You are on page 1of 14

'O Academy of Management journal

1999, Vol. 42, No. 5, 526-538.

CORPORATE PERFORMANCE AND STAKEHOLDER


MANAGEMENT: BALANCING SHAREHOLDER AND
CUSTOMER INTERESTS IN THE U.K. PRIVATIZED
WATER INDUSTRY
STUART OGDEN
University of Leeds

ROBERT WATSON
University of Strathclyde

This study examined a major contention of stakeholder theory: namely, that a firm can
simultaneously enhance the interests of its shareholders and other relevant stakehold-
ers. Financial data relating to the U.K. water supply industry and the customer service
performance indicators introduced after privatization in 1989 to protect customer
interests provided the hasis of our empirical analysis. The results show that, although
improving relative customer service performance is costly for firms in terms of current
profits, shareholder returns respond in a significantly positive manner to such im-
provements. We interpret this finding as being consistent with stakeholder theory.

Privatization has been a significant feature of the tor, of performance measures of customer service.
political and economic scene in the United King- These measures provide an opportunity to empiri-
dom since 1980. Privatization refers to the transfer cally examine a key contention of stakeholder the-
of ownership and control of an economic activity ory, namely, that companies practicing stakeholder
previously undertaken hy nationally or locally gov- management will, other things being equal, be rel-
ernment-controlled agencies to private-sector, prof- atively successful in conventional financial perfor-
it-seeking organizations. In various forms, privat- mance terms (cf. Donaldson & Preston, 1995).
ization has also become increasingly popular in the Privatization in 1989 resulted in the ten state-
rest of western Europe (Vickers & Wright, 1989), in owned regional water companies becoming public
the formerly centrally planned economies (Ash, limited companies, each with a full London Stock
Hare, & Canning, 1994), in less developed countries Exchange listing of its shares. Despite the govern-
(Price, 1994), and in Canada and Australia (Rich- ment's claim that private-sector provision of goods
ardson, 1990). Privatization of publicly owned util- and services subject to the disciplines of market
ities is of particular interest from the perspective of forces would be more efficient than public-sector
stakeholder management. The transfer from public provision (Department of the Environment, 1986),
to private ownership not only involves significant there had been scant opportunity to develop market
changes in the composition of stakeholders, but competition in the water industry (Littlechild,
also requires consideration of how the interests of 1986). Consequently, privatization left the monop-
the different stakeholders are to be balanced by the oly character of the industry largely unchanged.
managers of the privatized utility. This is high- Each of the ten water companies continued to op-
lighted in the case of the recently privatized U.K. erate as a regional monopolist controlling the sup-
water industry, where, by virtue of the essential ply of an essential commodity. Privatization, there-
nature of the product, managers could not be left to fore, required the U.K. government to design a
pursue the interests of the new shareholders exclu- regulatory system that would ensure that the man-
sively. The need to ensure that account was taken agers of the ten water companies had, in addition to
of customer interests has led to the development, legal obligations regarding water quality and other
by an independent government-appointed regula- public health matters, incentives to maintain a sat-
isfactory balance between the potentially conflict-
We thank the editors of this AMJ special research fo- ing interests of two key stakeholders: the new
rum and the two anonymous reviewers for their helpful shareholders, and customers. The regulatory sys-
comments on a draft of this article and Helen Short of the tem, though primarily based upon price controls,
University of Leeds for her invaluable research assis- also provides strong financial incentives for firms
tance. Both authors contributed equally to this work. to be cost-efficient while encouraging them to in-
526
1999 Ogden and Watson 527

vest resources on improvements in customer ser- economic efficiency. The "incomplete contracting"
vice. Thus, the regulatory system provides an op- literature (Ezzamel & Watson, 1997; Garvey &
portunity to empirically test stakeholder notions Swan, 1994; Hart, 1995; Kay & Silberston, 1995), for
whereby the proper objectives and responsibilities example, contains the argument that economic ef-
of firms extend beyond the maximization of share- ficiency frequently requires firms' executives to ex-
holder returns (cf. Freeman, 1984; Freeman & Evan, ercise their discretion in a way favoring the inter-
1990). ests of other stakeholders, such as customers and
The purposes of this study were, first, to examine suppliers. The executives do so because, if other
how the potential conflicts of interest between stakeholders perceived that managerial discretion
shareholders and customers were intended to be was always being exercised in favor of one partic-
reconciled through the system of regulation and, ular partyfor instance, shareholders or the exec-
second, to determine whether any empirical evi- utives themselvesthey would be unwilling to do
dence suggested that the system of regulation actu- business with the firms. From this perspective, an
ally achieved its main purpose. We empirically economically successful firm will necessarily be
investigated the performance of the privatized wa- one in which senior management adopts corporate
ter companies in terms of both financial measures governance strategies and policies that facilitate the
(that is, relative shareholder returns and profitabil- maintenance of an appropriate balance between
ity) and customer service performance measures. different stakeholder interests.
These latter performance measures, which are Though this argument is conceptually clear, it
monitored and published by the water industry has proved difficult in practice to evaluate specific
regulator annually, constitute an important crite- institutional arrangements for incorporating non-
rion for determining the maximum allowable price shareholder interests, particularly in terms of their
increase for each water company. In addition, a effect on economic performance. Indeed, the ease
water company's high score on customer service with which shareholders can be identified and the
measures both reduces the probability of its expe- ready availability of shareholder wealth and finan-
riencing adverse regulatory interventions and en- cial performance measures in part explain the con-
hances its reputation with potential purchasers of tinuing primacy attached to shareholder interests.
nonregulated services. Consequently, attaining Defining who other stakeholders are, determining
high levels of customer service can be expected to how their interests are best served, and developing
have a positive effect upon anticipated future in- performance indicators that measure a compajiy's
come streams. This expectation in turn is an incen- degree of success in doing so are corhplex issues
tive for water company executives to ensure that not easily resolved in practice. Donaldson and
their organizations perform well on these customer Preston, for example, commented that testing a
service measures. simple hypothesis, such as the statement that cor- .
It is hypothesized that although discretionary ex- porations whose managers adopt stakeholder prin-
penditures made to improve customer service will ciples and practices will perform better financially
be costly in terms of current reported profits, they than those that do not, "involves some formidable
will be associated with higher shareholder returns challenges" (1995: 77). Not surprisingly, they noted
since investors will perceive that future profit lev- a dearth of empirical tests of such hypotheses and
els and risk exposure will be improved. Our empir- cited the work of Clarkson (Clarkson, Deck, &
ical results are consistent with the above hypothe- Shiner, 1992; cf. Clarkson, 1995) as the only signif-
ses. We found that performance on customer icant example known to them.
service measures is significantly, negatively corre- In the case of the U.K. privatized water compa-
lated with current profits but significantly, posi- nies, these problems of defining stakeholder inter-
tively correlated with shareholder returns mea- ests and measuring how well those interests are
sures. served are much reduced. The regulatory system
for the water industry requires an explicit articula-
tion of the interests to be served by regulation and
STAKEHOLDER THEORY AND THE the measures by which its effectiveness may be
REGULATION OF THE PRIVATIZED assessed. The water companies therefore provide
WATER INDUSTRY an interesting research site for empirically examin-
Stakeholder models of the firm have attracted ing some of the issues raised by a stakeholder view
considerable support in recent years (e.g., Donald- of the firm. Although managers had for the first
son & Preston, 1995), not only because of ethical time to consider the interests of shareholders after
dissatisfaction with the exclusive privileging of water privatization, maximizing shareholder re-
shareholder interests, but also on the grounds of turns could not be pursued without constraint.
528 Academy of Management foumal October

Given the nature ofthe product, managers had also supplier while still providing a reasonable return to
to satisfy a numher of public health and safety investors (Cowan, 1994; Littlechild, 1986). This
concerns and to meet standards set for water qual- partial adjustment process promotes cost efficiency
ity and customer service. In this context, the water hy providing firms with an incentive to achieve
companies presented a strong prima facie case for greater-than-anticipated cost savings, since the re-
arguing that managers were required to take a stake- sulting increase in profitability represents a recur-
holder perspective on their performance. The ap- ring annual windfall gain until the ic-factor is rene-
propriateness of this was widely acknowledged. gotiated.
Kay and Silherston (1995), for example, writing An exclusive focus on providing incentives for
from an incomplete contracting perspective, com- firms to reduce costs may, however, result in man-
mented that, given the nature of water as a product, agers reducing expenditures on activities related to
no sensible person would wish to have water sup- customer service. Indeed, Littlechild, in his official
plied hy a company that invariably put the interests report for the Department of the Environment on
of its shareholders ahead of those of its customers! the regulatory framework for the privatized indus-
The essence of the U.K. water company regula- try, questioned whether "a privatized Water Au-
tory system is contained in the duties prescrihed thority [would] have any incentive to set and meet
for the director general of the Office of Water Ser- challenging levels of service targets which do not
vices (OFWAT). According to the 1991 Water In- contribute directly to profits" (1986: 18). Public
dustry Act, he^ has a primary duty to ensure that awareness of the obvious conflict of interests be-
the functions of water and sewerage undertakers tween shareholders' desire to have increases in
are properly carried out and that companies are profits and customer service requirements was
able (in particular, by securing reasonable returns high. Consequently, in establishing the new regu-
on their capital) to finance the proper carrying out latory framework, the government claimed that it
of their functions. The director general also has the would "be designed to ensure that the benefits of
secondary duties of protecting the interests of cus- greater efficiency are systematically passed on to
tomers in respect to the level of charges, the quality customers in the form of lower prices and better
of services, promoting economy and efficiency and, service than would otherwise have occurred" (De-
where possible, facilitating competition between partment of the Environment, 1986: 3). This claim
the water companies. is reflected in OFWAT's aim, stated in an informa-
Econom.ic regulation operates through price con- tion leaflet distributed to the public: "to ensure that
trols, based on the so-called RPI + k formula. The the companies provide customers with a good qual-
first component of the pricing formula is designed ity and efficient service at a fair price" (Office of
to allow each firm to recover general rises in prices Water Services, 1998).
outside of its control, or inflation, as measured by To allow companies to finance their provision of
the retail price index (RPI), and the second compo- water services and to encourage them to improve
nent is an adjustment factor (k) that is separately customer service levels, the regulator is able to
negotiated between each company and the director allow^ all or part of the costs involved to be recov-
general of OFWAT. The individual ic-factors, which ered from customers through adjustments to the
are subject to periodic review, are based on an i:-factor in the pricing formula. Customer service
assessment of each company's inherited infrastruc- improvements have typically involved reducing
ture and the new investment it needs to achieve the. problems of low water pressure, improving the se-
requisite water quality and service standards, other curity of the water supply, reducing the need for
unique local factors that impact upon costs (such as restrictions in periods of low rainfall, and improv-
geology and climate), and an efficiency target. The ing the handling of contacts with customers, such
director general assesses the scope for improved as billing complaints. In determining whether to
efficiency in terms of both the individual operating allow the costs of new investment to improve cus-
circumstances of each company and comparisons tomer service levels, the director general of
with the costs incurred by the most efficient of the OFWAT has first to decide whether a planned in-
other companies for similar activities (the so-called vestment is appropriate and second, what propor-
yardstick or benchmark cost basis). Where appro- tion of these costs may be passed on to customers.
priate, the director general determines the speed In considering this, he takes into account the qual-
with which a firm can reasonahly be expected to get ity of service already provided, the levels of service
its costs down to the levels of the most efficient provided by the other water companies, cost com-
parisons with other companies, and the scope for
improvements in internal efficiency. Insofar as the
^ One man has held this office since its inception. director general allows costs (including a reason-
1999 Ogden and Watson 529

able return on capital) to be passed on to customers, sessments of company performance are then pub-
a firm may enhance its future profits, although lished in late November or early December.
clearly, its current-year profits would be reduced OFWAT has noted, however, that only four of the
by the costs of the improvements. measures of servicewater pressure, interruptions
However, there are penalties as well as incen- of supply, responses to billing queries, and re-
tives in the privatized system. The director general sponses to written complaintscurrently allow for
annually scrutinizes each company's progress to- comparisons between companies (see Table 1).
ward meeting its quality obligations and its perfor- OFWAT views the number of properties at risk for
mance in delivering services to customers. He may sewer flooding as unsuitable for comparative pur-
penalize companies whose performance is poor by, poses because the data currently available lack con-
for example, making punitive adjustments to the sistency. The adequacy of the water supply and
ic-factor, or by requiring a company to engage in restrictions on water use are also considered un-
additional expenditure to make good performance suitable as they are largely influenced by climatic
shortfalls without taking any compensating allow- and weather patterns (Office of Water Services,
ance for the costs incurred (cf. Office of Water 1994). Also, reliable comparable data have only
Services, 1997). The director general is likely to be been available since 1991 for two of the measures
particularly severe to companies in which invest- that can be compared, pressure and interruptions.
ment programs are not on track for delivering the Another initiative to protect customers' interests
targeted service improvements allowed for in price involved the establishment of ten customer ser-
limits. Investigations (Office of Water Services, vices committees (CSCs). Each covers a geographic
1996) of three companies' failure to meet agreed- area approximately equivalent to the boundaries of
upon outputs resulted in one company, Yorkshire one of the old water authorities. The committees
Water, having to agree not to raise charges by more are independent of the water companies, and the
than the rate of inflation from April 1, 1998, until chair and members (usually 12) of each customer
March 2000. The benefit to Yorkshire Water's cus- service committee are all appointed by the director
tomers has been estimated to be approximately 44 general. Their mission statement, as set out in an
million. Ultimately, of course, the director general annual report, is the following: "The CSC will rep-
may seek to have a company's appointment to pro- resent the interest of customers of the water and
vide water services terminated. Consequently, per- sewerage companies in its region and will advise
forming well in delivering services to customers is and support the DG in regulating the water industry
of critical importance to the water companies. to secure for customers the combination of service
and price they would have in a competitive mar-
ket" (Office of Water Services National Customer
Council, 1998). One of the CSCs' principal tasks is
MEASURES OF CUSTOMER SERVICE
to investigate and resolve complaints made to them
OFWAT has developed seven indicators of levels about the water companies. These are reported, as a
of service to monitor the quality of service the U.K. percentage of each company's customer base, each
water companies provide to their customers. These year in the CSCs' annual reports and are high-
are the adequacy of water resources, the pressure of lighted in OFWAT's annual reports. The com-
water mains, interruptions to the supply, water use plaints to the customer service committees provide
restrictions, properties at risk of sewer flooding, the an important additional measure of customer ser-
total number of written and telephoned queries vice; see Table 1, where this measure appears as
about billing and the time taken to respond to them "complaints to OFWAT."
and, finally, the total number of written complaints
received about any aspect of service and the time
INCENTIVES FOR BALANCING SHAREHOLDER
taken to respond to them. These measures are seen
AND CUSTOMER INTERESTS
by OFWAT as "important output measures" (Office
of Water Services, 1990: 1). Each year all the com- The water company executives have had to take
panies are required to report to OFWAT on the OFWAT's disciplinary powers and the regulatory
quality of the delivery of their services in terms of penalties for poor or substandard performance se-
these seven indicators (e.g.. Office of Water Ser- riously, particularly since the director general has
vices, 1991). The reporting period covered by the declared his intention to take into account each
customer service measures coincides with the company's performance on customer service in his
firms' accounting year, which runs from April 1 to periodic review of prices and ic-factors (Office of
March 31. Firms are required to supply the regula- Water Services, 1993). Consequently, the managers
tor with the necessary data in July. OFWAT's as- have been keen to achieve quality improvements to
530 Academy of Management Journal October

TABLE 1
Descriptive Statistics by Year'
Variable 1992 , 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997

Financial characteristics
and firm performance
Total sales'' 332.40 (179.20) 393.30 (233.70) 467.80 (279.80) 524.50 (314.90) 584.40 (326.40) 627.20 (350.20)
Total capital employed'' 1,243.20 (505.60) 1,505.50 (607.70) 1,700.80 (671.80) 1,891.80 (773.10) 2,034.30 (837.40) 2,210.10 (962.70)
Debt/equity '^ 0.13 (0.07) 0.29 (0.08) 0.35 (0.12) 0.38 (0.16) 0.38 (0.18) 0.68 (0.72)
Posttax profit/equity "^ 12.10 (2.30) 12.70 (1.90) 12.50 (1.70) 11.90 (1.60) 12.40 (1.30) 14.20 (2.20)
Annual shareholder 30.60 (7.60) 0.80 (2.50) 55.50 (3.90) 8.30 (4.40) -0.30 (13.30) 27.00 (7.10)
returns (April-March) "*
Shareholder returns for -0.04 (0.03) -0.03 (0.02) -0.05 (0.03) 0.05 (0.03) 0.08 (0.03) 0.04 (0.10)
profits announcement
month (May-June) "*
Shareholder returns for - 0 . 0 6 (0.02) 0.05 (0.02) -0.04 (0.03) 0.06 (0.02) 0.02 (0.03) 0.02 (0.03)
customer service
performance
announcement month
(November-December) "^
Customer service performance
measures
Complaints to OFWAT 1.80 (0.80) 4.80 (3.60) 6.60 (4.50) 6.50 (4.60) 5.20 (3.00) 5.50 (2.70)
Inadequate water 0.90 (1.00) 1.00 (0.80) 1.00 (0.80) 0.80 (0.70) 0.60 (0.50) 0.80 (0.90)
pressure''
Supply interruptions "^ 0.40 (0.40) 0.20 (0.20) 0.30 (0.30) 0.40 (0.50) 0.30 (0.40) 0.70 (0.90)
Responses to billing 2.20 (1.20) 2.90 (1.20) 2.90 (1.30) 3.80 (1.20) 4.40 (0.70) 4.80 (0.40)
queries
Responses to written 1.90 (1.00) 1.90 (0.90) 3.20 (1.40) 3.90 (1.70) 4.80 (0.40) 4.90 (0.30)
complaints

Statistics are means and standard deviations (in parentheses). JV = 10 (observations per year).
^ Millions of U.K. pounds.
" Proportions.
^ Percentages.
" Ratings on a five-point scale, where 1 was "very poor" and 5 was "very good."

customer service within declared time scales and newly privatized companies from the old public sec-
budgets and have, on occasion, volunteered to pro- tor companies. They were also anxious to counter the
vide additional improvements in customer service. many critics of the water privatization process (Og-
Companies have variously offered customers re- den, 1991). On both counts, there is little doubt that
bates or abatements of the available price increase managers believed that being responsive to customer
allowed for in their A:-factors, and they have intro- needs and providing good service to customers w^as
duced customer service initiatives that went be- part of the definition of a successful private sector
yond statutory requirements in areas such as com- company. From the perspective of resource depen-
pensation for missed appointments (Office of Water dency theory (e.g., Pfeffer & Salancik, 1978), a credit-
Services, 1997). These improvements were de- able demonstration of commitment to customer ser-
signed to secure the goodwill of the director general vice was simply seen as a condition of their
as w^ell as to benefit customers. However, all these continued survival. This is particularly evident in the
"voluntary" provisions have entailed significant mission statements made by the boards of the water
amounts of expenditure, which have on occasion companies in their statutory annual reports. The
caused concern to shareholders. Certainly invest- Northimibrian Water Group's 1994 annual report pro-
ment analysts have been conscious that the water vides a typical example: "At the heart of our new
companies could spend too much money on vision of the Group's future is the need for us all
achieving high standards of customer service, as within Northumbrian Water to focus our efforts
well as too little (Ogden, 1997). ever more intensely on the needs and desires of our
Senior managers of the water companies have had customers."
reasons beyond regulatory considerations for pursu- Furthermore, managers were conscious that im-
ing improvements in customer service. In the first proved customer service could serve as a source of
instance, managers were keen to distinguish their legitimacy for their new private-sector status. Manag-
1999 Ogden and Watson 531

ers' pursuit of legitimacy may be considered as re- tially rich research setting for examining many of
flecting strategic initiatives (cf. Ashforth & Gibbs, the implications and actual consequences that arise
1990; Pfeffer & Salancik, 1978; Suchman, 1995) to in the practical application of stakeholder concep-
instrumentally deploy and manipulate their new- tions of the firm. Our primary concern here was to
found commitment to customer service and thus to investigate whether any empirical evidence sug-
gamer support for their new private-sector status. It gested that the postprivatization regulatory system
may also be considered as an example of an institu- actually produced significant benefits to both
tional response to cultural pressures for enterprise shareholders and customers. Positive results are
and consumer sovereignty that underpinned the gov- not a forgone conclusion since the history of utility
errunent's whole privatization project (Ogden, 1997). regulation is replete with examples of "regulatory
Managers were also aware that comparisons of capture" (for a review, see Self [1993]). The many
performance made possible by OFWAT's measures statements in OFWAT and water company publi-
of levels of service were used by other audiences, cations affirming the importance of customer ser-
most notably the City and financial analysts. Ana- vice may have simply constituted marketing hype
lysts' reports on individual water company perfor- and/or self-serving rhetoric declaimed by the inter-
mance, although primarily concerned with finan- ested parties to legitimate their current policies and
cial performance, have considered performance on practices. What would count as evidence that the
customer service as an important indicator of man- regulator and the water companies w^ere taking im-
agerial competence and company success. Analysts provements in customer service seriously would be
have also incorporated the levels of service perfor- (1) evidence that customer service performance (as-
mance into assessments of a company's exposure to sessed in terms of the published measures) was
regulatory risk and the likelihood of any company's improving over time coupled with (2) evidence that
having to remedy some shortfall in performance customer service performance was also economi-
expected by the regulator, with all its attendant cost cally significant in relation to reported profits and
im^plications and reputational damage [e.g., Char- shareholder w^ealth measures.
terhouse Tilney Equity Research, 1993; Warburg Given the possibility that the published customer
Securities, 1991). service measures might simply reflect the regula-
Finally, senior managers have seen commercial tor's and the water companies' joint desire to be
potential in achieving good performance on cus- seen to be attending to customer interests, a plau-
tomer service measures that extends beyond the sible null hypothesis was that results on these mea-
regulatory sphere of OFWAT. Establishing a repu- sures would not be related in any economically
tation as a customer-focused organization, particu- meaningful manner to either the companies' profits
larly when doing so may be externally validated by or their returns (dividend payments and capital
an independent body such as OFWAT, is valued as gains) to their shareholders. The following two al-
a resource in exploiting business opportunities out- ternative hypotheses suggest themselves:
side the regulated activities of water services. The
importance of this, and the resource-based view of Hypothesis 1. The customer service perfor-
the firm it reflects (e.g.. Hall, 1992), should not be mance ofthe United Kingdom's privatized wa-
underestimated. To date, the two main areas of ter companies, as measured by published cus-
diversification for the water companies have been tomer service levels, will be negatively related
waste management services and international con- to the companies' contemporaneous reported
, tracts for providing water services. Further support profitability.
for this consideration can be drawn from the mar- Hypothesis 2. The customer service perfor-
keting literature (e.g., Kotler, 1984). In particular, mance ofthe United Kingdom's privatized wa-
Narver and Slater's study (1990) indicates that ter companies, as measured by published cus-
business performance may be enhanced in the tomer service levels, can be expected to have a
longer term by increasing market orientation, par- positive impact on future profitability and
ticularly in terms of the attention given to custom- will therefore be positively related to current-
ers' current and future needs. This effect appears to period shareholder returns.
apply whatever the degree of competition within a
company's environment (Slater & Narver, 1994), a We tested the first hypothesis to establish
finding of particular relevance to the water compa- whether or not differences between companies in
nies since they remain regional monopolists in re- terms of the published measures of customer ser-
gard to the provision of water services. vice were related to differences in profits. Support-
From the above, it can be argued that the privat- ive results would indicate that the water companies
ization ofthe U.K. water industry provides a poten- were prepared to commit real resources, which
532 Academy of Management Journal October

would have otherwise accrued to their sharehold- firm-specific fixed effects, both the average profit
ers, to improving their customer service. We tested levels and shareholder returns of the sample were
the second hypothesis to ascertain whether these influenced by common economy- or sector-wide
customer service results had any consequences for factors. In testing our hypotheses, therefore, we
shareholder wealth. If the regulator allowed com- needed to be able to control for these time-varying
panies to recoup all or most of their costs (plus a and firm-level fixed effects in order to isolate the
profit margin) through higher charges to customers, influence of different customer service perfor-
then external capital markets would interpret mance levels on profitability and changes in share-
better-than-average customer service levels as holder wealth (returns). In both the profits and
value-enhancing. In these circumstances, the cus- shareholder returns models described below, the
tomer service indicators could be expected to be dependent variables are expressed in terms of the
positively related to current-period relative share- deviation of company j's profits (or returns) at time
holder returns. t from the sector's average profits (or returns) for
It is by no means certain that managers' decisions the same period. This method effectively overcame
about expenditures to improve customer service the problem of time-specific effects.^ As for the
will inexorably enhance future profitability. Con- firm-level fixed effects, these were only likely to be
siderable pressures and risks influence managers' of any importance in respect to the profit model
judgments about how best to balance shareholder because, in an informationally efficient market,
and customer interests. On the one hand, there is, share prices will rapidly incorporate the financial
of course, the regulatory imperative to achieve min- consequences of any anticipated firm-level fixed
imum standards of customer service. There is reg- effects (see Malkiel [1996] for a review). Hence, we
ulatory risk if not enough is achieved. Managers estimated only the relative profits models control-
may also enhance the legitimacy of their companies ling for fixed effects.^
as private-sector actors and secure reputational Finally, given the combination of price regula-
benefits that can be commercially exploited in tion and highly stable operating and cost condi-
other markets. On the other hand, achieving im- tions that give rise to fixed effects with respect to
proved customer service entails considerable ex- relative profitability, one of the few ways open to
penditure. Moreover, managers may be too ambi- an individual water company to significantly im:
tious in their plans for customer service, be prove its posttax profitability ranking is to increase
inefficient in carrying out those plans, or fail to its debt-to-equity ratio. For any positive level of
secure enough recompense through the ic-factor de- operating profits, taking on more debt and/or re-
termined by the director general, all of which ducing the equity base (through, for instance, share
would have adverse consequences for their compa- repurchases) has the effect of increasing the posttax
nies' financial performance. Despite these potential return per unit of equity. Hence, because capital
difficulties, the regulator can be expected to have structure changes could be expected to have a sig-
confidence in the reliability of his own system for nificant impact on our relative profits measure, our
determining customer service levels and to there- empirical analysis also had to include controls for
fore reward the water companies with high scores this factor.
on these measures.
Relative Profits Model
EMPIRICAL MODELING OF THE
RELATIONSHIPS BETWEEN SHAREHOLDER We controlled for common time period influ-
WEALTH, PROFITS, AND CUSTOMER ences on company profits by defining our depen-
SERVICE LEVELS
Our empirical testing of Hypotheses 1 and 2 ^ We also reestimated each of the empirical models
needed to take account of the character of the water including five dummy variables relating to the time pe-
industry and the panel nature of our dala, which riod of the observations (the number of years covered by
consisted of six annual cross sections of ten obser- our panel data minus one, which is represented by the
constant term). However, as expected, the dummies' in-
vations, each representing one water company. As clusion did not result in any improvement in the explan-
we were analyzing regulated enterprises supplying atory power of the estimates.
an identical basic product, but with very different
^ All of the shareholder returns models were also re-
inherited cost bases and local operating conditions, estimated with controls for fixed effects included. How-
there was likely to be very little intertemporal vari- ever, as expected, the fixed effects models did not result
ation in the ranking of companies in terms of their in any statistically significant improvement in the ex-
profitability. In addition to these time-invariant. planatory power of the estimates.
1999 Ogden and Watson 533

dent variable in terms of the relative profits avail- Our empirical equation thus was:
able for distribution to sbareholders (that is,
posttax profits or, in U.S. accounting terminology, Relative returnSjt
net income). To obtain an accounting-based mea- = 2 li(firm-specific factors)it + u^.
sure of the return to shareholders, we needed to
control for differences in the sizes of the compa- Because we assumed an informationally efficient
nies' equity bases by deflating the profit measure by capital market, the vector of firm-specific factors
the book value of shareholders' equity (issued share assumed to influence returns included only infor-
capital plus reserves). The dependent variable, the mation (news) received by the market within time
sector-relative profit of company J over time t (a period t that could have been expected to have
year) was therefore defined as follows: altered investor expectations regarding the level
and riskiness of an individual firm's anticipated
Relative profits^ = (profits/equity)^ future profits. The two items of firm-specific infor-
mation incorporated into our empirical models that
(sector-average profits/equity j^.
would have been released to the market during a
Our estimating equation for explaining the differ- one-year period w^ere relative profits and measures
ences in relative profitability became: of customer service performance.
Relative profits^ = 2 a,-' A major difficulty in any analysis ofthe impact of
an economic variable upon shareholder returns is
+/3 log (book value of capital employedjj determining the most appropriate time frame for
+ ^(debt/equity)n observing such an impact. All ten privatized water
companies had accounting year-ends on March 31,
+^(customer service performancen)+ Uy^, and the financial accounts for each year were all
where 2 a^ represents firm-specific fixed effects* published in late May or early June. To date, the
and u,-f is an error term. director general has published results on the cus-
Three alternative specifications of the above tomer service performance measures between late
profit model were estimated. Model 1, our bench- November and early December of each year. To test
mark, did not include any customer service vari- Hypothesis 2, we measured returns over two differ-
ables. Models 2 and 3 both included customer ser- ent periods. We assessed announcement or news
vice measures. Model 2 included five customer effects by measuring returns over the month in
service variables, which consisted of the standard- which the regulator released the customer service
ized values of five individual measures, and model findings. Only the customer service variable or
3 had a single composite customer service variable. variables were included in this customer service
Thus, the difference between models 2 and 3 was announcement month model. Then, to compare the
this: in model 2, the individual slope coefficients relative announcement impacts upon share prices
could differ, but in the more restrictive model 3, the of profits and ofthe performance variables, we also
slope coefficients on the individual customer ser- estimated a profit announcement month model.
vice variables were of equal sign and magnitude. To test the possibility that investors inferred
some financial and customer service performance
information from other sources prior to the infor-
Shareholder Returns Model mation's actual release by the regulator, and to
allow for the possibility that investors may have
As for the relative profits models, for the share- taken some time to appreciate the impact of such
holder returns model we isolated the common ex- information on future profitability, we also mea-
ternal influences upon shareholder returns from sured returns for the subsequent one-year period,
the firm-specific factors in each period. Our depen- from April 1 to March 31. The resulting annual
dent variable, relative shareholder returns for firm i returns model included both relative profits and
over time t, was thus defined as follows: customer service as explanatory variables since
both items were released during the year covered
Relative returns^ = returns^ by the dependent variable.
sector-average returnst To ensure that the values associated with all five
of the indicator variables were all positively asso-
ciated with improvements in customer service lev-
els, we expressed three of them (complaints to
* See chapter 2 of Baltagi (1995) for an exposition of OFWAT, inadequate water pressure, and supply
the methods used to control for fixed effects. interruptions) as 100 percent minus the reported
534 Academy ofManagement Journal October

TABLE 2
Estimation of Relative Profits Function 1991-92 to 1996-97"
Independent Variable Model 1 Model 2 Model 3

Book value of capital employed,-,'' -0.013 (1.39) -0.010 (1.39) -0.012 (1.41)
(Debt/equity),-, 0.012 (2.58)** 0.011 (2.88)** 0.012 (2.68)**

F for constant and firm-level fixed effects 15.570** 18.180** 17.520**

Complaints to OFWAT,, 2.802E-3 (1.26)


Inadequate water pressure,-,'^ -7.804E-3 (3.60)**
Supply interruptions,-," -4.269E-3 (2.83)**
Responses to billing queries,/ 0.325E-3 (0.21)
Responses to written complaints,-,'^ -3.281E-3 (2.33)*
Customer service,-," -2.150E-3 (2.79)**

F for new variables 4.06** 6.26**


Adjusted R^ 72.00 78.80 74.80
Equation F 14.79** 14.68** 15.57**

" The dependent variable was calculated as (profits/equity)^, - (sector-average profits/equity],. N = 60. White's (1980) heteroskedasticity-
adjusted (-values are shown in parentheses.
*" Logarithm.
" Standardized measure.
* p < .05
** p S .01

percentages pnblished by OFWAT (and shown in our composite measure into the relative profits
Table 1). The five variables could not, however, be (model 3] and shareholder returns models. A sta-
simply aggregated to provide a summary overall tistically significant, negative coefficient on this
measure of customer service levels because the variable in the profits model would imply that per-
measurement units differed: the three just noted forming on customer service was costly in terms of
were percentages, but the variables measuring re- current reported profitability, as stated by Hypoth-
sponses to billing queries and to written com- esis 1. However, although such an effect was ex-
plaints were expressed as integer values on a five- pected to depress profits, the costs associated with
point scale. In order to aggregate the five indicator improvements in customer service are costs that
variables, we thus transformed each variable into the regulator may allow to be passed on to custom-
an annual standardized value. ers. Hence, as stated by Hypothesis 2, a statistically
These standardized relative measures of cus- positive coefficient on this variable was to be ex-
tomer service were individually entered into the pected when it was entered into the (announce-
model 2 relative profits estimate.^ Standardization ment month and annual) shareholder returns mod-
also enabled us to aggregate these five measures to els, since thus passing costs on implies higher
produce a single composite indicator of relative future profits, which is good news to shareholders.
customer service performance, customer service, in
which each indicator had equal weight (that is, the
indicators were added together). RESULTS
In order to summarize each firms' customer ser- Table 2 presents our estimates relating to Hy-
vice performance, the regulator had to have con- pothesis 1. As stated above, we made three alterna-
structed a similar composite measure.^ We entered tive estimates of our relative profits model. Model
1, which includes controls for the unobservable
firm-level fixed effects, firm size, and differences in
^ The individual standardized customer service vari- capital structure, is able to explain a high propor-
ables were also entered into the shareholder returns mod- tion of the cross-sectional variability in relative
els. However, none of the individual variables were of profits. As anticipated, the firm-level fixed effects
any statistical significance and, consequently, these re- are highly significantindeed, on their own, they
sults are not reported here.
* Moreover, given the relatively few degrees of free-
dom associated with our data set and the "pairwise" tors, this composite variable was also likely to provide a
correlations between the individual nonfinancial indica- more efficient statistical estimator of their influence.
1999 Ogden and Watson 535

TABLE 3
Relative Shareholder Returns Functions 1991-92 to 1996-97'
Earnings Customer Service
Independent Announcement Month Announcement Month Annual
Variable Returns Returns Returns

(Profit/equity),-, 0.125 (0.28) 0.121 (0.16)


Customer service,-. 2.611E-3 (2.29)* 10.045E-3 (2.46)*

Constant 0.014 (1.93)'*' -0.069E-3 (0.02) 0.288E-3 (0.03)

Adjusted R^ -1.6 6.3 7.5


Equation F 0.09 4.96* 3.40*

" The dependent variable was calculated as relative returnSj, = returns,, - sector-average returns,. The returns for each company and
the sector-average returns were calculated as natural logarithms. N = 60. White's (1980) heteroskedasticity-adjusted f-values are shiown in
parentheses.

.05

account for some 70 percent of the cross-sectional period shareholder returns. We made this predic-
variation in profitability. Also, the debt-to-equity tion because some or all of the costs associated with
ratio is, as expected, positive and statistically sig- improvements in customer service can likely be
nificant at the 1 percent confidence level. subsequently passed on to customers, thus increas-
Model 2 includes the five individual standard- ing future profits and current value.
ized customer service variables (complaints to Though in both the annual returns and announce-
OFWAT, inadequate water pressure, supply inter- ment month returns models the relative profits
ruptions, and responses to billing queries and writ- measure has a positive coefficient, neither of these
ten complaints). The incremental impact of these coefficients is statistically significant at a 5. percent
five measures is statistically significant at the 1 level. These results imply that the revelation of the
percent confidence level. However, although only profit figures to the capital markets did not appear
three of the five variables are negative, all three are to be regarded as news in that there is no statistical
statistically significant at 5 percent or better levels evidence that this information systematically al-
of confidence. Model 3 includes only the aggregate tered the existing perceptions of investors regard-
variable customer service, which thereby con- ing the current values of the firms.'' Of course,
strains all five variables to have the same slope given the huge fixed effects in relation to relative
coefficients. Despite this restriction, model 3 ap- profits shown in Table 2, this finding should not be
pears to be well specified: the composite variable is too surprising. These firm-level fixed effects reflect
negative and statistically significant at a 1 percent the highly regulated nature of the industry's pricing
level of confidence, though there is a slight de- policies, the inherited infrastructure, the location-
crease in the overall explanatory power of the specific cost structures of individual firms, and the
model relative to model 2.
limited scope for increasing sales of their price-
These results provide strong empirical support regulated product. In an informationally efficient
for our first hypothesis. As can be seen from Table market, share prices should already reflect any an-
2, in both models that include customer service
ticipated intertemporal profitability rankings.
measures, the variables are negatively related to the
Hence, much of the information contained in the
dependent variable at a 1 percent confidence level.
financial statements regarding relative profitability
These results imply that, despite the negative con-
would not constitute news and, therefore, no share
sequences of customer service increases for current
reported profits, managers are prepared to expend
resources to improve such service. We now con-
sider whether such expenditures appear to also be ^ After obtaining the results presented in this article,
in the interests of shareholders. we reestimated the shareholder return models using dif-
Table 3 presents our empirical estimates of the ferent time horizons for the measurement of the depen-
shareholder returns functions used to test Hypoth- dent variable. These additional estimates did not, how-
esis 2, which predicts that the customer service ever, produce significantly different results from those
measures will be positively related to current- presented here.
536 Academy of Management Journal October

price reaction should occur at the time of its re- of regulation that provides a relatively high degree
lease. of discretion to the regulator can, when coupled
The situation in regard to the customer service with market-based incentives and trust, result in
performance measures is, however, somewhat dif- mutual benefits for different stakeholder groups
ferent. Table 2 shows that the estimated positive with apparently conflicting economic interests.
coefficient on the customer service variables, for Clearly, the effectiveness of this regulatory system
both the announcement and annual returns ver- relies very heavily on how the regulator exercises
sions of the model, is statistically significant at its discretion and on the quality of the relationships
better than 5 percent confidence levels. This pat- between the regulator and water company execu-
tern appears to indicate that our composite cus- tives. Without a high level of mutual trust between
tomer service variable is of some statistical impor- the parties, the system would be beset with legal
tance in explaining both relative annual share- challenges to the regulator's decisions. The fact
holder returns and relative shareholder returns for that, in the nine years since privatization, only one
the month immediately surrounding revelation of of the ten privatized water companies has sought
this information to the market. These results imply, judicial review of any of the regulator's decisions
for example, that a firm that performs one standard suggests that the required high level of mutual trust
deviation better than the mean on customer service exists. Southwest Water appealed to the Monopo-
in any period will earn an approximately 1 percent lies and Mergers Commission over the OFWAT di-
higher-than-average return for its shareholders. Al- rector general's determination of its efficiency tar-
though this positive relationship between relative get (that is, its ic-factor) following its 1994 periodic
shareholder returns and relative performance in review. The outcome of this appeal for the com-
terms of customer service measures is not particu- pany was, in fact, a more demanding ir-factor than
larly large, it does nevertheless appear to constitute that originally proposed by the director general
an important form of value-relevant information to (Monopolies and Mergers Commission, 1995).
equity investors. Indeed, it appears to be much The role of trust identified here echoes the im-
more important to shareholders than information portance Jones (1995) attached more generally to
releases regarding relative profitability over the trust in developing an instrumental theory of stake-
same period. holder management. He argued that "trusting and
cooperative relationships help solve problems re-
lated to opportunism" (Jones, 1995: 432) and that
DISCUSSION AND CONCLUSIONS
because "the costs of opportunism and of prevent-
The empirical results presented in this article pro- ing or reducing opportunism are significant, firms
vide statistical evidence indicating that it is possible, that contract on the basis of trust and cooperation
to some extent, to align the apparently conflicting will have a competitive advantage over those that
concerns of different stakeholder groups. Our find- do not use such criteria" (1995: 432). Seeking this
ings support both the plausibility of the stakeholder advantage, he concludes, provides not only an ex-
model of the firm and the possibility of quantifying planation for altruistic firm behaviors, but also a
and empirically testing propositions and predictions basis for an instrumental theory of stakeholder
grounded on the stakeholder model. management.
Opportunities to test these propositions further Our discussion of the respective roles of manag-
could be explored in other regulated and/or privat- ers and regulator in balancing competing stake-
ized utilities. In the United Kingdom, for example, holder interests also has implications for debates
customer service standards have been incorporated about the basis of stakeholder theory. Although
into the regulatory frameworks for British Telecom instrumental justifications for stakeholder theory
and the privatized gas and electricity industries. are well established (Freeman, 1984; Freeman &
However, it is important to note that the use of Evan, 1990), some commentators have argued that
measures of customer service in these regulatory these are inadequate as a basis for stakeholder the-
processes is still at an early stage of development. ory. Donaldson and Preston (1995), for example,
With all the privatized utilities, including water, a suggested that even if it is prudent for managers to
number of issues remain unresolved. Principal pay attention to stakeholder interests, there is no
among these is the question of who determines guarantee that they will do so. Stakeholders have
what customer service standards are to be, how no assurance that their interests will be properly
they are to be measured, and their adequacy in considered or that managers will not behave oppor-
reflecting customer needs. tunistically at their expense. Donaldson and Pres-
Nevertheless, from the evidence presented here, ton argued instead for a normative basis for stake-
it is apparent that in some circumstances a system holder theory, which, they suggested, resides in
1999 Ogden and Watson 537

managers' recognition that all stakeholders' inter- portunity to demonstrate the validity of their
ests have intrinsic value. The ultimate managerial claims about serving stakeholders.
implication of stakeholder theory is that, rather
than treat stakeholders' interests instrumentally,
managers "should acknowledge the validity of di- REFERENCES
verse stakeholder interests and should attempt to
Ash, T., Hare, P., & Canning, A. 1994. Privatisation in the
respond to them within a mutually supportive
former centrally planned economies. In P. M. Jack-
framework, hecause that is a moral requirement son & C. M. Price (Eds.), Privatisation and regula-
for the legitimacy of the management function" tion: 213-236. London: Longman.
(Donaldson & Preston, 1995: 87). Our evidence in-
dicates, however, that such a hasis for managerial Ashforth, B. E., & Gibbs, B. W. 1990. The double-edge of
organizational legitimation. Organization Science.
behavior is still far from heing realized. It could be 1: 177-194.
expected, given the essential nature of their prod-
uct, that managers in the water industry would take Baltagi, B. H. 1995. Econometric analysis of panel data.
due account of all stakeholders' interests in their Chichester: Wiley.
decision making. However, the regulatory system Charterhouse Tilney Equity Research. 1993. Water sec-
presumes the opposite. The responsibility for en- tor review (mimeo). London: Charterhouse Tilney
suring that customer interests are adequately at- Equity Research.
tended to is located with the regulator. Moreover, Clarkson, M. B. E. 1995. A stakeholder framework for
the incentives and sanctions at its disposal are de- analyzing and evaluating corporate social perfor-
signed to operate on the assumption that managers mance. Academy of Management Review. 20: 92-
will act instrumentally. 117.
One limitation of our study is that it was re- Clarkson, M. B. E., Deck, M. C, & Shiner, N. J. 1992. The
stricted to one industry. Moreover, given the stakeholder management model in practice. Paper
changes occasioned by that industry's recent pri- presented at the annual meeting of the Academy of
Management, Las Vegas.
vatization, the small number of companies operat-
ing within it, and its regulatory environment, the Cowan, S. 1994. Privatisation and regulation ofthe water
U.K. water industry can by no means be considered industry in England and Wales. In M. Bishop, J. Kay,
typical. Another limitation of the study concerns C. Mayer, & D. Thompson (Eds.), Privatisation and
economic performance: 112-136. Oxford: Oxford
the measures of customer service. Although we
University Press.
used the measures employed by the U.K. Office of
Water Services, only four of the seven measures Department of the Environment. 1986. Privatisation of
lent themselves to comparison. As regards our em- the water authorities in England and Wales (cmnd.
9734). London: Her Majesty's Stationery Office.
pirical analysis of the data, the power of the tests of
the shareholder returns models might be improved Donaldson, T., & Preston, L. E. 1995. The stakeholder
if daily share data were used instead of monthly theory of the corporation: Concepts, evidence, and
data. Further, although the estimation problems implications. Academy of Management Review.
20: 65-91.
would be complex, there might be benefits from
undertaking a more detailed analysis of the cash Ezzamel, M., & Watson, R. 1997. Wearing two hats: The
flow consequences directly associated with each conflicting control and management roles of non-
customer service indicator. executive directors. In K. Keasey, S. Thompson, & M.
Wright (Eds.), Corporate governance: 54-79. Ox-
Beyond the confines of regulated utilities, our
ford: Oxford University Press.
research has two major implications for stake-
holder theory. The first of these is reiteration of the Freeman, R.E. 1984. Strategic management: A stake-
importance of the abilities to define stakeholders' holder approach. Boston: Pitman.
interests and to measure and monitor those inter- Freeman, R. E., & Evan, W. M. 1990. Corporate gover-
ests. The second is to emphasize the need for the nance: A stakeholder interpretation. Journal of Be-
measurement and monitoring of companies' perfor- havioral Economics, 19: 337-359.
mance in regard to stakeholders' interests to be Carvey, C, & Swan, P. 1994. The economics of corporate
transparent. Such transparency would facilitate in- governance. Joumal of Corporate Finance, 1: 139-
dependent substantive evaluation of companies' 174.
treatment of stakeholders and avoid the reliance on Hall, R. 1992. The strategic analysis of intangible re-
companies' own assessment of their performance. sources. Strategic Management Journal, 13: 135-
Companies that believe that they already take seri- 144.
ous account of stakeholder interests may welcome Hart, O. 1995. Corporate governance: Some theory and
such evaluation, because it would provide an op- implications. Economic Journal, 105: 678-689.
538 Academy of Management Journal October

Jones, T. M. 1995. Instrumental stakeholder theory: A annual report of the OFWAT National Customer
synthesis of ethics and economics. Academy of Council and the ten regional Customer Service
Management Review, 20: 404-437. Committees. Birmingham: Office of Water Services.
Kay, J., & Silberston, A. 1995. Corporate governance. Ogden, S. G. 1997. Accounting for organizational perfor-
National Institute Economic Review, 3(August): mance: The construction of the customer in the pri-
84-97. vatized water industry. Accounting, Organizations
Kotler, P. 1984. Marketing management: Analysis, and Society. 22: 529-556.
planning and control. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Pren- Ogden, S. G., & Anderson, F. 1995. Representing cus-
tice-Hall. tomer interests: The case of the UK privatized water
Littlechild, S. 1986. Economic regulation of privatised industry. Public Administration, 73: 535-559.
water authorities: A report to the Department of the Pfeffer, J., & Salancik, G. 1978. The external control of
Environment. London: Her Majesty's Stationery Of- organizations: A resource dependence perspec-
fice. tive. New York: Harper & Row.
Malkiel, B. G. 1996. A random walk down Wall Street Price, C. M. 1994. Privatization in less developed coun-
(6th ed.). New York: Norton. tries. In P. J. Jackson & C. M. Price (Eds.), Privatiza-
Monopolies and Mergers Commission. 1995. South West tion and regulation: 237-254. London: Longman.
Water Services Ltd: A report on the determination Richardson, J. (Ed.). 1990. Privatisation and deregula-
of adjustment factors and infrastructure charges tion in Canada and Britain. Aldershot: Dartmouth.
for South West Water Services Ltd. London: Her
Self, P. 1993. Government by the market? London: Mac-
Majesty's Stationery Office.
millan.
Narver, J. C, & Slater, S. F. 1990. The effect of market
Slater, S. F., & Narver, J. C. 1994. Does competitive envi-
orientation on business profitability. Journal of
ronment moderate the market orientation-perfor-
Marketing, 54: 20-35.
mance relationship? Journal of Marketing, 58: 4 6 -
Office of Water Services. 1990. The water industry of 55.
England and Wales: Levels of service information
Suchman, M.C. 1995. Managing legitimacy: Strategic and
1989/90. Birmingham: Office of Water Services.
institutional approaches. Academy of Management
Office of Water Services. 1991. Annual report 1990. Lon- Review, 20: 571-610.
don: Her Majesty's Stationery Office.
Vickers, J., & Wright, V. 1989. The politics of industrial
Office of Water Services. 1992. Levels of service report privatization in Western Europe. London: Cass.
for the water industry of England and Wales
1991/2. Birmingham: Office of Water Services. Warburg Securities. 1993. Analyst's report on the water
industry (mimeo). London: S.G. Warburg Securities.
Office of Water Services. 1993. Annual report 1992. Lon-
don: Her Majesty's Stationery Office. White, H. 1980. A heteroskedasticity-consistent covari-
ance matrix estimator and a direct test of heteroske-
Office of Water Services. 1994. Levels of service report dasticity. Econometrica, 48: 817838.
for the water industry of England and Wales
1993/4. Birmingham: Office of Water Services.
Stuart Ogden is a professor of accounting and organiza-
Office of Water Services. 1996. The director general's
tional analysis at the University of Leeds. He received his
annual report 1995. London: Her Majesty's Statio-
M. A. in industrial relations at the University of Warwick.
nery Office.
His current research interests are privatization and pro-
Office of Water Services. 1997. The director general's cesses of organizational change, corporate governance
annual report 1996. London: Her Majesty's Statio- and executive compensation, and management compe-
nery Office. tences.
Office of Water Services. 1998. OFWAT complaints pro- Robert Watson is a professor of finance and accounting at
cedure: How we can help you if you have a com- the University of Strathclyde. He received his Ph.D. in
plaint about a water company. Birmingham: Office finance at the University of Manchester. His current re-
of Water Services. search interests are corporate governance and executive
Office of Water Services National Customer Council. compensation, managerial labor markets, and financial
1998. Representing water customers: The 1997-98 statement analysis.

You might also like