You are on page 1of 20

Economic Modelling 30 (2013) 7989

Contents lists available at SciVerse ScienceDirect

Economic Modelling
journalhomepage:www.elsevier.com/locate/ecmod

Governments under influence: Country interactions in discretionary fiscal policy


a b c, d
Aurlie Cassette , Jrme Creel , Etienne Farvaque , Sonia Paty
a EQUIPPEUniversits de Lille, France
b OFCE and ESCP Europe, France
c EDEHN, Universit du Havre and Skema Business School, France
d GATE-LSEUniversit de Lyon 2 and CNRS, France
article info abstract

Article history: We investigate the interactions between countries, and their effect on the discretionary (i.e. the cyclically-adjusted and
Accepted 31 August 2012 interest-adjusted) components of national fiscal policies, observing and investigating the parts of public spending and tax
receipts over which governments retain full discretion. Our sample in-cludes 18 OECD countries for the period 1974 2008.
JEL classification: First, we construct a measure of a discretionary fiscal policy from the residual component in a VAR model. We then compute
E62
this measure for the full sample. Using these data, we next run estimations of the discretionary fiscal policy interactions among
H60
the countries in the sample. Our results show that public decisions are affected by interactions between neighbor countries,
H87
neighborhood being defined by economic leadership as well as geography. We found evidence of opportunis-tic behavior by
Keywords: OECD country governments in relation to discretionary public spending. Finally, our estima-tion results reveal the crucial
Fiscal policy leadership role played by the USA in relation to discretionary fiscal policy decisions in Europe.
Discretion
Interactions
VAR 2012 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.
Spatial econometrics

1. Introduction This paper aims to investigate the existence of these influences. First we
define a discretionary policy in order to study the behavioral interac-tions
The idea that public policies diffuse from one country to another is not between governments: only the part of public spending and/or tax receipts
new. It is developed in the literature, e.g. in work on yardstick com-petition over which governments retain full control can be used strate-gically in
(see Besley and Case, 1995), tax competition (see Wilson, 1999), response to the behavior of other governments.
coordination issues (see Oudiz and Sachs, 1984, for a seminal contribution), We need to understand the structure of a discretionary fiscal policy.
capital account policies (see Steiner, 2010), and in the political science Countries publish only one annual budget; however, budget supplements may
literature (see Gilardi, 2010, for a recent contribution). Although binding be applied in response say, to changes to welfare benefits, public employees'
fiscal rules and peer pressure have been studied ex-tensively (see, e.g., wages following a new collective agree-ment, or new tax exemptions. The
Hallerberg et al., 2009, for the European case), other means of diffusion of tax implementation of supplements to annual budgets is common practice; they
and fiscal policies, i.e., imitation, have been rather overlooked. This paper may be included as part of the mid-year budget review but in most countries
aims, therefore, to show that the tax and fiscal policies of one country have an can be proposed to the legislature at any time (see OECD, 2004). For
influence on those implemented in other countries. instance, in the UK, the end-of-the-year budget represents a substantial
revision to the Pre-Budget Report which is the basis for the UK annual
budget. The reasons for revisions include forecasting changes, not directly
The authors acknowledge financial support from the French National Research Agency attributable to policy decisions and the effects of discretionary changes which
(grant ANRFRAL022). This paper has benefited from useful comments from a referee and do result from policy decisions. The OECD countries do not set a limit on
from Cristina Badarau-Semenescu, Lars Borge, Martial Foucault, Jean-Luc Gaffard, Marcel these supplements, although it is generally accepted that they should not be
Grard, Massimo Giuliodori, Jurgen von Hagen, Hakim Hammadou, Jrme Hricourt, Grgory too large (OECD, 2004). If the mid-year budgets and possible supplementary
Levieuge, Ioana Moldovan, Edoardo di Porto, Laurence Rioux, David Wildasin, Blandine
budgets include dis-cretionary changes, this can affect the fiscal policy
Zimmer, participants in the Public Economics Day (Paris 1), the European Public Choice
Society 2010 meeting, the 44th Canadian Economics Association conference, Journes AFSE outcome for the current fiscal year, even if only marginally. What matters is
2010, the 27th symposium on Money Banking and Finance Bordeaux 2010, AFSE Annual that these changes cannot be entirely expected (and, at least, induce a re-
Confer-ence 2010, the workshop on New issues on fiscal federalism and tax competition and vision to expectations), meaning that discretionary policy measures, even in a
seminar participants in Bonn. The usual disclaimer applies. rational expectations setting, may have a lasting impact.
Corresponding author.
E-mail address: etienne.farvaque@univ-lehavre.fr (E. Farvaque).

0264-9993/$ see front matter 2012 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.econmod.2012.08.032
80 A. Cassette et al. / Economic Modelling 30 (2013) 7989
The paper is structured as states (Baicker, 2005; Case et al.,
Assessing these measures is not follows. Section 2 briefly reviews would be necessary to reveal such a 1993; Figlio et al., 1999; Redoano,
straightforward. Various attempts the related literature. Section 3 modification. Moreover, the scope 2007). For instance, Case et al.
have been made to extract or reveal describes the empirical for discretionary fiscal interactions (1993) estimate the effect of a
discretionary fiscal measures (see, methodology, and defines and may extend beyond the EU area. state's spending on that of its
e.g., Beetsma and Giuliodori, computes our measure of Beetsma and Giuliodori (2010a) neighbors using a spatial lag model.
2010a; Blanchard and Perotti, 2002; discretionary fiscal policy. Sections make use of real-time data for the They find that states' per capita
Mountford and Uhlig, 2009; Ramey 4 and 5 present the estimation OECD countries, but focus on expenditures are positively and
and Shapiro, 1998; Romer and results and Section 6 con-cludes the changes to domestic fiscal plans signifi-cantly correlated with their
1 neighbors' spending. These results
Romer, 2010). We review these paper. driven by changes in cyclical
briefly in Section 2. However, apart conditions, rather than on external are confirmed by Figlio et al.
from the two studies by Beetsma interactions. (1999), who check the existence of
and Giuliodori (2010a,b), the issue 2. Related literature spillovers in welfare spending.
of external influences on the Agnello and Cimadomo (2012) Baicker (2005) finds that each dollar
adoption of the new policy The literature on fiscal policy investigate the revenue aspects of of state spend-ing causes spending
measures is not explored and most the government budgets of EU in neighboring states to increase by
and its determinants and
work focuses on only one country. countries in relation to discretionary between 37 cents and 88 cents.
consequences is abundant but
The scope of the present study is policy and whether discretionary Finally, Redoano (2007) estimates
consists mainly of two strands:
much broader. reaction functions for taxes and
macro-founded studies and micro- measures are implemented as a re-
founded studies. action to economic fluctuations. public expenditure, aggregated and
Our study of external influences disaggregated, using a dataset of
In the macroeconomic work, They show that legislated changes
on the design of discretionary fis-cal countries for the period 19851995.
only a few papers address the mea- to taxes and social security
policy provides two contributions to She finds that govern-ments behave
surement and determinants of contributions respond to the
the literature. First, we define a strategically with respect to those
reciprocal influences in business cycle in a strongly pro-
measure of discretionary fiscal expenditures that are more directly
discretionary fiscal policy. cyclical way. However, their
policy for 18 OECD countries for comparable, such as expenditures in
Giuliodori and Beetsma (2008) measure of discretion-ary fiscal
the period 19742008. We compute education: a country's education
analyze the inter-dependence of policy considers only revenue (our
a discretionary (i.e., a cyclically- budget deficits among European expenditure increases by over 40
measure is more com-prehensive),
and interest-adjusted) measure of Union (EU) countries, using real- cents for a $1 increase in spending
and their sample is of EU countries
public spending, and a discretionary time data. They find some evidence on education by neighbor countries.
while our sample of OECD
(i.e., a cyclically-adjusted) measure of fiscal policy inter-dependence, However, to our knowledge, all
countries is much larger.
of tax receipts. Second, we use with the fiscal plans of the large these papers use broad measures for
spatial econometrics to measure countries affecting the fiscal plans spending and gross fiscal data; we
Neely and Rapach (2009)
country interactions in discretionary of smaller ones, but not vice versa. believe that to properly investigate
analyze co-movements in four
tax or fiscal policy. Although spatial However, they focus only on fiscal the interactions between countries,
measures of budget surpluses, for
econometrics is used in the plans i.e., measures announced ex it is necessary to isolate the part that
18 OECD countries in 19802008
empirical literature to measure ante by EU govern-ments which is the sole responsibility of policy
within a dynamic latent factor
strategic interactions among local require them to internalize how they makers, i.e., the discretionary part
model. They show that the world
governments, very few studies will abide by the rules of the of public spending and tax receipts.
factor in national budget surpluses
investigate public policy Stability and Growth Pact.
2
declined substantially in the 1980s
interdependencies at the Although fiscal plans to ad-dress and then rose throughout most of
(inter-)national level. We consider European recommendations are the 1990s reaching a peak in 2000
several weight matrices and various included in discretionary fiscal 3. The empirical methodology
that was followed by decline. They
political variables not identified in policies, these policies can include show that this world factor explains
the first step but which may other elements. Governments may This section first presents the
a substantial portion of the
contribute to explain why countries modify their fiscal policies during a spatial method and then describes
variability in budget surpluses
imitate each other. Our approach particular year without their being the construction of the dependent
across countries. Although they
suggests a new way of approaching justified by fiscal obedience to a variables, i.e., the discretionary
document a common trend, their
the problem by combining two well European rule: ex post data public policy impulses.
modeling strategy does not allow
established methodologies from
them to verify whether this com-
different fields. 3.1. Assessing fiscal policy
mon trend is in fact driven by some
1 See Beetsma and Giuliodori (2010b) for interactions among OECD countries
of their sample countries' influ-ence.
a review of discretionary fiscal policy which
highlights estimates in an open economy It also does not allow them to
Our results show that there are Strategic interactions among
framework. Exchange rates and cur-rent investigate the determinants of the
interactions among our sample accounts are beyond the scope of the present governments have been a central
contribution.
interrelations exhibited. In the
countries and that the closer the issue in public finance theory since
2 Giuliodori and Beetsma (2008) use present study we examine discre-
countries involved, the more im- the early 1990s (see the survey by
OECD forecasts in order to avoid recurring tionary fiscal policy (and not on
portant are these interactions. to fiscal forecasts possibly manipulated by Wilson, 1999). More recently,
aggregates that may be subject to
Closeness is defined as similar governments. However, as Giuliodori and spatial econometric techniques have
Beetsma (2008) acknowledge, given that other influences such as
relative per capita GDP or close been used to estimate inter-
OECD figures come from government generalization of the welfare state,
geographic location. We find also institu-tions, OECD forecasts are influenced governmental interaction models
along the lines of the case in
that political cycles are influential; by politics: economic forecasts can be (see Brueckner, 2003; Revelli,
expected to abide ex ante by the rules of the Lindbeck, 2008), and deepen the
we show that OECD country
Stability and Growth Pact. analysis by uncovering the origins 2005).
Building on the spatial
governments dem-onstrate
of reciprocal national influences. econometric method
opportunistic behavior in relation to
discretionary public spending. Also, developed
estimation results confirm the
The micro strand in the
crucial role of the USA as a leader
literature focuses on spending
in relation to discretionary public
interactions among countries or
decisions in Europe.
A. Cassette et al. / Economic Modelling 30 (2013) 7989 81
autoregressive process in the error people (over 65 years) in the
by Anselin (1988), the model term, or a spatial error model: contiguity. In line with the empirical population, based on the European
includes the spatially lagged literature, we choose a common Commission AMECO (Annual
u
CA;i
Xi t i t i t and i t geographical definition of Macro-Economic) database.
dependent variable: neighborhood based on the
Wj; t mi t 2 k;t ; ; ; ; Although a positive sign is usually
u
CA;i
Wu
CA;j
Xi t i t Euclidean dis-tance between
3 expected since they are expected to
countries (dij). This scheme is reflect higher needs from these
i t where is the spatial correlation DIST
with ij given by the weight matrix W 5
coefficient, W is a weight matrix particular population groups, we
1 and imposes a smooth distance
k;t k;t ; and m is a vector of the i.i.d. error believe that these macroeconomic
; decay with weights wij, given by
terms. covariates should not be significant
1/dij when i is different from j (and
CA, i
where uk ,t is the discretionary Turning to the estimation given our measures of discretion.
wij = 0 otherwise). We nevertheless deliberately
(cyclically-adjusted, CA) spending techniques, Anselin (1988) shows
A second set of matrices is based include them to confirm that our
(or tax receipts) of the i=1, N that, due to endogeneity bias, 4
countries, X is the set of exogenous on economic criteria. We con- public policy dependent variables
ordinary least square (OLS) sider the case where countries
national socio-economic produces incon-sistent estimators measure discretion.
follow an economic leader, the latter
characteristics, i is a country fixed when estimating spatial lag and being defined by its per capita GDP.
GDPL
effect, t is a period fixed effect and spatial error models. However, The matrix W assigns higher
weights to countries j with higher A second group of control
is a vector of i.i.d. error terms. instrumental variables (IV) or
In this spatially lagged model, GDP per capita: wij = GDPj/jGDPj variables includes political data
maximum likelihood (ML)
W is a weight matrix that assigns if i is different from j, and 0 collected from the Database of
estimation methods lead to
neighbors to each country otherwise. This allows us to assess Political Institutions (DPI, see Beck
consistent estimators (Brueckner,
(according to the definition below); size effects. Trade flows between et al., 2001). Left is a dummy
2003; Elhorst, 2003).
CA, i countries may also promote variable for the country's political
the spatial lagged variable Wuk ,t
mimicking behavior. Similar to preference. It takes the value 1 if the
is a weighted average of all other If spatial error dependence is TRADE
coun-tries' fiscal policies, is the W , country i is closer to chief executive of country i in year t
ignored, estimations can give false
spatial autoregressive coefficient, country j than to country k if the belongs to a left-wing party, and 0
evi-dence of strategic interaction.
that gives the sign and the intensity share of trade with j is higher than otherwise. We introduce dummies
We can use ML to deal with this the share of trade with k in the total
of the impact of neighboring fiscal for the electoral cycle. Election year
problem since ML takes account of trade of the country i.
policies on one country's public both spatial lag and error models, (t) is a dummy variable that takes
It is a convention in the
decisions. the value 1 if there is a legislative
however, this method, which is empirical spatial literature that all
A negative implies that election in year t. Election year t1
implemented by Case et al. (1993), these weight matrices are
expenditure spillovers explain the (resp. t + 1) is a dummy variable
is computa-tionally challenging standardized so that the elements of
spatial correlation between that takes the value 1 for the year
(Brueckner, 2003). The IV method, each row sum to 1. Also, we need to
countries' decisions (Brueckner, before/after a legislative election,
however, yields consistent estimates include some control variables in
2003; Revelli, 2005). When is and zero otherwise. If there is a
even with spatial error dependence. our model to reflect the impact of
positive, a form of imitation trend towards an opportunistic
Therefore, we run all the differences in the socio-economic
(mimicking, i.e., fiscal competition political business cycle during the
estimations using the generalized and political factors grouped within
or yardstick competition) explains legis-lature, we will observe higher
spatial two-stage least squares the vector X in Eq. (1). Following
the ob-served interaction. For discretionary public spending and
(GS2SLS) method including both the empirical literature, we include
example, in the presence of tax base lower tax receipts in the year
the spatial lag and error models. some explanatory variables that
mobility, a government's fiscal preceding the election and in the
Arraiz et al. (2010) show that this might affect fiscal policies.
policy may affect the budget election year.
procedure produces consis-tent However, we do not expect an
constraints of other governments,
estimates when disturbances are important impact from these
through capital migration (Wilson, Thirteen of the countries in our
heteroskedastic, and provides variables on the validation of a
1999). This is the assumption of sample are members of the EU. We
simulation evidence that the ML former step of the empirical
fiscal competition for mobile introduce three dummies for EU
estimator produces inconsistent esti- procedure. It should be noted also
resources. In yard-stick competition membership, Eurozone membership
mates in that case. that a matrix based on GDP per
theory, information on the fiscal and respect of the Stability and
policy of neighbor governments acts capita is not considered in this step
The weight matrix, denoted W, Growth Pact (SGP) respectively.
as a yardstick for the electorate in because this variable is already
defines the structure of the inter- included in the former step of the
any given coun-try. As a result, any
action, the neighborhood among estimation procedure (see below).
country's citizens will compare the
countries. Since an a priori defini- 3 Geodesic distances are calculated
performance of their own following the great circle formula, which
tion of interaction might arbitrarily
policymakers to that of neighboring uses the geographic coordinates of capital
influence the estimations results, we Our data set includes the 18 cities (CEPII data base).
ones, triggering electoral reprisals. 4 See Case et al. (1993) and Baicker
test the robustness of our fiscal OECD countries (Australia, Austria,
This encourages mimicking (2005), for a discussion of these matrices,
policy interaction model using Belgium, Canada, Germany, defin-ing similarities between countries in
behavior by govern-ments to avoid terms of income, population, etc.
various criteria i.e., different weight Denmark, Spain, Finland, France,
stigmatization and secure reelection 5 The variable old people is designed to
matrices. United Kingdom, Greece, Ireland,
(Besley and Case, 1995; Salmon, capture the demand for social services by
Empirical studies testing for Italy, Japan, Netherlands, Norway, older members of the electorate. This
1987).
fiscal competition, yardstick segment of the population constitutes an
Sweden and the United States),
interest group with growing political power,
competi-tion or spillover effects considered over a period of 34 years and this variable is expected to be positively
Finally, a spatial auto- when neighborhood is a central (19752008). Descriptive statistics relat-ed to the size of the government.

correlation pattern may simply feature, tradi-tionally use weight are shown in Table 1.
reflect com-mon shocks affecting matrices based on geographical The first group of control
public policy, or the omission of distance or simple variables, in line with the literature,
variables (such as country is a set of socio-demographic
characteristics) that are spatially variables, such as unemployment
dependent (Manski, 1993). In this rate, population density, and shares
case, we have a spatial of young people (under 14) and old
82 A. Cassette et al. / Economic Modelling 30 (2013) 7989
one country to its counterpart in countries show no significant
Table 1 another country and to in-vestigate simplest form, the identification of cointegration relation. A VECM is
Descriptive statistics. the existence of a causal fiscal policy shocks depends not required for these 15 countries;
Sources
relationship and whether discre- substantially on the computed for the other three, and for the sake
tionary interactions (if they exist) elasticities of pairs of the dependent of comparison with the remaining
Unemployment AMECO change with political closeness, variables, a process that does not 15, we decided not to implement a
rate geographical closeness, and good require any types of restrictions. VECM experiment.
Young people AMECO and bad times, etc. We can examine Because the method can be made
Old people AMECO also where these interactions occur automatically systematic, it can be We first exploit a canonical VAR
Population AMECO
(in relation to countries' public applied to many countries. Recent model, but the residuals are not
density
Election year DPI spending and/or between to applications to, e.g., France (Biau informative about the response of
Left DPI countries' tax policies). and Girard, 2005), the UK (Creel et the endogenous variables to shocks:
EU membership European Commission they are only estimation errors.
al., 2009), and the Euro area as a
Eurozone European Commission We use an approach related to
membership whole (Burriel et al., 2010) testify Hence, in order to extract the
that in Blanchard and Perotti to this property, making the method discretionary parts of fiscal data
SGP European Commission and
AMECO (2002), which uses structural VARs public spending and tax receipts
very appealing. Using this
to extract the discretionary part of we need to isolate the structural part
AMECO: database of the European methodology, we provide a com-
fiscal policy in a dynamic and of the respective canonical residual.
Commission, Economic and parative assessment for 18 OECD
atheoretical model in which they While the canonical residual of, say,
Financial affairs. DPI: Database of countries.
Political Institutions, World Bank. assume that GDP reacts sluggishly tax receipts collects information on
7
to fiscal policy shocks. In its The method used to obtain all unexpected movements of that
adjusted fiscal data that characterize variable, the corresponding
6 Recall that the focus here is on policy
design rather than policy effectiveness. the discretionary part of gross fiscal structural residual is obtained by
Belonging to the EU and the eliminating all the instantaneous
7 Other approaches for measuring the data is as follows. We obtained
Eurozone take the value 1 if the discretionary part of fiscal policy include a feedback mechanisms triggered by
discretionary public spending and
country i in year t belongs narrative one (Romer and Romer, 2010) and evolutions of the other endogenous
tax receipts data for 18 OECD
respectively to the EU and to the Mountford and Uhlig's (2009) method. The
former is appealing because it relates to coun-tries, for the period 1974 to variables.
Eurozone, and zero otherwise. SGP
real-time and real discretionary fiscal 2008. Gross annual data were taken
takes the value 1 if the EU country episodes, but gathering information of the The identification method
from the OECD database. Our
i's deficit does not respect the SGP same kind and quality for 18 countries is a consists of isolating structural
public spending data are not free of
in year t, and zero otherwise. There difficult methodological task. The latter
approach identifies fiscal shocks using a net inter-est because for a few residuals according to the following
will be a negative (positive) sign for procedure. Following Blanchard
VAR model with sign restrictions on the countries net-of-interest spending
this parameter if the SGP is a dynamics of the fiscal variables, and and Perotti (2002), we begin with
data were missing. We can adjust
constraint on or a disciplining imposes orthogonality on a business cycle by writing the reduced form
shock and a monetary policy shock.
spending data for long-run interest
device for the manipulation of canonical residuals of the two fiscal
Although the au-thors claim that the rates except in the case of Greece
discretionary spending (taxes) in policy variables as linear
identifying assumptions are close to where, for the entire period, only
EU countries experimenting with minimal, the identification procedure combinations of the structural and
short-run interest rate data are
high deficits. A positive (negative) requires certain assumptions, including co-
automatic components:
movement of consumption, GDP and non- available.
sign will emphasize the
ineffectiveness of the disciplining
residential investment for 4 quarters u u u u e
following the shock to characterize For each country we estimate a g;t g;y y;t g; ;t g;r r;t g;t
device for discretionary spending automatic stabilizers. Conversely, it could be single VAR model. Let g, , , r and u u u u e
(taxes). argued that the latter should apply if a shock ;t ;y y;t ; ;t ;r r;t ;t
y denote, respectively, government
on consumption or a shock on non-
residential investment occurs, not because spending, tax revenues, consumer
both variables co-move. inflation, long-term interest rate, and where eg,t and e,t are the structural
GDP growth. Public finance shocks to the two fiscal policy
3.2. Measuring discretion in fiscal variables. The first three terms on
policy variables are expressed as
the RHS of each equation in block
percentages of GDP; all variables
(3) capture the automatic responses
We next explain a former step of are expressed in percentages. Let Y t of fiscal policy to a change in GDP
the estimation procedure that has and Ut respectively denote the growth, inflation, and interest rate
permitted to measure our dependent vector of the endogenous variables (the elasticities, denoted by ). The
variables, the discretionary public and of the reduced-form residuals of last term captures the structural
policy impulses on taxes and the VAR. The reduced form VAR policy component, which will be
spending. can be written as: interpreted as the discretionary
It is acknowledged that macro- component.
fiscal data are distorted by various Yt AL Yt1 Ut Elasticities
influences that make it difficult to (,y,g,y,g,,,,g,r,,r) are
extract their discretionary part, computed as estimations of the log
which importantly is the part in the where Yt = [gt, t, yt, t, rt] and Ut change of the variable public
sole control of policymakers, and = [ug,t, u,t, uy,t, u,t, ur,t]. A(L) is spending or tax receipts on
for which they can be held the L-year lag operator. Based on
6
accountable by citizens. the usual tests (Akaike information
In order to extract discretionary cri-terion, Schwartz information
fiscal stances, we need to make criterion), the optimal lag has been
adjustments to the interactions with set at 3 for all countries. With the
other policies (central banks' and exceptions of Greece, Italy and the
foreign policymakers' decisions) UK, where Johansen cointegration
and adjustments to business-related tests point to the existence of one
cyclical variations. This allows us to cointegration equation (at 1%) for
relate discretionary fiscal policy in each country, the remaining (15)
A. Cassette et al. / Economic Modelling 30 (2013) 7989 83
y

the contemporary log change of Our method introduces some Table 2


either GDP, inflation, or the interest new elements to that proposed by Elasticities. d
8 Blanchard and Perotti (2002). Since i
rate. g,y g,r g, f
we include inflation and interest
Australia 0.03 0.05
a 0.0001 f
Next, the canonical residuals are rates (as in Perotti, 2004), we can a e
Austria 0.04 0.03 0.02
corrected for GDP growth (the adjust the fiscal variables for a wide Belgium 0.04 0.005 0.003r
array of macroeconomic shocks. e
automatic stabilizers), inflation, and Canada 0.04 0.004 0.00003
a n
interest rate variations, in order to Under the assumption that long- Germany 0.03 0.03 0.009
t
a a
term and short term interest rates Denmark 0.02 0.02 0.004
extract the respective discretionary a a
Spain 0.08 0.04 0.03
parts of spending and tax vari-ables. are related along the yield curve, the Finland 0.03 a
0.03
0.03 f
We can then define the cyclically- adjustment to fiscal data can be France 0.02 0.007 0.002r
adjusted (CA) public spend-ing and interpreted as involving correc-tion UK 0.05 0.09 0.008o
a
tax receipts as their respective for changes in monetary policy. In Greece 0.09 0.02 0.002m
a
relation to adjustments to for-eign Ireland 0.04 0.12 0.007
canonical residuals net of the effects a
Italy 0.06 0.0003 0.02
of the other contemporaneous fiscal policies, the spatial a a
0
Japan 0.02 0.02 0.004.
endogenous variables, hence: econometric method we implement Nld. 0.04 0.009 0.0005
below is a novelty in the literature Norway 0.04 0.04
a
0.01
a
a a
on the discretionary components of Sweden 0.01 0.04 0.002 The values of the elasticities are
CA
ug ;tug;t g;yuy;t g; u;t g;r u fiscal policy. USA 0.04 0.04
a
0.01
a
reported in Table 2. The picture is
CA
u ;tu;t ;yuy;t ; u;t ;r u S relatively diverse for the different
o countries. Note that the sign of sole
u
r elasticity, g,y, is always negative
As a consequence, without 8 Two other computation methodologies c and is statistically significant for
are possible. First, taking all taxes into ac- e
theoretical priors, estimations errors most countries. Other elasticities
count (from income to social contributions), s
of the canonical VAR are adjusted we could compute a weighted average of tax : testify to variations among coun-
for changes in the macroeconomic elasticities where the weights would depend tries in terms of degrees of
environment. The ensuing structural on the respective contribution of taxes to tax indexation and tax structures. The
revenues. Second, as in Blanchard and O
component can be interpreted as E con-temporaneous impact of long
Perotti (2002), overall tax elasticity to GDP
discretionary because it is related could be a weighted average of the product C term interest rates on public
D spending often is not statistically
neither to the other endogenous of the elasticity of each tax to its own base
and the elasticity of its tax base to GDP. The ,
variables nor to their unexpected significant. This is not surprising as
methodology used in this paper is the
variations. simplest to perform uniformly for a large
one would expect relative inertia of
a
Although we use the method sample of countries. total public spending vis--vis short
u
proposed by Blanchard and Perotti 9 Blanchard and Perotti (2002) identify t term change in the nominal long
(2002), the present elaboration does one structural residual e.g. the public h term interest rate, so that no clear
spending one as the canonical one. It is o
not completely endorse their iden- pattern emerges which, at first
then possible to regress the second canonical r
tification strategy. In addition to residual on tax receipts on the first one, glance, makes the disclosure of
s
introducing automatic responses to and to identify the new residual as the sec- ' inter-actions between countries ever
macroeconomic shocks in the ond structural residualon tax receipts. In more challenging. Beyond these
their robustness checks, Blanchard and
adjusted residuals of public c
differentiated underlying forces
Perotti (2002) also reverse the identification
spending and tax receipts, assumption: the canonical residual of a behind public spending and tax re-
Blanchard and Perotti (2002) adjust spending is regressed on the structural l ceipts behaviors, it is worth
public spending (tax receipts) for residual of tax receipts to identify the c studying whether political or
structural residual of spending, where the u
the instantaneous interaction with l
institutional determinants, like
structural residual of tax receipts is identical
tax receipts (public spending). to its ca-nonical residual. a yardstick competition, opportunistic
Nevertheless, their identification t behavior, or fiscal limits in the vein
methodology requires one of these 10 This avoids entering into the unresolved i of the Stability and Growth Pact,
discussion on the best fiscal framework, in o
two potential interactions to be fixed n
can trigger comparable fiscal
this case, for a sample of 18 countries over
9 behaviors.
at zero. However, this as-sumption 40 years. However, we cannot completely s
avoid this strategic issue: although we fix all .
requires taking a stand in the debate
contemporaneous interactions to zero, we do
over two competing the-ories: so only at the macroeconomic stage of the
Spend & Tax or Tax & Spend empirical procedure; in the spatial stage, we
a Before that, three issues with
public finance frameworks (see conduct an analysis of the strategic our dataset need to be acknowl-
Musgrave, 1966), depending on interactions across tax or fiscal policies.
: edged and discussed. First, the use
which variable must be constrained of annual data may seem at odds
by the other when designing policy N
with some papers, like Blanchard
action. Within the VAR model, a o and Perotti (2002) which make use
first case arises where public t of quarterly data. However,
spending is left free to affect taxes quarterly public finance data are,
but not the reverse. In a second s more often than not, interpolations
case, tax receipts are left free to t of yearly data (see Perotti, 2004, for
a
affect public spending but not the a discussion and Giuliodori and
t
reverse. Because there are no a i Beetsma and Giuliodori, 2010b, for
priori reasons to consider that one s a clear statement justifying the use
of these frameworks is better than t of annual data). It was thus im-
i
the other for all the countries under possible to find truly quarterly data
c
review at any one time, we do not a for all the countries under study
use this method for identifying the l over the whole sample period.
11
10 l
structural components.
Second, it can be argued that there
is no reason to fix the
contemporaneous interaction
between taxes and spending to zero.
The use of Generalized Impulse
Response Func-tions (GIRFs, see
Pesaran and Shin, 1998) can be
considered as an ad-equate tool to
overcome such a potential problem
of identifying restriction. Without
identifying restrictions, the use of
GIRFs permit-ted to extract the
VAR residuals of public spending
and tax receipts that we compared
to the discretionary fiscal stances
that our method delivers. It turns
out that, on average for the whole
sample period and the whole range
of countries, the correlation for
spending between our method and
GIRF is equal to .8 and is even
stronger for tax re-ceipts with a
correlation of .9. Hence both
methods give very similar
outcomes. However, the statistical
properties of residuals from GIRF
are weaker than with our method.
For spending and receipts, in all the
countries we cover, the mean and
standard deviation of GIRF

11
The exception was the USA. We
compared our annual dataset with the
interpolated yearly-equivalent quarterly data
obtained with the same identification
procedure. The correlations between both
are equal to 0.32 and 0.58 for public
spending and tax re-ceipts, respectively.
84 A. Cassette et al. / Economic Modelling 30 (2013) 7989

Table 3a
Estimation resultsdiscretionary spending (GS2SLS estimations).
Weight matrix GDP
W leader
WDIST WTRADE
Dependent Spending Spending Spending Spending Spending Spending
variable GIRF GIRF GIRF
W*Y (rho) b c c c a a
0.588 0.849 0. 880 0.884 0.176 0.370
(.231) (0.154) (.089) (0.081) (0.233) (0.359)
Unemployment rate 0.004 0.002 0.006 0.002 0.005 0.007
(0.101) (0.011) (0.009) (0.010) (0.010) (0.012)
Young people 0.005 0.008 0.011 0.016 0.004 0.014
(0.015) (0.017) (0.012) (0.014) (0.016) (0.020)
Old people 0.005 0.001 0.005 0.004 0.005 0.007
(0.020) (0.023) (0.019) (0.022) (0.020) (0.020)
Population density 0.0001 0.0008 0.0001 0.0001 0.0001 0.0005
(0.0004) (0.0005) (0.0004) (0.0005) (0.0004) (0.0005)
Election year (t) c c c c c c
0.200 0.182 0.183 0.161 0.202 0.193
(0.073) (0.086) (0.069) (0.082) (0.073) (0.085)
Election year (t+ 1) a a b a a a
0.124 0.104 0.141 0.129 0.048 0.151
(0.069) (0.081) (0.061) (0.073) (0.070) (0.081)
Election year (t1) 0.044 0.141 0.027 0.022 0.048 0.016
(0.069) (0.086) (1.52) (0.074) (0.068) (0.016)
Left a a a a a a
0.129 0.141 0.101 0.091 0.125 0.119
(0.073) (0.086) (0.062) (0.077) (0.073) (0.083)
Left*Coal 0.021 0.073 0.006 0.016 0.007 0.036
(0.090) (0.106) (0.084) (0.100) (0.090) (0.103)
EU membership 0.032 0.021 0.019 0.023 0.048 0.064
(0.079) (0.093) (0.081) (0.095) (0.081) (0.101)
Eurozone membership 0.043 0.069 0.043 0.044 0.052 0.090
(0.087) (0.099) (0.068) (0.084) (0.105) (0.159)
SGP a a b a b c
0.159 0.162 0.178 0.281 0.213 0.359
(0.095) (0.108) (0.074) (0.088) (0.103) (0.130)
Lambda 0.007 0.079 c c a a
1.311 1.241 0.328 0.702
Notes: 612 observations. Standard errors in parentheses.
Lambda is the spatial error coefficient.
a Significant at the 10% level.
b Significant at the 5% level.
c Significant at the 1% level.

Table 3b
Estimation resultsdiscretionary tax receipts (GS2SLS estimations).
Weight matrix GDP
W leader
WDIST WTRADE
Dependent variable TR TR TR TR TR TR
GIRF GIRF GIRF
W*Y b b a b b b
1.000 0.989 0.886 0.892 0.946 0.956
(0.091) (0.099) (0.061) (0.067) (0.108) (0.118)
Unemployment rate 0.004 0.005 0.009 0.006 0.003 0.009
(0.008) (0.009) (0.008) (0.009) (0.008) (0.009)
Young people 0.003 0.002 0.001 0.004 0.003 0.004
(0.011) (0.013) (0.011) (0.013) (0.011) (0.013)
Old people 0.001 0.006 0.006 0.0002 0.006 0.001
(0.018) (0.20) (0.018) (0.020) (0.017) (0.019)
Population density 0.0001 0.0001 0.0001 0.0001 0.0001 0.0001
(0.0003) (0.0004) (0.0004) (0.0004) (0.0004) (0.0004)
Election year (t) 0.066 0.079 0.111 0.110 0.091 0.097
(0.066) (0.074) (0.066) (0.075) (0.065) (0.072)
Election year (t+ 1) 0.084 0.069 0.023 0.014 0.017 0.016
(0.062) (0.070) (0.057) (0.063) (0.060) (0.067)
Election year (t1) 0.017 0.013 0.090 0.108 0.007 0.033
(0.062) (0.070) (0.057) (0.064) (0.061) (0.067)
Left 0.018 0.027 0.052 0.073 0.051 0.061
(0.066) (0.074) (0.056) (0.064) (0.062) (0.069)
Left*Coal 0.008 0.024 0.008 0.036 0.042 0 .015
(0.082) (0.092) (0.079) (0.088) (0.079) (0.088)
EU membership 0.011 0.010 0.057 0.063 0.017 0.010
(0.071) (0.074) (0.075) (0.084) (0.067) (0.075)
Eurozone membership 0.028 0.024 0.087 0.093 0.049 0.060
(0.061) (0.092) (0.065) (0.072) (0.058) (0.063)
SGP 0.002 0.012 0.002 0.025 0.004 0.028
(0.070) (0.079) (0.077) (0.090) (0.073) (0.085)
Lambda 0.780 0.702 1.1423 1.491 0.644 0.688
a Significant at the 5% level.
b Significant at the 1% level.
A. Cassette et al. / Economic Modelling 30 (2013) 7989 85
Countries also closely mimic their equation, but consistently negative
residuals are always superior to the main trade partners and economic should nevertheless be remembered in the discretion-ary tax revenues
mean and standard deviation leaders in the OECD: the coef- that our measure of fiscal policy equation although it is not
obtained with our method. Thus, we ficients are all close to 1. It is draws on discretionary fiscal policy, statistically significant. We interpret
give preference to our method and interesting that the coefficients of whereas Brender and Drazen (2005, this result as showing that the EU
limit the use of discretionary the three weight matrices are very 2007) use an overall deficit i.e., the fiscal framework is not effective at
stances obtained with GIRFs to a similar (although the trade matrix is difference between receipts and prompting a corrective effect when
14
ro-bustness check of our main barely significant for spending, but expenditures. public deficits in the EU are above
outcomes. Third, we already strongly so for tax receipts). As this the SGP threshold. The disciplining
acknowl-edged that other methods result cannot be attributed to a Second, we find evidence of device of the SGP is not working.
had been used in the literature to similarity of contexts (taken into ideological effects on discretionary This result complements the study
extract discretionary stances (i.e. account in the first step of the spending decisions: the coefficient by Fats and Mihov (2003),
Mountford and Uhlig, 2009; Romer estimation procedure), we interpret of political affiliation (Left) for the showing that once countries fall
and Romer, 2010). Though we this as showing that the estimation chief executive is significant and below a 3% threshold, the
praise the simplicity of applying our results may be hiding different types negative. Left-wing chief execu- incentives to go further (towards the
meth-od to a wide range of of interactions. Strategic interaction, tives seem to set lower discretionary final objective of close to balance or
countries, we compare the linked to yardstick compari-son or public expenditures than right-wing surplus budgets) are much weaker
discretionary parts of tax receipts in tax competition may be the leading chief executives. As shown by the and countries reduce their efforts.
the USA with earlier estimations. mechanism, something we coefficient of the variable Left*Coal
Discretionary stances are fully investigate further in the next (where Coal stands for coalition), Finally, as a robustness check, it
consistent whatever the section. this result is not driven by the fact is worth mentioning that results
identification procedure used.
12 that Left-wing governments are obtained using discretionary stances
more often than their Right-wing extracted with GIRFs are consis-
4. Results In relation to the estimation counterpart, members of a ruling tent with the ones obtained with our
results associated with the other coalition, a claim often found in the preferred method. In contrast with
explan-atory variables, none of the literature. The empirical results for our first results, interactions are
Our estimation strategy is as
parameters associated with the the relationship between partisan magnified if GIRF-obtained dis-
follows. First, we estimate model
traditional variables, such as politics and public finance, drawing cretionary public spending is used;
(1) using OLS without taking
unemployment and demographic on a panel of advanced economies, the influence of the SGP is also
account of the potential influence of
variables, is signifi-cant for either generally are mixed (see Cusack, stronger, whereas the opportunistic
the fiscal policies set by other type of public policy. This is further 1999, for a survey). Our result behavior is somewhat lessened;
countries. Because serial correlation confirmation that our measure of
in panel data models biases the would be consistent with debt being finally, interactions with GIRF-
discretionary fiscal policy really used strate-gically la Persson and
standard errors and causes the obtained discretionary tax receipts
13
measures discretion. Svensson (1989), and which, to our are almost similar. Hence, the
results to be less efficient, we
Among the political variables, knowl-edge, has not been observed choice of the discretionary dataset
performed a Wooldridge (2002) test
there are two important results for earlier. If an incumbent government does not bias the results.
to identify potential serial
public spending. First, the dummy is afraid of not being reelected, it
correlation in the idiosyncratic error
variables associated with an elec- might decide to increase overall
term. No correla-tion was observed.
tion year indicates opportunistic use public spending, hence feeding debt
of (i.e., an increase in) discre- growth. Newly elected governments 5. Further results
We next estimate the full model
tionary public spending in the year have no choice but to reduce
(1). The dependent variable is our
CA of the election. This is strong spending whatever the economic Here we investigate the source
first step u residual, considering
evidence of a political budgetary condi-tions: thus discretionary of interdependence in national dis-
the influence of the other countries'
cycle for discretionary public public spending will fall. Our cretionary fiscal policies (5.1) and
policies (weighted spending
decisions or tax receipts) using the expen-diture. This result contrasts results support this hypothesis when check whether belonging to the EU
GS2SLS method developed by with Brender and Drazen's (2005, the incumbent government is on the matters (5.2).
Arraiz et al. (2010). We estimate the 2007) findings of a political deficit Right and the newly elected one is
spa-tial lag parameter (denoted for cycle in a large cross-section Left wing.
CA
W*u ) and the spatial error between 74 and 106 countries, a
parameter (denoted ). Estimation result that is driven by the
results for discretionary spending experience of new democracies. The remaining explanatory 14
The result may also be due to an
decisions and tax receipts are variables for socio-demographic incumbent effect or to the election of a new
presented in Tables 3a and 3b Our sample contains mature fea-tures (unemployment rate, polit-ical team. We believe that further
estimations are needed to distinguish
respectively. democracies only. Although our young people, old people, and between these effects. However, as the
The estimates in Tables 3a and results reaffirm the presence of population densities) and European purpose of the present paper is not to
3b show that the sign of the coeffi- opportunistic cycles in older characteristics (EU and Eurozone investigate the effect of the political agenda
cient associated with neighboring on discretionary public policy, we do not
democracies, it member-ship) have the expected develop this issue further here.
OECD countries' decisions on dis- signs although they are never
cretionary public expenditures and significant. This again confirms that
tax receipts are significant and 12 A comparative graph is available upon it is only the discretionary
positive. These results confirm the request. components of fiscal policy that are
existence of fiscal policy 13 Recall also that taxes and spendings are
not in (per capita) real terms but in per-cent present in our dependent variables
interactions for all weighting of GDP. (i.e., the first step has purged the
schemes based on either fiscal data, and our measure
geographical proximity or economic correctly esti-mates discretionary
leadership. This implies that impulses). The only significant
geographically close countries tend explanatory vari-able is the SGP
to imitate each other when defining dummy, which has a positive sign in
their discretionary fiscal pol-icy the discretionary public spending
(public spending and tax receipts).
86 A. Cassette et al. / Economic Modelling 30 (2013) 7989

Table 4
Source of the interactions in the OECD (ML estimations).

Dependent variable Spending Tax receipts


Weight matrix WD GDP US leader WD GDP US leader
W leader WTRADE W leader WTRADE
ELECT*W*Y c c c c c c c c
0.30 0.25 0.16 0.29 0.43 0.48 0.24 0.35
(3.21) (3.27) (3.20) (4.35) (4.97) (7.15) (5.37) (5.48)
(1ELECT)*W*Y a b a a a a a a
0.29 0.28 0.14 0.20 0.21 0.04 0.03 0.10
(1.80) (2.35) (1.75) (1.84) (1.36) (0.37) (0.46) (0.95)
Unemployment rate 0.01 0.01 0.02 0.01 0.003 0.005 0.004 0.002
(1.28) (1.23) (1.35) (1.21) (0.31) (0.48) (0.37) (0.19)
Young people 0.02 0.02 0.03 0.02 0.003 0.002 0.004 0.004
(1.21) (1.39) (1.43) (1.37) (0.20) (0.10) (0.24) (0.20)
Old people 0.01 0.02 0.02 0.01 0.0006 0.0007 0.0007 0.002
(0.64) (0.70) (0.68) (0.64) (0.02) (0.03) (0.027) (0.07)
Population density 0.0001 0.0001 0.0002 0.0002 0.0001 0.0008 -0.0003 0.0001
(0.30) (0.31) (0.38) (0.34) (0.32) (0.14) (0.06) (0.29)
Election year (t) b c b c 0.11 0.09 0.09 -0.10
0.19 0.20 0.20 0.19
(2.55) (2.60) (2.56) (2.58) (1.49) (1.26) (1.17) (1.34)
Election year (t+ 1) 0.03 0.04 0.04 0.04 0.02 0.009 0.009 0.01
(0.54) (0.65) (0.64) (0.56) (0.33) (0.13) (0.13) (0.18)
Election year (t1) a 0.11 0.11 a 0.05 0.06 0.06 0.05
0.12 0.13
(1.74) (1.51) (1.49) (1.81) (0.72) (0.84) (0.83) (0.76)
Left a a a a 0.04 0.04 0.04 0.04
0.14 0.16 0.15 0.13
Left*Coal (1.88) (1.94) (1.93) (1.75) (0.60) (0.57) (0.60) (0.61)
0.04 0.05 0.04 0.03 0.03 0.03 0.01 0.02
(0.38) (0.47) (0.43) (0.28) (0.34) (0.28) (0.13) (0.27)
EU membership 0.0005 0.02 0.003 0.006 0.05 0.07 0.07 0.06
(0.005) (0.17) (0.03) (0.05) (0.57) (0.69) (0.71) (0.60)
Eurozone membership 0.06 0.04 0.05 0.07 0.08 0.08 0.08 0.10
(0.74) (0.46) (0.60) (0.81) (0.90) (0.95) (0.96) (1.16)
SGP a b b b 0.09 0.11 0.14 0.12
0.18 0.19 0.19 0.19
(1.92) (2.07) (2.01) (2.06) (1.07) (1.18) (1.51) (1.38)
c c a
Wald test rho 0.007 0.04 0.02 0.08 0.22 0.44 0.27 0.25
(0.03) (0.25) (0.26) (0.63) (1.15) (3.25) (3.23) (1.84)
Log likelihood 633.9 636.1 637.7 632.6 621.6 622.2 627.9 623.7

Notes: 612 observations. Spatial fixed effects are included.


a Significant at the 10% level.
b Significant at the 5% level.
c Significant at the 1% level.

5.1. Interpreting the interactions among OECD fiscal policies In line with Elhorst and Frret (2009), we use a ML estimator to deal with
15
this specific model. The results are reported in Table 4. We find no
In moving from theory to empirics, it is necessary to identify the significant difference in the interactions related to discre-tionary spending.
theoretical model generating the observed spatial pattern, i.e., to dif-ferentiate However, the coefficient of spatial interaction shows highly significant
among alternative theoretical explanations for fiscal inter-actions among differences for the discretionary tax receipts. OECD countries mimic the
governments. We are particularly interested in the sources of interdependence discretionary revenues of the economic leaders (all GDP leaders or only the
in national discretionary fiscal policies. As Redoano (2007) emphasizes, the US). Thus, the yardstick competi-tion hypothesis cannot be rejected for
coefficient associated with the interaction term is not negative, so our results discretionary tax receipts. In-terestingly, the coefficient related to the US
do not point to the ex-istence of spillovers caused by free riding behaviors. leadership is inferior to the ones relative to the matrix using the whole set of
However, we want to find out whether the positive interaction coefficient countries (GDP leaders). This shows that the US is clearly a leading economy,
stems from fiscal competition or yardstick competition. but that its leadership is shared with other OECD countries. An inter-pretation
of this result could be related to the intensity of competition between
To distinguish between fiscal competition and yardstick competi-tion, we countries to attract mobile capital bases, either attracted by favorable tax
need to check whether the spatial effect is stronger in an election year. regimes or by the better quality of infrastructure (pro-vided deficits are
Yardstick competition occurs when citizens compare the fiscal and spending directed towards growth-enhancing expenditures). This interpretation does not
decisions made by the incumbent government with those made by their contradict the yardstick hypothesis, but would point to the fact that the
neighbors' policy makers (Besley and Case, 1995; Salmon, 1987). In this competition could be more intensely felt in election years.
context, policy-makers will be more concerned about neighbor incumbents in
election periods, and strate-gic interactions are likely to be stronger at such
times. Tax competi-tion, in theory, is not driven by political agendas. A
straightforward way of testing the yardstick versus the tax competition
hypotheses is to use variables for the election cycle (Elhorst and Frret, 2009;
Redoano, 2007). We interact the weighted average discretionary pol-icy of 5.2. Does belonging to the EU matter?
neighbors (Yj,t) with an election dummy (D) and estimate two interaction
Since 13 of the countries in our sample are members of the EU, we
coefficients, one for the year of election (1) and one for the rest of the period 16
estimate Eq. (2) on a subsample of European countries. The
(2). We thus exploit a two-regime spatial lag model:
15 Unfortunately, GS2SLS estimator is not available when estimating a two regime spatial lag
model. However, previous studies show that the interactions are not driven by common shocks.

16 Since these countries did not join the EU at the same time, we include a dummy for EU membership.
CA ;i CA ;j CA ;j
u k;t 1DWu k;t 21 DWu k;t Xi;t i t i;t 5
A. Cassette et al. / Economic Modelling 30 (2013) 7989 87

Table 5a
Estimation resultsdiscretionary spending for EU13 (GS2SLS estimations).
Weight matrix GDP US leader
W leader
WDIST WTRADE
Dependent variable Spending Spending Spending Spending Spending Spending GIRF Spending Spending GIRF
GIRF GIRF
W*Y (rho) a c c c c c c c
0.737 0.889 1.038 0.968 0.144 0.191 0.894 1.013
(0.243) (0.223) (.083) (0.072) (0.064) (0.064) (0.200) (0.160)
Unemployment rate 0.001 0.001 0.005 0.002 0.016 0.005 0.003 0.005
(0.011) (0.013) (0.008) (0.010) (0.015) (0.018) (0.010) (0.012)
Young people 0.001 0.004 0.003 0.010 0.0007 0.024 0.004 0.011
(0.017) (0.021) (0.011) (0.014) (0.023) (0.028) (0.016) (0.018)
Old people 0.010 0.009 0.008 0.003 0.062 0.057 0.008 0.006
(0.027) (0.032) (0.021) (0.027) (0.047) (0.056) (0.026) (0.031)
Population density 0.0001 0.0001 0.0001 0.0001 0.001 0.0007 0.0001 0.0005
(0.0005) (0.0006) (0.0005) (0.0005) (0.005) 0.006 (0.0005) (0.0006)
Election year (t) b c c c c c c c
0.307 0.291 0.277 0.304 0.335 0.337 0.322 0.314
(0.087) (0.103) (0.065) (0.081) (0.092) (0.110) (0.083) (0.098)
Election year (t+ 1) 0.113 0.110 0.143 0.144 0.115 0.124 0.149 0.141
(0.080) (0.100) (0.062) (0.079) (0.089) (0.107) (0.082) (0.096)
Election year (t1) 0.025 0.021 0.008 0.026 0.035 0.025 0.014 0.034
(0.085) (0.100) (0.066) (0.081) (0.089) (0.107) (0.082) (0.097)
Left 0.040 0.011 0.025 0.046 0.075 0.044 0.008 0.032
(0.093) (0.109) (0.090) (0.108) (0.107) (0.127) (0.092) (0.107)
Left*Coal 0.038 0.049 0.066 0.062 0.061 0.062 0.062 0.061
(0.108) (0.127) (0.090) (0.113) (0.128) (0.152) (0.107) (0.124)
EU membership 0.001 0.022 0.016 0.012 0.048 0.083 0.003 0.027
(0.108) (0.128) (0.107) (0.127) (0.144) (0.172) (0.107) (0.125)
Eurozone membership 0.055 0.065 0.052 0.021 0.177 0.261 0.075 0.052
(0.092) (0.116) (0.048) (0.066) (0.139) (0.166) (0.074) (0.091)
SGP 0.120 0.145 0.153 0.116 0.256 0.472 0.133 0.191
(0.101) (0.123) (0.042) (0.057) (0.109) (0.130) (0.085) (0.101)
Lambda 0.048 0.158 2.166
c
1.66
c 0.076 0.041 0.401 0.296

Notes: 442 observations. Standard errors in parentheses.


a Significant at the 10% level.
b Significant at the 5% level.
c Significant at the 1% level.

Table 5b
Estimation resultsdiscretionary tax receipts for EU13 (GS2SLS estimations).
Weight matrix GDP US leader
W leader
WDIST WTRADE
Dependent variable TR TR TR TR TR TR TR TR
GIRF GIRF GIRF GIRF
W*Y a c b c c c c c
1.05 1.028 0.925 0.934 0.371 0.304 1.122 1.085
(0.110) (0.17) (0.039) (0.039) (0.068) (0.067) (0.158) (0.159)
Unemployment rate 0.005 0.006 0.001 0.006 0.004 0.003 0.001 0.006
(0.009) (0.010) (0.008) (0.008) (0.015) (0.175) (0.010) (0.011)
Young people 0.003 0.003 0.007 0.004 0.010 0.001 0.009 0.004
(0.014) (0.016) (0.009) (0.009) (0.023) (0.026) (0.014) (0.016)
Old people 0.004 0.003 0.017 0.012 0.016 0.007 0.017 0.010
(0.026) (0.030) (0.019) (0.020) (0.046) (0.052) (0.025) (0.028)
Population density 0.0001 0.0002 0.0001 0.0006 0.0001 0.002 0.0001 0.0002
(0.0004) (0.0005) (0.0005) (0.0008) (0.0005) (0.006) (0.0005) (0.0005)
Election year (t) 0.078 0.053 c c 0.121 0.115 0.092 0.073
0.073 0.065
(0.079) (0.089) (0.036) (0.025) (0.090) (0.102) (0.079) (0.090)
Election year (t+ 1) 0.091 0.088 0.003 0.004 0.092 0.116 0.087 0.097
(0.078) (0.089) (0.035) (0.029) (0.087) (0.099) (0.079) (0.090)
Election year (t1) 0.021 0.001 0.021 0.033 0.014 0.45 0.042 0.007
(0.077) (0.087) (0.036) (0.025) (0.087) (0.099) (0.079) (0.089)
Left 0.111 0.117 0.114 0.103 0.112 0.119 0.098 0.100
(0.090) (0.102) (0.071) (0.055) (0.104) (0.118) (0.089) (0.101)
Left*Coal 0.040 0.011 0.076 0.028 0.006 0.062 0.040 0.028
(0.103) (0.116) (0.068) (0.055) (0.125) (0.142) (0.103) (0.117)
EU membership 0.008 0.026 0.113 0.137 0.124 0.160 0.066 0.095
(0.099) (0.112) (0.103) (0.151) (0.141) (0.160) (0.106) (0.120)
Eurozone membership 0.021 0.006 b b 0.140 0.191 0.061 0.067
0.076 0.069
(0.068) (0.077) (0.033) (0.029) (0.136) (0.154) (0.068) (0.077)
SGP 0.006 0.005 0.009 0.031 0.092 0.117 0.010 0.021
(0.075) (0.084) (0.034) (0.035) (0.107) (0.122) (0.081) (0.093)
Lambda c c c c 0.036 0.002 b b
0.642 0.731 4.634 12.41 0.576 0.636
(0.246) (0.232) (1.522) (1.793) (0.258) (0.255)

Notes: 442 observations. Standard errors in parentheses.


a Significant at the 10% level.
b Significant at the 5% level.
c Significant at the 1% level.
88 A. Cassette et al. / Economic Modelling 30 (2013) 7989

Table 6
Interactions in the OECD (ML estimations).

Dependent variable Spending Tax receipts


Weight matrix WD GDP US leader WD GDP US leader
W leader WTRADE W leader WTRADE
EU*W*Y c b cc c b c c b
0.40 0.25 0.16 0.28 0.30 0.28 0.21 0.17
(3.09) (2.41) (2.79) (3.85) (2.45) (3.13) (3.59) (2.22)
(1EU)*W*Y b c c c c c b c
0.23 0.27 0.14 0.23 0.40 0.41 0.12 0.37
(2.42) (3.12) (2.87) (3.00) (4.65) (5.44) (2.46) (5.17)
Unemployment rate 0.01 0.01 0.01 0.01 0.003 0.004 0.002 0.002
(1.19) (1.24) (1.34) (1.19) (0.29) (0.39) (0.24) (0.16)
Young people 0.02 0.02 0.02 0.02 0.004 0.001 0.003 0.003
(1.22) (1.38) (1.30) (1.39) (0.23) (0.08) (0.20) (0.17)
Old people 0.02 0.02 0.02 0.02 0.00004 0.001 0.001 0.0009
(0.65) (0.69) (0.67) (0.67) (0.001) (0.06) (0.06) (0.03)
Population density 0.0001 0.0001 0.0002 0.0002 0.0002 0.0001 0.0001 0.0001
(0.30) (0.31) (0.34) (0.36) (0.31) (0.20) (0.21) (0.27)
Election year (t) c c b c 0.11 0.10 0.10 0.10
0.20 0.20 0.19 0.19
(2.60) (2.60) (2.54) (2.58) (1.52) (1.41) (1.36) (1.41)
Election year (t+ 1) 0.03 0.05 0.05 0.04 0.02 0.01 0.02 0.01
(0.52) (0.65) (0.70) (0.56) (0.33) (0.22) (0.30) (0.24)
Election year (t1) a 0.10 0.10 a 0.05 0.06 0.05 0.05
0.12 0.13
(1.77) (1.51) (1.47) (1.79) (0.73) (0.84) (0.70) (0.77)
Left a a a a 0.04 0.05 0.05 0.05
0.14 0.15 0.15 0.13
(1.87) (1.94) (1.93) (1.75) (0.63) (0.68) (0.71) (0.68)
Left*Coal 0.03 0.05 0.05 0.03 0.03 0.03 0.008 0.03
(0.37) (0.48) (0.50) (0.28) (0.35) (0.31) (0.08) (0.30)
EU membership 0.005 0.02 0.01 0.007 0.06 0.07 0.08 0.06
(0.05) (0.17) (0.11) (0.07) (0.56) (0.72) (0.78) (0.63)
Eurozone membership 0.06 0.04 0.05 0.07 0.08 0.09 0.10 0.09
(0.70) (0.45) (0.54) (0.77) (0.86) (1.01) (1.15) (1.06)
SGP b b b b 0.09 0.10 0.14 0.12
0.18 0.19 0.20 0.19
(1.98) (2.05) (2.13) (2.10) (1.03) (1.14) (1.52) (1.33)
a
Wald test rho 0.16 0.02 0.02 0.05 0.09 0.13 0.09 0.20
(0.96) (013) (0.27) (0.48) (0.60) (1.00) (1.12) (1.84)
Log likelihood 633.5 636.1 636.8 632.7 622.1 624.2 630.0 623.6

Notes: 612 observations. Spatial fixed effects are included. T-Student in parentheses.
a Significant at the 10% level.
b Significant at the 5% level.
c Significant at the 1% level.

estimation results in Tables 5a and 5b, confirm the robustness of the results in its neighbor, even if the leaders (and especially the US) are stronger players in
Tables 3a and 3b; the political cycle coefficients are stronger for the sample of the game.
EU countries than for the whole sample. The coeffi-cient of the SGP dummy
is very robust to different specifications of the weight matrices and the 6. Conclusion
different samples. Note also that the es-timation results confirm the crucial
role of the US as a leader in terms of discretionary public decisionsamong Although spatial econometrics is commonly used to measure stra-tegic
the sample of European countries and the whole sample. This result confirms interactions among local governments, the literature investi-gating state
the increased dependencies among countries. public policy interdependences is small. Our paper tries to fill the gap by
extracting the relevant component of policy choices at national state level, i.e.,
Another way to test whether EU membership matters for in-terdependence the discretionary part of these choices.
among fiscal policy decisions, is to include in the full sample two interaction We investigated the relationship between the discretionary com-ponents of
coefficients for whether the country i belongs to the EU or not. On the one fiscal policies, for a sample of 18 OECD countries, during the period 1974
hand, EU membership may cause more interdependence in these countries' 2008. In a first step, we built two indicators of dis-cretionary fiscal policy,
decisions since these countries have fewer policy tools to compete with other considered as residual components of a VAR model: one for public spending,
Euro-pean countries. As Redoano (2007) states: they move in a similar and one for tax receipts. In a second step we estimated discretionary fiscal
competitive and institutional environment and are subject to similar budget policy interactions among these countries, using spatial econometrics.
and political constraints, moreover policy makers have more occasions to
meet and discuss formally or informally their plans. On the other hand, non- Our results confirm the existence of strong interactions among neighbor
EU members may engage in more compet-itive behavior. countries' public decisions (neighborhood being defined by economic as well
as geographic proximity). We found evidence of opportunistic behavior by
OECD countries' governments in relation to discretionary public spending,
We estimate Eq. (5) on the full sample, including a dummy D that is equal and this behavior was even stronger for the sub-sample of European countries.
to 1 for EU membership and 0 otherwise. Among the 18 coun-tries in our Finally, our estimation results confirmed the important role of the US as a
dataset 8 were EU members at the beginning of the period and 13 were leader in terms of EU countries' discretionary public decisions.
members at the end of the period. Table 6 shows that the degree of interaction
is the same, whether the country is a member or is not a member of EU. This We believe that this study could be extended in various
result is obtained for both measures of discretionary policy. We consider this
subset of results as confirming the preceding ones, revealing the strong
ways, including a deeper investigation of the role of political
influence of each country on variables in the setting of discretionary expenditures and tax
receipts. It may be interesting also to introduce measures of
exchange rates,
A. Cassette et al. / Economic Modelling 30 (2013) 7989 89
Kingdom? Scottish Journal of Political Steiner, A., 2010. Contagious policies: an
Economy 56 (5), 580607. Elhorst, J.P., Frret, S., 2009. Evidence of analysis of spatial interactions among
competitiveness, or current account Cusack, T.R., 1999. Partisan politics and countries' capital account policies.
political yardstick competition in France
balances, as policy-makers could fiscal policy. Comparative Political using a two- regime spatial Durbin Pacific Economic Review 15 (3), 422
want to react to variations in these Studies 32 (4), 464486. model with fixed effects. Journal of 445.
Elhorst, J.P., 2003. Specification and Regional Science 49 (5), 931951. Wilson, J., 1999. Theories of tax
variables. estimation of spatial panel data models. competition. National Tax Journal 53, 269
Fats, A., Mihov, I., 2003. On constraining
Interna-tional Regional Science Review fiscal policy discretion in EMU. Oxford 304. Wooldridge, J.M., 2002. Econometric
26, 244268. Review of Economic Policy 19 (1), Analysis of Cross Section and Panel Data.
112131. MIT
References Press, Cambridge, MA.
Figlio, D.N., Kolpin, V.W., Reid, W.E., 1999.
Agnello, L., Cimadomo, J., 2012. Do states play welfare games? Journal
Discretionary Fiscal Policies over the of Urban Economics 46, 437454.
Cycle: New Evi-dence based on the Gilardi, F., 2010. Who learns from what in
ESCB Disaggregated Approach. policy diffusion processes. American
International Journal of Central Banking Journal of Political Science 54 (3), 650
8 (2), 4386. 666.
Anselin, L., 1988. Spatial Econometrics: Giuliodori, M., Beetsma, R., 2008. On the
Methods and Models. Kluwer relationship between fiscal plans in the
Academic, Dordrecht. European Union: an empirical analysis
based on real-time data. Journal of
Arraiz, I., Drukker, D.M., Kelejian, H.H., Comparative Eco-nomics 36, 221242.
Prucha, I.R., 2010. A spatial Cliff-Ord- Hallerberg, M., Strauch, R., von Hagen, J.,
type models with heteroskedastic 2009. Fiscal governance in Europe.
innovations: small and large sample Cambridge University Press.
results. Journal of Regional Science 50 Lindbeck, A., 2008. Welfare State, 2nd
(2), 592614. edition. New Palgrave Dictionary, vol.
Baicker, K., 2005. The spillover effects of 8, pp. 731738.
state spending. Journal of Public
Economics 89, 529544. Manski, C., 1993. Identification of
Beck, T., Clarke, G., Groff, A., Keefer, P., endogenous social effects: the reflection
Walsh, P., 2001. New tools in problem. Review of Economic Studies
comparative political economy: The 60, 531542.
Database of Political Institutions. World Mountford, A., Uhlig, H., 2009. What are the
Bank Economic Review 15 (1), 165 effects of fiscal policy shocks? Journal
176. of Applied Econometrics 24 (6), 960
Beetsma, R., Giuliodori, M., 2010a. Fiscal 992.
adjustment to cyclical developments in Musgrave, R., 1966. Principles of budget
determination. In: Cameron, H.,
the OECD: an empirical analysis based
Henderson, W. (Eds.), Public Finance:
on real-time data. Oxford Economic
Selected Readings. Random House.
Papers 419441.
Neely, Ch.J., Rapach, D.E., 2009. Common
fluctuations in OECD budget balances.
Beetsma, R., Giuliodori, M., 2010b.
Working Papers, 2009055. Federal
Discretionary fiscal policy: review and
Reserve Bank of St. Louis.
estimates for the EU. CesIfo Working
OECD, 2004. The legal framework for
Paper 2948.
budget systems: an international
Besley, T., Case, A., 1995. Incumbent
comparison. OECD Journal on
behavior: vote seeking, tax setting and
Budgeting 4 (3) (special issue).
yardstick competition. American
Oudiz, G., Sachs, J.D., 1984.
Economic Review 85, 2545.
Macroeconomic policy coordination
Biau, O., Girard, E., 2005. Politique
among the industrial economies.
budgtaire et dynamique conomique en
Brookings Papers on Economic Activity
France: l'approche VAR Structurel.
1, 175.
Revue conomique 56 (3), 755764.
Perotti, R., 2004. Public investment: another
Blanchard, O.J., Perotti, R., 2002. An
(different) look. IGIER Working Paper
empirical characterization of the
277. Bocconi University. December.
dynamic effects of changes in
Persson, T., Svensson, L., 1989. Why a
government spending and taxes on
stubborn conservative would run a
output. Quarterly Journal of Eco-nomics
deficit: policy with time-inconsistent
117 (4), 13291368.
preferences. Quarterly Journal of
Brender, A., Drazen, A., 2005. Political
Economics 104.
budget cycles in new versus established
Pesaran, H.H., Shin, Y., 1998. Generalized
democracies. Journal of Monetary
impulse response analysis in linear
Economics 52, 12711295.
multivariate models. Economics Letters
Brender, A., Drazen, A., 2007. Electoral
58 (1), 1729.
fiscal policy in new, old, and fragile
Ramey, V.A., Shapiro, M.D., 1998. Costly
democracies. Comparative Economic
capital reallocation and the effects of
Studies 49, 446466.
government spending. Carnegie-
Brueckner, J., 2003. Strategic interaction
Rochester Conference Series on Public
among governments: an overview of
Policy, 48(1), pp. 145194.
empirical studies. International Regional
Redoano, M., 2007. Fiscal interactions
Science Review 26, 175188.
among European countries. Does the
Burriel, P., de Castro, F., Garrote, D., Gordo,
EU matter? : CESIFO Working paper
E., Paredes, J., Perez, J.J., 2010. Fiscal
No. 1952. March.
policy shocks in the Euro area and the
Revelli, F., 2005. On spatial public finance
US: an empirical assessment. Fiscal
empirics. International Tax and Public
Studies 31 (2), 251285.
Finance 12, 475492.
Case, A., Hines, J., Rosen, H., 1993. Budget
Romer, C., Romer, D., 2010. The
spillovers and fiscal policy
macroeconomic effects of tax changes:
interdependence. Journal of Public
estimates based on a new measure of
Economics 52, 285307.
fiscal shocks. American Economic
Creel, J., Monperrus-Veroni, P., Saraceno, F.,
Review 100, 763801.
2009. Has the Golden Rule of public
Salmon, P., 1987. Decentralization as an
finance made a difference in the United
incentive scheme. Oxford Review of
Economic Policy 3, 2443.

You might also like