You are on page 1of 20

This article was downloaded by: [University of Otago]

On: 28 July 2015, At: 12:02


Publisher: Routledge
Informa Ltd Registered in England and Wales Registered Number: 1072954 Registered
office: 5 Howick Place, London, SW1P 1WG

Innovation: Management, Policy


& Practice
Publication details, including instructions for authors and
subscription information:
http://www.tandfonline.com/loi/rimp20

Rethinking science, technology


and innovation (STI) institutions
in developing countries
a
Jorge Niosi
a Professor, Department of Management and Technology,
Uniyersité du Québec á Montréal, Canada Research Chair on
the Management of Technology, Montréal, Québec, Canada
Published online: 17 Dec 2014.

To cite this article: Jorge Niosi (2010) Rethinking science, technology and innovation (STI)
institutions in developing countries, Innovation: Management, Policy & Practice, 12:3, 250-268
To link to this article: http://dx.doi.org/10.5172/impp.12.3.250

PLEASE SCROLL DOWN FOR ARTICLE

Taylor & Francis makes every effort to ensure the accuracy of all the information (the
“Content”) contained in the publications on our platform. However, Taylor & Francis,
our agents, and our licensors make no representations or warranties whatsoever as to
the accuracy, completeness, or suitability for any purpose of the Content. Any
opinions and views expressed in this publication are the opinions and views of the
authors, and are not the views of or endorsed by Taylor & Francis. The accuracy of
the Content should not be relied upon and should be independently verified with
primary sources of information. Taylor and Francis shall not be liable for any losses,
actions, claims, proceedings, demands, costs, expenses, damages, and other
liabilities whatsoever or howsoever caused arising directly or indirectly in connection
with, in relation to or arising out of the use of the Content.

This article may be used for research, teaching, and private study purposes. Any
substantial or systematic reproduction, redistribution, reselling, loan, sub-licensing,
systematic supply, or distribution in any form to anyone is expressly forbidden. Terms
& Conditions of access and use can be found at
http://www.tandfonline.com/page/terms- and-conditions
Copyright © eContent Management Pty Ltd. Innovation: Management, policy & practice (2010) 12: 250–268.

Rethinking science, technology


and innovation (STI) institutions
in developing countries
JORGE NIOSI
Professor, Department of Management and Technology, Université du Québec à Montréal,
Canada Research Chair on the Management of Technology, Montréal, Québec, Canada

ABSTRACT
Downloaded by [University of Otago] at 12:02 28 July 2015

Developing countries need appropriate science, technology and innovation (STI) policies in order
to absorb, diffuse and master advanced knowledge that fosters growth. They also need them in
order to nurture new dynamic sectors. In many developing countries, public expenditures on R&D
are invested in university research and public laboratories. Industrial R&D is most often lagging
behind, in spite of several government incentives. Business expenditures on R&D (BERD), as a
consequence, are small in absolute terms and as a percentage of GDP. The paper suggests that
sever-al factors explain this situation, including badly designed incentives, reduced government
commit-ment to these incentives, lack of appropriate vertical STI policies, and high levels of
causal ambiguity around specific policy incentives. This paper argues that increased government
commit-ment, policy evaluation and the implementation of vertical STI policies aimed at creating
new sec-tors can solve the technological stalemate.

Keywords: Science, technology and innovation institutions; development planning and policy;
technological change; research and development; business expenditures; vertical STI policies

conomic development is primarily depend- industrial countries. The central hypothesis is


E
ent on the adoption and creation of tech- that in LDCs these institutions are either absent
nological innovation. The nuts and bolts of or highly inefficient, particularly policy incen-
innovation systems are institutions, and more tives for private R&D. The first section of this
specifically those institutions that are related to paper recalls some basic notions of evolutionary
the production, diffusion and transfer of sci- economics, and introduces the evolutionary
ence, technology and innovation. The proper approach to public policy. The second section
functioning of these institutions is thus essen- presents some STI institutions in industrial
tial for economic development. However, the nations. The third introduces the corresponding
right science, technology and innovation (STI) institutions in developing countries, and argues
institutions are not always in place, particularly that they are fairly inefficient and poorly fund-
in developing countries (LDCs). This paper ed. The public policy implication is that in
examines STI institutions in less developed order to accelerate growth, developing countries
countries from the perspective of evolutionary need to carefully evaluate, revamp and nurture
economics, and compares them with those in their STI institutions.

250 INNOVATION: MANAGEMENT, POLICY & PRACTICE Volume 12, Issue 3, December 2010
Rethinking science, technology and innovation (STI) institutions in developing countries

1. EVOLUTIONARY ECONOMICS, National systems of innovation (NSI) are sets


COMPLEX ADAPTIVE SYSTEMS, of institutions that contribute to the creation,
INSTITUTIONS AND LEARNING adoption, diffusion and transfer of new products
Economic development and catching up are less and processes. The core of these institutions is
about increasing productivity in existing sectors research universities, public laboratories, innova-
than about adding new sectors to the economy tive enterprises, venture capital firms and those
(Saviotti & Pyka, 2004). Developing countries organisations, public or private, that support,
will not catch up with rich ones by just produc- finance and regulate the production of science
ing more minerals or agricultural products, or by and technology (Freeman, 1987; Lundvall, 1992;
producing them more efficiently; they will need Nelson, 1993). National STI policies are a central
to add other industries to the economy. More component of the NSI.
precisely, LDC need to incorporate new and Yet most NSI are collections of sectoral systems
more dynamic sectors, particularly those based of innovation (SSI) (Malerba, 2004). These SSI are
on advanced technologies, to compensate for the industries, as well as their supporting insti-
Downloaded by [University of Otago] at 12:02 28 July 2015

declining non renewable natural resources, as tutions, in which each country innovates. Each
well as for wild fluctuations on the prices of advanced and emergent country is composed of a
resources. Also, these resources set a clear limit small number of innovative sectors. In Finland,
to the possible growth of LDC. Today, the only telecommunications equipment represents over 50%
countries that are converging with developed of the country’s R&D. In Singapore, infor-mation
ones are those of South and South East Asia and and communication technologies (ICT) and the bio-
they are doing so not by exploiting static com- pharmaceutical industry represent over 90% of the
parative advantages provided by resources, but 1
country’s industrial R&D effort . In Canada,
by continuously adding new sectors, from aerospace, pharmaceutical products, software and
software and automobiles in India to ICT and telecommunication equipment rep-resent close to
cars in Korea, to anything in China. 80% of industrial R&D. As Archibugi and Pianta
However, market forces alone will not (1992, 1994) have shown, smaller countries tend to
produce medium and high technology sectors be more specialised than larger ones, and all
in LDC. Fairly sophisticated institutions are industrial countries reinforce their specialisation
required to attract high-quality investments, through time. Only very large countries, such as the
absorb foreign technology and create human United States, need not to specialise in a few
capital and new technology. sectors.
Most authors bundle together very different kind
Institutions and systems of innovation of institutions. In this paper, four types of
Evolutionary economics and management, in all its innovation institutions are to be distinguished. It is
different schools and currents, has argued that useful to keep the distinction in mind because they
institutions are those regular patterns of behaviour are fairly different from one another and they
that constitute the canvass of society (Hodgson, evolve under very different sets of conditions:
1999; Nelson, 2005). Institutions fulfil important 1. Public policies, first, are rules or norms
roles. They gather and process information then designed and implemented by governments, and are
make it accessible to economic agents. They pro- thus most often compulsory. Policies evolve
vide rules and norms. At the same time, they con- through several patterns and mechanisms. Policy
strain and enable action because they allow the analysts suggest that policy implementation occurs
anticipation of the behaviour of other agents. by small additions of policy evolution followed by

1
It is worth recalling that the median country has a population of around 4.5 million, like Finland, Ireland or Singapore.

Volume 12, Issue 3, December 2010 INNOVATION: MANAGEMENT, POLICY & PRACTICE 251
Jorge Niosi

sudden periods of policy revolution (Sabatier, resistant to change than routines. But they have
1999). Increasingly since the 1970s, policies change an impact on economic development, and on
through evaluation by independent parties (research the adoption of science and technology, as the
institutes, consultants, academics) on behalf of the studies on the relationship between Islam and
administration system. Evaluation has often underde-velopment show (Kuran, 1997).
produced policy refining and modifica-tion, thus Institutions are not optimal, nor do they tend
change (Georghiou, 1998). to optimality (Burns & Dietz, 2001). All eco-
2. There are formal organizations or associa- nomic and policy-making agents are bounded
tions, such as private firms, government laborato- rational, and even if they sometimes change insti-
ries or universities, the individual adherence to tutions for their own benefit, the result may be
which is, up to a certain extent, voluntary. Organ- that most or even all agents reduce their well-
isations are prone to inertia due to the fact that being. This unexpected result occurs because
they are essentially bundles of routines. Inertia is eco-nomic systems are complex adaptive
generated by many concurrent factors, from systems:
Downloaded by [University of Otago] at 12:02 28 July 2015

bounded rationality of agents that stick to what • They are made of dispersed interaction
they know and are able to do, to contracts among heterogeneous agents
regulat-ing rights and responsibilities of agents, • No global controller can exploit all
to the internal and external rules and regulations opportuni-ties
that shape them. Yet, some organizations change • They contain multiple hierarchical organiza-
in response to environmental pressures. tions
3. We find routines within these organizations. • Agents continuously adapt through learning
These routines are norms, implemented hierarchi- • There is permanent novelty in technologies,
cally by the managers of these organisations, ‘exe- markets, behaviours and institutions
cutable capabilities for repeated performance in • Out of equilibrium dynamics because of the
some context that has been learned by an organisa- introduction of novelty (Arthur et al., 1997)
tion in response to selective pressures’ (Cohen et
al., 1996). Routines are also the repositories of Under such conditions, agents operate not by
capabilities, but as Leonard (1996) has underlined, accurate calculations, rational anticipations or per-
today’s capabilities may be tomorrow’s rigidi-ties. fect knowledge about future states of the world, but
Nelson and Winter (1982: 116) have argued by a trial-and-error kind of behaviour (Axelrod,
‘organisations tend to resist change’. Yet, routines 1997). Policies that are introduced in order to cor-
change from time to time, under the pressure of rect problems often result in poor outcomes because
other, dynamic, routines, as well as environmental of system resistance (Sterman, 2002). Complex
pressures (usually from government, markets, or systems have their own dynamics that individuals
suppliers). Routines change in a path dependent are often unable to understand. An evo-lutionary
manner, and they build on the past; thus the possi- approach and some research and model-ling may
bility of ‘competency traps’, where organisations help to uncover their hidden patterns.
are locked in inferior routines because of their Due to inertia, path-dependency, sunk cost
accumulated experience with the inferior ones, and both in infrastructures and learning, the special
lack of understanding of the superior ones. interests supporting them, among other factors,
4. Customs, habits of thought, or inherited rules policies, organisations and routines can survive
of the game that are not usually supported by law, for long periods of time even if they are ineffi-
but are mostly consuetudinary, and sup-ported by cient, as the story of Soviet communism has
beliefs, such as religious practices. In many cases, shown. The elementary components of innova-
these habits of thought are even more tion systems, thus, are as efficient as the
systems themselves (Niosi, 2002).

252 INNOVATION: MANAGEMENT, POLICY & PRACTICE Volume 12, Issue 3, December 2010
Rethinking science, technology and innovation (STI) institutions in developing countries

The government sector is a system in itself, Report to the US President by Vannevar Bush
where information keeps flowing in, agents would certainly be close to the top of the list:
learn, and novelty occurs in missions,
The most important ways in which the Gov-
personnel, poli-cies, and routines. Ideally,
ernment can promote industrial research are
policy implementa-tion, including STI policy,
to increase the flow of new scientific
occurs through a four-stage process:
knowledge through support of basic research
I. Identification of system or market failures,
and to aid in the development of scientific
usually by the top levels of bureaucracy
talent. In addi-tion, the Government should
and government
provide suitable incentives to industry to
II. Determination of goals and priorities
conduct research. (Bush, 1945)
III. Policy design and implementation, and
even-tual creation of public bodies or The incentives that governments designed were
adding mis-sions to existing ones not optimal, but they attained their goals in a fairly
IV. Policy evaluation and reformulation satisfactory way. History explains why simi-lar
Downloaded by [University of Otago] at 12:02 28 July 2015

(Sabatier, 1999) incentives display a particular set of character-istics


in one country as opposed to other ones. Later on,
All these stages require a continuous flow of Romer (1986) gave this idea a more ele-gant
information in the form of data provided by statis-tical treatment: scientific and technological knowledge
agencies and departmental studies, bench-marking was the source of increasing returns. Rediscovering
exercises comparing the specific incentives, Schumpeter, he understood that, for capitalism to
investments and outcomes of different policy schemes, grow, science and technology needed to be internal
with those in different countries and regions. Figure 1 or endogenous to the busi-ness enterprise
summarizes the policy process. (Rosenberg, 2000).
Many authors have underlined the key role
2. STI INSTITUTIONS IN INDUSTRIAL of STI institutions in economic development. In
COUNTRIES the systems of innovation current, Crow and
In industrial countries, STI institutions have Boze-man (1998), Nelson (2005), Mazzoleni
developed through decades of trial and error, and Nel-son (2007), among others, have
redesigning and tinkering. If one were to pinpoint studied the key role of public research
a major landmark in government intervention for laboratories and universi-ties in economic
the promotion of research in industry, the 1945 development. Aghion et al. (2009) have related
the performance of academic institutions to
Policy design their autonomy and competition for financial
Policy
implementation
support.
The World Bank (WB) has also emphasized the
Benchmarking
role of such institutions as contract enforcement,
intellectual property rights, and democratic
Institutional processes. The WB suggested that there is a unique
and economic
change set of institutions (‘one size fits all’) that represents
Problem
identification the pre-condition for development. On the con-trary,
other authors have brought evidence against the
Benchmarking 2
Policy theory that democratic institutions and the rule of
evaluation
law cause economic growth. Conversely, they argue:
(a) human capital is a more basic source of growth
FIGURE 1: THE POLICY PROCESS than are (democratic) institu-tions; (b) ‘poor
countries get out of poverty

Volume 12, Issue 3, December 2010 INNOVATION: MANAGEMENT, POLICY & PRACTICE 253
Jorge Niosi

through good policies, often pursued by dictators’; Biotechnology Policy (such as those implemented
and (c) only later do countries improve their polit- in Canada, in 1983, or Singapore in 1988) may be a
ical institutions (Glaeser et al., 2004). The authors typical example. The principal advantage of a
recall that South Korea, Taiwan and China have targeted policy is that it concentrates resources in
grown rapidly under dictatorships and only then the the sector the country wants to nurture.
first two adopted democratic institutions. In sum, Is there a right sequence in STI policy imple-
not all institutions support growth, but only those mentation? Are horizontal policies to be imple-
related to the production, the absorption and the use mented before vertical policies, concurrently with
of human capital in the public and private sectors. them, or after them? The empirical evidence reveals
And innovation systems theory suggests that each different patterns. Sometimes, though not often,
developed country has devel-oped its own set of governments have a clear idea of sectors whose
STI institutions, none of them being optimal but growth needs to be stimulated, due to the resources
just satisfactory and more or less adapted to the (existing or potentially accessible) and historical
country’s historical conditions. Each developing dynamic or static advantages of the country; in
Downloaded by [University of Otago] at 12:02 28 July 2015

country needs to invent its own institutional road to these cases it is possible to develop concurrently
economic growth. horizontal and vertical policies. In the late 1940s
These STI institutions, are mainly composed of and 1950s, Canada implemented at the same time
sets of horizontal and vertical policies, as well as horizontal policies (tax credits for R&D and subsi-
science and technology organizations such uni- dies for SME’s R&D) and vertical policies (giving
versities and public laboratories, and routines for priority to aerospace, nuclear energy and telecom-
the generation of innovation in business firms, munications). Later on, in the 1980s, it chose
academic and research organisation. These insti- advanced materials, biotechnology and software. In
tutions are extremely diverse from country to the 1980s, Ireland chose the software industry, and
country. Let’s pinpoint some central differences only then implemented horizontal policies (i.e., tax
among industrial countries and their institutions. credit for R&D in 2004). In terms of horizontal
policies, Finland has no R&D tax credits but a
2.1 Horizontal and vertical policies sophisticated grant system. The country selected
Two main types of STI policies are to be differen- communications equipment out of Nokia’s success-
tiated. Horizontal STI policies are those that apply ful experience in the industry; it is now trying to
equally to all industries, without targeting any diversify in other industries through its government
sector. Tax credits for R&D are the archetyp-al innovation fund (Sitra) and granting agency (Tekes)
horizontal policy. Many public subsidies for R&D to avoid extreme reliance on one sector. The United
in smaller firms are of a similar nature. The main States has no official technology policy, but chose
th
advantage of such policies is that they apply to all agriculture and railways in the 19 century, while it
firms. They are easy to implement and they do not protected its infant manufacturing industry. In the
often establish a basis for political corrup-tion. twentieth century, the US federal government
However, they cannot be used as an incen-tive to picked defence technologies, health and space,
support the growth of a particular industry. If a which have been among the most subsidized sectors
developing country wants to avoid a dispersion of in that country. Federal US tax credits appeared late
efforts in many different industries, and intends to (1981) and do not represent a key policy incentive
establish comparative advantages in one or several in the United States. State tax credits appeared in
sectors, it will need to add a set of vertical policies the US in 1982 in Minnesota; by 2005, 32 US states
applying to the desired sector. had implemented some kind of R&D tax credit.
Vertical (or targeted) policies are those that apply Direct subsidies to targeted sectors represent the
to a particular industry or sector. A National unofficial but very active US technology policy.

254 INNOVATION: MANAGEMENT, POLICY & PRACTICE Volume 12, Issue 3, December 2010
Rethinking science, technology and innovation (STI) institutions in developing countries

2.2 Governments learn include regulations, procurement, creation of


through evaluation net-works, and building infrastructure.
Market organizations learn through competition A major point goes sometimes unnoticed
and market signals. Governments do otherwise. and needs to be stressed:
Audretsch et al. (2002) have underscored that These horizontal and vertical technology
public authorities are accountable to tax payers, poli-cies generate demand for human capital
and they thus must be able to document their within the firms.
performance through specific indicators and met-
Countries with few or inefficient industrial
rics. Thus, accountability is at the basis of policy
R&D policies run the risk of not having demand
evaluation. However, the processes through
for scientists and engineers in industry. Business
which such evaluations take place are extremely
organisations thus become ‘illiterate’ in scientific
different from one country to the next. Also, the
and engineering matters. Their absorptive capaci-
functions of evaluation are variegated. They
ty is therefore limited. A few major examples of
include legitimating the policies, improving man-
Downloaded by [University of Otago] at 12:02 28 July 2015

STI policies follow.


agement and providing transparency (Becher &
Kuhlmann, 1995). 2.3 Horizontal policies: Tax
Since the early 1990s, in the United States, the credits for R&D
General Accounting Office (GAO) and the Chief Tax credits are increasingly adopted as incentives
Financial Officer have the mission of eval-uating for R&D in OECD countries. They have several
the performance of government programs. The advantages over direct subsidies. They do not
goal of the Government Performance and Results dis-criminate in favour of any type of firm,
Act of 1993 is to increase efficiency and improve sector, or region. They are easy to manage and to
management of the federal agencies and evaluate. They are less prone to political
programs through evaluation by GAO. However, corruption than outright subsidies. They do not
as Audretsch et al. (2002) have emphasized, data represent dis-bursements, so they attract less
are not always available and not always credible, political opposi-tion than direct subsidies for
particularly about such key outputs as externali- R&D.
ties and other public benefits. The comparative data available for several coun-
In Germany, evaluation pursued similar objec- tries point to the fact that fiscal policy matters for
tives of accountability, improvement and trans- R&D and innovation (Bloom et al., 2002). How-
parency. However, science indicators and peer ever, although increasingly popular, fiscal incen-
reviews seemed more in use for universities and tives are used very differently in OECD countries
government scientific organizations, while panels (see Table 1). They are important in Canada, mod-
composed of industrialists assessed the usefulness erately so in Norway or Spain, and negligible in the
of more applied government research institutes. United States, where direct subsidies are much more
Kuhlmann (1998) emphasized the scattered nature widely used to support private R&D.
of these efforts in Germany, as different programs Canada supposedly has the third most attrac-tive
and organisations are using different metrics and fiscal environment for industrial R&D, after Spain
indicators. The US evaluation proce-dures, though, and Australia. Yet, official figures show that
seemed no better than the German ones in terms of Canada’s tax credit for R&D is far more central to
homogeneity of procedures, regu-larity of the NSI than Australian or Spanish incentives.
assessments and publication of results. Among OECD countries, the US federal fiscal
Smits and Kuhlmann (2004) underlined the credit system is not a critical public R&D incen-
fact that financial incentives are most frequently tive. Implemented in 1981, the US tax credit fund-
used to promote R&D. Other STI policies ed ‘research and experimentation’ (R&E, meaning
substantial technology advances), and not simply

Volume 12, Issue 3, December 2010 INNOVATION: MANAGEMENT, POLICY & PRACTICE 255
Jorge Niosi

TABLE 1: COST OF FISCAL CREDIT FOR R&D I+D, best, the federal US tax credit has had a marginal
2005, SELECTED COUNTRIES (US$
MILLIONS PPP) AND AS % OF GERD
effect on business expenditures on R&D in the
country. Billings (2003) argues that the ineffective
Cost of
fiscal credit GERD Fiscal credit US tax credit is a deterrent for both foreign and
(US$ millions (US$ as % of domestic companies to conduct R&D in the US, and
Country PPP) millions PPP) GERD
an incentive for them to conduct R&D abroad. In
USA 5110.0 3,244,664 0.16%
November 2008, the US President’s Council of
Canada 2290.4 21,777 10.5% Advisors on Science and Technology recommended
France 1009.9 40,684 2.5% to ‘Update and enhance the R&D tax credit to make
UK 937.3 35,171 1.13%
it a more stable and effective incentive for industry
Netherlands 419.3 9992 4.2%
to perform R&D’ (US Council, 2008).
Mexico 401.1 5641 7.1%
Australia 355.6 11,751* 3.0% The relative success of Canada’s program for fis-
Belgium 355.4 6434 5.52% cal credits for R&D, to which close to 20,000
Spain 343.3 13,391 2.56% companies of different sizes submit a claim for the
Downloaded by [University of Otago] at 12:02 28 July 2015

Norway 137.0 3396 4.03% 2


rebate each year, is due to its particular design .
Ireland 65.2 2030 3.2%
Large companies may deduct up to 20% of eligible
Argentina** 8.3 854 0.97%
expenses, and smaller firms are eligible to 35% of
Portugal 3.3 1705 0.19%
up to C$2 million of R&D expenditures. Unused
Source: OCDE (2007): Science, Technology and credits can be carried forward for 20 years and
Industry Scoreboard, Paris.
backwards for three years, and are refundable in
* Figures for 2004; ** FONTAR (www.agencia.gov.ar)
case smaller firms have no tax to pay in a particular
R&D. Besides, the credit only funds up to 20% of year. The Canadian system is permanent and it has
any increment over a base R&D figure, not to the no limit on the amounts that firms can request,
total R&D expenditure. Thus, if companies do not except for smaller ones, or on the number of firms
increase their expenditure, they have nothing to that may obtain the credit. Yet the program has been
claim. Also, during its 25-year history, the law has criticised, because smaller companies that already
been changed 11 times making its precise advan- entered the stock market are not considered eligible
tages blurrier to innovative companies (Tassey, to the 35% deduction. It was also suggested that the
2007). In addition, the precise calculations of C$2 million maximum rebate was too low for many
deductible items are cumbersome for the compa- smaller firms particularly in such domains as
nies, and difficult to monitor for the government. biotechnology or nanotechnology.
Finally, the tax credit is not refundable; it is thus Our short review shows no optimal fiscal credit
useless for new small technology firms, such as programs but many different versions, more or less
biotechnology or semiconductor companies, which adapted to their particular environments. The much
incur losses during several years before turning a criticised US tax credit system is partially
profit. On the top of that, the US tax credit system is compensated by more efficient direct subsidies for
not permanent, and has to be renewed every year, R&D, as we see later. To conclude this section, it is
therefore it does not help companies wishing to worth noting that some countries without any type
establish permanent R&D centres in the country. In of R&D tax credit, such as Finland and Swe-den,
2004, over 55% of the credit went to 100 com- rely on direct subsidies for R&D, and are among the
panies and the remaining to slightly more than most active in the world in terms of R&D and
10,000 other firms. Tassey (2007) concludes that, at innovation.

2
In 2004, almost C$ 3.4 billion in assistance was provided to 19,600 companies through the R&D tax credit; 80% of the
companies were smaller firms and they received some 23% of the tax claims (Canadian Chamber of Commerce, 2007).

256 INNOVATION: MANAGEMENT, POLICY & PRACTICE Volume 12, Issue 3, December 2010
Rethinking science, technology and innovation (STI) institutions in developing countries

2.4 Horizontal policies: R&D have already received venture capital). The program
subsidies for SMEs is two-phased. In Phase I, a peer-review committee
Subsidies for R&D in small firms are a common assesses the project, and may grant up to
STI policy component in all OECD innovation US$100,000 for feasibility studies during 6–12
systems. Their specific policy design varies months. The most promising projects move to Phase
widely from one country to the next. II that funds the primary R&D process for two
In 1962, Canada launched its Industrial Research years, the typical grant being $750,000. After Phase
Assistance Program (IRAP). Its goal was to II, the SMEs are supposed to apply for pri-vate
‘stimulate wealth creation for Canada through tech- funds (i.e., venture capital). From 1983–1999, SBIR
nological innovation’ and ‘to stimulate innovation made 45,000 awards for a total of US$8.4 bil-lion
in Canadian SMEs’ (NRC, 2010). The program (1998 dollars). A more recent evaluation, con-
incorporated several components, including non- centrated on the DoD, a one billion section, found
refundable R&D subsidies for SMEs, and a tech- that the program was successful, but did not allow
nology counsellor program. Some 260 technology enough funds for the management and metrics of
Downloaded by [University of Otago] at 12:02 28 July 2015

counsellors visit thousands of SMEs every year and the results on a regular basis (RAND Corp, 2006).
suggest them technical improvements in products In 1995, under its worst economic recession
and processes; they also help SMEs to request since World War II, Japan introduced its first law
financial support either within IRAP or from other for the support of innovative SMEs in order to revi-
programs, and assist them to find academic or gov- talize the Japanese economy (Eshima, 2003). It was
ernment research centres that could conduct collab- the Temporary Law concerning Measures for
orative R&D with the firms. The latest evaluation Changing Business in Specific Small and Medium
of IRAP found that in the 1996–2001 period the Enterprises. The program took inspiration from the
program had funded 12,300 projects that resulted in US SBIR Program. It encouraged innovation
over 39,000 innovations; C$11.3 billion of sales through SME cooperation with universities and
were linked to those IRAP-assisted innovations. public laboratories. Like SBIR, the Japanese pro-
In 1982, the US implemented its highly regard- gram allocates subsidies in two phases. The main
ed Small Business Innovation Research Act (SBIR) subsidies are granted in Phase II. In the first three
that launched the SBIR program. The goals of the years of the program (1995–97), over 3000 SME
program are ‘to more effectively meet R&D needs were supported, with over ¥61 billion (over US$6
brought on by the utilization of small innovative billion). These 1995–97 phase II awards included
firms … and to attract private capital to commer- over US$1 billion for R&D activities in 902 firms,
cialize the results of Federal Research’ (Wessner, as well as venture capital investments in some 300
1999: 19). SBIR provides up to US$850,000 for SME, for ¥14.2 billion (US$1.4 billion). Japan’s
early stage R&D activities to entrepreneurs or new Small and Medium Enterprise Agency runs the
th
technology based companies that wish to explore program that is now in its 13 year, following sub-
advanced technologies. All government depart- stantial improvements, introduced particularly in
ments with a budget over US$100 million have to 1999. The new Law has four goals: promoting
contribute to the program. In fiscal year 2007, SBIR business innovation, launching new business start
invested US$1.14 billion, with the Depart-ment of ups, strengthening the management base of SMEs,
Defence (DoD) representing close to 65% of all and offering a safety net. By 2007, and thanks to the
SBIR funds. The requesting companies must have government program, over 50% of Japanese
less than 500 employees, they must conduct R&D manufacturing SME were conducting R&D and in
in the United States, be controlled at 50% or more most cases it was collaborative R&D, partnering
by their managers or employees (a provision, with universities and public laboratories (Japan
though, that makes it difficult to fund SMEs that SME Agency 2008).

Volume 12, Issue 3, December 2010 INNOVATION: MANAGEMENT, POLICY & PRACTICE 257
Jorge Niosi

2.5 Vertical policies: days for MNC establishing drug production and/or
Biotechnology and software R&D in the country. In 2003, Singapore inaugu-
Horizontal policies may strengthen existing sec- rated the first phase of Biopolis, a major science
tors; they will seldom be a major contributor to the park dedicated to life sciences, the second phase of
generation of new ones. For new sectors to emerge, which was completed in 2006. The park is hosting
particularly high-technology ones, scarce resources seven research institutes, legal and patent services,
and sophisticated policies need to be concentrated and all types of private firms, from global multina-
in those sectors. Concentration of resources tionals to emerging start-ups. The total cost of the
represents, at the same time, investing in human Biopolis Park was US$392 million; by the end of
capital, attracting industrial organisa-tions that will 2007, some prominent tenants included Glaxo-
create demand for skilled labour, and implementing SmithKline (GSK) from Britain, Novartis from
incentives for R&D. Switzerland, and Takeda (Japan) (JTC, 2007). At the
At independence, in 1965, Singapore was a poor end of 2007, Singapore had invested over US$2
South East Asia country, a former British trade post. billion in these organizations. With a total popula-
Downloaded by [University of Otago] at 12:02 28 July 2015

With only 310 square miles, and no natural tion of 4.5 million, Singapore was also exporting
resources, it may be difficult to understand how it over US$125 billion in high technology products,
moved from trading outpost to high-technology more than all Latin American countries combined.
manufacturing centre. Since independence, the In the last 20 years, Israel has become a small
government managed to dramatically increase the but active exporter of domestic software products
education levels of the population, put English as (Breznitz, 2005). Behind the Israeli software mira-
the first language of the country, establish a modern cle one finds a very supportive state, heavily invest-
infrastructure and attract overseas industrial compa- ing in human capital through education and
nies. At the beginning, all types of manufacturing attraction of foreign talent. Also, in 1984, the soft-
firms from abroad were welcome. By the 1980s, ware industry became eligible to the substantial
electronic parts manufacturing emerged as the major direct grants offered by the Office of the Chief Sci-
sector in Singapore’s secondary industry. The entist. The Israeli government promoted the emer-
industry required little space and a disciplined and gence of a private sector venture capital industry
fairly educated labour force. However, after the through its 1992–97 Yozma program (Avnimelech
mid-1980s recession, the government understood & Teubal, 2005). Israeli venture capital is essen-
that innovation, R&D and a highly skilled labour tially aimed at high-technology new ventures. The
force were essential. Industrial policy turned from result was a very fast growth of the sector: exports
luring MNC’s manufacturing activities to attracting moved up from US$90 million in 1990 to US$2.6
R&D centres and creating national companies in billion in 2000 and US$23.6 billion in 2008.
technology-intensive sectors. Electronic products
had become the leading manufacturing sector. 2.6 Horizontal and vertical policies:
Pharmaceuticals followed suit. While some MNC Public laboratories
were already producing drugs in Singapore, R&D In industrial countries, government research labora-
was absent from the country. In 1988, Singapore tories fulfil many different missions. Some of them
launched a National Biotechnology Program, and help government in the quest of specific public
implemented a large series of policies to become missions, such as defence, environment and health
one of the major drug development, genetic thera-py (Crow & Bozeman, 1998). Other institutes, such as
and human biotechnology hubs in Asia. New public particle accelerators or astronomical observato-ries,
laboratories were established and in 2000 the pursue objectives of basic science. Many are related
Biomedical Sciences Initiative was launched to specific industrial sectors such as aero-space,
(Parayil, 2005). Singapore implemented tax holi- agriculture, biotechnology, energy or tele-

258 INNOVATION: MANAGEMENT, POLICY & PRACTICE Volume 12, Issue 3, December 2010
Rethinking science, technology and innovation (STI) institutions in developing countries

communications, and are sometimes part of vertical organisations (Georghiou et al., 2000). They go
industrial policies. The mandates and missions of from counting publication, patents, spin-off com-
these are variegated. At their most basic level, they panies, new or improved products or processes
include ‘extension’ (the application of agricultural transferred to companies, as well as networking
or industrial best practices through education) such activities, to measuring customer satisfaction with
as teaching farmers how to analyse production services rendered by the institutes. Also, the evalu-
problems or industrial SMEs how to conduct quali- ating agencies vary, from national and internation-al
ty control. At a higher level, they include conduct- academics, research institutes and consulting firms
ing R&D on behalf of farmers or manufacturing (as in Canada or the US), to in-house evalu-ation by
firms and transferring the results of the research the same laboratories, as in Japan.
project to them, be it new or improved crops to
farmers or product designs to industry. At its high- 2.7 Conclusion
est level they could develop entirely new technolo- Through different horizontal and vertical incen-
gies for government or industry, including satellites, tives, a set of industrial countries has managed to
Downloaded by [University of Otago] at 12:02 28 July 2015

semiconductor manufacturing processes or chip attain some level of endogeneity in the produc-
designs, and spin-off new companies for the pur- tion of innovation. In these countries, business
pose of transferring them to the private sector. enterprise normally performs a high percentage
In 2006, federal agencies and federally of the country’s R&D, usually well over 50% of
funded R&D centres in the United States have the national total. But the set of incentives that
spent US$37 billion in R&D expenditures; this produced such change in the behaviour of pri-
amount exceeds the total national expenditures vate enterprise varies from country to country
of every country in the world except China, and is always subject to improvement through
Germany and Japan (National Science continuous evaluation.
Foundation, 2008: 4–12). They accounted for
11% of all US R&D expen-ditures and were 3. STI INSTITUTIONS IN LDC
performed in some 800 labo-ratories. Developing countries are not without STI insti-
In 2006, Canada’s federal and provincial intra- tutions, but these are often poorly funded and
mural expenditures on R&D represented some managed, and their evaluation procedures are
10% of GERD. These more than 100 national weak. Also, one hears a frequent complain from
institutes included scientific research organisa- developing country academics about the ‘puz-
tions (including those working on atomic energy, zling’ low involvement of industry in R&D (Aro-
defence, health, and space) and more industrially cena & Sutz, 2001). The evolutionary approach
related laboratories such as those working on suggests that developing-country STI institu-
biotechnology, communications, construction, tions, and particularly those that are aimed at
and measurement standards. increasing R&D in industry, are flawed, badly
Also in 2006, in the OECD, the government funded, and/or were not implemented with the
sector performed 11% of GERD. Former com- necessary persistence. Thus they were unable to
munist countries such as the Czech and Slovak make science and technology endogenous to
Republics, Hungary and Poland together with industry. A few cases can illustrate the pattern.
France, Italy and Greece were spending well
above the OECD average (OECD, 2008). 3.1 Tax credits in Argentina
How did these government institutes perform? and Mexico
The evaluation of public R&D is not easy and it Both Argentina and Mexico have implemented
has been done using different metrics due to the tax credits for R&D. Yet these policies did not
very different missions and activities of such produce the expected outcomes.

Volume 12, Issue 3, December 2010 INNOVATION: MANAGEMENT, POLICY & PRACTICE 259
Jorge Niosi

Mexico national tax credit. Representatives of the


In 1976, Mexico launched its fiscal incentives for Econom-ics Department and other agencies form
R&D, but put from the start a cap on the total fis-cal the com-mittee (Foro Consultivo, 2006: p. 57).
cost of the credit; this is a major difference Another major problem with the Mexican sys-
compared to Canada, France or the US, where any tem was its high concentration in just one sector,
company can request such credits almost without the auto industry. In 2005, the car industry
limits. In 2006, the Mexican government allowed dwarfed all the others, with a towering 45% of all
some 400 million in tax rebates to 887 companies tax benefits. The 2006 distribution by sectors
over than 3000 projects. Some 30% of expendi- appears in Figure 2. The automobile sector still
tures in R&D, including the training of R&D per- represents the major portion but new areas appear
sonnel, could be deducted from business taxes. In (including biotechnology and pharmaceu-ticals)
2008, Mexico had increased its fiscal budget for tax that were absent a few years before.
credits to some 4,500 million pesos (450 million US Probably in response to such criticisms, the
dollars approximately). Table 2 shows the evo- 2007 version of the Mexican fiscal credit law
Downloaded by [University of Otago] at 12:02 28 July 2015

lution of the Mexican fiscal incentives in the 2000s. reserves 22% of the sums to small firms and
The table shows that, over a five-year peri-od, only for R&D in the area of new energies.
52% of the fund applications but almost 90% of the Some evaluation is performed in Mexico, and
demands were accepted. Yet the num-ber of the Foro Consultivo is a key agent of this evalua-
companies is exceedingly small: just 4.5% of the tion. The Foro was created in 2002 as an inde-
Canadian total of around 20,000 firms obtain-ing pendent consulting organism of the Mexican
the credit, or ten percent of the US firms. Also, tax government. Its mission includes the analysis of
credit concentration in large Mexican firms has policy incentives for science and technology, and
been strong: in the 2001–04 period, some 505 the proposal of new measures to develop the sci-
Mexican companies received the credit, but only 92 ence and technology capabilities of the country. It
companies received some 70% of the fiscal credit, regularly publishes evaluations of different
and 69% of the credit to these large compa-nies science and technology policies.
went to foreign firms (Foro Consultivo, 2006). An In spite of its centrality, the Mexican incentive
independent study cited in the Foro survey (2006), does not change the landscape of the country’s
calculates that, in the 2001–04 period, only some reduced business expenditure on R&D. In 2005,
1020 companies conducted R&D in Mexico (over Mexico’s GERD was only 0.46% of GDP and
20,000 in Canada). Finally, contrary to the US or BERD represented 41% of that amount.
Canadian system where no public official has the
authority to choose who will get credit, the Mexican Argentina
system gives to an inter-institutional committee the Argentina launched its tax credits on R&D in
power to distribute the 1997, with a US$20 million cap in 1998 and

TABLE 2: MEXICAN FISCAL CREDIT FOR R&D DEMAND AND SUPPLY (2001–06)
2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006

Companies receiving the credit 192 242 275 398 643 887
Projects supported 679 1067 1197 1606 2361 3155
Credit demanded (M$ m) 735 911 1251 2301 4658 8351
Credit offered (M$ m) 500 500 500 1000 3000 4000
Credit offered as a % of demand 68% 55% 40% 43% 64% 48%

Source: CONACYT (2007): Estímulo fiscal para la investigación y desarrollo tecnológico, Mexico

260 INNOVATION: MANAGEMENT, POLICY & PRACTICE Volume 12, Issue 3, December 2010
Rethinking science, technology and innovation (STI) institutions in developing countries

program. With such very modest amounts, it is


understandable that the business involvement in
R&D of Argentina has not made any particular
progress since the inception of the credit. R&D
expenditure as a percentage of GDP was stagnant
at 0.45% in 1999 and 0.46% in 2005. BERD was
26% of GERD in 1999 and 31% in 2005.
Considering the fact that in 2005, Argentina’s
GDP was US$553 billion, the incentive, as in the
case of Mexico is, to say the least, highly insuffi-
cient to stimulate industrial R&D and create
demand for skilled scientists and engineers.
FIGURE 2: MEXICAN TA X CREDIT FOR R&D 2006 BY
INDUSTRY
Source: CONACYT (2007) 3.2 SME policy in Chile and Argentina
Downloaded by [University of Otago] at 12:02 28 July 2015

In most developing countries, except in South


1999. The Argentinean Technology Fund East Asia, innovative SMEs receive a timid
(FONTAR) manages the credit; FONTAR is an sup-port from the state. Chile and Argentina are
office of the National Agency for Science and cases in point.
Technology Promotion of the federal govern-ment.
Public servants thus, as in the case of Mexi-co, Chile and subsidies for R&D
distribute the credit, which can represent up to 50% In Chile, CORFO is the national agency that sup-
of eligible costs of the project. The gov-ernment ports innovative activities in firms of all sizes
certificates are valid up to three years after they are through many different programs including ven-ture
emitted, and they serve to cancel federal capital, long-term loans, R&D subsidies and other.
government taxes. In the first year, 125 companies The set of programs is handled by INNOVA Chile, a
presented 147 R&D projects; 94 of these projects division of CORFO. In 2007, CORFO had a total
were considered innovative and were accepted. budget of over 5000 million pesos or US$800
They emanated from 79 firms, 82% of which were million. One third of this amount comes from the
SME. Also, 90% of the funds were allocated to the accumulated royalties the national gov-ernment
manufacturing sector. At that time, the Argentinean collects from its mineral exports. By the end of
manufacturing sector consisted of some 1000 large 2007, the total amount of funds accumulat-ed
and medium-sized companies as well as 14,000 through this royalty was 37,000 Chilean pesos (or
SME. Thus the cred-it, was beneficial only to 0.5% US$6 billion). The price of copper, which fluc-
of Argentinean manufacturing firms (Chudnovsky et tuated from US$0.50–1.50/lb (pound), increased
al., 2000). substantially in the 2005–08 period, and the Chilean
After the major financial crisis of Argentina in government collected major rents. By December
2001 and 2002, the credit was maintained with 2008, however, it had gone back to its upper
similar characteristics. The amounts were pre- historical levels of US$1.50/lb.
served in pesos, but because of the abrupt devalu- In the area of support for innovative projects
ation of 2001–02, they were reduced by 66% in for R&D, CORFO has funded 409 projects in
US dollar terms. In 2007, the allocation was 2005 and 798 in 2006; 85% of them were SME.
slightly increased to 25 million pesos (US$8 mil- Yet, in 2006, only 204 Chilean firms represented
lion), and in 2008 the government allocated 45.4 some 80% of BERD. Most SMEs requesting
million pesos (or some US$15 million) to the subsidies for R&D are in agriculture, fish pro-
credit, under similar conditions as in the original duction and other primary activities, and request

Volume 12, Issue 3, December 2010 INNOVATION: MANAGEMENT, POLICY & PRACTICE 261
Jorge Niosi

and obtain small amounts. An academic evaluation


(Benavente et al., 2007) estimated that Chilean
subsidies for R&D had a positive effect on private
innovative activities. The ‘crowding out hypothesis’
was rejected and a fair level of additional R&D was
found. Yet, in October 2008, the national associa-
1
tion of small firms (CONAPYME) requested an
evaluation of CORFO programs for SMEs, man-
aged by private banks, under the argument that
banks were not channelling all available funds to
FIGURE 3: GERD 1995–2005 SELECTED COUNTRIES
small firms. At the same time, in September 2008, a
study published by the National Statistical Insti-tute By comparison to IRAP, with annual budgets of
of Chile found that only 2.4% of the country’s SME C$150 million dollars, of which some C$65 mil-lion
use CORFO’s programs. Again the interme-diary are distributed annually in non-reimbursable grants
Downloaded by [University of Otago] at 12:02 28 July 2015

banks were pointed as the main obstacle to more for R&D, the Argentinean program seems, once
adequate financial support to SMEs. The funds are again, poorly funded. Compared to SBIR or the
there and the instrument produced some good Japanese programs, even when normalised by
results, yet total business expenditure on R&D population and GDP, the Argentinean effort looks
remains low: under 30% of GERD. irrelevant. If Argentina decided to invest the equiv-
In 2004, Chile invested 0.68% of GDP in alent of US$1.4 billion annually (the present SBIR
R&D, or some US$635 million. That same year, program), or IRAP, it should spend at least US$50
46% of that amount was the nation’s BERD. million annually in direct subsidies to R&D.
However, during the affluent years, according to
preliminary estimates, the country’s GERD 3.3 Vertical policies
remained at 0.6–0.7% of GDP. This score is Vertical policies are often implemented in devel-
slightly better than in the cases of Argentina and oping countries. Many of them aimed at the cre-
Mexico and a minor improvement with respect to ation of advanced technology industries such as
previous years. In spite of favourable conditions, aerospace, electronics or pharmaceutical. With a
Chile’s R&D effort is far from the average 2.26% few exceptions they failed. Alcorta and Peres
of GDP that OECD countries devote to R&D. (1997) summarized some of the shortcomings of
these policies under the following headings:
Argentina (a) Lack of clarity. Many developing countries
In Argentina, FONTAR is the main agency that imposed restrictions on technology transferred to them
distributes fiscal credits, subsidies and loans for by MNC under the rationale that foreign firms used
R&D. In the latest year available, 2006, technology to extract royalties. Thus, they generated
FONTAR had supported some 527 projects for a obstacles to local learning. In the 1970s, countries such
total of US$50 million; this amount includes as Argentina and Brazil created offices of intellectual
fiscal credits, non-reimbursable R&D subsidies property (IP) or foreign collab-oration not so much to
and other sup-ports. The non-reimbursable funds generate local IP, but to con-trol incoming technology
were exclusively aimed at SMEs. In 2006, these from abroad. India made a similar move with the India
funds amounted to some US$10 million on 271 Investment Agency.
projects; in the 2003– 06 period, some 1100 (b) Lack of priorities. Too many institutions and
projects were approved for US$33 million. policies, as well as too many sectors being nur-

1
www.conapyme.com

262 INNOVATION: MANAGEMENT, POLICY & PRACTICE Volume 12, Issue 3, December 2010
Rethinking science, technology and innovation (STI) institutions in developing countries

tured at the same time. Brazil intended to pro- countries. This is due partially to the weakness of
mote an electronics industry without any lack private sector R&D activities for promoting agri-
of specialization. Today its list of target sectors culture, health or industry: public laboratories
includes 25 industries. appear to occupy a major role only because pri-
(c) Excessive complexity and detail, as well as vate R&D is almost non-existent. Most of these
out-of-control scope. Brazil New industrial Policy institutes perform basic service and extension
in 1988 was to promote too many industries at the activities. In a few cases they have succeeded in
same time through import liberalization for managing large research projects as in the case of
machinery and equipment, under the proviso that all EMBRAPA, the Brazilian agricultural research
industries were connected. However, the sectoral institute (Dalhman & Frischtak, 1993).
import quotas, market access and equity participa- It was suggested that research in public labora-
tion restrictions generated obstacles to growth. tories and universities did not represent a major
(d) Technology policies and organisations factor in catching up, with a few exceptions in
are rarely assessed. Evaluation and Brazil (aircraft), Korea and Taiwan (electronics)
Downloaded by [University of Otago] at 12:02 28 July 2015

particularly independent evaluation are seldom (Mazzoleni & Nelson, 2007). Yet, Linsu Kim
part of developing coun-tries’ culture. (1997) thought otherwise in the case of Korea:
Given the inadequacy of Korean university
One may also add lack of persistence and low research, the government developed a network
investments. Argentina’s promotion of a domes- of R&D institutes (GRIs) to play a major role
tic aircraft industry through a government enter- in advanced industrial R&D. The Korea Insti-
prise that, with many ups and owns, produced tute of Science and Technology (KIST) spent a
several hundred units of different locally large proportion of the nation’s total R&D
designed models since the 1920s, was revived in funds in the early decades, but they suffered
the 1940s and 1950s (with the help of French, from poor linkages with industries in the
German and Italian immigrant aircraft engi- 1960s and 1970s. (Kim, 1997: 201)
neers), and knew a short restoration in the 1970s
and 1980s. By the mid 1990s, however, the gov- Kim identified two problems: lack of demand
ernment aircraft manufacturing company was from industry and insufficient manufacturing
sold to Lockheed Martin. In December 2008, the know-how in the GRIs. In order to establish
company was being nationalised again. linkages, ‘the government coerced large firms to
In 1984, Brazil implemented import restric- undertake joint research with GRIs’ (Kim, 1997:
tions to support the growth of a national phar- 202) in the automobile, chemical, electronics
maceutical industry. Also, in order to nurture and other industries. These GRIs strengthened the
domestic production the government invested bargaining power of local firms with foreign
over US$5 million in laboratories in the city of multinationals, reverse engineered technology,
Campinas. However, the weaknesses of the and provided prior knowledge to firms in a wide
research infrastructure generated major range of industries. They conducted global tech-
obstacles for a local industry to grow and nology scanning, educated industrialists, provid-
import restric-tions were lifted in the 1990s. ed common infrastructure to firms unable to
conduct R&D by themselves, and served as cat-
3.4 Public labs: Agricultural and alysts of skills and competencies (Lim, 1999).
industrial extension versus In Singapore, also, government biotechnology
industrial promotion research institutes have played a major role as
In developing countries, government institutes ini-tiators and catalysts of local competencies in
perform a larger share of GERD than in OECD the late 1980s and 1990s (Parayil, 2005: 56):

Volume 12, Issue 3, December 2010 INNOVATION: MANAGEMENT, POLICY & PRACTICE 263
Jorge Niosi

Public research institutes and centres were bureaucracies may also be less competent than
mandated to work closely with firms and to those in industrial nations. This gives rise to a
recover part of their R&D expenditures vicious circle of underdevelopment: local
from these industrial sources. educa-tion systems produce few high-level
graduates (and attract even less of them from
Finally, Taiwan’s ITRI has played a key role abroad). Bureaucracies are unable to find
not only in electronics but also in the highly skilled civil servants who would design,
machinery industry (Chen, 2009); other implement and assess sophisticated policies
laboratories are playing a similar role in that would improve such education systems.
biotechnology (Dodgson et al., 2008).
The point here is that, if not connected to local 4. CONCLUSION AND POLICY
industrial partners, and provided with a large set IMPLICATIONS
of useful mandates (none of which is the Science, technology and innovation institutions
provision of basic science), as well as adequate must be revised under the light of evolutionary
Downloaded by [University of Otago] at 12:02 28 July 2015

funding, public research organizations (PROs) in economics and learning. Two major issues seem
developing countries will not play a key role in important for catching up. First, developing
catching up. The examples of South East Asia countries must set up new sectors and for thus
show that they can and should play a major role. purpose they need both horizontal and vertical
PROs should not need to wait from industrial STI policies. Second, in order to make techno-
demand to develop. Through appropriate incen- logy endogenous (Rosenberg, 2000), business
tives, governments must promote linkages and enterprise must be stimulated to conduct R&D
cooperative R&D between PROs and industry, and innovate, to hire scientists and engineers. For
and postpone the advancing of basic science. that purpose, horizontal policies have to be
In 2005, expenditure performed by Latin redesigned and assessed continuously, and
American government institutes was much larger vertical policies need to be implemented in order
than in the average OECD countries: Argentina to launch new, technology-intensive sectors.
(40%), Brazil (21%), Chile (45%) and Mexico This paper has argued several major points:
(23%). But this is only due to the reduced (1) In STI policies, there is no ‘one size fits all’,
involvement of industry in R&D and innova- universal solution. Different countries apply var-
tion. These countries had fewer government ious policy solutions to specific economic struc-
institutes than industrial countries, and all but a tures, strategies and local conditions. Also, the
handful of them were conducting either basic precise way in which these policies are applied is
science or agricultural and industrial extension. important, and there are many different ways of
Few vertical institutes in advanced implementing what at arm’s length appears to be
technologies existed in the region. the same program (i.e., grants for R&D in smaller
firms) (Lach, 2002).
3.5 Conclusion (2) STI policies, crucial components of the
Developing countries have arrived later to science national and sectoral systems of innovation,
and technology. Many of them have underesti- are of variable efficiency and effectiveness. No
mated the key role of institution building. For many clear movement towards optimal or merely
reasons (lack of focus or resilience and/or adequate more efficient institutions is in sight. The rea-
investment) their policies and organisa-tions did not son is the major and permanent ambiguity
produce the expected results. More often than not, about best practices, incentive designs, out-
policies were abandoned instead of being assessed comes, evaluation methods and factors that
and improved. Government explain the results.

264 INNOVATION: MANAGEMENT, POLICY & PRACTICE Volume 12, Issue 3, December 2010
Rethinking science, technology and innovation (STI) institutions in developing countries

(3) Benchmarking and evaluation are, successful and unsuccessful paths and policies,
however, the key learning mechanisms. There and develop its own road to innovation and
is evidence that evaluation, particularly development.
independent one, serves to improve policy The policy implications are straightforward.
designs, through contin-uous improvement. Developing country governments need to pay
However, a substantial amount of trial-and- much more attention to these STI institutions,
error and tinkering remains unavoidable. invest in them, and evaluate them with the goal
(4) Horizontal policies are not enough. Vertical of continuously improving them. They also
policies are required to create new sectors. Little need to built a professional public bureau-
vertical policies were to be found in these Latin cracy of highly skilled civil servants in these
American countries, but if found, they are areas, one that is able to design, implement and
flawed, poorly funded and badly coordinated. monitor the outcomes of public invest-ments in
(5) Also, Latin American countries invest little science, technology and innovation. And they
in business R&D. Their policies are often also need to coordinate human capi-tal supply
Downloaded by [University of Otago] at 12:02 28 July 2015

inconsistent, which reveals the modest with demand, particularly with business sector
manage-rial capabilities of their public demand.
bureaucracies. Although starting from much A final caveat is necessary. Efficient R&D,
lower levels of governance sophistication than science and technology institutions may not be
Latin America, several South East Asian sufficient conditions for catching up, without
countries are much more active and successful industrial policies, an intellectual property
in all these STI poli-cy fields. regime, and a stable macro-economic environ-
(6) It is critical to plan, at the same time, both ment. Industrial policies include some type of
human capital supply (through investment in infant industry protection either through tariffs,
education), and skilled labour demand, the lat- quotas and/or currency management. A wise use
ter being promoted through increasing of these tools allowed Japan to catch up with the
business R&D and stimulating private sector United States in computers (Anchor-doguy,
absorptive capacity. The lack of demand for 1989) or Korea in automobiles (Kim, 1997).
human capi-tal produces ‘brain drain’ Currency management is important, particularly
conditions. An insuf-ficient supply of human in developing countries such as those on Latin
capital generates barriers to innovation in both America where the curse of nat-ural resources is
public and pri-vate sectors. too often evident: in periods of high resource
(7) Because governments design and implement prices, the value of their currency increases and
policy, the construction of an efficient public industrial as well as sophisticated services
bureaucracy is another major condition towards exports become difficult. For decades Asian
the operation of successful STI policies. countries have chosen to maintain a low
(8) STI institutions in OECD countries may exchange rate in order to favour their exports.
provide models for would be catchers up. But An appropriate intellectual property rights
the virtuous circle of policy execution and regime (IPR) is also required (Mazzoleni & Nel-
learning also appears in South East Asian son, 2007). In most industries, but more acutely
countries under fairly different models. Also, in such sectors as biotechnology and pharmaceu-
one learns not only from success stories, but ticals, semi-conductors or software, the existing
also from errors and wrong policy decisions. IPR regime in the world economy may restrict
If any general conclusion is to be drawn from their ability to learn and master existing or in-
this overview, it is that each developing country, coming new technology. All Asian developing
if it is to catch up, will need to examine previous countries have chosen weaker IPR regimes with a

Volume 12, Issue 3, December 2010 INNOVATION: MANAGEMENT, POLICY & PRACTICE 265
Jorge Niosi

view to increase learning and manage the in Chilean manufacturing firms, Universidad
transi-tion from imitation to innovation de Chile Intellis Working Paper, Santiago.
A stable macro-economic environment is anoth- Billings, B. A. (2003) Are US tax incentives for
corporate R&D likely to motivate American
er pre-condition (Cimoli et al., 2008). Many Latin
firms to conduct research abroad? Tax
American countries have suffered from prolonged Executive 7-8: 291-315.
periods of inflation accompanied by fixed exchange Branscomb, L. and Keller, J. (eds.)(1998) Investing
rates, and often such periods were followed by in innovation, creating a research and innovation
macro-devaluations. In the last 50 years, Argentina policy that works, MIT Press, Boston.
Bresnitz, D. (2005) The Israeli software industry. In A.
has been the classic example of such nations prone
Arora and A. Gambardella (Eds.), From under-dogs
to chronic macro-economic instability. to tigers: The rise and growth of the software
industry in Brazil, China, India, Ireland, and Israel,
References pp. 72-98, Oxford University Press, New York.
Aghion, P., Dewatripont, M., Hoxby, C., Mas-Collel, Burns, T., and Dietz, T. (2001) Revolutions. An
A, and Sapir, A. (2009) The governance and evolutionary approach, International Sociology
Downloaded by [University of Otago] at 12:02 28 July 2015

performance of research universities: Evidence 16(4): 531-555.


from Europe and the US. National Bureau of Bush, V. (1945) Science, the endless frontier. A report to
Economic Research WP 14851, Cambridge, MA. the President, US Printing Office, Washington, DC.
Alcorta, L., and Peres, W. (1997) Innovation systems Canadian Chamber of Commerce (2007) Improving
and technological specialization in Latin American the scientific research and experimental
and the Caribbean, Research Policy 26: 857-881. development tax incentives, Submission in
Anchordoguy, M. (1989) Computers Inc. Japan’s chal- response to the Joint Finance Canada-Canada
lenge to IBM, Harvard University Press, Boston. Revenue Agency Consultation, Ottawa.
Archibugi, D., and Pianta, M. (1992) Chen, L.-C. (2009) Learning through informal local
Specialization and size of technological and global linkages: The case of Taiwan’s machine
activities in industrial countries: the analysis tool industry, Research Policy 38(3): 527-535.
of patent data, Research Policy 21: 79-93. Chudnovsky, D., Niosi, J. and Bercovich, N.
Archibugi, D., and Pianta, M. (1994) Aggregate con- (2000) Sistemas nacionales de innovación,
vergence and sectoral specialisation in innovation, procesos de aprendizaje y política tecnológica:
Journal of Evolutionary Economics 4: 17-33. una comparación de Argentina y Canadá,
Arocena, R., and Sutz, J. (2001) Changing Desarrollo Económico 158: 213-252.
knowledge production and Latin American Cimoli, M., Dosi, G. and Stiglitz, J. (2008) The future
universities, Research Policy 30: 1221-1234. of industrial policies in the new millennium:
Arthur, W.B., Durlauf, S. N. and Lane, D. A. Toward a knowledge-centred development agenda,
(Eds.) (1983) The economy as an evolving LEM (Laboratory of Economics and Manage-
complex system II, Perseus, Reading, MA. ment) Working Paper Series, Pisa.
Audretsch, D., Bozeman, B., Combs K.L., Cohen M.D., Burkhart R., Dosi G., Egidi M.,
Feldman, M. Link, A. N., Siegel, D. N., Stephan, Marengo L., Warglien M. and Winter S. (1996)
P., Tassey, G., and Wessner, C. (2002) The Routines and other recurrent action patterns of
economics of science and technology, The organizations: Contemporary research issues.
Journal of Technology Transfer 27: 155-203. Industrial and Corporate Change 5: 653-698.
Avnimelech, G. and Teubal, M. (2005) Evolutionary Crow, M. and Bozeman, B. (1998) Limited by design.
innovation and high-tech policy: What can we National laboratories in the US national innovation
learn from Israel’s targeting venture capital, The system, Columbia University Press, New York.
Samuel Nemean Institute Working Papers 25. Dalhman, C. and Frischtak, C. (1993) National
Axelrod, R. (1997) The complexity of cooperation, systems supporting technical advance in
Princeton University Press, Princeton. industry: the Brazilian experience. In R. R.
Becher, G. and Kuhlmann, S. (Eds.) (1995) Nelson (Ed.). National innovation systems, pp.
Evalu-ation of technology programmes in 414-450, Oxford University Press, Oxford.
Germany, Kluwer, Boston. Dodgson, M., Matthews, J., Kastelle, K. and Hu,
Benavente, J. M., González, R. and Olivari, J. (2007) The M. C. (2008) The evolving nature of Taiwan’s
effect of public subsidies on private R&D spending national innovation system: The case of

266 INNOVATION: MANAGEMENT, POLICY & PRACTICE Volume 12, Issue 3, December 2010
Rethinking science, technology and innovation (STI) institutions in developing countries

biotechnology innovation networks, Malerba, F. (Ed.) (2004) Sectoral systems of innovation,


Research Policy 37: 430-445. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.
Dosi, G., Llerena, P., and Sylos Labini, M. (2006) The Mazzoleni, R., and Nelson, R.R. (2007) Public
relationships between science, technologies and research institutions and economic catching
their industrial exploitation: An illustration through up. Research Policy 36(10):1512-1528.
the myths and realities of the so-called ‘European Mohnen, P., and Roeller, L.-H. (2005)
paradox’, Research Policy 35:1450-1464. Complem-entarities in innovation policy,
Eshima, Y. (2003) Impact of public policy European Economic Review, 49, 1431-1450.
towards innovative SMEs in Japan, Journal National Research Council of Canada (NRC):
of Small Business Management 41(1): 85-93. Mandate, mission, values, program goals
Foro Consultivo Científico y tecnológico (2006) and strategic objectives, Ottawa. Retrieved
Diagnóstico de la política científica, from www.nrc-cnrc.gc.ca/eng/ibp/irap/about/
tecnológica y de fomento de la innovación en mandate.html
México (2000-2006), Mexico D.F. National Science Foundation (2008) Science
Freeman, C. (1987) Technology policy and economic and engineering indicators, Washington DC.
performance: Lessons from Japan, Pinter, London. Nelson, R. R., (Ed.) (2003) National innovation
Downloaded by [University of Otago] at 12:02 28 July 2015

Georghiou, L. (1998) Issues in the evaluation of inno- systems, Oxford University Press, New York.
vation and technology policy, Evaluation 4: 37-51. Nelson, R. R. (2005) Technology, institutions
Georghiou, L. and Roessner, D. (2000) and economic growth, Harvard University
Evaluating technology programs: Tools and Press, Cambridge, MA.
methods, Research Policy 29(4-5): 657-678. Nelson, R. R. and Winter, S. (1982) An evolutionary
Glaeser, E. L., La Porta, R., López de Silanes, F. and theory of economic change, Belknap Press, Boston.
Shleifer, A. (2004) Do institutions cause growth? Niosi, J., 2002. National systems of innovation
Journal of Economic Growth, 9: 271-303. are x-efficient. Why some are slow learners,
Hodgson, G. M. (1999) Evolution and Research Policy 31(2): 291-302.
institutions, Elgar, Cheltenham. OECD (2008) Main science and technology
Japan Small and Medium Enterprise Agency indicators, Volume 1, Paris.
(2008) White paper on small and medium Osman-Gani, A. (2004) Human capital develop-
enterprises in Japan, Tokyo. ment in Singapore: An analysis of national
Kim, L. (1997) Imitation to innovation. The policy perspectives, Advances in developing
dynamics of Korean technological learning, human resources 6: 276-289.
Harvard Business School Press, Boston. Parayil, G. (2005) From ‘Silicon Island to
Kuhlmann, S. (1998) Moderation in policy Biopolis of Asia’: Innovation policy and
making? Science and technology policy shifting compet-itive strategy in Singapore,
evaluation beyond impact measurement: The California Manage-ment Review 47(2): 50-74.
case of Germany, Evaluation 4(2): 130-148. Pugliese, J. C. (Ed.) (2003) Políticas de estado
Kuran, T. (1997) Islam and underdevelopment: An para la universidad argentina, Ministerio de
old puzzle revisited, Journal of Institutional educación, ciencia y tecnología, Buenos Aires.
and Theoretical Economics 153: 41-72. RAND Corporation, 2006. Evaluation and recom-
Lach, S. (2002) Do R&D subsidies stimulate or mendations for improvement of the Department
displace private R&D? Evidence from Israel, The of Defense SBIR Program. Santa Monica, CA.
Journal of Industrial Economics, L(4): 369-390. Romer, P. (1986) Increasing returns and long-
Laranja, M., Uyarra, E. and Flanagan, K. (2008) run growth, Journal of Political Economy
Policies for science, technology and innovation. 94: 1001-1037.
Translating rationales into regional policies in a Rosenberg, N. (2000) Schumpeter and the
multi-level setting, Research Policy 37(5): 823-35. endogeneity of technology, Routledge, London.
Leonard, D. (1996) Wellsprings of knowledge, Sabatier, P. (Ed.) (1999) Theories of the policy
Harvard Business School Press, Boston. process, Westview Press, Boulder, CO.
Lim, Y. (1999) Technology and productivity, Sands, A. 2005. The Irish software industry. In A.
The Korean way of learning and catching Arora and A. Gambardella (Eds.), From underdogs
up, MIT Press, Cambridge, MA. to tigers. The rise and growth of the software
Lundvall, B.-A. (1992) National systems of industry in Brazil, China, India, Ireland and Israel,
innovation, Pinter, London. pp. 41-71, Oxford University Press, Oxford.

Volume 12, Issue 3, December 2010 INNOVATION: MANAGEMENT, POLICY & PRACTICE 267
Jorge Niosi

Saviotti, P. P. and Pyka, A. (2004) Economic Journal of Technology Transfer, 32(6): 605-
development by the creation of new sectors, 615. United Nations (UN) (2007/8) UN Human
Journal of Evolutionary Economics, 14: 1-35. Development Report, New York.
Shapira, P. and Kuhlmann, S. (Ed.) (2003) United States President’s Council of Advisors on
Learning from science and technology policy Science and Technology (2008) University-
evaluation, experiences from the United private sector research partnerships in the
States and Europe, Elgar, Cheltenham. innovation ecosystem, Office of Science and
Smits, R. and Kuhlmann, S. (2004) The rise of Technology Policy, Washington DC.
systemic instruments in innovation policy, Wessner, C. (Ed.) (1999) The Small Business
International Journal of Foresight and Inno-vation Research Program: Challenges
Innovation Policy, 1(1-2): 4-32. and oppor-tunities, National Academies
Sterman, J. (2002) All models are wrong, Press, Washington DC.
System Dynamics Review 18: 510-531.
Tassey , G. (2007) Tax incentives for innovation: Received 29 November 2009
Time to restructure the R&E tax credit, The Accepted 28 January 2010
Downloaded by [University of Otago] at 12:02 28 July 2015

FORTHCOMING FROM eCONTENT


Educating for Sustainability and Stability & Change + General
CSR: What is the role of business section Special Issue of Journal of
schools? Special Issue of Journal of Management & Organization
Management & Organization ISBN: 978-1-921348-50-1 ~ Volume 17
ISBN: 978-1-921348-76-1 ~ Volume 17 Issue Issue 6 ~ ii+128 pages ~ November
3 ~ ii+142 pages ~ May 2011 Editors: 2011 Editors: Stephane Tywoniak and
Suzanne Benn and Robin Kramar, Macquarie Jennifer Bartlett, Queensland
University, Sydney, Australia University of Technology
This special issue explores the role of business This special issue aims to widen understanding of the
schools, higher education and other organisations in processes of stability and change in today's organizations,
fostering change for Corporate Social Responsibility with a particular emphasis on the contribution of
(CSR) and Sustainability. institutional approaches to organizational studies.
Mixed Methods Research in The Future of Technical and
Business and Management Vocational Education (TVET):
Special Issue of International Journal of Global challenges and possibilities
Multiple Research Approaches Special Issue of International Journal
ISBN: 978-1-921348-95-2 ~ Volume 5 of Training Research
Issue 3 ~ ii+110 pages ~ October 2011 ISBN: 978-1-921729-10-2 ~ Volume 9
Editors: Roslyn Cameron, Southern Issue 1 ~ ii+126 pages ~ April 2011
Cross University (Australia) and José F. Editor: Rupert Maclean, Chair Professor
Molina-Azorín, University of Alicante (Spain) of International Education and Director of the Centre for
This special issue is dedicated to Multiple Lifelong Learning Research and Development, Hong
Research Approaches and Mixed Methods in Kong Institute of Education, and Foundation Director,
Business and Management Research. UNESCO International Centre for Technical and
Vocational Education and Training, Bonn, Germany
Home-based Business + General Transformations in Health Care: privati-
section Special Issue of Small sation, Corporatisation and the Market
Enterprise Research Special Issue of Health Sociology Review
Volume 17 Issue 2 ~ ii+128 pages ~ ISBN: 978-1-921729-04-1 ~ Volume
December 2010 20 Issue 3 ~ September 2011
Editor: Professor Colin Mason, Hunter Editors: Kevin White, The Australian
Centre for Entrepreneurship, University National University, Fran Collyer, The
of Strathclyde, Glasgow, Scotland University of Sydney and Jane
This Special Issue seeks to encourage the Jones, Flinders University of South Australia
publication of new research that expands our This special issue is devoted to international, regional
understanding of the home-based business sector. and national papers exploring the increasing reliance
on markets.

eContent Management Pty Ltd, PO Box 1027, Maleny QLD 4552, Australia
Tel.: +61-7-5435-2900; Fax. +61-7-5435-2911
www.e-contentmanagement.com

268 INNOVATION: MANAGEMENT, POLICY & PRACTICE Volume 12, Issue 3, December 2010

You might also like