You are on page 1of 3

MANAGERIAL AND DECISION ECONOMICS

Manage. Decis. Econ. 26: 499–512 (2005)


Published online in Wiley InterScience (www.interscience.wiley.com). DOI: 10.1002/mde.1237

Strategic Managerial Incentives Under


Adverse Selection
Michel Cavagnac*
University of Limoges, GREMAQ and LEERNA-Toulouse I, France

We extend the strategic contract model where the owner designs incentive schemes for her
manager before the latter takes output decisions. Firstly, we introduce private knowledge
regarding costs within each owner–manager pair. Under adverse selection, we show that
delegation involves a trade-off between strategic commitment and the cost of an extra
informational rent linked to decentralization. Which policies will arise in equilibrium? We
introduce in the game an initial stage where owners can simultaneously choose between control
and delegation. We show that if decision variables are strategic substitutes, choosing output
control through a quantity-lump sum transfer contract is a dominating strategy. If decision
variables are strategic complements, this policy is a dominated strategy. Further, two types of
dominant-strategies equilibrium may arise: in the first type, both principals use delegation; in
the second one, both principals implement delegation for a low-cost manager and output
control for a high-cost one. Copyright # 2005 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd.

INTRODUCTION tre and López-Cuñat (2001) in the context of


oligopoly including the possibility, for the firms, to
Following Vickers (1985), the literature on com- constitute cartels. Fershtman et al. (1991) incor-
petition in oligopolies has developed the idea that porate in the contract the realization of a given
the separation of ownership and management objective (target compensation). In Salas (1992),
within a firm may be a good thing for the owner the contract takes into account both the profit
because a non-profit-maximizing manager may brought by the manager and the profits achieved
bring about higher profits than a profit-maximiz- by the other firms. In Labory (1997), it is a system
ing one. We find two variants in this literature. The of promotion that is used to affect the managers’
first one is the strategic contract model where the incentives in a strategic way. The second variant is
owner designs incentive schemes for her manager the strategic organization model. Indeed, commit-
before the latter takes decisions. In duopoly ment to a behavior different from profit max-
contexts, Vickers (1985), Fershtman and Judd imization can also be achieved through the
(1987) and Sklivas (1987) base the contracts on internal organization of the firm. For example, in
profit and sales. This type of contract is also used Fershtman (1985) and Sen (1993), each firm has
by Barros (1995) in a situation of mixed duopoly two managers who jointly decide on the produc-
(private firm–public firm) and by González-Maes- tion level, after the owner has determined the
bargaining power of each one.1 In Gal-Or (1993),
it is once more in terms of strategic commitment
*Correspondence to: Université des Sciences Sociales-Gremaq, that the principal chooses, for the operations of
Manufacture des Tabacs - Bât. F, 21 Allée de Brienne, 31042
Toulouse Cedex, France. production and distribution, between depart-
E-mail: michel.cavagnac@univ-tlse1.fr mentalization and integrated management.

Copyright # 2005 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd.


500 M. CAVAGNAC

Considering multi-product firms, Fauli-Oller and tive setting. This is the first extension brought by
Giralt (1995) base the remuneration contracts, in our work: we make the organizational choice
each division of the firm, on the profit achieved by endogenous. Hence, we introduce in the game an
the other divisions.2 The external organization of the initial stage where owners can simultaneously
firm can constitute a strategic variable as well. This choose (with commitment) between control and
is the case in Bonanno and Vickers (1988) where, for delegation. Our game is a differentiated duopoly
the sale of her products, the principal chooses game. Firms compete in quantities. Since the result
between a vertical structure and a vertical integra- of delegation appears to be closely related to the
tion (direct selling). In Gal-Or (1992) and Barros nature of the decision variables, we consider that
(1997), it is once more the search for a strategic goods may be either substitutes (strategic substitute
commitment that determines the choice between decision variables) or complements (strategic com-
proceeding (or not) to the vertical integration of plement decision variables). It is well known (e.g.
specific production operations. Let us note that in Gal-Or, 1985) that the first player that moves earns
other domains, such as international competition, the highest (lowest) profits when decision variables
some analogous opportunities exist. The taxes and are strategic substitutes (complements). However,
subsidies applied to the firm by the principal (the at the initial stage of our game, choosing direct
government) replace there the incentives schemes of control only will eliminate the possibility of being a
the managers’ rewarding contracts above.3 follower and choosing to delegate only will exclude
Let us stress that when the individual owner– the possibility of leading.
manager relationship is examined within a sym- The main motivation for this paper stems from
metric competitive framework, that is when each the informational context. Most of the studies
owner–manager pair can make use of strategic quoted above are based on the assumption of
contracts, the positive effect of delegation is not so complete information. However, this may be a
clear. For example, Fershtman and Judd (1987) strong assumption insofar as the delegation of
and Sklivas (1987) show that the delegation result authority is often the source of asymmetries of
critically depends upon the nature of the competi- information. Indeed, it can be very expensive for
tion in duopoly (in fact, upon the nature of the the principal to control with precision the actions
decision variables). On one hand, in the Cournot- undertaken by her manager. Besides, the manager
quantity competition case (strategic substitute is closer to the realities of the market and to the
decision variables), at the incentive equilibrium, organization of production; she has often private
each owner gives her manager a positive incentive information. Here, we introduce private knowl-
for sales, therefore motivating him towards a high edge by considering that managers have better
production level. As a result, firms end up information than owners with respect to costs.
achieving lower profits than they would have in More precisely, in our model, each manager knows
the usual Cournot outcomes. On the other hand, her own costs (which can be of two types) but none
when firms compete in a Bertrand way via of the other participants in the game do. It follows
differentiated products (strategic complement de- that within each owner-manager pair, we have a
cision variables), at the incentive equilibrium, each situation à la Baron–Myerson (1982). In this sense,
owner gives her manager a negative incentive for we are within the usual principal–agent frame-
sales, therefore encouraging high prices. Conse- work. The crucial difference, however, is that we
quently, firms achieve higher profits than they have to consider agency problems for two princi-
would have in the usual direct price competition. pal–agent pairs in competition. There are still few
However, although comparing profits earned by studies that exploit, in situations of competition,
strategic delegation contracts with profits supplied the results obtained by the theory of the agency:
by a direct control of managers is an interesting Gal-Or (1992,1993), Barros (1997) and Labory
question in itself, it does not answer the question (1997). In these works, strategic effects on compe-
which organizational structure arises in equili- tition are the result of the internal organization
brium. Even if each owner prefers, say, the chosen for the firm. In our model, the owner may
outcome where both owners use strategic delega- manage her firm so that she keeps the control on
tion to the outcome where both owners directly output decisions. Alternatively, the owner may
control managers, it does not follow that this type organize delegating that provides strategic oppor-
of organization will be reached in a non-coopera- tunities. In the latter case, in the spirit of the

Copyright # 2005 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Manage. Decis. Econ. 26: 499–512 (2005)
STRATEGIC MANAGERIAL INCENTIVES 501

strategic contract model, she uses rewarding are complements, two types of dominant-strategies
schedules in order to gives strategic incentives to equilibrium may arise. In the first type, both
her manager. principals use delegation; in the second one, both
We show that the assumption of asymmetry of principals implement delegation for a low-cost
information brings all its specificity in the search manager and output control for a high-cost one.
of a strategic advantage through managers’ The paper is organized as follows. The next
incentives. Indeed, introducing private knowledge section describes the model in more detail. In the
strongly modifies the strategic background. section following this, we solve the relevant
Firstly, using a traditional incentive scheme (linear duopoly subgames using backward-induction.
in profit and sales) makes no longer sense facing The optimal incentive contracts are determined
unobservable costs. Secondly, considering a simple in the subsequent section. The penultimate section
rewarding contract is no longer sufficient; here, to enlarges the principals’ strategic space by adding
elicit truthful revelation of manager’s cost, the open policies in which principals are not limited to
owner must offer a menu of agreements. Thirdly, the binary choice: control or delegation. The final
the strategies-space turns out to be enlarged: section concludes this work and discusses the
through the screening contract, an owner can still necessary extension of the model.
choose to implement delegation as well as direct
control whatever her manager’s type; but, she
must here consider additional policies by which THE MODEL
she implements delegation for one type of manager
alone and direct control for the other type. The We consider a differentiated duopoly facing a
fourth aspect concerns the competitive framework linear demand structure.4 In the region of quantity
itself. Costs are managers’ private information and space where prices are positive, inverse demands
there is no signaling from owners, either through are given by (with a>0 and b>|g|50):
the initial choice of a policy, or through the
pa ¼ a  bqa  gqb and pb ¼ a  gpa  bqb ;
corresponding contracts. Thus when outputs must
be chosen, each owner (if direct control) or where pi and qi are, respectively, the price and the
manager (if delegation) is playing a Bayesian game amount of the good produced by firm i (i=a,b).
where she knows neither the rival’s cost nor the The consumers’ willingness to pay for good i=a,b
agreement that has been chosen within the rival is always decreasing in quantity and decreases
owner’s menu. Let us stress that without signaling, (increases) with the quantity of the other good
the revelation principle can be applied in our when g>0 (g50). Hence, goods are substitutes,
competitive framework. independent, or complements according to the sign
The main results rely on informational rents. The of g. The two firms compete in quantities and the
ability of a low-cost manager to mimic a high-cost functional form of inverse demands is common
one forces each owner to give up a rent to her low- knowledge.
cost manager in order to induce cost revelation. In a In our model, on the production side, we have a
control policy, the amount of this rent is equal to principal and a manager for each firm. By
the comparative-cost advantage of the efficient principal we mean a decision-maker whose objec-
manager over the inefficient one, when the former tive is to maximize the profits of the firm; manager
mimics the latter by producing the same output. In refers to an agent whom the principal hires to
a delegation policy, managers can choose their make real-time decisions concerning output. The
outputs, such that, when the efficient manager quantities sold are commonly observable. More-
wishes to mimic the inefficient one, she produces a over, it is common knowledge that each manager
higher output than the latter; it follows that an extra bears a private constant unit-cost which can take
informational rent arises. Therefore, delegation two values: c1>0 with probability n1 and c2=0
involves a trade-off between strategic commitment with probability n2=1n1. (Because we can choose
and inherent additional rent cost. It follows that if a freely in inverse demands, we normalize c2 to
goods are substitutes, choosing output control zero.) Within the model, the discrepancy in costs
through a quantity-lump sum transfer contract is between managers is essential; therefore, we will
a dominating strategy. If goods are complements, use the redundant but more explicit notation:
this policy is a dominated strategy. Further, if goods Dc  c1c2 (Dc>0 and small enough to remain

Copyright # 2005 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Manage. Decis. Econ. 26: 499–512 (2005)

You might also like