You are on page 1of 9

Estimating Dynamic Demand for Cigarettes Using Panel Data: The Effects of Bootlegging,

Taxation and Advertising Reconsidered


Author(s): Badi H. Baltagi and Dan Levin
Source: The Review of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 68, No. 1 (Feb., 1986), pp. 148-155
Published by: The MIT Press
Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/1924938
Accessed: 07-07-2015 18:12 UTC

Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at http://www.jstor.org/page/
info/about/policies/terms.jsp

JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of content
in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms of scholarship.
For more information about JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org.

The MIT Press is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to The Review of Economics and Statistics.

http://www.jstor.org

This content downloaded from 165.190.89.176 on Tue, 07 Jul 2015 18:12:26 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
ESTIMATING DYNAMIC DEMAND FOR CIGARETTES
USING PANEL DATA: THE EFFECTS OF BOOTLEGGING,
TAXATION AND ADVERTISING RECONSIDERED
BadiH. BaltagiandDan Levin*
Abstracct-A dynamic demand for cigarette consumption is cigarettes and therefore benefit the cigarette in-
estimated using pooled data of 46 states over the period 1963 to
1980. A price elasticity of -0.2 and an insignificant income
dustry.2
elasticity is found using pooled estimation techniques. The In an effort to assess the net effect of the adver-
"bootlegging" effect is modeled explicitly using "neighboring" tising ban on cigarette consumption, Hamilton
price. The effect is found to be significant. Two major policy
issues are analyzed in light of these new estimates: (1) Cigarette
(1972) estimated a demand for cigarettes equation
taxation is found to be an effective tool for generating revenues incorporating prior estimates of price and income
even though there may be spillover effects to neighboring states elasticities. He finds that pro-smoking messages
where bootlegging is significant. (2) The effects of the Fairness
Doctrine Act and the advertising ban on cigarette consumption
are less effective determinants of cigarette con-
are re-examined. We find mild support for the effectiveness of sumption than the health-scare anti-smoking mes-
subsidized anti-smoking messages in reducing cigarette con- sages. Hamilton therefore concludes that the net
sumption, and no support for the thesis that the ban on
advertising helps to increase per capita consumption.
effect of the advertising ban will be to increase the
per capita consumption of cigarettes.
Cigarette taxation may deter cigarette consump-
I. Introduction tion. The effectiveness of this policy instrument
M EDICAL journals as well as the Surgeon depends upon the price elasticity of demand for
General have published numerous reports cigarettes and on whether this elasticity can be
warning about the health hazards of smoking.' accurately predicted over time.3
The federal government has also played a major Underlying both policy questions is the proper
role in attempting to reduce the consumption of specification and estimation of the cigarette de-
cigarettes. Major policy interventions are (i) the mand equation. Prior evidence on the magnitudes
imposition of warning labels by the Federal Trade of price and income elasticities show a wide range
Commission effective January 1965, (ii) the appli- of estimates varying from - 0.10 to - 1.48 for
cation of the Fairness Doctrine Act to cigarette price elasticity and 0.12 to 0.82 for income elas-
advertising in June 1967, and (iii) the Congres- ticity. For example, Lyon and Simon (1968), using
sional ban of broadcast advertising of cigarettes a quasi-experimental approach, computed arc price
effective January 1971. The banning of pro-smok- elasticities using state sales data before and after a
ing messages from television and radio has virtu- tax change. The median price elasticity found was
- 0.511 with a 95% confidence interval of - 0.346
ally eliminated anti-smoking messages, since the
broadcasting stations are no longer required to to - 0.71]3.Maier (1955), on the other hand, arrived
adhere to the Fairness Doctrine Act. If these at a higher range of price elasticities (-1.08 to
health-scare-oriented messages are more effective - 1.48) using a cross-section study of state data.
than pro-smoking messages, the net effect of the Sackrin (1957) using a cross-section study found
ban might be to increase the consumption of an income elasticity of 0.12. Hamilton (1972) using
Lyon and Simon's (1968) price elasticity estimate
ran cross-section regressions over state data and
Received for publication July 20, 1984. Revision accepted for obtained an income elasticity of 0.73. Faced with
publication April 11, 1985.
*University of Houston. this wide range of price and income elasticities, the
The authors would like to thank the Center for Public Policy policy maker arrives at different conclusions using
at the University of Houston for its generous support; Franklin
M. Fisher, James M. Griffin, Jeffrey E. Harris, Jerry Hausman
2 See Hamilton (1972) and Doron (1979) for support of this
and anonymous referees for their helpful comments; and Luis
Rivas for his able research assistance. Any remaining errors are view.
our own. 3See Laughhunn and Lyon (1971) for support of cigarette
l The latest Surgeon General's report finds that in 1983, 80% taxation as an effective policy tool in reducing cigarette con-
to 90% of chronic lung disease in the United States can be sumption. They estimate a price elasticity of -0.81 and find
directly attributable to cigarette smoking. that this demand for cigarettes is stable over time.

[ 148 1 Copyright (C 1986

This content downloaded from 165.190.89.176 on Tue, 07 Jul 2015 18:12:26 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
DYNAMIC DEMAND FOR CIGARETTES 149

different elasticity estimates. In this study we tion is modelled as follows:


estimate a dynamic demand for cigarettes based
C = f (P, Y, A, H) (1)
on pooled data of 46 states over the period 1963 to
1980.4 These panel data allow for regional varia- where C is the per capita consumption of cigarettes
tion in prices, income and consumption patterns, by persons of smoking age (14 years and older), P
and cover ten years after the ban on advertising. is the real price of cigarettes, Y is the real disposa-
Another distinctive feature of this paper is that ble income per capita, A is the per capita index of
it tackles the problem of bootlegging in the advertising,6 and H is the health dummy varia-
cigarette industry. Briefly stated, due to the varia- bles.
tion in tax rates across states, consumers in state A It is also assumed that cigarette consumption is
might be tempted to buy from lower tax state B. governed by a partial adjustment or habit per-
This will imply that consumption per capita in sistence model,7 i.e.,
state B is over-reported and that in A under-
reported. Hence a cross-section study based on lnC - lnC1 = 8(lnC* - lnC_1) + u (2)
state data that does not account for this effect
where C*, the expected or "desired" level of con-
leads to price elasticities that are biased. In this
sumption of cigarettes, is given by
study, the bootlegging effect is modeled explicitly
by the use of a neighboring price effect which acts ln C* = a + f1ln P + 321nY + 31nPn
as a substitute price. This effect is found to be 00
statistically significant.5 +yOEA A_i. (3)
Finally, this paper examines two policy ques- i=O
tions in light of the pooled results. The first tests
whether there is any support for the hypothesis Note that advertising enters with an infinite geo-
that the net effect of the advertising ban is to metric lag.8 Also, a distinctive feature of this
increase rather than decrease the consumption of specification is the introduction of Pn, which de-
cigarettes. The second determines to what extent notes the minimum real price of cigarettes in any
cigarette taxation is an effective tool for generating neighboring state.9 This can be justified as fol-
state revenues. lows: At any point in time, cigarette prices vary
In section II we outline our demand equation across states because cigarette tax rates vary.
and contrast it with previous specifications. Sec- Smokers in a high tax state are tempted to buy
tion III examines the results of the pooling tech- from neighboring states with lower tax rates. This
niques and reports our estimates of price, income smuggling or bootlegging effect can be estimated
and neighboring price effects. Section IV probes by the use of Pn which acts as a substitute price.10
the question of the advertising ban and cigarette 6 Telser (1962) and McGuinness and Cowling (1975) suggest
taxation and their effects on cigarette consump- that advertising be measured by the number of "messages"
tion. Section V gives our summary and conclusion. received by consumers. Unfortunately, the absence of such
information renders this task impossible. Like Hamilton (1972)
and others our study uses an index of per capita advertising
II. The Model expenditures.
7 For a detailed discussion on the application of the partial
Following Hamilton (1972) and McGuinness adjustment model to cigarette demand, see McGuinness and
and Cowling (1975), the cigarette demand equa- Cowling (1975).
8 See Palda (1964) for arguments in support of this hypothe-
4 Data on advertising was available from the U.S. Federal sis.
Trade Commission report from 1963 to 1980. Extending the 9 A selector matrix, made up of zeros and ones, is constructed
sample before 1963 requires reconciling two different sources of identifying the neighboring states for each state. Each row of
data. Other data sources are given in the appendix. this matrix is multiplied by the price variable to pick out the
S The Advisory Commission on Intergovernmental Relations prices of neighboring states. Finally, the minimum of these
estimates that in 1975 cigarette bootlegging cost the high-tax prices is computed for each state.
states $391 million. The Commission also finds that bootleg- 10 This bootlegging specification is a first attempt at dealing
ging is mainly due to wide disparities in tax rates among states, with this issue and is not free of problems. For example, (i) it
and is responsive to it. The seriousness of the problem was does not account for the fact that in a geographically large
officially recognized by the enactment of the 1978 Federal state, cross-border shopping may take place in different neigh-
Contraband Cigarette Act which made the transportation of boring states and not just in the minimum-price neighboring
contraband cigarettes in interstate commerce a federal criminal state. (ii) It does not explicitly account for bootlegging done
offense. over long distances by trucks.

This content downloaded from 165.190.89.176 on Tue, 07 Jul 2015 18:12:26 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
150 THE REVIEW OF ECONOMICS AND STATISTICS

Substituting (3) into (2) and performing some III. Results


iterative substitutions,11 the model becomes
A. Hausman-Taylor Estimation
In C, = ao + aA! + f318In P1 + f328 ln Y1
Following Balestra and Nerlove (1966), we pool
+?I38 In Pn + -yO8Zt(X) these data using an errorcomponent model."4Since
+((- S)ln C,- + ut (4) advertising and the Fairness Doctrine variables are
where Z1(X) = At + XAt_11+ * +/XA-Al and a invariant across states, their effects vanish when
is a constant involving initial values. we apply the Within transformation. In order to
The presence of lagged consumption in the estimate these effects and account for the possible
cigarette demand equation can therefore be correlation between these variables and the time-
justified on the basis of the partial adjustment specific effects, the Hausman-Taylor (1981) effi-
model (equation (2)) or the presence of an infinite cient estimation procedure is applied. This is an
geometric lag on advertising (equation (3)).12 This instrumental variables technique which necessarily
means that one ought to make careful distinction requires at least as many exogenous state-varying
between 8 and A, the two different sources of variables as there are endogenous state-invariant
dynamic behavior in this demand equation. variables. Intuitively, the instrumental variables
For the period 1964-1980, we focus on two needed come from the between variation, i.e., the
major events that may have changed the effect of state means, of the state-varying exogenous vari-
advertising on cigarette consumption. The first is ables. In addition, the within variation of the
the Fairness Doctrine Act which subsidized anti- state-varying variables are used as instruments for
smoking messages from 1968 to 1970. The second the variables themselves. This is an advantage of
is the broadcast ban of cigarette advertisement panel data; instruments are obtained from both
effective January 1971. The effect of the first policy the between and within variation of the exogenous
measure is incorporated in our model by including state-varying variables. Table 1, panel A, gives the
a dummy variable FD which takes the value of the ordinary least squares (OLS), Within, and the
per capita index of advertising in television and Hausman-Taylor results. Except for income and
radio for the years 1968-1970, and zero for the advertising both of which are insignificant, the
remaining years.13 The effect of the second policy results indicate little variation between OLS and
measure is incorporated by allowing separate dum- the efficient estimator."5 These results indicate a
mies for each year in which the ban was in effect, significant lagged coefficient of consumption (0.9),
i.e., 1971-1980. a significant price elasticity (-0.2) and an insig-
In the next section the pooled time-series of nificant income elasticity ranging between - 0.002
cross-section results are presented for the demand and 0.004. The neighboring price elasticity coeffi-
equation using an error component model. The cient is significant (0.08) and advertising and the
Hausman-Taylor (1981) estimation procedure is Fairness-Doctrine effects are both insignificant.
applied to account for the fact that advertising is The Hausman (1978) chi-squared statistic is 0.001
invariant across states. Finally, a Zellner-Geisel indicating that we cannot reject the null hy-
(1970) estimation procedure is applied to equation pothesis of no misspecification."6
(4) to distinguish between lagged effects due to
advertising and those due to habit persistence. B. Zellner-Geisel Estimation
See Zellner and Geisel (1970). So far, the dynamic specification considered does
12
Hamilton (1972), for example, does not assume a partial not attribute any lagged effect due to advertising.
adjustment model. His model is dynamic solely because of the
infinite geometric lag on advertising. Also, the moving average
14
error term resulting from the Koyck transformation is ignored. For more detailed analysis on estimation and test of hy-
This renders his least-squares estimates inconsistent and ineffi- potheses in an error component model, see Baltagi (1981) and
cient. the references cited there.
13 The Fairness Doctrine Act tied the number of anti-smok- 15 This may be attributed to the close results of OLS and the
ing messages to the number of cigarette commercials. The value Within estimator and the high value of 0 obtained (0.888).
of these anti-smoking messages was estimated at $75 million 16 For this model, the null hypothesis specifies that the time-

for 1970; see Harris (1979). This is roughly one-third of cigarette specific effects are not correlated with the included exogenous
advertising expenditures on TV and radio for that year. variables, some of which are invariant across states.

This content downloaded from 165.190.89.176 on Tue, 07 Jul 2015 18:12:26 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
DYNAMIC DEMAND FOR CIGARETTES 151

TABLE 1.-ESTIMATED COEFFICIENTS


OF THE CIGARETTEDEMAND EQUATION

A. Pooled Estimation Resultsa


(lnC,)1 ln P, ln Y, ln Pnt Adv FD Constant S.E. R2

OLS 0.927 -0.225 0.004 0.081 0.038 -0.005 0.114 0.047 0.95
(97) (9.4) (0.3) (4.5) (1.2) (1.1) (1.4)
Within 0.931 -0.215 -0.002 0.078 - - - 0.046 0.95
(99) (9.1) (0.1) (4.4)
Hausman- 0.930 - 0.215 - 0.002 0.078 0.063 - 0.005 0.070 0.047 0.95
Taylorb (98) (9.1) (0.1) (4.4) (0.2) (0.1) (0.1)
B. The Zellner-Geisel Search Procedure for Different Values of X
X (ln C,) lnJP ln Y, ln Pnt Adv FD Constant S.E.C R2

0.1 0.930 -0.219 -0.004 0.079 0.001 -0.013 0.210 0.047 0.95
(97.3) (9.2) (0.3) (4.4) (0.04) (2.8) (2.3)
0.01 0.931 -0.219 -0.004 0.079 0.008 -0.012 0.196 0.047 0.95
(97.4) (9.2) (0.3) (4.4) (0.3) (2.6) (2.3)
0.001 0.931 -0.219 -0.004 0.079 0.009 -0.012 0.194 0.047 0.95
(97.4) (9.2) (0.3) (4.4) (0.3) (2.6) (2.3)
C. The Zellner-Geisel Search Procedure Truncating the Remainder
X (lnC,)1 ln P, In Yt In Pnt Adv FD Constant S.E. R2

0.43 0.930 -0.215 -0.002 0.078 0.022 -0.014 0.138 0.047 0.95
(98.0) (9.0) (0.1) (4.4) (0.6) (0.6) (1.1)
a Numbers in parentheses are t-statistics.
bThe estimates of the variance components used in the Hausman-Taylor procedure are -2 = 0.002, ax = 0.004,
and 0 = 0.888.
CAs X varies between 0.999 and 0.001, the standard error of the regression systematically drops from 0.04667 to
0.04659 and W2 increases from 0.925 to 0.953.

In fact, the above results find the effect of advertis- Next, we applied the following two-step estima-
ing generally insignificant. In what follows, we tion procedure which accounts for the error com-
consider the specification given in (4) which dis- ponent specification: In the first step, a X is
tinguishes between the dynamics due to advertis- chosen and the Zellner-Geisel transformation is
ing and that due to habit persistence. We apply applied on each variable. In the second step, the
the Zellner-Geisel (1970) estimation procedure to Hausman-Taylor efficient estimation method is ap-
determine the significance of both causes of dy- plied, and the process is repeated for X between
namics and to determine if the price and income 0.001 and 0.999. Again, this procedure obtained a
elasticities change under this specification. residual sum of squares which was decreasing in X.
Table 1, panel B, shows the results of a search However, ignoring X' in equation (4), i.e., truncat-
procedure for various values of X. As X decreases ing the remainder, this procedure converged for
from 0.999 to 0.001 so does the residual sum of X = 0.43 and the results are given in table 1, panel
squares. However, for small values of X close to C.18 Comparing with the Hausman-Taylor results
zero, the regression estimates do not change given in panel A, only the coefficients of advertis-
much."7 The lagged coefficient on consumption ing and FD are different. However, both of these
(1 - 8) is 0.93 and significant, the price elasticity coefficients are insignificant.
is - 0.2 and significant. Income elasticity is - 0.004 These results show a slow but statistically sig-
and insignificant, and the neighboring price elas- nificant adjustment coefficient in the habit per-
ticity is 0.08 and significant. Finally, advertising is sistence model (8 = 0.07). X, on the other hand, is
insignificant, whereas the Fairness Doctrine effect 0.43 in case we ignore the truncation remainder,
is - 0.01 and significant.
18
Dhrymes (1971) showed that ignoring the truncation re-
17 In fact, the only significant change is in the estimate of the mainder makes no difference asymptotically. However, Pesaran
coefficient of X'. Estimates of the dummy variables and XA (1973) and Schmidt (1975) argued for the inclusion of this
coefficients are not presented here and are available upon term, based on empirical as well as small sample Monte Carlo
request from the authors. results.

This content downloaded from 165.190.89.176 on Tue, 07 Jul 2015 18:12:26 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
152 THE REVIEW OF ECONOMICS AND STATISTICS

and very small and close to zero in case we do not More important,such cross-sectionregressions
ignore it. This indicates a fairly quick decay rate assume a rather simplisticform for cigarettede-
for the effect of advertising on consumption of mand. Performingthe dynamic cross-sectionre-
cigarettes.19 gressions for the years 1964 through 1980, one
It is important to emphasize the robustness of gets: (i) a lagged coefficienton cigaretteconsump-
the above results. To summarize, we have found a tion, whichis 0.9, and is statisticallysignificantfor
lower price elasticity (-0.2) than Lyon and Simon; all years; (ii) a price elasticitythat variesbetween
an insignificant income elasticity contrary to the - 0.02 and - 0.33 and is statisticallysignificantin
large income elasticity of (0.73) found by Ham- most years;(iii) an incomeelasticitythat is statisti-
ilton; a neighboring price elasticity of (0.08), indi- cally insignificantin 11 out of 17 years and has a
cating a small but significant bootlegging effect on negative sign in 5 out of the 6 significantyears.
the demand for cigarettes. Finally, we found an This income elasticitynever exceeds 0.156 in ab-
insignificant effect of advertising on the consump- solute value.
tion of cigarettes. The implications of these results In summary,static cross-sectionregressionsare
to policy analysis are given in the next section. biased and should not be relied upon to give
At this stage, we pause to explain the difference unbiasedestimatesof the incomeelasticityeven if
between our results and those obtained by Ham- a prior price elasticity is used. Hamilton'shigh
ilton (1972), who used the prior price elasticity of income elasticity of 0.73 is not supportedby the
- 0.511 to generate an average income elasticity of dynamic cross-sectionresults nor by our pooled
0.734 from two cross-section regressions of states, dynamic model. Our resultsindicate an insignifi-
one in 1954 and another in 1965. Similar cross-sec- cant incomeelasticityfor cigarettedemand.22
tion regressions performed for each year show a
supporting income elasticity to Hamilton's in the IV. PolicyAnalysis
range of 0.61 to 0.75 but only over the period
In this section we tackle two importantpolicy
1963-1970. In fact, this income elasticity estimate
implications of our estimatesof the demand for
drops steadily from 0.49 in 1971 to 0.01 in 1979
becoming insignificant from 1972 and on, and
cigarettes.The first is the impact of the Fairness
Doctrine Act and the ban on broadcastadvertis-
even switching sign in 1980.20 At the least, these
ing, and the second is the impact of taxation on
results should cast serious doubt over the use of
prior constant price and income elasticities for the
cigarettedemand.
purpose of estimation and policy calculations over
A. The Fairness Doctrine Act and the Advertising
the period of study, 1963-1980.21
Ban on Cigarette Consumption

19 Previousstudies,most notablyHamilton(1972),
The importance of advertising in affecting cigarette de-
mand has mixed reviews in the literature. Many economists argued that the health scare and anti-smoking
argued that cigarette advertising is "the main competitive messageswere morepotent than promotionalads,
weapon" by which oligopolists sought to increase their relative and that the net effect of the ban is to give a
shares. See Telser (1962, p. 407). Some studies found cigarette
advertising to have an insignificant effect on demand (see stimulus to cigaretteconsumption.Given the re-
Schoenberg (1933) and Schmalensee (1972)), while others found sults in section III, we ask the followingquestions:
it to be significant (see Hamilton (1972) and McGuinness
and Cowling (1975)). More recently, Ashley, Granger and (1) Was the FairnessDoctrine Act effectivein
Schmalensee (1980) found that causality runs from consump- reducing the effect of promotionalads (on
tion to advertising and not vice versa, and that advertising
effects on consumption are short-lived. television and radio)on cigaretteconsump-
20 For space limitations, the results upon which the remainder tion?
of this section are based are given in tables 2 and 3 and are (2) For 1968-1970, the yearswhen the Fairness
available upon request from the authors.
21 Hamilton (1972) used this prior estimate of the price Doctrine Act was in effect, does the reduc-
elasticity in order to circumvent the multicollinearity problem tion of one real per capita dollarof broad-
between price and income. Although the multicollinearity prob- cast advertisingincreasecigaretteconsump-
lem may be serious in an aggregate time-series regression for
the United States, we do not find it to be the case at the state tion, ratherthan decreaseit?
level. For our pooled data, the simple correlation coefficient
22
between price and income never exceeded 0.4 over the entire Insignificant income elasticities are also supported by
sample period 1963 to 1980. Warner (1977) and Lyon and Spruill (1979).

This content downloaded from 165.190.89.176 on Tue, 07 Jul 2015 18:12:26 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
DYNAMIC DEMAND FOR CIGARETTES 153

Question I can be formulated as testing whether answer has to do with oligopolistic competition via
the coefficient of FD in the demand equation is advertising. We have to distinguish between the
non-negative, versus the alternative that it is nega- effectiveness of advertising to increase total sales,
tive. Table 1 shows that the coefficient of FD is which is low, and its effectiveness to make smokers
negative for both the OLS and the Hausman- switch from one brand to the other, which can be
Taylor estimators. However, we cannot reject the high. This argument finds support in Scherer(1980;
null hypothesis of non-negativity in both cases. p. 389), who summarizes previous studies and
Hence, these results offer support, albeit mild, to concludes on the following note: "That repeated
the effectiveness of the Fairness Doctrine on the rivalrous escalations of cigarette advertising have
reduction of cigarette consumption. carried outlays far beyond the short run profit-
Question 2 is at the heart of the hypothesis maximizing point seems indisputable." He also
proposed by Hamilton (1972, p. 401) which claims adds that much of the industry's advertising is
that "... . the net effect of the ban may be to self-cancelling and unprofitable even in the long
increase consumption, not decrease it." This state- run.25
ment, if true, implies that during the Fairness
Doctrine years (1968 to 1970), a dollar decrease in B. The Impact of Taxation on Cigarette Demand
real per capita broadcast advertising may increase
A second important policy issue is the extent to
consumption rather than decrease it. This can be
which taxation can be used to reduce cigarette
formulated as testing whether the sum of the
consumption and/or to raise revenue. The
coefficients of advertising and FD is non-negative
effectiveness of taxation as a policy tool depends
versus the alternative that this sum is negative. For
critically on the price elasticity of demand for
the results given in table 1, this sum is positive for
cigarettes. Before we assess this effect, it is im-
both OLS and the Hausman-Taylor results, and
portant to distinguish between the two price elas-
we cannot reject the null hypothesis of non-nega-
ticities estimated from the demand equation. The
tivity. Hence, in our opinion, this evidence does
first is the usual own price elasticity of demand
not provide support to Hamilton's hypothesis.23
and the second is the neighboring price elasticity
Hamilton (1972, p. 408) supports his argument
effect.
by bringing to evidence the fact that
The pooled results reported in table 1 show an
... prior to the Congressional ban the cigarette companies own price elasticity of -0.22 and a neighboring
volunteered to Congress a private broadcast advertising ban, if
in exchange Congress gave the companies' agreement antitrust price elasticity of 0.08. This means that a tax
immunity and all federal agencies dropped their proposals for increase across the board raising real prices in all
stronger health warnings. Given that the health scare was a states by 10% will reduce consumption per capita
stronger marginal determinant of cigarette demand than was
cigarette advertising, the companies' eagerness to assist the of cigarettes by only 1.4%.To assess the impact of
government to end the subsidized antismoking advertising was a tax hike in individual states on; ought to be
not surprising. careful in determining whether neighboring states
However, using Hamilton's own results and profit levied a tax or not, and to what extent bootlegging
maximization that accounts for the cost of adver- is important for that state. For example, New
tising, one can explain the above voluntariness of Hampshire and Massachusetts are neighboring
the cigarette companies without necessarily states with the latter being consistently a higher
reaching Hamilton's conclusions.24 tax state with lower per capita consumption.26
Why then do companies use advertising so ex- Own price elasticity in New Hampshire27is - 0.856
tensively beyond the point of profitability? The (1.4) and the neighboring price elasticity is 1.316
(2.8). For Massachusetts, own price elasticity is
- 0.386 (1.6) and the neighboring price elasticity is
23
Support for Hamilton's hypothesis is a rejection of Ho, i.e.,
a negative significant sum of the coefficients of Adv and FD.
25
However, it is important to add that our results do not deci- See also Schmalensee (1972) and Doron (1979) and the
sively refute Hamilton's hypothesis, i.e., the sum of the coeffi- references cited there.
cients obtained is not significantly positive. 26 See Doron (1979, p. 64) who noticed that per capita

24 Calculations based on our insignificant advertising elastic- smoking in New Hampshire was double that in neighboring
ity are clearly in favor of this view. See also Doron (1979) and Massachusetts and argued that this must be due to the ex-
Simon (1967) for more detailed calculations in support of this istence of bootlegging.
27
view. Numbers in parentheses are t-statistics.

This content downloaded from 165.190.89.176 on Tue, 07 Jul 2015 18:12:26 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
154 THE REVIEW OF ECONOMICS AND STATISTICS

0.163 (0.5). Using these numbers,let us assess the sumption. The small but significant own and
impact of a tax levied in each of these states.28A neighboringpriceelasticitiesindicatethat cigarette
tax increase in Massachusettsinducinga 10%in- taxation will generaterevenueseven thoughthere
crease in the real price of cigarettesin that state may be spillovereffectsto neighboringstateswhere
will (ceteris paribus) decreasereportedconsump- bootlegging is significant.However, as an anti-
tion per capita in that state by 3.9%and increase smoking tool, cigarette taxation may not be as
reported consumptionper capita in New Hamp- effectivein reducingcigaretteconsumptionas pre-
shire by 13.2%.Similarly,a tax increasein New viously thought.Finally,our findingsindicatemild
Hampshire inducing a 10% increase in the real support for the effect of subsidizedanti-smoking
price of cigarettesin that state will (ceterispari- messages in reducing consumptionof cigarettes
bus) decreasereportedper capita consumptionin and no supportfor the hypothesisthat the adver-
that state by 8.6% and cause an increasein re- tising ban has the effectof increasingconsumption
ported per capita consumptionin Massachusetts ratherthan reducingit.
of 1.6%.29This examplegives an idea of how one
can assess the net effect of a tax increase on APPENDIX
consumptionfor a specificstate. It is importantto
calculatethe percentagereductionsor increasesin Data Sources
reportedconsumptionin the adjoiningstateskeep- The Tobacco Tax Council reports the annual per capita
ing in mind the varying population size across consumption of cigarettes by state. This is measured in packs
of cigarettes per head. It also gives the average retail price per
these states. pack. Per capita disposable income data on a state basis are
What about the tax on cigarettesas a revenue published in various issues of the Survey of CurrentBusiness.
generatingtool? Ourresultsindicatea price-inelas- Population data are obtained from various issues of the Current
Population Reports. Price deflators are obtained from the Bureau
tic demandfor cigaretteswith a lowerpriceelastic- of Labor Statistics. Advertising expenditures are taken from the
ity than reported in the literature.This implies United States Federal Trade Commission report to Congress.
that there is room for generatingrevenueat the
federal level using tax increases.30For state reve-
REFERENCES
nues, one ought to refer to the state regressions
and worry about the importanceof bootleggingin Advisory Commission on Intergovernmental Relations,
"Cigarette Tax Evasion: A Second Look," Washington,
shiftingrevenuesamongneighboringstates. D.C. (Mar. 1985).
Ashley, Richard, W. J. Granger, and Richard Schmalensee,
V. "Advertising and Aggregate Consumption: An Analysis
Summary and Conclusion of Causality," Econometrica48 (July 1980), 1149-1167.
In this paper, we have considereda dynamic Balestra, Pietro, and Marc Nerlove, "Pooling Cross-Section
and Time-Series Data in the Estimation of a Dynamic
demandfor cigarettesandestimatedit usingpooled Model: The Demand for Natural Gas," Econometrica34
time-seriesof cross-sectiondata. Our resultsindi- (July 1966), 585-612.
cate an insignificantincomeelasticity,a significant Baltagi, Badi H., "Pooling: An Experimental Study of Alterna-
tive Testing and Estimation Procedures in a Two-Way
price elasticitymuchlowerthan reportedin previ- Error Component Model," Journal of Econometrics 17
ous literatureand a small but significantbootleg- (Sept. 1981), 21-49.
ging effect acrossneighboringstates.The insignifi- Dhrymes, Phoebus J., DistributedLags: Problems of Estimation
and Formulation (San Francisco: Holden-Day, 1971).
cant income elasticitycontradictshigherestimates Doron, Gideon, The Smoking Paradox: Public Regulation in the
reportedin the literature,implyingthat states ex- Cigarette Industry (Cambridge, MA: Abt Books, 1979).
hibiting growthin theirincomeper capitawill not Hamilton, James L., "The Demand for Cigarettes: Advertising,
the Health Scare, and the Cigarette Advertising Ban,"
necessarilyexhibit more per-capitacigarettecon- this REVIEW 54 (Nov. 1972), 401-411.
Harris, Jeffrey E., "Cigarette Smoking in the United States,"
28 from Smoking and Health: A Report of the Surgeon
To keep the analysis simple, we assume that Massachusetts
is New Hampshire's only neighbor. General, U.S. Department of Health, Education, and
29 That this latter effect is not statistically significant is not Welfare, Office of Smoking and Health, Washington,
surprising given that New Hampshire's real prices (even after D.C. (Jan. 1979).
the tax hikes) have always been less than those in Massachu- Hausman, Jerry A., "Specification Tests in Econometrics,"
setts. Econometrica 46 (Nov. 1978), 1251-1271.
30 This is in agreement with Lyon and Spruill's (1979) recom- Hausman, Jerry A., and William E. Taylor, "Panel Data and
mendations. However, their study finds a higher price elasticity Unobservable Individual Effects," Econometrica 49
of - 0.45 which varies across different regions in the United (Nov. 1981), 1377-1398.
States. Laughhunn, Dan J., and Herbert L. Lyon, "The Feasibility of

This content downloaded from 165.190.89.176 on Tue, 07 Jul 2015 18:12:26 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
DYNAMIC DEMAND FOR CIGARETTES 155

Tax Induced Price Increases as a Deterrent to Cigarette A Cross-Section Analysis," Agricultural Economics Re-
Consumption," Journal of Business Administration 3 search 9 (Jan. 1957), 1-9.
(Fall 1971), 27-35. Scherer, Frederic M., IndustrialMarket Structureand Economic
Lyon, Herbert L., and Julian L. Simon, "Price Elasticity of the Performance (Chicago: Rand McNally, 1980).
Demand for Cigarettes in the United States," American Schmalensee, Richard L., On the Economics of Advertising
Journal of Agricultural Economics 50 (Nov. 1968), (Amsterdam: North-Holland Publishing Company,
881-893. 1972).
Lyon, Herbert-L., and M. Lynn Spruill, "A Temporal Cross- Schmidt, Peter, "The Small Sample Effects of Various Treat-
Section Analysis of Cigarette Price Elasticity in the ments of Truncation Remainders in the Estimation of
United States," working paper, University of Houston Distributed Lag Models," this REVIEW 57 (Aug. 1975),
(Sept. 1979). 387-389.
Maier, Frank H., "Consumer Demand for Cigarettes Esti- Schoenberg, Erika H., "The Demand Curve for Cigarettes,"
mated from State Data," Journal of Farm Economics 37 Journal of Business 6 (Jan. 1933), 15-35.
(Nov. 1955), 690-704. Simon, Julian L., "The Effect of the Competitive Structure
McGuinness, Tony, and Keith Cowling, "Advertising and the upon Expenditures of Advertising," QuarterlyJournal of
Aggregate Demand for Cigarettes," European Economic Economics 81 (Nov. 1967), 610-627.
Review 6 (1975), 311-328. Telser, Lester G., "Advertising and Cigarettes," Journal of
Palda, Kristian S., The Measurementof CumulativeAdvertising Political Economy 70 (Oct. 1962), 471-499.
Effects (Englewood Cliffs: Prentice-Hall, 1964). Warner, Kenneth E., "The Effect of the Anti-Smoking
Pesaran, M. Hashem, "The Small Sample Problem of Trunca- Campaign on Cigarette Consumption," American Jour-
tion Remainders in the Estimation of Distributed Lag nal of Public Health 67 (July 1977).
Models with Autocorrelated Errors," International Eco- Zellner, Arnold, and Martin S. Geisel, "Analysis of Distributed
nomic Review 14 (Feb. 1973), 120-131. Lag Models with Applications to Consumption Func-
Sackrin, S. M., "Income Elasticity of Demand for Cigarettes: tion Estimation," Econometrica38 (Nov. 1970), 865-888.

This content downloaded from 165.190.89.176 on Tue, 07 Jul 2015 18:12:26 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

You might also like