You are on page 1of 22

Leonardo Felli 3 December, 2001

Advanced Economic Analysis Lecture 2

Consider now a moral hazard problem involving a


strictly risk-averse agent with CARA utility:

U (x, a) = −e−r(x−φ(a))

Recall that the index of absolute risk aversion is


then constant:
∂ 2U (x, a)/∂x2
r=−
∂U (x, a)/∂x

Let the outcome y be such that

y = a + ε, ε ∼ N (0, σ 2)

1
Advanced Economic Analysis 2

The cost of effort is quadratic:


a2
φ(a) =
2
and we normalize U = 1.

Restrict now the principal to offer only linear con-


tracts:
w(q) = β q + γ

Recall also that if

x̃ ∼ N (µ, σ 2)

then:
µ t+ 21 σ 2 t2
 t x̃
Ex̃ e = e
Advanced Economic Analysis 3

First best contract is the solution to the following


problem:

max Ey [y − β y − γ]
w(·),â
h i
s.t. Ey −e−r(β y+γ−φ(â)) ≥ 1

Notice that:
h i h i
Ey −e−r(β y+γ−φ(â)) = Ey −e−r(β a+β ε+γ−φ(a)) =

−r(β a+γ−φ(a))+ 21 β 2 r2 σ 2
= −e

We can then rewrite the problem as:

max a − βa − γ
β,γ,a

a2 r 2 2
s.t. βa+γ− − β σ ≥0
2 2
Advanced Economic Analysis 4

Since the objective function is monotonic decreasing


in γ while the constraint is monotonic increasing in
γ we conclude:
a2 r 2 2
βa+γ− − β σ =0
2 2

Solving for γ we have:


a2 r 2 2
γ = + β σ −βa
2 2

Substituting we get:
a2 r 2 2
max a − − β σ
β,a 2 2
Advanced Economic Analysis 5

The solution is then:


1
β ∗ = 0, a∗ = 1, γ∗ =
2

This implies:

• effort choice
a∗ = 1

• transfer to the agent


1
w∗ =
2
for every y, full insurance.

• expected profit of the principal


∗ 1
Π =
2
Advanced Economic Analysis 6

Assume now that the agent’s effort a cannot be in-


cluded in a contract.

The agent then chooses â so as to maximize her own


expected utility:
h i
−r(β y+γ−φ(a))
â ∈ argmax Ey −e
a

Second best problem is then:

max Ey [y − β y − γ]
w(·),â
h i
s.t. Ey −e−r(β y+γ−φ(â)) ≥ 1
h i
−r(β y+γ−φ(a))
â ∈ argmax Ey −e
a
Advanced Economic Analysis 7

Therefore the agent’s incentive problem is then:


a2 r 2 2
â ∈ argmax β a + γ − − β σ
a 2 2

The unique solution to this problem is then

â = β

Then the second best problem becomes:

max â − â2 − γ
γ,â
2
2 â r 2 2
s.t. â + γ − − â σ ≥ 0
2 2

The solution is then:


1 r σ2 − 1
â = β = , γ=
1 + r σ2 2 (1 + r σ 2)2
Advanced Economic Analysis 8

Moreover:
1
â < a∗, Π= < Π ∗
2 (1 + r σ 2)

Tradeoff: between incentives (need for risk in the


remuneration) and insurance (need to reduce risk).

If the agent becomes less risk averse, r decreases, the


tradeoff is less strong and hence the agent’s effort is
closer to first best and the principal profits are higher.

The same conclusion apply if y becomes a better sig-


nal for a: σ 2 decreases.

In both these cases the power of the optimal incentive


scheme increases: higher β.
Advanced Economic Analysis 9

Hidden Information

Static Adverse Selection problem: one principal


facing one agent who has private information on his
type (preferences, intrinsic productivity).

We consider a monopolist’s pricing model: a trans-


action between a buyer (the agent) and a seller (the
principal).

The seller sets the terms of the contract.

The seller does not know how much the buyer is


willing to pay for the commodity.
Advanced Economic Analysis 10

The buyer’s preferences are represented by:

U (q, T, θi) = θi u(q) − T

where:

• T total transfer from the buyer to the seller,

• θi preference characteristics of the buyer,

• u(q) is the buyer’s preferences for the quality of


the good, u(0) = 0, u0(q) > 0 and u00(q) < 0.

The seller is risk neutral, the unit’s cost of production


is c > 0 and her profit for selling q units of quality
in exchange of T is:

Π = T − cq
Advanced Economic Analysis 11

Question: what is the profit maximizing pair (T, q)


the seller will be able to induce the buyer to choose?

Assume that:
θi ∈ {θL, θH }

and
λ = Pr{θi = θL}

Let U = 0 be the buyer’s outside option.

First best: assume that the seller is perfectly in-


formed on each buyer’s type θi.

The contract is then (Ti, qi), for i ∈ {L, H}


Advanced Economic Analysis 12

The seller’s problem is:

max Ti − c qi
Ti ,qi

s.t. θi u(qi) − Ti ≥ 0

The constraint is the individual rationality (IR)


constraint of the agent.

The solution is such that:

θi u0(qi∗) = c, ∀i ∈ {L, H}

and
Ti∗ = θi u(qi∗), ∀i ∈ {L, H}
Advanced Economic Analysis 13

The seller maximizes total surplus by:

• choosing a quantity qi∗ such that marginal utility


is equal to marginal cost (efficiency),

• extracting the consumer’s total willingness to pay


by means of the transfer Ti∗.

The seller’s total expected profit:

λ (TL∗ − c qL∗ ) + (1 − λ) (TH∗ − c qH



)
Advanced Economic Analysis 14

If the seller cannot observe the the buyer’s type then


she has to offer the same contract to both types.

In other words the seller may offer to the agent (what-


ever his type) a set of choices

(T (q), q)

In principle the contract space is potentially large:


the set of functions T (q), of all shapes and features.

Fortunately we can appeal to the Revelation Prin-


ciple to simplify the search for the best contract.
Advanced Economic Analysis 15

Revelation Principle: There is no loss in generality


in restricting attention to direct revelation mech-
anisms.

The direct mechanism is an alternative environment


where the principal asks the agent to report his pri-
vate information

θ̂i ∈ {θL, θH }

The principal chooses this the direct mechanism so


that it maximizes the principal’s expected profits
and it is optimal for the agent to report the truth.

The revelation principle tells us that there is no need


to look for other mechanism the one you derive is the
best among all.
Advanced Economic Analysis 16

The principal’s problem can be structured in 5 steps.

Step 1: Using the revelation principle the principal’s


problem is to identify the best direct mechanism:

max λ (TL − c qL) + (1 − λ)(TH − c qH )


Ti ,qi

s.t. θH u(qH ) − TH ≥ θH u(qL) − TL

θL u(qL) − TL ≥ θL u(qH ) − TH

θH u(qH ) − TH ≥ 0

θL u(qL) − TL ≥ 0

Where (Ti, qi) = (T (q(θ̂i)), q(θ̂i)), i ∈ {L, H} is the


contract associated with the direct revelation game.

An incentive compatibility constraint (IC) and an


individual rationality constraint (IR) for every θi.
Advanced Economic Analysis 17

Step 2: The individual rationality constraint of the


type H will not bind at the optimum.

Since θH > θL:

θH u(qH )−TH ≥ θH u(qL)−TL > θL u(qL)−TL ≥ 0

Step 3: We solve the relaxed problem that ignores


the (ICL) constraint.

To select which constraint to omit consider the two


(IC) constraints at the first best optimum.

Indeed:

θH u(qH ) − TH∗ = 0
and

θH u(qL∗ ) − TL∗ = (θH − θL) u(qL∗ ) > 0

.
Advanced Economic Analysis 18

While
θL u(qL∗ ) − TL∗ = 0
and

θL u(qH ) − TH∗ = (θL − θH ) u(qH

)<0

Therefore the key (IC) constraint is the one of the


H-type.

The reason why the (IC) constraint of only one type


of agent binds is Spence-Mirrlees Single Crossing
Condition:
 
∂ ∂U/∂q
− = u0(q) > 0
∂θ ∂U/∂T

That is: the marginal utility of consumption (relative


to the marginal utility of money) rises with θ.
Advanced Economic Analysis 19

Step 4: Notice that the relaxed problem is such that


both constraints bind at the optimum:

max λ (TL − c qL) + (1 − λ)(TH − c qH )


Ti ,qi

s.t. θH u(qH ) − TH ≥ θH u(qL) − TL

θL u(qL) − TL ≥ 0

If (ICH ) does not bind then the principal can raise TH


without affecting (IRL), while improving the maxi-
mand.

The maximand is monotonic decreasing in TL while


(IRL) is monotonic increasing in TL.
Advanced Economic Analysis 20

Step 5: Eliminate TL and TH from the binding con-


straints and substitute them into the maximand. We
get:

max λ [θL u(qL) − c qL] +


qi

+ (1 − λ) [θH u(qH ) − (θH − θL) u(qL) − c qH ]

The second best contract (qi∗∗, Ti∗∗) is then such that:

∗∗ ∗
• efficiency at the top: qH = qH

θH u0(qH
∗∗
)=c

• inefficiency at the bottom: qL∗∗ < qL∗


 −1
0 ∗∗ 1 − λ θH − θL
θLu (qL ) = c 1 − >c
λ θL
Advanced Economic Analysis 21

• inefficient premium to the top type: TH∗∗ < TH∗

TH∗∗ = θH u(qH
∗∗
) − (θH − θL) u(qL∗∗)

• efficient transfer to the bottom type: TL∗∗ = TL∗

TL∗∗ = θL u(qL∗∗)

Notice that from the first two conditions we obtain

qL∗∗ < qH
∗∗

We therefore obtain that the (ICL) constraint is sat-


isfied

θL u(qL∗∗) − TL∗∗ ≥ θL u(qH


∗∗
) − TH∗∗

from θH > θL and


∗∗
θH [u(qH ) − u(qL∗∗)] = TH∗∗ − TL∗∗
Advanced Economic Analysis 22

The result obtained can be re-interpreted in terms of


the taxation principle.

The principal offers a menu of (two) two-part tariff


contracts:
∗∗
{(qH , TH∗∗), (qL∗∗, TL∗∗)}

These contracts are such that:

• the L-type agent self-selects in choosing the con-


tract (qL∗∗, TL∗∗),

• the H-type agent self-selects in choosing the con-


∗∗
tract (qH , TH∗∗).

Notice that this re-interpretation corresponds to a


realistic indirect mechanism.

You might also like