You are on page 1of 7

Journal Of Investment Management, Vol. 12, No. 1, (2014), pp.

62–68
© JOIM 2014
JOIM
www.joim.com

THE INTEREST RATE SENSITIVITY OF TAX-EXEMPT


BONDS UNDER TAX-NEUTRAL VALUATION
Andrew Kalotaya

We explore the effect of taxes on the prices of municipal bonds. Although interest is tax-
exempt, the gain resulting from purchasing a muni at a deep discount—below the so-called
de minimis threshold—is subject to severe tax treatment. The gain is taxed as ordinary
income at maturity; currently for a typical investor the applicable rate is roughly 40%.
Thus, purchasing a bond at 80 would trigger an 8-point tax liability.
The paper develops a rigorous approach to the pricing of munis by incorporating taxes
into the industry-standard OAS-based valuation framework. The key concept is ‘tax-neutral
value’, which is simply the fair value that takes into account potential tax payments. Tax-
neutral valuation allows us to explore how muni prices respond to changing interest rates.
The basic insight is that due to the interaction of the purchase price and the related tax
payment, discount tax-exempt bonds are significantly more sensitive to interest rates than
taxable bonds. For example, currently the duration of a 10-year taxable bond is roughly
8.5 years, while that of a 10-year muni can exceed 13 years.
Tax-neutral valuation provides the foundation for accurately projecting the prices of
munis under various interest rate scenarios. The primary application of this approach is
risk management, including hedging. It is also essential for determining the optimum time
to recognize a loss in order to maximize after-tax performance.

1 Introduction capital gains and losses are subject to complex tax


treatment. Taxes affect investors’ after-tax per-
While interest payments on municipal bonds formance. For example, because the gain on a
(‘munis’) are exempt from federal income taxes, bond purchased in the secondary market at a dis-
count and held to maturity is subject to taxes,
a President, Andrew Kalotay Associates, Inc., 61 Broadway, the after-tax yield of the investment will be lower
Suite 1400, New York, NY 10006, USA. Tel.: (212) 482 than the pretax yield. The prices of discount tax-
0900; E-mail: andy@kalotay.com exempt bonds are routinely converted to so-called

62 First Quarter 2014


The Interest Rate Sensitivity of Tax-Exempt Bonds under Tax-Neutral Valuation 63

after-tax cashflow yields to maturity. Converting Investors who purchase a bond in the secondary
price to an after-tax yield is straightforward, market at a discount and hold it to maturity or call
and it allows investors to compare alternative are taxed on the gain. At a modest discount to par
investments on an-apples-to-apples basis. (a so-called de minimis discount, defined as less
than 0.25 times the number of years remaining to
The prices of tax-exempt bonds reflect these com-
maturity) the applicable rate is the relatively low
plex tax considerations. This phenomenon is well
capital gains rate (at the time of writing, 20% if
recognized by practitioners but their attempts to
long-term). If the discount exceeds the de minimis
deal with the effects analytically have been lim-
threshold, the entire gain is taxed at the higher
ited to using yields and modified durations, and
ordinary income rate (around 40% at the time of
not contemporary fixed income analytics (e.g. see
writing). We also note that the loss on a bond
Leibowitz, 1981; Merrill Lynch, 2007). In this
purchased at a premium and held to maturity has
paper we will extend the conventional arbitrage-
no tax effect.
free method of bond valuation (the so-called
option-adjusted spread approach) to incorporate The tax treatment is more complicated if the bond
tax effects. We first determine the tax-neutral is sold prior to maturity or call. But because the
(‘fair’) value of a bond assuming a buy-and-hold values in the current discussion are based on buy-
policy. This fair value provides the basis for rigor- and-hold, we ignore taxation related to sales.
ous risk analysis.1 As we shall see, the interest rate
sensitivity of a muni can be significantly greater
3 Market prices of munis
than that of a like taxable bond.
The obvious first question to explore is the rea-
The implications of this observation are far-
sonableness of the assumption that market prices
reaching. At the present, standard commercially
can be imputed from a buy-and-hold strategy. On
available analytical systems do not take taxes into
the one hand, Constantinides and Ingersoll (1984)
account. This is particularly troublesome in the
argue that active tax management can produce
case of exchange traded funds and mutual funds
superior return over buy-and-hold. This would
that attempt to replicate the performance of a
imply that market prices should be higher than
large index—which may consist of over 10,000
that indicated by buy-and-hold. On the other hand,
bonds—with a few hundred securities. Matching
there is scant empirical evidence that such is the
durations on a pretax basis does not assure that
case. In fact, according to Ang et al. (2010),
the same relationship holds when the effect of
the market prices of deep discount munis are
taxes is properly accounted for. In light of this,
significantly lower than would be implied by buy-
the large tracking errors of these ‘index-matching’
and-hold, and they provide a possible explanation
portfolios do not come as a surprise.
for this phenomenon.
In any case, for risk management purposes it is
2 Relevant tax treatment
irrelevant whether the actual prices are marginally
A thorough discussion of the tax treatment of higher or lower than that indicated by buy-and-
munis, including original issue discount bonds hold. The relevant fact is that prices of munis do
(OIDs) and original issue premium bonds (OIPs), reflect the presence of taxes, and our approach
is provided by Ang et al. (2010). For illustrative could be readily adapted to pricing models more
purposes, we will assume that the bonds under sophisticated than ‘buy-and-hold’, should such
consideration were originally sold at par. become available.

First Quarter 2014 Journal Of Investment Management


64 Andrew Kalotay

4 Methodology the case of a callable bond the fair value has to


be determined iteratively, as the timing of the
Our initial goal is to determine the tax-neutral
tax payment depends on the evolution of inter-
value (‘fair value’) of tax-exempt munis using
est rates. The calculation can be simplified if the
arbitrage-free analysis (see Kalotay et al. (1993)).
bond is optionless, as illustrated below.
In the absence of taxes and options, fair value is
obtained by discounting prospective cash flows at Assume that the bond has 10 years remaining to
the appropriate spot rates; if options are present, maturity, its pretax value is 80, the discount factor
such discounting is performed on a lattice. The for a cash flow occurring 10 years from now is
taxation of munis complicates the calculation 0.45, and the tax rate applicable to the gain is
because the cash flows depend on the purchase 40%. Solving
price; roughly speaking, the lower the purchase
V = 80 − 0.45 × 0.40 × (100 − V )
price the more taxes will be due when the bond is
retired. gives the fair value V = 75.610.
Figure 1 displays the fair values of 10-year bonds
4.1 Practical considerations with various coupons. For comparison purposes,
Arbitrage-free valuation requires an issuer- we also show the values in the absence of taxes.
specific optionless (par) yield curve for discount- The calculations are based on the yield curve
ing, and for valuing options at a specified interest displayed in Table 1. The assumed volatility for
rate volatility. In the case of tax-exempt bonds, callable bonds (see Figure 3) is 20%. The long-
optionless long-term rates are not readily avail- term capital gains rate is 20%, and the tax rate
able, because the industry-standard MMD and applicable to ordinary income is 40%.
MMA yield curves assume that the underly- Note that the pretax value of a discount muni
ing bonds are callable at par after 10 years. exceeds its fair value by the present value of
The approach of extracting optionless par curves the taxes paid at the time the bond is redeemed.
from callable curves is described in Kalotay and (The discount rate applied to the tax payment is
Dorigan (2008). The numerical examples below
assume that the optionless curve has been pro-
vided and that it evolves according to an industry-
standard lognormal process. Our methodology,
of course, is applicable to arbitrary interest rate
processes.

5 Tax-neutral value
We now determine the value of a bond under
the buy-and-hold strategy. We define the tax-
Figure 1 Fair value of 10-year bonds.
neutral (fair) value as the price which is equal
to the present value of after-tax cashflows (i.e.
interest and principal payments minus the taxes Table 1 Issuer’s optionless par yield curve.
paid at the time of redemption). Simply put, the
Maturity (yrs) 1 2 5 10 15 20 30
fair value is the ‘pretax’ value adjusted for taxes.
Rate (%) 1.0 1.5 2.0 3.0 3.5 4.0 4.5
Because taxes depend on the purchase price, in

Journal Of Investment Management First Quarter 2014


The Interest Rate Sensitivity of Tax-Exempt Bonds under Tax-Neutral Valuation 65

the spot rate derived from the issuer’s yield curve.)


Here the de minimis threshold is 97.50% of par
(100 − 10 × 0.25). In the absence of taxes, a
bond with a 2.72% coupon would be valued at
97.50 (blue line), but due to the tax on the gain
the value would be less. Conspicuous in Figure 1
is how the fair value (red line) ‘falls off the cliff’
at the de minimis level. The ‘critical’ coupon (dis-
cussed below) is 2.76%. If the coupon is 2.75%,
the fair value declines by 0.60% to about 96.90.
The reason is that above 97.50 the gain is taxed Figure 3 Fair value of 30-year NC10’s.
at the 20% capital gains rate, but below 97.50 the
gain is taxed at 40%. In comparison to Figure 2, the presence of the call
The de minimis threshold with 30 years to matu- option reduces both the pretax and after-tax val-
rity is 92.50%. The critical coupon for a bullet is ues. In the case of lower-coupon bonds the results
4.10%; at 4.09% the fair value drops by 0.36% are similar to those in Figure 2, because the effect
to 92.14 (red line). The effect is less pronounced of the call option is relatively insignificant. In the
than in Figure 1, because the maturity is farther case of higher-coupon bonds the tax effect is rel-
away. In the absence of taxes, a coupon of 4.07% atively insignificant to begin with, because the
would give a 92.50% value (blue line). price is closer to par.

As discussed above, it is more difficult to deter-


mine the fair value of a callable bond than that 5.1 Critical coupon level
of a bullet, because the redemption date is uncer- As we saw in the examples above, for a given yield
tain and in turn so is the present value of the tax curve and bond structure (i.e. maturity and option-
payment. We also note that the redemption date ality) there is a theoretical coupon level where the
depends on the interest rate volatility (assumed to fair value falls off the cliff. While in reality the
be 20% in the illustration below). Thus in this case price decline is not as abrupt as indicated by our
the fair value must be calculated by lattice-based model, this critical coupon level is still of prac-
recursion. tical interest. If a bond is purchased at a price
slightly above the de minimis threshold, its price
could decline significantly even if rates rise only
modestly. Because the market anticipates this pos-
sibility, the price experiences downward pressure
when the coupon is slightly above the critical
level. Similarly, the price can be higher than that
predicted by our model if the coupon is slightly
lower than the critical level. Price behavior near
the de minimis level is of independent interest and
could be explored as a separate study.
We also observe that while market prices are
Figure 2 Fair value of 30-year bullets. extremely important to investors whose portfolios

First Quarter 2014 Journal Of Investment Management


66 Andrew Kalotay

must be marked to market (such as mutual funds The general approach to determining interest rate
and ETFs), they are less significant for buy-and- risk is as follows:
hold investors. The point is that the value of the
(1) Determine the OAS of the bond at the given
remaining cashflows to an existing investor can be
price relative to the benchmark yield curve.
higher or lower than to a marginal buyer. This is
(2) Shock the yield curve.
discussed in Kalotay and Howard (forthcoming).
(3) Reprice the bond at the OAS obtained in (1).
For a given yield curve, the critical coupon of an (4) Calculate risk measures.
optionless can be determined easily (see below). In the case of tax-exempt bonds, it is imperative
For a callable bond the calculation is obviously to recognize that the prices may be depressed by
more complicated. potential tax payments; otherwise the interest rate
Illustration: Determining the Critical Coupon C sensitivity can be severely underestimated. The
of an Optionless 10-Year Bond intuition is clear: higher rates depress the price,
and a lower price increases taxes. The OAS should
Assume the present value of a 10-year $1 annuity be an indication of only credit risk or mispricing,
is $8.50, the discount factor for a cash flow occur- but it should not reflect tax effects. The appro-
ring 10 years from now is 0.70, and the capital priate spread measure for munis is tax-neutral
gains rate is 20%. Solving OAS, that is, the OAS that equates the price to
the tax-neutral value.
8.50 × C + 0.70 × (100 − 0.20 × 2.50)
Naturally the higher the applicable tax rate the
= 97.50,
greater is the above effect, so it is most pro-
results in C = 3.28%. nounced when the price is below the de minimis
threshold. At the de minimis threshold the price
Note that the fair value of a bond whose coupon is discontinuous, and therefore interest rate sensi-
is slightly below 3.28% is tivity is not defined. Whenever the tax treatment
is discontinuous it is desirable to distinguish
97.50 − 0.70 × (0.40 − 0.20) × 2.50 = 97.15,
between ‘up’ and ‘down’ durations.
which accounts for the incremental tax bill arising The exhibits below display the durations of vari-
from the applicability of the ordinary income tax ous tax-exempt bond structures using tax-neutral
rate (40%) over the tax bill arising from applying prices (based on the benchmark curve).
the short-term gain rate (20%).
Figure 4 displays the durations of 10-year
optionless bonds. As we saw in Figure 1, the
6 The interest rate sensitivity of critical coupon in this case is 2.76%. The
tax-exempt bonds durations of bonds with coupon below 2.76%
exceeds 12 years, which is 2 years longer
In the preceding sections of this paper we devel-
than the bonds’ maturity! Duration slightly
oped a tax-neutral valuation model for tax-exempt
exceeds 10 years even in the de minimis
bonds assuming buy-and-hold, and explored the
region (coupons larger than 2.76% but less than
behavior of this model for various bond structures.
3.00%).
Given the above foundation, we are ready to inves-
tigate the interest rate sensitivity of tax-exempt Since the pretax duration of a bond cannot exceed
bonds. the bond’s maturity, any calculator that disregards

Journal Of Investment Management First Quarter 2014


The Interest Rate Sensitivity of Tax-Exempt Bonds under Tax-Neutral Valuation 67

again when it falls below 92.50 (the de min-


imis threshold price occurring at around a 4.33%
coupon).
There is an obvious extension to key rate durations
(not discussed here).

6.1 Observations about ‘pretax’


risk measures
Figure 4 Duration of 10-year optionless bonds.
As described at the beginning of this section, inter-
est rate risk measures are calculated using a fixed
taxes will severely underestimate the true duration
OAS relative to a benchmark yield curve. Note
of discount bonds. But the error is significant even
that OAS depends on whether or not tax effects
if the price is close to par—for example, the pretax
are incorporated.
duration of a bond in the de minimis region is 8.85
years, considerably shorter than the true duration. Example: Solve for OAS, Calculate Duration
It is well known that taxes can have a drastic Suppose that the price of an optionless 10-year
effect on interest rate sensitivity. For example, 2.5% bond is 84.15; calculate its OAS relative to
as pointed out by Kalotay (1984), the after-tax the benchmark curve given earlier.
duration of an original issue discount bond issued
Pretax (incorrect): OAS = 147 bps, dura-
by a taxable corporation can exceed the bond’s
tion = 8.87 years
maturity.
Tax-neutral: OAS = 90 bps, duration = 12.14
Figure 5 below shows similar information for 30- years
year bonds callable in 10 years. As long as the Correct calculation of interest rate risk requires
price is below par, the duration is longer than an explicit adjustment for taxes. In the absence of
it would be in the absence of taxes (latter not such, the risk of tax-exempt bonds is underesti-
shown). The duration is not defined when the price mated.
is discontinuous—in this case when it declines
below par (slightly below a 5.00% coupon) and
7 Conclusion
It is generally recognized that taxes on capital
gains depress the prices of tax-exempt bonds. We
have presented a rigorous approach to incorpo-
rating this effect in the valuation of tax-exempt
bonds. Specifically, we extended the conventional
OAS framework to after-tax analysis, including
tax-neutral value and tax-neutral OAS.
Using tax-neutral values as a foundation, we have
shown that the interest rate sensitivity of tax-
Figure 5 Duration of 30NC10 bonds. exempt bonds can be significantly greater than

First Quarter 2014 Journal Of Investment Management


68 Andrew Kalotay

that indicated by pretax calculation, which unfor- Constantinides, G. M. and Ingersoll, J. E. (1984). “Optimal
tunately is the current standard in the industry. The Bond Trading with Personal Taxes,” Journal of Financial
difference is most pronounced for shorter-term Economics 13(3), 299–335.
Kalotay, A. (1984). “An Analysis of Original Issue Discount
bonds selling below the de minimis level, whose
Bonds,” Financial Management (Autumn), 29–38.
duration can exceed their maturity by several Kalotay, A. and Dorigan, M. (2008). “What Makes the
years. Municipal Yield Curve Rise,” Journal of Fixed Income
(Winter), 65–71.
In light of the fact that under current prac- Kalotay, A. and Howard, C. D. “The Tax Option in
tice the interest rate sensitivity of tax-exempt Municipal Bonds,” Journal of Portfolio Management.
bonds is miscalculated, the large tracking errors forthcoming.
of ‘index-matched’ ETFs and mutual funds are Kalotay, A., Williams, G., and Fabozzi, F. (1993). “A Model
not surprising. Tax-adjusted analytics are essen- for Valuing Bonds and Embedded Options,” Financial
tial for proper management of tax-exempt bond Analysts Journal (May/June), 34–46.
Leibowitz, M. (1981). “Volatility in Tax-Exempt Bonds: A
portfolios.
Theoretical Model,” Financial Analysts Journal (Novem-
ber/December).
Note Merrill Lynch (not an individual) (2007). “Dealing with
Deeper Discounts,” Muni & Derivatives Commentary
1 Tax-neutral values, durations, and other values in (June 18), 1–2.
this paper were calculated using Kalotay Analytics’
MuniOASTM library (patent pending).
Keywords: Municipal bonds; tax-neutral value;
taxes; duration; de minimis rule; bond valuation;
References after-tax; interest rate sensitivity; risk manage-
Ang, A., Bhansali, V., and Xing, Y. (2010). “Taxes on Tax- ment; tax-neutral OAS; option-adjusted spread;
Exempt Bonds,” Journal of Finance 65(2), 565–601. critical coupon

Journal Of Investment Management First Quarter 2014

You might also like