N., &
Nepal, S. K., & Weber, K. (1994). A buer zone for Ndegwa, T. (2002). Mapping poverty and livestock in
biodiversity conservation: Viability of the concept in the developing world. Nairobi: ILRI (International
Nepals Royal Chitwan National Park. Environmen- Livestock Research Institute).
tal Conservation, 21, 333341. UNDP (United Nations Development Program) (1994).
Netting, R. McC. (1981). Balancing on an Alp. Cam- Parks and People Project Document (DNPWC/
bridge: Cambridge University Press. UNDP). His Majestys Government of Nepal, Kath-
Nightingale, A. J. (2002). Participating or just sitting in? mandu.
The dynamics of gender and caste in community UNDP (2000). Consolidating Conservation through
forestry. Journal of Forestry and Livelihoods, 2(1), Peoples Participation: Parks and People Programme
1724. (DNPWC/UNDP). His Majestys Government of
Olson, M. (1965). The logic of collective action. Cam- Nepal, Kathmandu.
bridge: Harvard University Press. Vandergeest, P. (1996). Property rights in protected
Ostrom, E. (1990). Governing the commons. New York: areas: Obstacles to community involvement as a
Cambridge University Press. solution in Thailand. Environmental Conservation,
Ostrom, E. (2005). Understanding institutional diversity. 23(3), 259268.
New York: Cambridge University Press. Verba, S., Schlozman, K. L., Brady, H., & Nie, N. H.
Ostrom, E., Gardner, R., & Walker, J. (1994). Rule, (1993). Citizen activity: Who participates? What do
games, and common pool resources. Ann Arbor: they say? American Political Science Review, 87(2),
University of Michigan Press. 303318.
Poteete, A. R., & Ostrom, E. (2004). Heterogeneity, Weinberger, K., & Jutting, J. P. (2001). Womens
group size and collective action: The role of institu- participation in local organizations: Conditions and
tions in forest management. Development and constraints. World Development, 29(8), 13911404.
Change, 35(3), 435461. Wells, M. (1993). Neglect of biological riches: The
Ribot, J. C. (2002). Democratic decentralization of economics of nature tourism in Nepal. Biodiversity
natural resources: Institutionalizing popular participa- and Conservation, 2, 445464.
tion. Washington, DC: World Resources Institute. Willis, E., Christopher da, C. B. G., & Haggard, S.
Sidahmed, A. E. (1993). Institutional and economic (1999). Decentralization in government: Latin Amer-
framework conditions for livestock development in ica. Latin American Research Review, 34(1), 756.
developing countries and their interrelationships. Wunsch, J. S., & Olowu, D. (1997). Regime transfor-
Plenary paper, Proceedings of the international mation from below: Decentralization, local gover-
conference on livestock development in developing nance, and democratic reform in Nigeria. Studies in
countries, Weilheim, Germany, May 1720, 1993. Comparative International Development, 31(4), 6682.

You might also like