You are on page 1of 8

Do Budget Decits Cause Ination?

BY KEITH SILL

I s there a relationship between government Yet for developed countries, such as


the U.S., which tend to have relatively
budget deficits and inflation? The data show low inflation, there is little evidence
that some countriesusually less developed of a tie between deficit spending and
inflation. Why is it that budget deficits
nationswith high inflation also have large are associated with high inflation in
budget deficits. Developed countries, however, show little some countries but not in others?
The key to understanding the re-
evidence of a tie between deficit spending and inflation. lationship between government budget
In Do Budget Deficits Cause Inflation?, Keith Sill deficits and inflation is the recognition
that government deficit spending is
states that the extent to which monetary policy is used linked to the quantity of money cir-
to help balance the governments budget is the key to culating in the economy through the
government budget constraint, which is
determining the effect of budget deficits on inflation. He
the relationship between resources and
examines the theory and evidence on the link between spending. At its most basic level, the
budget constraint shows that money
fiscal and monetary policy and, thus, between deficits
spent has to come from somewhere: in
and inflation. the case of local and national govern-
ments, from taxes or borrowing. But
national governments can also use
In 2004, the federal budget deficit amount of federal debt held by the monetary policy to help finance the
stood at $412 billion and reached 4.5 public as a fraction of GDP has been governments deficit.
percent of gross domestic product rising since the early 1970s. It now The extent to which monetary
(GDP). Though not at a record level, stands at a little over 37 percent of policy is used to help balance the
the deficit as a fraction of GDP is now GDP (Figure 2). government's budget is the key to
the largest since the early 1980s. More- For a long time, economists and determining the effect of budget
over, the recent swing from surplus to policymakers have worried about the deficits on inflation. In this article, we
deficit is the largest since the end of relationship between government will examine theory and evidence on
World War II (Figure 1). The flip side budget deficits and inflation. These the link between fiscal and monetary
of deficit spending is that the amount worries stem from the possibility that policy and, thus, between deficits and
of government debt outstanding rises: the government will finance its deficits inflation.
The government must borrow to by borrowing or by printing money.
finance the excess of its spending over Should deficit spending and a large BUDGETS AND ACCOUNTING
its receipts. For the U.S. economy, the public debt be worrisome for monetary Budget constraints are a fact of
policymakers who are concerned about life we all face. Were told we cant
the economys level of inflation? Do spend more than we have or more than
government budget deficits lead to we can borrow. In that sense, budget
Keith Sill is a higher inflation? When looking at constraints always hold: They reflect
senior economist
in the Research
data across countries, the answer is: the fact that when we make decisions,
Department of it depends. Some countries with high we must recognize we have limited
the Philadelphia inflation also have large government resources.
Fed. budget deficits. This suggests a link An example can help fix the idea.
between budget deficits and inflation. Imagine a household that gets income

26 Q3 2005 Business Review www.philadelphiafed.org


cial assets such as stocks and bonds.1
FIGURE 1 The households budget constraint
says that the sum of its income from
Federal Surplus/Decit Relative to GDP
working, from financial assets, and
0.06 from what it borrows must equal its
spending plus debt repayment, plus
0.04 new investment in financial assets.
There are no financial leaks in the
0.02
budget constraint: The households
0 sources of funds are all accounted for,
its spending is all accounted for, and
-0.02 the two must be equal. The household
may use borrowing to spend more than
-0.04
it earns, but that source of funding is
accounted for in the budget constraint.
-0.06
If the household has hit its borrowing
-0.08 limit, fully drawn down its assets, and
1950 1954 1958 1962 1966 1970 1974 1978 1982 1986 1990 1994 1998 2002 spent its work wages, it has nowhere
else to turn for funds and would there-
Source: Haver Analytics fore be unable to finance additional
spending.
Just like households, governments
FIGURE 2 face constraints that relate spending
to sources of funds. Governments can
Federal Public Debt Outstanding raise revenue by taxing their citizens,
as a Fraction of GDP and they can borrow by issuing bonds
0.6 to citizens and foreigners. In addition,
governments may receive revenue from
0.5 their central banks when new cur-
rency is issued. Governments spend
0.4 their resources on such things as goods
and services, transfer payments such
0.3 as Social Security to its citizens, and
repayment of existing debt. Central
0.2 banks are a potential source of financ-
ing for government spending, since the
0.1 revenue the government gets from the
central bank can be used to finance
0 spending in lieu of imposing taxes or
issuing new bonds. For example, the
73

83

93

03
69

79

89

99
71

81

91

01
65

75

85

95
67

77

87

97
19

19

19

20
19

19

19

19
19

19

19

20
19

19

19

19
19

19

19

19

U.S. Treasury received a little more


Source: Ofce of Management and Budget, Flow of Funds Accounts than $22 billion from the Federal
Reserve in 2003.2
Much of a central banks revenue
from working and from past invest- food, clothing, and haircuts. It can also
comes from its monetary policy opera-
ments in financial assets. The house- use the funds to pay back some of its
hold can also borrow, perhaps by using past borrowing and to invest in finan-
a credit card or getting a home-equity
loan. The household can then spend
2
Recent detail on Federal Reserve payments to
1
The household can also sell some of its assets the Treasury can be found in the 90th Annual
the funds obtained from these sources to finance consumption. This is tantamount to Report, Board of Governors of the Federal Re-
to buy goods and services, such as negative investment in assets. serve System, 2003, Table 5, page 270.

www.philadelphiafed.org Business Review Q3 2005 27


tions. An important aspect of modern Interest payments on government inflation. Since the creation of high-
monetary policymaking is controlling debt held by the public.3 powered money, and thus seigniorage,
the short-term interest rate. Central This spending is funded by: is undertaken by the central bank, the
banks do this by purchasing and selling Tax receipts; consolidated budget constraint shows
interest-earning government bonds. The increase in debt held by the the link between fiscal policy and
If the central bank wants to raise the public; and monetary policy. Money creation is a
interest rate, it sells government bonds. The increase in high-powered source of revenue for the government.
If it wants to lower the interest rate, it money. The amount of revenue the govern-
buys government bonds. As a conse- Note that if the government ment gets from seigniorage has impli-
quence of these open market operations, increases the quantity of high-powered cations for the governments choices
central banks have government bonds money it can reduce other taxes or about taxes, borrowing, and spending.5
in their portfolios, and these bonds borrowing.
earn interest. Thus, one component of The revenue the government HOW MUCH CAN THE
central bank revenue is interest earned gets from the increase in high-pow- GOVERNMENT BORROW?
on the government bonds it holds. ered money is called seigniorage.4 The consolidated budget con-
The second component of central The extent to which governments straint shows the link between the
bank revenue is also related to open use seigniorage as a means for financ-
market operations. Central banks ing budget deficits plays a key role in 5
There is also a subtle way in which govern-
are able to create and issue money to the link between budget deficits and ments can use monetary policy to help finance
spending. If the government can generate sur-
pay for the government bonds they prise inflation, the real value of the payments
purchase. The money that central 3
Recall that interest paid on government debt it makes to holders of its debt falls below what
held by the central bank goes back to the trea- investors expected to receive when they bought
banks create is called high-powered sury. the debt. Surprise inflation erodes the value
money, and it takes the form of cur- of government debt, which means that a lesser
4
More technically, seigniorage is the real amount of real tax revenue must be raised to
rency held by the nonbank public plus
increase in the stock of high-powered money pay off bondholders. However, generating sur-
the reserves banks are required to (currency held by the nonbank public plus bank prise inflation to finance spending is ultimately
hold against certain types of depos- reserves), i.e., the increase in the stock of high- a losing game for the government. Eventually,
powered money adjusted for the level of prices investors will catch on to what the government
its. Since the central bank can issue in the economy. As shown in Figure 3, for the is doing and demand a high enough interest
high-powered money to pay for things U.S., this measure of seigniorage has been small. payment to compensate them adequately for the
See the book by Frederic Mishkin. governments inflation policy.
like government bonds, an increase
in high-powered money represents a
source of central bank revenue. FIGURE 3
Revenues are one side of the
central banks budget constraint. Seigniorage Relative to Government Spending
What does the central bank spend its 0.06
revenue on? As mentioned, a major
0.05
use of funds is to purchase government
debt in the conduct of open market 0.04
operations. The other component of
0.03
central bank spending is residual: what
is left over after the central bank pays 0.02
its expenses. In the U.S., this residual
gets turned over to the Treasury each 0.01

year. 0
We can get a consolidated govern-
ment budget constraint by combining -0.01

the budget constraints of the treasury -0.02


and the central bank. The govern- 1962 1966 1970 1974 1978 1983 1986 1990 1994 1998 2002
Q4 Q4 Q4 Q4 Q4 Q4 Q4 Q4 Q4 Q4 Q4
ment spends its revenue on:
Goods and services;
Source: Haver Analytics
Transfer payments; and

28 Q3 2005 Business Review www.philadelphiafed.org


governments choices about spending, that backs government debt must be value of seigniorage. Since seignior-
taxing, borrowing, and seigniorage. discounted to take account of the time age is related to high-powered money
This relationship is a constraint only value of money. That is, the current growth, the implication is that money
in the sense that there may be limits value of debt must equal the present growth must increase in the future.
on the governments ability to borrow discounted value of future surpluses Similarly, if the government decides to
or raise taxes. Obviously, if there were and future seigniorage.8 permanently increase future surpluses
no such limits, there would be no con- for example, a permanent increase
straint on how much the government Monetary policy in taxes or a permanent reduction in
could spend at any point in time. borrowing so that the present dis-
Certainly governments are limited
does not necessarily counted value of future surpluses rises,
in their ability to tax citizens. (That is, have to adjust money the present discounted value of future
the government cant tax more than growth in response seigniorage must fall; therefore, future
100 percent of income.) But are gov- money growth must fall.10
ernments constrained in their ability to decit spending... Note that the constraint does not
to borrow? Indeed they are. Informally, provided that decit say that an increase in deficits must
the value of government debt out- be accompanied by a rise in seignior-
standing today cannot be more than
spending is expected age. An increase in the deficit could
the value of the resources the govern- to be offset by future be temporary in the sense that it will
ment has to pay off the debt.6 surpluses. be offset by future surpluses. In other
How do governments pay their words, a deficit today could be negated
current debt obligations? One way is We call this relationship the by a future surplus, so that the present
for the government to collect more governments intertemporal budget con- discounted value of future surpluses
tax revenue than it spends. In this straint.9 It indicates that the govern- remains unchanged. In that case, no
case, the surplus can be used to pay ment must plan to raise enough rev- offsetting adjustment in the value of
bond holders. Another way to finance enue (in present value terms) through discounted future seigniorage would
existing debt is to collect seignior- taxation and seigniorage to pay off its be necessary. Monetary policy does
age revenue and use that to pay bond existing debt and to pay for its planned not necessarily have to adjust money
holders. Finally, the government can expenditures on goods, services, and growth in response to deficit spend-
borrow more from the public to pay ex- transfer payments. ing by the government, provided that
isting debt holders. If the government The intertemporal budget con- deficit spending is expected to be offset
chooses this last option, any new debt straint has some interesting implica- by future surpluses. But if the present
it issues would, in turn, have to be paid tions for monetary and fiscal policy. discounted value of future surpluses
off using future surpluses, future sei- Suppose the government decides that, changes, there must be an offsetting
gniorage, or future borrowing. As long for a set path of future spending, it will change in the present discounted value
as the amount of debt the government lower current and future taxes perma- of seigniorage, and vice versa.
issues to pay its obligations does not nently. This policy would lower the
grow too fast over time, we can think present discounted value of future sur- POLICY, DEFICITS, AND
of the current value of outstanding pluses. So, to fund the path of future INFLATION
government debt as being ultimately spending, the government would need Suppose that whenever there is a
backed by a stream of future surpluses to increase the present discounted change in the present discounted value
and future seigniorage.7 Since inves- of seigniorage, fiscal policy adjusts so
tors generally prefer to receive payouts that the intertemporal budget con-
sooner rather than later, the future 8
Present value refers to an amount of money to- straint holds. In this case, monetary
day that will become a given amount at a stated
stream of surpluses and seigniorage point in the future, depending on the interest policy is independent in the sense that
rate. For example, if the interest rate is 10 per- monetary policymakers take action
cent, $100 today will be worth $110 in one year.
without regard to fiscal policy, and
6
A formal derivation of this relationship can be So the present value of $110 one year from now
found in the Technical Appendix. (with an interest rate of 10 percent) is $100. then fiscal policy adjusts to maintain
7
We have assumed that in the long run, govern- 9
An intertemporal constraint shows how gov-
ment debt does not grow at a rate faster than ernment resources and spending are linked over 10
The government can permanently increase fu-
the interest rate. time. ture surpluses by raising taxes or borrowing less.

www.philadelphiafed.org Business Review Q3 2005 29


a balanced budget.11 With monetary policy is independent and fiscal policy value of seigniorage must rise to match
independence, policymakers are free to is dependent or vice versa is the key the increase in the value of public
pursue goals such as low and stable in- to answering the question of whether debt outstanding. That is, the central
flation and not have to worry about us- budget deficits imply higher inflation. bank will be required to increase the
ing money growth to finance treasury Dependent Monetary Policy May rate of money growth (seigniorage), an
budget deficits. In this case, we would Result in Unexpected Outcomes. In action that ultimately leads to higher
not expect a tight link between gov- a 1981 article, Thomas Sargent and inflation.12 In this case, efforts to use
ernment budget deficits and inflation Neil Wallace offer a famous example monetary policy to lower inflation are
because current government budget of how dependent monetary policy can self-defeating.
deficits are expected to be largely offset lead to unexpected outcomes. Suppose
by future government budget surpluses. fiscal policy is independent, monetary EMPIRICAL EVIDENCE ON
In addition, the path of government policy is dependent, monetary policy INFLATION AND DEFICITS
budget surpluses is expected to offset responds to fiscal policy, and the Economic theory suggests that the
changes in seigniorage, so that the strength of the relationship between
intertemporal budget constraint holds. It seems safe to say government budget deficits and infla-
This does not mean that we may tion depends on whether monetary
not observe some correlation between
that, for the U.S. policy is independent or dependent
deficits and spending. For example, economy, there relative to fiscal policy. In countries
if the economy is hit by a recession, is little, if any, link where seigniorage is an important
the deficit is likely to rise because tax component of government finance,
revenues fall. At the same time, mon- between decits and we are likely to find that govern-
etary policymakers may lower interest ination. ment budget deficits and inflation are
rates to combat the recession, an act empirically linked. In countries with
that may subsequently lead to higher intertemporal budget constraint holds. independent monetary authorities, the
inflation. In this case, though, deficits In this case, an attempt by monetary link between deficits and inflation is
are not, per se, the cause of inflation. policymakers to rein in inflation today likely to be weaker.
Rather, deficits and inflation are both by lowering money growth can result Evidence for the U.S. Economy.
consequences of the recession. in higher inflation in the future: As we can see from a plot of deficits
The alternative case is one in Policymakers are ultimately defeated and inflation for the U.S. economy
which monetary policy is dependent. in their efforts to lower inflation. How since the end of World War II, there
When monetary policy is dependent, could this happen? does not appear to be much of a rela-
the central bank adjusts seigniorage Suppose monetary policymak- tionship between government budget
so that the budget constraint holds. ers lower current money growth in an deficits and inflation (Figure 4). The
Monetary policy responds to fiscal effort to bring down inflation. Lower contemporaneous correlation between
policy, so that seigniorage revenue money growth means lower seignior- federal budget deficits and inflation
becomes an important component of age. If government spending and taxes (GDP deflator inflation) is essentially
government finance. An independent do not change, the government will zero. It is possible that deficits today
treasury might decide to run perma- have to borrow more from the public are more highly correlated with future
nent deficits, a situation that requires in order to make up for the lost rev- inflation than with current inflation
seigniorage to make up the gap be- enue from seigniorage. If the outstand- it may take some time for deficits to
tween the value of the public debt and ing public debt increases, the intertem- be felt in the form of higher inflation.
the present discounted value of budget poral budget constraint implies that But even if we look for the largest cor-
surpluses. In this case, we could expect there must be a corresponding increase relation between current deficits and
to see a link between deficits and in the present discounted value of fu- future inflation, we find that it is still
inflation, since monetary policymak- ture budget surpluses and seigniorage. rather low at 10 percent, when current
ers respond directly to a fiscal policy In a regime of fiscal independence, deficits are correlated against inflation
of deficit spending. Whether monetary fiscal policy does not adjust, so the
present discounted value of budget 12
There is a strong empirical link between mon-
ey growth and inflation for a wide range of
11
See Michael Dotseys article for more on inde- surpluses does not change. But that countries over a long span of time. See the ar-
pendent and dependent monetary policy. means that the present discounted ticle by George McCandless and Warren Weber.

30 Q3 2005 Business Review www.philadelphiafed.org


six quarters ahead. It seems to be the GDP averaged about 4 percent in high- A 2003 study by Luis Catao and
case that for the U.S. economy, deficits inflation countries versus an average of Marco Terrones uses a broader sample
and inflation are largely unrelated. 1.5 percent in low-inflation countries. of 107 countries over the period 1960
It seems safe to say that, for the High-inflation countries rely more on to 2001 to look for a link between fis-
U.S. economy, there is little, if any, seigniorage to help finance govern- cal deficits and inflation. They find a
link between deficits and inflation. ment spending. The authors find that strong link between fiscal deficits and
The reason is that the Federal Reserve for high-inflation countries, a worsen- inflation in developing countries. For
largely sets monetary policy indepen- ing fiscal balance is much more likely example, a 1 percent reduction in the
dently of what the Treasury is doing to to be accompanied by an increase in ratio of the budget deficit to GDP is
finance the federal government budget seigniorage than is the case in low-in- associated with an 8.75 percent lower
deficit. The Fed turns over its profit flation countries. inflation rate. Catao and Terrones also
to the Treasury each year, but the Fed What triggers inflation? The au- find results similar to those of Fischer,
does not conduct monetary policy to thors use standard techniques to show Sahay, and Vegh when the sample is
raise revenue for the Treasury. Rather, that fiscal deficits lead to high infla- broken into high-inflation and low-in-
the Fed focuses on stabilizing infla- tion when the government depends on flation countries using the 100 percent
tion and unemployment and does not revenue from seigniorage to finance annual inflation rule. But they also
conduct monetary policy with an eye debt. They find that for high-infla- find a statistically significant relation-
toward financing fiscal deficits. tion countries, a 10-percentage-point ship between deficits and inflation in
More thorough evidence than reduction in the fiscal balance (i.e., countries with moderate inflation as
simple correlations bears out the deficit) as a fraction of GDP is associ- well, though the link is weaker. For
finding that deficits and inflation are ated with, on average, a 4.2 percent low-inflation and advanced countries,
weakly linked, if at all, in the U.S. and, increase in seigniorage. For low-infla- Catao and Terrones find no link be-
for that matter, in most of the worlds tion countries, there is no significant tween fiscal deficits and inflation.
advanced economies.13 However, there link between deficits and seigniorage. For developing countries, seignior-
does seem to be a link between deficits Also, when high-inflation countries age is a significant source of revenue,
and inflation in the worlds less-devel- experience episodes of low inflation, and fiscal policy appears to be an
oped economies. For those countries, the link between deficits and inflation important ingredient for the amount
high inflation is often associated weakens dramatically. of inflation. Indeed, over the period
with high average government budget
deficits.
Evidence for the Rest of the FIGURE 4
World. A recent study by Stanley
Fischer, Ratna Sahay, and Carlos Vegh Federal Decit and Ination
classified a sample of 94 countries
into high-inflation and low-inflation
countries. High-inflation countries, of
which there were 24 in their sample,
are those that experienced at least one
episode of 12-month inflation exceed-
ing 100 percent over the span 1960 to
1995. On average, inflation in those
countries was a bit over 150 percent
per year. Seigniorage as a fraction of

13
An older set of empirical studies tended
to find that there was at best a tenuous link
between deficits and inflation for the U.S.
economy. See the papers by G. Demopoulos,
G. Katsimbris, and S. Miller; K. Grier and
H. Neiman; D. Joines; and Robert King and Source: Haver Analytics
Charles Plosser.

www.philadelphiafed.org Business Review Q3 2005 31


1980 to 1995, seigniorage as a fraction lot of resources to devote to building policy goals and implementing them.15
of GDP averaged about 2.2 percent, an efficient tax-collection system. For the U.S. economy, there is
compared with only 0.64 percent in little evidence of a link between fiscal
advanced economies such as the U.S., SUMMARY deficits and inflation, precisely because
Germany, and Japan.14 One possible Monetary policy and fiscal policy monetary policymakers have been free
reason for the greater reliance on seign- are linked because money growth, to pursue goals such as low and stable
iorage revenue in developing econo- in the form of seigniorage, provides inflation. They are able to do this
mies is that, for them, seigniorage may revenue to the fiscal branch of the because fiscal policy is seen as sustain-
be a relatively efficient method to raise government. But whether deficits lead able, in the sense that deficit spending
revenue compared with other forms to inflation depends on the extent to today is not expected to continue to
of taxes. In developing countries, it which monetary policy is independent, the extent that monetary policy will
may be difficult to collect tax revenue, that is, the extent to which monetary have to provide major funding for the
since the tax base tends to be small policymakers must react to fiscal Treasury. This is largely the case for
and difficult to identify, especially financing developments when setting the developed countries of the world.
when the government does not have a Developing countries, however, often
require revenue from seigniorage to
15
We have focused on the possible inflation meet their fiscal financing needs.
14
For more detail on seigniorage revenue in consequences of government budget deficits. Thus, these countries tend to show a
developing and advanced economies, see the Other questions of interest we have not ex-
article by Paul Masson, Miguel Savastano, and plored include the impact of budget deficits on
strong link between fiscal deficits and
Sunil Sharma. real interest rates and exchange rates. subsequent inflation. BR

Technical Appendix
The Government's Intertemporal Budget Constraint
We can express the consolidated budget constraint in the symbolic form:

i t -1 B t -1+G t = Tt+(B t B t -1 )+( H t H t -1 )


where G t is government spending at time t, i t - 1 B t - 1 is interest payments on publicly held government debt out-
standing, Tt is tax receipts, and H t is high-powered money. The left-hand side of the expression is total spending by the
government and the right-hand side is total sources of revenue. It is convenient to put the budget constraint in infla-
tion-adjusted, or real, terms by dividing through by the price level Pt . Define the real interest factor as
1+it
(1+rt ) =
(Pt / Pt-1)
Well use lower case to denote real values. Then re-arranging terms, we can write the consolidated budget con-
straint as:

( 1 + r ) b t- 1 + g t = t t + b t + s t
In this expression, tt is the real value of taxes collected, and st is the real value of the increase in money, or
seigniorage. Finally, ( 1+ r ) is the real interest factor on government debt, which we assume (for simplicity) is constant
over time. If we iterate the budget constraint forward T times into the future, we get:
T
t t+i - g t+i+ s t+i
T
bt+T
(1+ r ) b t -1= +
i=0 (1+ r ) i i=0 (1+ r ) i (1+ r ) T
As long as the real amount of debt outstanding grows no faster than the real interest rate, which is a condition that
says enough economic resources will be available to fully pay off any debt outstanding, then as T gets larger, the last
term in the expression should get closer and closer to zero.
The first term on the left-hand side of the equal sign is the present discounted value of future budget surpluses. The
second term is the present discounted value of future seigniorage. The equation shows that the real value of debt held
by the public (principal and interest) is constrained by the governments ability to raise revenue to pay it off.

32 Q3 2005 Business Review www.philadelphiafed.org


REFERENCES

Board of Governors of the Federal Grier, K., and H. Neiman. Deficits, McCandless, George, and Warren
Reserve System. 90th Annual Report, Politics and Money Growth, Economic Weber. Some Monetary Facts,
2003. Inquiry, 25(2), April 1987, pp. 201-14. Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis
Quarterly Review, 19(3), Summer
Catao, Luis, and Marco Terrones. Joines, D. Deficits and Money 1995, pp. 2-11.
Fiscal Deficits and Inflation, IMF Growth in the United States 1872-
Working Paper WP/03/65 (2003). 1983, Journal of Monetary Economics, Mishkin, Frederic A. The Economics of
16(3), November 1985, pp. 329-51. Money, Banking and Financial Markets,
Demopoulos, G, G. Katsimbris, and S. 6th edition. Reading, MA: Addison-
Miller. Monetary Policy and Central- King, Robert, and Charles Plosser. Wesley, 2001.
Bank Financing of Government Money, Deficits, and Inflation,
Budget Deficits, European Economic Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series Sargent, Thomas, and Neil
Review, 31(5), July 1987, pp. 1023-50. on Public Policy, 22, Spring 1985, pp. Wallace. Some Unpleasant
147-96. Monetarist Arithmetic, Federal
Dotsey, Michael. Some Not-So- Reserve Bank of Minneapolis
Unpleasant Arithmetic, Federal Klein, Martin, and Manfred Neumann. Quarterly Review, 5(3), Winter 1981,
Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Seigniorage: What Is It and Who pp. 1-17.
Quarterly, 82, 4 Fall 1996. Gets It? Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv.,
126(2), 1990, pp. 205-21. Walsh, Carl. Monetary Theory and
Dwyer, Gerald P., Jr., and R.W. Hafer. Policy. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press,
The Federal Governments Budget Masson, Paul R., Miguel A. Savastano, 2003.
Surplus: Cause for Celebration, and Sunil Sharma. Can Inflation
Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta Targetting Be a Framework for
Economic Review, July 1998. Monetary Policy in Developing
Countries? IMF Finance and
Fischer, Stanley, Ratna Sahay, and Development, March 1998, pp. 34-37.
Carlos Vegh. Modern Hyper- and
High Inflations, Journal of Economic
Literature 60 (2002), pp. 837-80.

www.philadelphiafed.org Business Review Q3 2005 33

You might also like