You are on page 1of 7

American Economic Association

Alcohol Consumption During Prohibition


Author(s): Jeffrey A. Miron and Jeffrey Zwiebel
Source: The American Economic Review, Vol. 81, No. 2, Papers and Proceedings of the
Hundred and Third Annual Meeting of the American Economic Association (May, 1991), pp.
242-247
Published by: American Economic Association
Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/2006862
Accessed: 21-08-2017 19:14 UTC

JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide
range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and
facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org.

Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at
http://about.jstor.org/terms

American Economic Association is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend
access to The American Economic Review

This content downloaded from 200.130.19.168 on Mon, 21 Aug 2017 19:14:16 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
Alcohol Consumption During Prohibition

By JEFFREY A. MIRON AND JEFFREY ZWIEBEL*

The burgeoning debate over drug legal- estimate the consumption of alcohol during
ization in the United States has drawn re- Prohibition.
newed attention to the nation's experience We find that alcohol consumption fell
with Prohibition. Although the parallels be- sharply at the beginning of Prohibition, to
tween the criminalization of alcohol and the approximately 30 percent of its pre-Prohibi-
criminalization of drugs are not exact, Pro- tion level. During the next several years,
hibition provides a natural setting in which however, alcohol consumption increased
to examine the impact of legal restrictions sharply, to about 60-70 percent of its pre-
on the use of substances such as alcohol or Prohibition level. The level of consumption
drugs. The popular media asserts widely remained virtually the same immediately af-
divergent accounts of the changes in alcohol ter Prohibition as during the latter part of
consumption during Prohibition, claiming Prohibition, although consumption in-
both that drinking increased substantially creased to approximately its pre-Prohibition
and that drinking fell to a small fraction of level during the subsequent decade.
its pre-Prohibition level. To date, however,
most such assertions have been based on I. Historical Background
little hard evidence.
It should come as no surprise that accu- The Prohibition movement in the United
rate data on alcohol consumption during States traces it origins to the mid-nine-
Prohibition do not exist. Perhaps more sur- teenth century. It was not until the 1910's,
prisingly, there have been few serious at- however, that sufficient support was gar-
tempts to estimate consumption using re- nered to make national prohibition a real-
lated statistics. With the notable exception ity. During the latter half of this decade,
of Clark Warburton (1932), which has the many states enacted dry laws, and in 1917
drawback of being conducted in the middle Congress provided for Wartime Prohibition.
of Prohibition, we know of no careful at- National Prohibition became effective in
tempt to estimate this consumption. We January 1920 under the 18th Amendment to
employ Warburton both as a starting point the Constitution. Prohibition remained in
and as a comparison for our estimation. effect for almost 14 years, until rescinded by
Attempts to estimate alcohol consump- the 21st Amendment in December 1933.
tion from related variables suffer the draw- By the mid-1920's it was apparent that at
back that Prohibition may have altered the best limited success had been achieved in
relationship between these series and alco- prohibiting alcohol consumption. Initially
hol consumption. We address this problem Congress responded with increased enforce-
by using data drawn from widely varying ment. Money appropriated for enforcing
sources; plausibly the biases in these series Prohibition increased from $6.3 million in
will be unrelated. In particular, we use mor- 1921 (the first year of large-scale enforce-
tality, mental health, and crime statistics to ment) to $9.2 million in 1925 and to $13.4
million in 1930 (U.S. Department of Trea-
sury, 1930, p. 2). However, the inability to
* Department of Economics,, Boston University, restrict the illegal trade and the inevitable
Boston, MA 02215 and Department of Economics, accompanying corruption eventually led to
MIT, Cambridge, MA 02139, respectively. Zwiebel ac-
widespread public disenchantment with
knowledges financial support from the National Sci-
ence Foundation and the Alfred P. Sloan Foundation. Prohibition.
We thank Peter Temin and Robert Margo for helpful By the turn of the decade, popular senti-
comments. ment had undergone a radical turnabout on

242

This content downloaded from 200.130.19.168 on Mon, 21 Aug 2017 19:14:16 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
VOL. 81 NO. 2 ECONOMICS OF DRUGS 243

Prohibition.' The 1930 election saw the where Xt, is alcohol consumption, t is a
anti-Prohibitionists' strength increase, and time trend, and Yt is one of the four series
by 1932 the Democratic Party supported related to alcohol consumption. We esti-
outright repeal. By 1933, support for repeal mate this equation for the years during the
was widespread in Congress. In February, 1900-50 period for which data for the par-
both Houses approved the 21st Amend- ticular series are available, exclusive of the
ment, and by December, three-quarters of Prohibition years 1920-35.2 We then use
the states had ratified the amendment, end- the estimated parameters from (1) to con-
ing the experiment of Prohibition. struct consumption from 1920 to 1935.
While Warburton assumes linear rela-
II. Data and Methodology tionships between alcohol consumption and
various statistics, we assume a log linear
Estimating alcohol consumption during relationship because this is the simplest
Prohibition is complicated by the possibility specification satisfying the restriction that
that Prohibition was accompanied by no alcohol consumption should imply no
changes in attitudes or actions that affected deaths from alcoholism, no alcoholic psy-
underlying relationships. Thus, for example, chosis and no drunkenness arrests (although
while the number of arrests for drunkenness the same cannot be said about cirrhosis).
may be closely related to alcohol consump- Additionally, this model fits well for all four
tion, Prohibition could lead to more vigor- series, and a linear specification yields simi-
ous enforcement of drunkenness laws, rais- lar results. The trend is included to capture
ing the number of drunkenness arrests for a other developments over time, such as a
fixed level of consumption. Alternatively, it tendency to treat more psychotic patients
could drive more drinking into the home, or an improvement in the treatment of cir-
thereby lowering the drunkenness arrest rhosis.
tally. Similarly, deaths due to alcoholism Including lagged consumption in these re-
may increase due to low-quality alcohol. We gressions does not substantively change the
address such complications by comparing results. For cirrhosis and drunkenness, the
estimates from several diverse sources. coefficients on lagged consumption are sta-
The series that we use to estimate alcohol tistically insignificant. For deaths due to
consumption are the death rate from cirrho- alcoholism and admittances for alcoholic
sis of the liver, the death rate from alco- psychosis, lagged values of alcohol con-
holism, the number of patients per capita sumption do enter significantly, but the es-
admitted to hospitals for the first time with timates of alcohol consumption based on
alcoholic psychosis, and the rate of drunk- regressions with these lags are not substan-
enness arrests. (The Data Appendix, avail- tially different from those based on the re-
able upon request, provides the details of gressions without lags.
the construction of these series.) For each The fact that lagged consumption does
of the series, we posit the relation. not explain cirrhosis may appear surprising,
since cirrhosis results from a lengthy history
(1) lnY,=a+I3t+ylnXt+ e, of alcohol consumption. While this may be

2The estimates reported below are robust to extend-


'For example, in 1915 popular magazine articles in ing the sample period. We use data only through 1950
favor of Prohibition outnumbered those opposed 20 to to minimize the effects of changes in underlying rela-
1; by 1930 this ratio had reversed to 1 to 2 (see Andrew tionships and to avoid definitional changes in the re-
Sinclair, 1962, p. 332.). Polls taken by Literary Digest ported data. We exclude 1934-35 from the sample
indicate that while in 1922 only 1 in 5 individuals because it took several years after the end of Prohibi-
favored complete repeal, by 1930 all states but 5 showed tion for the legal producers to fully recapture industry
a majority in favor of repeal or modification, and by control. For alcoholic psychosis, we fit the model only
1932 all states but 2 had a majority in favor of repeal through 1940 because this series (like other mental
(Sinclair, p. 335). health series) is quite volatile during World War II.

This content downloaded from 200.130.19.168 on Mon, 21 Aug 2017 19:14:16 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
244 AEA PAPERS AND PROCEEDINGS MAY1991

so, the data seem to suggest that one must TABLE 1-ESTIMATES OF EQUATION (1)
be presently drinking to die from cirrhosis.
Independent Variables
This view is mirrored in statistics that show
a steep drop in cirrhosis when consumption Dependent Sample

falls both during wartime Prohibition and at Variable Period Constant Trend Alcohol
the onset of constitutional Prohibition. If, Cirrhosis 1900-50 2.560 -.007 .619 .924
however, the true specification for cirrhosis (.046) (.001) (.046)
Alcoholism
involves lags that we do not include, our
Deaths 1900-50 2.366 -.027 .802 .902
estimates of consumption are likely over-
(.221) (.002) (.344)
stated immediately after the onset of Prohi- Drunkenness
bition (when consumption falls) and under- Arrests 1910-29 4.186 .013 .902 .933
stated in following years.3 (.345) (.007) (.076)
Alcoholic
Psychosis 1910-40 .691 .008 .949 .794
III. Results
(.123) (.002) (.078)

Table 1 presents ordinary least squares Notes: 1) Newey-West standard errors are shown in
parentheses. 2) Alcohol consumption is measured in
estimates of equation (1). Each row repre-
gallons of pure alcohol per capita. 3) Cirrhosis, alco-
sents a regression with one of the four de- holism deaths, alcoholic psychosis, and drunkenness
pendent variables. Low Durbin-Watson arrests are all measured in per capita terms. 4) The
statistics indicate the likelihood of serial equations are estimated over the sample periods indi-
correlation, so we report robust standard cated, excluding the years 1920-35.

errors calculated using Whitney Newey and


Kenneth West's (1987) procedure. For each
of the four series, the model explains a
large portion of the variation in the depen- more alcoholism deaths for given consump-
dent variable. The R2 exceeds .90 for alco- tion. Similarly, cirrhosis, which provides the
holism, cirrhosis, and drunkenness and is lowest estimates, may understate consump-
.79 for alcoholic psychosis. Alcohol con- tion if the functional relationship is mis-
sumption is significant at the .01 level of specified, as discussed above.
significance for all series except alcoholism All four estimates, however, show a simi-
deaths, for which it is significant at the .03 lar steep initial decline in consumption fol-
level. The time trend is significant at the .01 lowed by a steady increase. Consumption
level for cirrhosis, alcoholism, and psy- falls immediately after enactment of Prohi-
chosis, but is insignificant at the .05 level for bition to 20 to 40 percent of its pre-Prohibi-
drunkenness arrests. tion level. Alcoholism, drunkenness, and
The four estimates of consumption from psychosis estimates indicate a sharp re-
1920 to 1935, and true consumption before bound in consumption from 1921 to 1927
and after this period, are graphed in Figure and a less dramatic increase after 1927. The
1. Comparing the four series we find similar cirrhosis estimates exhibit a similar pattern,
estimates from cirrhosis, drunkenness, and but with a smaller initial decline in con-
psychosis, but substantially higher estimates sumption and a more moderate subsequent
from alcoholism. We suspect that the alco- increase. In the later years of Prohibition,
holism series overstates true consumption cirrhosis, drunkenness, and psychosis esti-
during Prohibition due to decreased alcohol mate consumption to be 50 to 70 percent of
quality. In particular, the consumption of its pre-Prohibition value, while alcoholism
wood or denatured alcohol likely produced estimates small increases in consumption.
The estimates in Figure 1 improve on
Warburton's by employing data beyond 1929
(both in fitting the model and in estimating
3For further discussion of this issue and a more
consumption at the end of Prohibition) and
detailed model of the relation between alcohol con-
sumption and the cirrhosis death rate, see P. J. Cook by considering a more reasonable functional
and G. Tauchen (1982). relationship. Nonetheless, both studies yield

This content downloaded from 200.130.19.168 on Mon, 21 Aug 2017 19:14:16 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
VOL. 81 NO. 2 ECONOMICS OF DRUGS 245

25
bition had little to do with the observed
Alooholism Deaihs
change in drinking patterns. Conversely, the
2 Akohol C upbo difference may result from a change in so-
cial attitudes due to Prohibition. Trying to
1 5
distinguish between these competing hy-
potheses is beyond the scope of this paper.
However, as far as the debate on drug legal-
ization is concerned, the comparisons to
Cirrhosis post-Prohibition consumption are more per-
Deaths

0 5 AoohorNc Psychosis tinent that those to pre-Prohibition con-


05 sumption.

IV. Discussion
i sc 1910 1 920 1 gOO * 90 * 9S
1 9C 191l5 1w 92 19:5 1 9.5

Alcohol Consumpton is measured n Pure Gallons of Alcohol Per Capita

There are several channels through which


FIGURE 1. ESTIMATED ALCOHOL CONSUMPTION
Prohibition may affect alcohol consumption.
First, Prohibition increases supply costs, as
these must include the cost of evading de-
similar results. Warburton considers agri- tection and the potential cost of punish-
cultural sources of production, death rates, ment. This implies a higher equilibrium
and arrests for drunkenness in estimating market price and less consumption. Second,
consumption. He estimates that consump- Prohibition inhibits consumer access to al-
tion per capita is around 65 percent of cohol by raising search costs, making quali-
pre-Prohibition levels by 1925 and around ty dubious, and increasing the possibility
71 percent by 1929. When comparing results of being cheated. Third, Prohibition may
from the same series, our estimates are create a prevailing sentiment that a certain
slightly higher than Warburton's. Overall, good is "bad" or "immoral," thereby de-
however, his average estimates are about creasing consumer demand. Finally, Prohi-
the same as ours because his highest esti- bition may deter some individuals' con-
mates are from agricultural production, sumption because of "respect for the law."
which we do not consider. Even though consumption per se was not
While for three of our series we find illegal, purchasing alcohol during Prohibi-
reductions in consumption compared to tion involved doing business with criminals.
pre-Prohibition levels, the decline is much Our results suggest that of these reasons,
more modest when compared to post-Pro- only the first two contributed significantly to
hibition levels. The level of consumption in the changes in alcohol consumption during
1937-40 is about the same as our average Prohibition. A careful consideration of price
estimate for the last years of Prohibition. quotes in newspapers by Warburton sug-
(However, consumption rises to pre-Pro- gests that prices in 1930 were approximately
hibition levels over the next decade.) three times as high as pre-Prohibition
Whether the pre- or post-Prohibition prices.4 Hence even if price changes alone
benchmark is appropriate depends both on were responsible for changes in demand,
what question is being asked and to what
one attributes the difference in pre- vs.
post-Prohibition consumption. This differ-
4See Warburton (pp. 113, 116, and 166). We assume
ence may result from demographic factors that the cost of homemade alcohol was at least as high
(for example, a smaller percentage of immi- as the market price after accounting for time and
grants who drank more, or a different age potential punishment costs. If it had been much
cheaper, there would not have been an illegal alcohol
composition of the population), or a con-
industry. Note that another interpretation of higher
tinuation of the social trend toward less
prices and lower consumption during Prohibition is
drinking that began well before Prohibition. that illegal suppliers possessed and exercised monopoly
Either explanation would imply that Prohi- power.

This content downloaded from 200.130.19.168 on Mon, 21 Aug 2017 19:14:16 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
246 AEA PAPERS AND PROCEEDINGS MAY 1991

global price elasticities would have to be within several years it rebounded to 60-70
extremely low, around .1.5 This suggests that
percent of its initial value and did not in-
the effect of all other avenues that could crease substantially immediately following
theoretically lower demand had a negligible the repeal of Prohibition. Claims either that
impact. consumption during Prohibition increased
This is consistent with anecdotal evidence significantly or that it fell to a small fraction
that suggests that the effect of public senti- of previous usage can be patently rejected.
ment in reducing consumption is unclear. Changes in consumption during Prohibition
Some evidence even suggests Prohibition were modest given the change in price. This
made consumption more desirable by en- suggests that legal deterrents had little ef-
dowing drinking with an illicit romance and fect on limiting consumption outside of their
sense of adventure. Thus, one plausible in- effect on price. Social pressure and respect
terpretation of the small changes in con- for the law did not go far in reducing con-
sumption given the change in price is that sumption during Prohibition. We speculate
the demand curve for alcohol shifted out that this is likely to be true as well with
during Prohibition. illegal drugs today, and therefore claims
There are important similarities and dif- based on such arguments exaggerate the
ferences to keep in mind when trying to extent to which drug consumption would
draw inferences from Prohibition on how increase upon legalization.
drug legalization might change consump- Of course, any debate on drug legaliza-
tion. Prices of illegal drugs appear to have tion is incomplete if it solely considers
been forced further above their production changes in consumption. The negative ef-
costs than that of alcohol during Prohibi- fects accompanying any increases in con-
tion, presumably because of more stringent sumption are costs that have to be weighed
enforcement. This effect, however, may be against various benefits of drug legalization.
countered by a more inelastic demand for These benefits are likely to include an elimi-
illegal drugs than for alcohol. There seems nation of the violent drug culture that re-
to be no compelling reason why respect for sults from the battle for illegal profits, a
the law or other social impediments are any reduction in overdoses from impure drugs, a
more likely to have a significant impact on reduction in robberies and burglaries com-
drug consumption than they did on alcohol mitted by addicts who pay inflated drug
consumption during Prohibition. Thus, we prices, the stabilization of Latin American
hypothesize that any increase in consump- regimes fighting control battles with drug
tion due to changes in social attitudes fol- lords, the ability to combat the spread of
lowing drug legalization is likely to be small. AIDS from needle exchanges more effec-
tively, and an unclogging of the criminal
V. Conclusion justice system. This paper does not attempt
to calculate the costs and benefits of legal-
We find that while alcohol consumption ization. Rather, it suggests that if Prohibi-
declined sharply at the onset of Prohibition, tion is any guide, the cost to society from
increased drug use is likely to be smaller
than commonly believed.
5Recent estimates of the demand elasticity for alco-
hol vary greatly. For example, Cook and Tauchen esti-
mate an elasticity of 1.8, while S. I. Ornstein and D. M.
REFERENCES
Hanssens (1985) estimate elasticities of .8 to 1.0 for
spirits but only .1 for beer. In any event, the applicabil-
ity of these figures here is questionable. These studies Cook, P. J. and Tauchen, G., "The Effect of
estimate local elasticities by considering tax changes. Liquor taxes on Heavy Drinking," Bell
However, alcohol elasticities are unlikely to be con-
Journal of Economics, Autumn 1982, 13,
stant over a wide range of prices and may have changed
379-390.
significantly over time. Furthermore, the above cited
studies, in addition to having conflicting results, are Newey, Whitney and West, Kenneth, "A Simple,
plagued by the lack of reliable price data. Positive Definite, Heteroskedasticity and

This content downloaded from 200.130.19.168 on Mon, 21 Aug 2017 19:14:16 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
VOL. 81 NO. 2 ECONOMICS OF DRUGS 247

Autocorrelation Consistent Covariance Sinclair, Andrew, Prohibition the Era of Ex-


Matrix," Econometrica, May 1987, 55, cess, London: Faber and Faber, 1962.
703-08. Warburton, Clark, The Economic Results of
Ornstein, S. 1. and Hanssens, D. M., "Alcohol Prohibition, New York: Columbia Univer-
Control Laws and the Consumption of sity Press, 1932.
Distilled Spirits and Beer," Journal of U.S. Department of Treasury, Statistics Con-
Consumer Research, September 1985, 12, cerning Introxicating Liquors, Washing-
200-13. ton: USGPO, 1930.

This content downloaded from 200.130.19.168 on Mon, 21 Aug 2017 19:14:16 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms

You might also like