You are on page 1of 16

World Development Vol. 94, pp.

406–421, 2017
0305-750X/Ó 2017 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.

www.elsevier.com/locate/worlddev
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.worlddev.2017.02.005

Property Tax Revenues and Multidimensional Poverty Reduction


in Colombia: A Spatial Approach
JUAN MAURICIO RAMÍREZ a, YADIRA DÍAZ b and JUAN GUILLERMO BEDOYA c,*
a
Centro Latinoamericano para el Desarrollo Rural, RIMISP, Bogotá, Colombia
b
United Nations Development Program, Poverty Reduction Unit, Haiti
c
Universidad de Los Andes, Colombia
Summary. — Fiscal decentralization as an instrument to reduce poverty is an open debate that still takes place with little and contra-
dictory empirical evidence regarding whether or not it has served the poor. This paper focuses on analyzing the impact of municipalities’
per capita property tax revenues on multidimensional poverty in the Colombian case. This locally raised tax is used as an indicator of the
state capacity that municipalities exercise when fiscal decentralization takes place. To estimate its impact on poverty, we control for the
possible endogeneity biases that might affect this relationship while taking into account that multidimensional poverty exhibits strong
spatial correlation among Colombian municipalities. We find statistically significant results that demonstrate a causal and diminishing
effect of property tax revenues on the poverty headcount ratio and gap. We also find that this effect has substantial spillovers across
municipalities. The findings of the paper highlight the need to strengthen subnational revenue systems through policy designs to increase
locally raised revenues. We simulate four different counterfactual scenarios to evaluate the potential effect of alternative policy designs on
multidimensional poverty. The results of these policy scenarios demonstrate that spatially differentiated policy schemes have greater
effectiveness in reducing multidimensional poverty than geographically mute designs.
Ó 2017 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.

Key words — fiscal decentralization, property tax revenues, multidimensional poverty, spatial interdependence, Colombia

1. INTRODUCTION the poor. On the one hand, cross-country studies such as those
of Von-Braun and Grote (2000), based on a sample of 50
Several developing and developed countries around the developing countries, and Sepulveda and Martinez-Vazquez
world have decentralized fiscal, administrative, and political (2011), based on information for 34 developing countries from
responsibilities to subnational governmental tiers during the 1976 to 2000, report opposite results. While the Von-Braun
past two decades. The argument behind the decentralization and Grote (2000) analysis suggests a positive association
of these responsibilities is that decentralization allows for the between the share of subnational expenditures and poverty
revelation of local preferences, makes possible a more ade- reduction, Sepulveda and Martinez-Vazquez (2011) find a sig-
quate supply of social services and basic goods appropriate nificant negative effect of the share of income of local govern-
to the conditions and necessities of local populations and puts ments over poverty.
citizens into a direct relationship with the level of government Country-specific analyses, on the other hand, are not much
in whose election they participate and over whom they can more conclusive. In particular, Jutting et al. (2004) performed
exert a closer accountability. For these reasons, decentraliza- a literature review on the relationship between decentraliza-
tion is also meant to improve participation, efficiency, and tar- tion and poverty reduction among 19 different developing
geting at the local level. With this view, decentralization serves countries. Their results suggest an ambiguous link between
the poor (Bardhan, 2002; Dethier, 2000; Von-Braun & Grote, decentralization and poverty reduction. The degree of success
2000). of fiscal decentralization in reducing poverty was found by the
There are also, nonetheless, arguments against decentraliza- authors to be mostly determined by country-specific institu-
tion policies as an effective way of reducing poverty. Poor and tional capacity and the political conditions that ensure the
less developed countries and local governments with low insti-
tutional capabilities can be arguably more prone to corruption
and political capture by local interest groups that distort and
divert resources to their own interests (Bardhan, 2002; * This paper is based on research funded by the Germán Botero de los
Bardhan & Mookherjee, 2005). In this context, and with weak Rios, 2012 Award conferred by Fedesarrollo to Juan Mauricio Ramı́rez.
local governments, decentralization would increase the provi- We would like to thank Claudia Quintero for excellent research assistance,
sion’s cost of social services, which in turn might increase ter- and Renata Pardo for her expertise in the construction of the Colombian
ritorial inequalities (Bird & Rodriguez, 1999). In addition, Multidimensional Poverty Index based on the 2005 census information.
decentralization would increase political tensions across We benefited from helpful comments from Julio Berdegué, Alain De
unequal territories, and in some cases might jeopardize politi- Janvry, Leonardo Villar, Guillermo Perry, Fernando Rojas, Olga Lucia
cal and economic progress to the greater detriment of the most Acosta, Carlos Eduardo Vélez (RIP), Fabio Sánchez, Ximena Cadena,
disadvantaged population (Von-Braun & Grote, 2000). and other seminar assistants at Rimisp, Fedesarrollo, CEDE (Los Andes
As a result, fiscal decentralization as an instrument to reduce University), and Banco de la República (Colombian Central Bank). We
poverty is a debate far from closed. This debate takes place,
also thank the anonymous referees for their helpful comments, which
nonetheless, with little and contradictory empirical evidence
contributed substantially to improving the paper. Any remaining errors
regarding whether or not fiscal decentralization has served
are ours. Final revision accepted: February 8, 2017.
406
PROPERTY TAX REVENUES AND MULTIDIMENSIONAL POVERTY REDUCTION IN COLOMBIA 407

responsiveness of the local governments to their populations’ poverty and local economic activity. Second, measuring
needs. locally raised taxes by exclusively considering the property
The lack of a clear and univocal relationship between decen- tax revenue, we exclude revenues coming from taxes that
tralization and poverty reduction probably arises from the fact depend heavily on economic activity and agglomeration
that, as stated by Careaga and Weingast (2003), there is not economies such as industry and commercial taxes. Third, in
one kind of decentralization but many, depending on the dif- our econometric regressions we control for decentralization
ferent institutional settings and they ‘‘differ enormously in the aspects that could be confounding for our results, such as
ways they allocate power and authority across levels of gov- transfers coming from the central government and administra-
ernment.” (p. 3). Some decentralization processes could lead tive and political decentralization indicators observed in previ-
to poverty reduction, while others might be conducive to inef- ous periods of our analysis, urbanization and rurality degree,
ficient allocation of resources and corruption. Careaga and and the presence of large urban municipalities and municipal-
Weingast (2003) in particular study how variations in the ities that are part of the National System of Cities (NSC). 2
locally raised taxes and electoral competitiveness might affect In our econometric analyses we take into account the fact
the subnational government decision-making process and that poverty is also a spatial phenomenon, which means that
argue that an increase in the share of these taxes increases it is not distributed randomly in the territory. Specifically,
the probability for a local government to choose the provision we implement a spatial autoregressive strategy with spatial
of public goods instead of rent seeking and corruption to gain autoregressive disturbances to model the multidimensional
political support. poverty headcount and gap.
Following the findings of Careaga and Weingast (2003), we The results of this paper demonstrate a causal negative effect
focus in this paper on the empirical analysis of the impact that of per capita property tax revenues over multidimensional
locally raised taxes have on multidimensional poverty for the poverty headcount and poverty gap. We also find that this
Colombian case. In particular, we use the municipalities’ per effect has substantial spillovers across municipalities, a finding
capita property tax revenue as an indicator of the local state that we argue worth taking into account when designing pub-
capacity to exercise fiscal decentralization and we concentrate lic policy interventions to incentivize the collection of locally
our attention on the effect that this source of revenue has on raised revenues. Specifically, to provide policy lessons to max-
the multidimensional poverty headcount ratio and gap. Two imize the effect of property tax revenues over multidimensional
remarks are worth marking in this regard: poverty reduction we test four counterfactual scenarios. The
First, in Colombia the main locally raised tax is the property results of these scenarios indicate that spatially differentiated
tax. In fact, only few municipalities collect taxes other than the decentralization policies have greater effectiveness than geo-
property tax, which are mainly local business taxes (industry graphically mute designs. Differentiated decentralization poli-
and commerce). Still, in 2003, after more than 30 years of cies that take into account the heterogeneity of regions and
decentralization policies in the country, locally raised tax only municipalities are urged for the eradication of deprivation in
represents on average 5.0% of the total municipal revenue and the main dimensions of public policy intervention.
varies greatly among municipalities. While there are munici- This paper is organized as follows. Section 2 reviews the
palities where income from property taxes represents almost relationship between fiscal decentralization and poverty allevi-
40% of their total revenue, other municipalities do not reach ation. Then, Section 3 analyses the empirical descriptive rela-
a share of this revenue larger than 1%. 1 We use this revenue tionship observed among Colombia’s municipalities between
source to reflect the different degrees of autonomy that subna- multidimensional poverty and property tax revenues. Section 4
tional governments exercise when determining tax levels or presents the econometric strategy that we pursue to disentan-
even when introducing new taxes. gle the causal effect that this source of revenue has on multidi-
Second, our outcome of interest is multidimensional poverty mensional poverty. Section 5 presents and analyses the
rather than monetary poverty. Besides the fact that there are obtained results from this empirical strategy. The paper final-
no monetary poverty figures at municipal level available for izes with Section 6, which provides some concluding remarks.
Colombia, through multidimensional poverty, we can assess
the impact of locally raised taxes over the joint distribution
of deprivation in multiple social outcomes where social public 2. FISCAL DECENTRALIZATION AND POVERTY: A
policies could have a direct effect (household educational con- REVIEW OF THE RELATIONSHIP
ditions; childhood and youth conditions; health; labor charac-
teristics; and access to household utilities and housing This section reviews the literature regarding the relationship
conditions). between fiscal decentralization and poverty. This review serves
Still, quantifying the causal effect of property tax revenues as a conceptual background for the subsequent empirical anal-
on poverty reduction is not always a straightforward task yses of the paper.
because of endogeneity problems (Bardhan, 2002). In particu- One of the main arguments to foster fiscal decentralization
lar, a double causality between a municipalities’ raised taxes policies is their effectiveness in increasing public expenditure
and poverty might take place, since municipalities with a lar- efficiency, which would redound in a more adequate supply
ger share of the population and economic activity due, for of social services and basic goods designed according to the
example, to agglomeration economies, have at the same time preferences and needs of the local population (Bardhan,
a higher per capita income, which is conducive to higher tax 2002; Martinez-Vazquez & McNab, 2003; Oates, 1993). Ser-
revenues and lower income and multidimensional poverty vices and basic goods in turn would be specifically targeted
ratios. As such, this double causality issue could bias econo- toward the most disadvantaged within the population. With
metric results regarding the relationship between locally raised this view, decentralization indirectly serves the poor.
taxes and poverty. Indeed, fiscal decentralization could indirectly serve the
We respond to this double causality problem in several poor through a plethora of channels, such as improving
ways. First, we apply an instrumental variable approach using economic growth, developing institutional capacity to
as instrument indicators of the capacity of the local govern- deliver public services at the subnational level, enhancing
ment to raise property taxes that are plausibly unrelated to governance, and improving accountability, among others
408 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

(Martinez-Vazquez, Lago, & Sacchi, 2015). The degree to From the theoretical perspective in this paper we follow
which these channels contribute to the achievement of social Careaga and Weingast (2003) and expect a significant and pos-
outcomes is context specific, as Jutting et al. (2004) found itive effect of municipally raised taxes on poverty reduction. In
when studying the relationship of fiscal decentralization to fact, the empirical causal evidence that we provide in this arti-
poverty across 19 developing countries, and as Bird and cle, and that we further describe below, underpins these
Vaillancourt (2008) also found when they reviewed the pro- results.
gress, problems, and potentials of fiscal decentralization poli-
cies across 10 developing countries around the world. (b) Empirical evidence
The following subsections briefly discuss the evidence that
the literature reveals about the relationship between fiscal The empirical evidence available in the literature regarding
decentralization and poverty, first from a theoretical point of the impact that decentralization has on poverty varies across
view and then from an empirical perspective. 3 contexts and studies. For instance, Bird and Rodriguez
(1999) analyze fiscal decentralization schemes across countries
(a) Theoretical links such as Chile, Malaysia, Argentina, India, Pakistan, and
Indonesia and based on that evidence, argue that fiscal trans-
Theoretical studies regarding the effects of fiscal decentral- fers are the key factor to increase the level of local expenditure
ization, rather than focusing on its relation to poverty, mostly in poorer regions. Also, based on a sample of 14 countries,
focus on the effect that these types of policies have over eco- with data covering the early 1990s, they find that the larger
nomic growth, governance, or social outcomes. the per capita public expenditure, the lower the incidence of
The theoretical analysis of the relationship between fiscal poverty. The authors argue that this negative relationship is
decentralization and economic growth is found to be essen- mostly observed because richer economies have more
tially inconclusive. For example, Bruecker (2006), using an resources to spend and therefore have a lower incidence of
endogenous-growth model with overlapping generations, finds poverty. In contrast, Crawford (2008), using primary informa-
that fiscal decentralization allows public-good levels to suit the tion for the case of Ghana, finds that the political decentraliza-
demands of different age cohorts of the population, which tion process in the country has had a limited effect of the
increases investment in human capital and economic growth. reduction of local poverty.
Opposite results are shown by Tresisman (2006), when taking Interestingly, for the cases of Colombia and Bolivia, Faguet
into account subnational governmental tiers and the central and Sanchez (2008) analyze the fiscal decentralization effect on
government at the same time within the analysis. Treisman education outcomes and find that in both countries, decentral-
argues that an increase in the share of locally raised taxes ization has improved educational outcomes, especially in the
improves the incentives for local authorities to deliver better smaller, poorer, and more rural municipalities. For the case
outputs, but at the same time worsens those incentives for of Colombia, the authors argue that this improvement is not
the central government, producing an overall undetermined only due the greater resources targeted at those areas, but also
effect. to an improvement in the quality of the provided services.
There is a similar case when analyzing the relationship On the other hand, cross-country studies such as the one
between fiscal decentralization and governance. In particular, developed by Sepulveda and Martinez-Vazquez (2011), includ-
Bardhan and Mookherjee (2005, 2006) develop a model that ing 34 developing economies for the period during 1976–2000,
addresses the relationship between decentralization and the find a positive and statistically significant effect of the share of
provision of social services and accountability in government subnational expenditure on the headcount ratio and poverty
service delivery. In their model the potential political capture gap.
of local government is crucial to determining the effect of cen- However, two main empirical drawbacks compromise the
tralization or decentralization on the welfare of the poor pop- conclusiveness of these studies. First, their results are based
ulation. According to their model, when there is no capture at on measures that do not reveal the degree of autonomy that
any level, the decentralized model behaves better and allows a characterizes the devolution of the decision-making power of
second best outcome to be achieved, which is characterized by subnational governments. Their results are mostly based on
cost effectiveness and targeting of the poor. But, with a suffi- expenditure shares, neglecting the impact that local tax rev-
ciently large extent of local capture, the decentralization model enues might have on poverty. Second, except for Sepulveda
fails and the centralized solution is more appropriate. and Martinez-Vazquez (2011), this empirical evidence does
To help explain this puzzled linkage between fiscal decen- not address the causal relationship between decentralization
tralization and subnational governance and to disentangle, and poverty; the provided evidence is entirely correlational.
from a theoretical perspective, the channels behind observing As such, these, and other embedded empirical issues, are
decentralization promoting political and economic develop- crucial to the provision of compelling and definitive evidence
ment but also in some other cases efficiency loses and greater when trying to disentangle the causal relationship between fis-
corruption, Careaga and Weingast (2003) explore how varia- cal decentralization and poverty. The next subsections further
tions in the fiscal systems affect subnational government deci- elaborate on these issues, which we address in this paper and
sion making. Specifically, they analyze the effect of changes in discuss below.
the share of locally raised taxes captured by subnational gov-
ernments. Their results suggest that the greater the proportion (c) Issues on the estimation of the causal relationship
of locally generated taxes controlled by local governments, the
greater the probability that the local government will focus on The estimation of the causal effect of fiscal decentralization
the provision of public goods instead of engaging in rent seek- on poverty is not an easy task because there is a double causal-
ing and corruption to gain political support. While both types ity between them. At least two specific elements drive the dou-
of expenditure provide political support, the authors argue ble causality between locally raised taxes and poverty. First,
that choosing public goods pushes out the budget constraint since most of the transfers from the central government to
through increased tax revenue, which means an additional the municipalities are based on municipality poverty criteria,
gain for the local government. the most deprived municipalities are therefore more dependent
PROPERTY TAX REVENUES AND MULTIDIMENSIONAL POVERTY REDUCTION IN COLOMBIA 409

on governmental transfers and have less incentive to increase might be confounded by these migration phenomena. For
their share of locally generated revenues. Second, since the instance, if one compares the poverty headcount of the people
most deprived municipalities have a smaller population and living in net expulsive regions decades ago with the poverty
business base to contribute to the municipality revenues, they headcount of those living there now, decentralization reforms
actually have less ability to collect taxes. might be seen as failing to serve the poor only because of the
In fact, when Ramirez and Bedoya (2014) analyzed the migration phenomenon. Then, empirical strategies to disen-
municipalities’ raised revenues and their relationship with cen- tangle this relationship must take into account these migratory
tral government transfers for the Colombian case, they found phenomena.
a larger dependence on central government transfers associ- It is worth noting that the empirical strategy that we pursue
ated with a lower amount of locally generated taxes in per cap- in this paper takes into account these latter two issues by
ita terms. This study also found that the effect on the locally introducing one control variable for each of these measure-
raised revenues coming from royalties is also negative and ment issues. On the one hand, within our models we use a con-
stronger. trol variable that takes into account the most important
Moreover, the relationship between locally raised revenues antipoverty social program in Colombia during the time frame
and deprivation at the municipality level is endogenous, not of our analysis. On the other hand, we include an initial state
only because of this double causality, but also because there of deprivation indicator (1993), which controls for possible
are non-observable factors such as political forces and the migration processes or any other social phenomena that could
dynamics of elites at the regional level, which are related to induce a bias given differentials in deprivation across regions
the fiscal effort that local authorities exercise and the locally during the past decades of our analysis.
provided social services for tackling deprivation. These factors The detailed empirical strategy that we use to disentangle
that depict the capture of local governments by special interest the relationship between municipal property tax revenue and
groups and their effect on the performance of antipoverty pro- poverty is described in Section 4 below. There, we present
grams have been theoretically analyzed by Bardhan and the identification strategy that we use to evaluate this causal
Mookherjee (2005) and were found to determine the overall relationship and also included is the description of the control
welfare effect of decentralization. Despite their theoretical variables that we used in our econometric models.
importance, they remain in this paper as empirically unobserv-
able and therefore as a potential source of endogeneity when (d) Spillover effects on poverty reduction
studying the relationship between raised revenues and depriva-
tion at the local level. Municipalities are not, in many cases, a set of disconnected
In this vein, and due to the endogeneity issues discussed political administrative units; there is a plethora of channels
above, the inverse relationship between the amount of locally through which localities interact with each other creating
raised taxes and poverty is not necessarily univocally deter- ‘functional territories’. Among these channels we could enu-
mined. As such, this paper goes beyond establishing that merate labor markets, commodity flows, and input and service
richer municipalities are those that have greater raised taxes availability. This relationship between localities that create
and lower levels of incidence of poverty; but rather looks to together functional territories has been analyzed in the litera-
determine whether or not an additional per capita unit of ture by several studies. For instance, Tolbert and Killiam
locally raised taxes reduces the poverty incidence and the pov- (1987), using the 1980 commuting to work census data for
erty gap, and to quantify the amount by which these reduc- the United States of America, identified groups of counties
tions would occur. that share strong ties generated by the commuting process.
The methodology that we use in this paper to estimate this A recent example is the study of Berdegue, Carriazo, Jara,
causal relationship takes this potential endogeneity bias into Modrego, and Soloaga (2015), who use the assertion of func-
account. On the one hand, to enable greater comparability tional territories and test the existence of these territories by
among municipalities with dissimilar economic levels, we limit empirically assessing city-driven territorial growth for the
the locally raised taxes to those that come from property tax, cases of Chile, Colombia, and Mexico.
excluding taxes on manufacturing and services provision busi- The channels through which the relationships among munic-
nesses. Also, we introduce within our models several control ipalities that behave together as functional territories are
variables that account for the economic heterogeneity across formed have been analyzed by several studies in the literature.
municipalities. On the other hand, and more importantly, we Two examples are worth noting here: Ballet and Llop (2000)
use an identification strategy based on the use of an instru- identified as drivers of this economic, social, and cultural ter-
mental variable approach to disentangle the impact of prop- ritorial interaction specialized goods and services that urban
erty tax revenues on poverty. centers offer to rural nearby localities and infrastructure net-
Finally, two additional empirical issues worth remarking on works that make possible the connections among all of the dif-
emerge from the establishment of the relationship between ferent localities to offer public services that fulfill local needs.
local taxes and poverty. First, as Sepulveda and Martinez- Also, Satterthwaite and Tacoli (2003) propose that it is
Vazquez (2011) discuss, many countries develop fiscal decen- through particular vehicles that more developed municipalities
tralization reforms along with implementing antipoverty pro- can contribute to the development process of smaller munici-
grams usually managed by the central government. Then, it palities and rural areas. Among these vehicles are markets for
becomes crucial to determine the extent to which these pro- agricultural products, production and distribution centers for
grams interact with the fiscal decentralization designs. Second, goods and services, and centers to attract the rural migrant
decentralization effects shall be with consideration of the labor force.
migration perspective. As Bird and Rodriguez (1999) pointed As such, when municipalities within a functional territory
out for the cases of Italy and The Philippines, among other interact among each other through these different channels,
countries, regions with the highest rates of poverty might suf- the increase in public goods and services provided by a partic-
fer important migration processes in which their inhabitants ular municipality fosters the local economy not only within
emigrate toward those regions with lower poverty rates. When that municipality’s own political and administrative limits
evaluating the effect of decentralization on poverty, results but also across the geographical areas linked to it. Functional
410 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

territories, therefore, do not necessarily correspond to political We now move on to presenting the empirical results that we
and administrative borders and can gather together geograph- obtain from the descriptive analysis of our main variables of
ical areas where spillover effects take place through these interest. Specifically, the next subsections describe first the mul-
strong linkages (Ballet & Llop, 2000; Berdegue et al., 2015; tidimensional poverty index that we use in this paper as our
Satterthwaite & Tacoli, 2003). outcome of interest, we then discuss the municipalities’ fiscal
Besides the spillover effect that smaller municipalities and resources and subsequently the observed relationship between
rural areas could receive from larger municipalities in terms municipalities’ property tax revenue and this poverty index.
of economic growth conducive to poverty reduction, and fol-
lowing Acemoglu, Garcı́a-Jimeno, and Robinson (2015), a (b) The Colombian multidimensional poverty index
spillover effect of greater state capacity on poverty reduction
could also occur through the strengthening of locally raised To describe poverty we use the Colombian Multidimen-
taxes. In particular, Acemoglu et al. (2015) studied the direct sional Poverty Index (CMPI) as it assesses deprivation of
and spillover effects of local state capacity on the provision the most important socially accepted basic minimum living
of public goods. They model the decision of a local govern- standards in Colombia. This index uses as the unit of analysis
ment to invest in state capacity, taking into account the spil- the household and aggregates 15 indicators among the five
lover of other municipalities state capacities and the most important Colombian social public policy dimensions
decisions of the national state. Using data for Colombia, they (household’s educational condition; childhood and youth con-
found that spillover effects account for more than 50% of the ditions; health; labor characteristics; and access to household
quantitative impact of an expansion of local state capacity. utilities and living conditions). It was launched by the
The authors found an even larger impact when taking into National Planning Department in 2012 and uses the Alkire
account the equilibrium responses of other municipalities. and Foster (2011) method for multidimensional poverty mea-
Then, we first expect that poverty is not randomly dis- surement. We briefly describe in the following paragraphs the
tributed across space but has a spatial correlation, which in CMPI, for a complete description of the official CMPI see
fact the empirical results that we present in the following sec- Angulo, Diaz, and Pardo (2015).
tions demonstrate; and also, following Acemoglu et al. (2015), Following Alkire and Foster (2011), the index defines a
we expect the local state capacity to be positively interdepen- household as deprived in a particular indicator whenever at
dent among interconnected municipalities and thus larger least one household member does not comply with the mini-
locally raised taxes enable municipalities to build a better local mum set for this particular variable in evaluation. For
state capacity. instance, the first variable that the index evaluates is educa-
tional achievement; then, any household having at least one
household member aged 15 years old or older that does not
3. MUNICIPAL FINANCING SOURCES AND hold at least 9 years of education is defined as deprived in this
MULTIDIMENSIONAL POVERTY IN COLOMBIA variable. Each of 15 variables where deprivation is evaluated,
was selected using normative and empirical criteria and was
This section describes the observed empirical relationship validated through a participatory process among the Colom-
between municipalities’ fiscal resources and multidimensional bian social policy community. The deprivation criterion or
poverty in Colombia. To do so, we first present the data that socially accepted minimums were selected, indicator-by-
we use for the analysis of this paper. Then, we present the styl- indicator, based on national legislation and policy-related cri-
ized facts that describe this relationship. teria already existing to define deprivation in each area. These
minimums are also termed the dimensional poverty lines. For
(a) Data instance, to design the variable relating to dwelling services,
the Colombian National Planning Department has set in its
For the subsequent empirical analysis of this paper we technical documents the characteristics that would define a
developed a comprehensive data set at the municipality level substandard housing. Then, Angulo et al. (2015) used those
for Colombia. The municipal indicators that comprise this criteria to define deprivation in access to dwelling services.
database are based on the 2005 Colombian population and The original CMPI was conceived using the Colombian Liv-
housing census and several administrative registers. The fol- ing Conditions Survey; however, since such a survey does not
lowing paragraphs briefly describe these sources of informa- allow for estimations at the municipality level, we opt for
tion. implementing the CMPI using the 2005 census individual data.
The 2005 population and housing Colombian census inter- Table 5 in the Annex describes the dimensions, variables, cut-
viewed 10.4 million households for a total of 41.5 million per- off points, and weights per variable of the CMPI indicator that
sons living in Colombia in 2005. The census was intended to we calculated based on these data. 5
cover all the national territories and according to a post- For the purposes of this paper we focus our analyses on two
census assessment, it had an overall estimated coverage of municipal poverty measures: the multidimensional poverty
96.3% of the total population. 4 headcount (H ), and the average multidimensional poverty
We utilized the following four Colombian administrative gap (M1). Both of these two measures are calculated as the
registers, each administrated by different Colombian agencies: average across households within municipalities. On the one
(i) the Municipal Budget Execution Capture System adminis- hand, the poverty headcount (H ) depicts the share of the pop-
trated by the Colombian National Planning Department ulation that is considered as multidimensionally poor within
(SICEP because its acronym is in Spanish); (ii) the 2003 each municipality. A household is considered as poor under
national registers on voting from the National Registry this indicator if it has more than 33% of the weighted sum
Department; (iii) primary and secondary road network infor- of the considered variables of deprivation. On the other hand,
mation from the National Geographical Institute (IGAC); the average poverty gap (M1) informs the average gap to reach
and (iv) the administrative register regarding social protection the achievement levels set as minimum. As such, M1 can be
affiliation for formal employees from the Social Protection seen as an opposite measure of convergence to social
Ministry. minimum because it expresses how distant each household is
PROPERTY TAX REVENUES AND MULTIDIMENSIONAL POVERTY REDUCTION IN COLOMBIA 411

from each of the dimensional poverty lines. For the sake of This non-random distribution of poverty among the
simplicity, henceforth in this paper we use the assertion pov- national territories highlights the need to analyze municipal
erty to refer to multidimensional poverty. poverty taking into account its spatial interrelation. We return
Figure 1a and b plot the average H-headcount ratio and to this issue in greater detail in Section 4, when discussing the
M1-poverty gap, across 1,113 observed municipalities in the methodological strategy that we pursue to estimate the impact
2005 census. Darker areas in the figures represent higher pov- of the property tax revenues on poverty.
erty and lighter areas lower poverty. It is observed in both that
higher poverty is concentrated in the country’s peripheral (c) Municipalities’ fiscal resources in Colombia
areas and lower poverty occurs in the more central areas of
the country. While peripheral areas are more disperse, central Colombian municipalities are financed mainly through cen-
areas correspond to more dense and populated municipalities. tral government transfers, royalties, and their own locally
We therefore observe less dense and disperse areas as register- raised taxes. Table 1 presents the descriptive statistics of the
ing a greater poverty headcount and gap. This spatial distribu- share of these three sources in the total income of 1,087
tion of poverty could be attributed to the fact that population Colombian municipalities. The data show that on average
dispersion implies higher transportation costs and makes more 61.5% of the municipal income comes from central govern-
difficult the provision of infrastructure and public services and ment transfers (SGP), 9.9% comes from royalties, and 13.0%
access to technology, education, and health services, as also from locally raised taxes.
lowers the quality of these services. Poverty, therefore, is not In terms of royalties, out of the 1,087 municipalities, only
randomly distributed in geographic terms. 385 received royalties from the production of minerals and
In fact, the largest contrast in terms of poverty incidence hydrocarbons and only in 58 of these municipalities such roy-
takes place between municipalities belonging to the National alties represented more than 20% of their total revenue.
System of Cities (NSC) and the municipalities that are not part Although, on average, this source of revenue is not as impor-
of them. In 2005, while the poverty ratio was on average 49.3% tant as transfers, for some municipalities represented in 2005 it
in a city belonging to the NSC, the same figure was 72.6% for is up to 15 times the size of the transfers coming from the cen-
the rest of the country. This does not mean, however, that tral government. 6
poverty is an out-of-the-city phenomenon. The poor popula- In terms of locally raised taxes, although there are some
tion in the NSC in 2005 represented 49.5% of the total poor municipalities for which almost 80% of their income comes
population of the country. from these tax revenues, there are also municipalities that do

a. Incidence (H) b. Gap (M1)

82 - 100 .31 - .67


71 - 82 .23 - .31
61 - 71 .81 - .23
14 - 61 .04 - .18
No data No data

Figure 1. Spatial distribution of multidimensional poverty, 2005. Source: Authors’ calculations based on 2005 census. Note: 1,113 municipalities in sample.
412 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

Table 1. Main municipal financing sources, 2005


N Mean Std. Dev. Min Max
a. Central government transfers (SGP) as a share of the total income 1,087 61.5 15.9 4.718 91.4
b. Royalties as a share of the total income 385 9.9 17.0 0.002 82.6
c. Tax revenues as a share of the total income 1,086 13.0 12.0 0.040 78.9
d. Property tax as a share of the total income 1,080 5.0 5.2 0.016 39.0
e. SGP, royalties and tax revenues (a + b + c) as a share of the total income 1,087 78.0 10.6 18.973 98.8
Source: Capture System of the Municipal Budget Execution administrated by the Colombian National Planning Department (SICEP because its acronym
in Spanish).

not reach a share of their own raised taxes larger than 1% of 4. DISENTANGLING THE CAUSAL EFFECT OF
their total income. PROPERTY TAX REVENUES ON POVERTY:
In Colombia, municipal locally raised taxes are mostly METHODOLOGY
based on property tax collection. Only a few municipalities
collect other taxes different from the property tax, which are This section describes the empirical strategy that we use to
mainly related to local business taxes (industry and com- quantify the causal effect of property tax revenues on the pov-
merce). Although this source of income is the most important erty headcount and gap. We first present the econometric
tax that municipalities collect, 90% of it is collected in 125 model and then describe the selected variables used to imple-
municipalities (out of 1,111) that are part of the NSC. Then, ment it.
despite the fact that Colombia’s decentralization began about
30 years ago, the tight municipal fiscal autonomy and large (a) The econometric model
dependency on the central government transfers of many
municipalities reflect the still limited and heterogeneous fiscal Since poverty at municipal level is spatially correlated, the
decentralization in the country. estimation procedure that we opt to use takes into account this
Specifically, while the central government sets the minimum spatial correlation, as well as addressing the endogenous rela-
and maximum rate for the property tax (in 2016 it was tionship between per capita property tax revenues and the
between $5 and $16 per $1,000), the local administration has poverty incidence and gap. This section briefly describes this
the ability to set the rate within this range with the approval methodological approach.
of the municipal council. Moreover, whereas by law the cadas- Due to the features of our data and our interest in under-
tral register (the source that local administrations use to col- standing poverty as an economic geography phenomenon with
lect property taxes) is meant to be updated by a national spillovers across geographical units, we focus our interest on a
agency every five years at a maximum, in many cases this does spatial econometric specification that allows us to test, at the
not happen. 7 Still the responsibility rests with the municipal- same time, the spillover effect from neighbor municipalities
ity, which has to co-finance this activity. and to take properly into account the correlation across spa-
As such, we use as our fiscal decentralization variable of tial units among unobservables, i.e., a spatial autoregressive
interest the per capita tax revenue that each municipality raises model with spatial autoregressive disturbances (SARAR).
because it portrays the degree of autonomy that subnational The SARAR model, proposed by Anselin and Florax
governments exercise when determining tax levels or even (1995), accounts at the same time for spillover effects in the
introducing new taxes. We now move on to analyzing the dependent variable and for spatial autocorrelation of the
observed relationship between this per capita property tax rev- errors (correlation among unobservables). The SARAR model
enue and poverty in the Colombian context. can be specified as follows:
X
n X
h
(d) Municipal property tax revenues and multidimensional yi ¼ k W ij y j þ bk xik þ ei ð1Þ
poverty j¼1 k¼1

Figure 2 shows the per capita property tax revenue for each X
n
municipality plotted against poverty in 2005. As expected, we ei ¼ q M ij ej þ ui ð2Þ
observe that on average there is a negative relationship j¼1
between property taxes and the poverty incidence and gap.
However, it is worth noting a caveat that arises in this where y i refers to the outcome of interest, which in our case
regard. Although the majority of municipalities show a nega- refers to the H -headcount or the M1-average gap for each i-
tive relationship between property tax revenues and poverty municipality. The SARAR model specification accounts for
incidence, there is also a large variation in this relationship. the spillover effect among geographical units considering the
For municipalities that have similar per capita property tax interaction among them via the introduction of a spatial lag.
revenues there are large differences in terms of poverty inci- InP Eqn. (1) this spatial lag term is represented by
dence. This result is not surprising as the relationship between k nj¼1 W ij y j , where n denotes the total number of observed
municipalities’ property tax revenues and social outcomes is municipalities, y j describes the value of the dependent variable
not univocally determined, and there is a double causality rela- in the j-neighbor municipality, W ij represents the ij-element of
tionship between them, an issue that was discussed at length in a W -matrix of spatial weights, 8 and k is the parameter that
2(c) Section 2(c) above. In the next section, the methodological accounts for the intensity of the spatial correlation of the
approach that we use to address this issue, and which allows lagged values of the dependent variable. Then, this spatial
us to provide thorough estimates of the causal effect of prop- lag or lagged values of the dependent variable represents the
erty tax revenues on multidimensional poverty reduction, is relation of each municipality with its neighbors and k is the
discussed. parameter that captures the spillover effect.
PROPERTY TAX REVENUES AND MULTIDIMENSIONAL POVERTY REDUCTION IN COLOMBIA 413

a. Incidence (H) b. Gap (M1)

Figure 2. Per capita property tax revenue and multidimensional poverty, 2005. Source: Authors’ calculations based on 2005 census and SICEP. Note: 1,060
municipalities in sample.

In the SARAR model, we control for a set of h different X


n X
h

independent variables that take values for each i- yi ¼ k W ij y j þ bk xik þ hzi þ ei ð3Þ
municipality. In Eqn. (1), each of these independent variables j¼1 k¼1

is represented by xik and is accompanied by a bk parameter.


To account for the correlation across spatial units among X
n

unobservables in the SARAR model, the ei -error term of ei ¼ q M ij ej þ ui ð4Þ


j¼1
Eqn. (1), as shown in Eqn. (2), is expressed in terms of its
ej -lag values, the M-spatial weighting matrix, the q-spatial In comparison with Eqn. (1), here Eqn. (3) includes an addi-
autocorrelation parameter given by the unobservables, and a tional term: hzi , which refers to the zi -endogenous explicative
ui remaining error term assumed to be independently and iden- variable (property tax revenue for the ith-municipality) and
tically distributed. its h-related parameter. This IV-SARAR model is our pre-
However, using the spatial lag term in Eqn. (1) introduces a ferred specification for disentangling the causal effect of
double causality between this term and the dependent vari- municipals’ property tax on poverty reduction. The following
able. Two different options for the SARAR model are consid- subsections describe the specification of the spatial weighting
ered in the literature to account for this double causality and matrices, the independent variables and the instruments that
to obtain consistent estimators. The first consists of using a we use to operationalize this IV-SARAR model.
maximum likelihood estimation (ML), and the second consists
of using instead the generalized spatial two-stage least squares (b) The spatial weighting matrices
(GS2SLS) approach. Following Kelejian and Prucha (1999),
who pointed out that there is neither a general statistical the- In general, the specification of the W -spatial weighting
ory nor a large sample theory for the ML estimator, we opt for matrix can be considered arbitrary and the results obtained
using a GS2SLS estimator. 9 from the IV-SARAR model could be heavily determined by
Besides the endogeneity that arises from the spatial lag term, the specification of the weighting matrix used. We therefore
possible endogeneity, as we discussed in Section 3, might arise use two alternative specifications of W to test the validity of
from the per capita property tax revenue variable, which is our results. First, we use the most common specification of
indeed our main explicative variable of interest. As a first W within the spatial econometric literature, which is a
methodological strategy to tackle this potential problem, we contiguity-based matrix. In such a case, two municipalities
use the lagged values of such a variable as a proxy of the con- are considered neighbors when their two geographical poly-
temporary one; meaning that instead of using the 2005 values gons are adjacent, meaning that they share a common bound-
we use the 2003 register. However, this ad hoc solution for our ary. However, this definition typifies pairs of municipalities by
main parameter of interest may not only suffer from problems whether or not they are neighbors and does not necessarily
of interpretability or precision; it also does not allow us to test capture economic geography interactions or the intensity of
further whether the solution deals properly with the problem. their relationship. Then, the second matrix that we use
Beyond this, we also found statistical evidence that indicated describes the relationship between municipalities intending to
to us that our main parameter of interest (the 2003 per capita capture the intensity of such a connection using economic
property tax income) is not yet exogenous. In particular, we geography indicators. As such, we built this economic geogra-
performed a Durbin–Wu–Hausman test, 10 which uses as the phy matrix by combining the factors into a single indicator
null hypothesis exogeneity of this variable, rejecting such a that ranges from 0 to 1 and that was constructed as the sum
hypothesis under a 1% statistical significance. of the four following indicators: (i) a dummy indicator for
For the specific case when there is evidence of endogeneity the presence or absence of a common boundary among munic-
from one of the explicative covariates in the context of the ipalities, (ii) the inverse distance between municipalities that
SARAR model, Drukker, Egger, and Prucha (2013) developed are not farther than 92 kilometres from each other, (iii) the
the IV-SARAR model, which can be expressed as follows: per capita commutation process captured by the 2005 census,
414 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

and (iv) the per capita average daily traffic per kilometer, dur- foundation. According to the 2003 registers, the number of
ing 2002–04 and reported within the national administrative years that a municipality in Colombia takes on average to
registers of daily traffic. update its cadastral register is 6.2; this variable ranges from
zero years, because of the last update during 2003, to 15 years
(c) The independent variables at most. The cadastral update enables municipalities’ adminis-
trations to have a more accurate register of each of the prop-
Besides our main explanatory variable of interest, we con- erties within the urban areas and constitutes, therefore, an
trol for a set of other decentralization aspects, location and important tool when trying to increase property tax revenues.
size indicators, demography, connectivity of the municipali- On the other hand, we argue that the launching year of each
ties, and other controls. Table 6 within the Annex presents municipality indicates the level of taxation experience of the
the descriptive statistics of these variables used in our analyses. municipality administration and is therefore related to the
The following paragraphs briefly discuss the relevance of locally raised taxes. We use three ranges of years of interest,
them. first municipalities launched before the institution of Law 48
of 1887, which governs the property tax in Colombia; then,
(i) Decentralization controls municipalities launched after Law 44 of 1990, when the prop-
We control for other sources of income of local governments erty tax was defined as a municipality revenue; and finally,
(per capita governmental transfers and per capita royalties) municipalities launched after 1887 but before 1990.
and also for the political and administrative components of
the decentralization process. These data come from 2003
administrative registers. Regarding administrative decentral- 5. RESULTS
ization, we use an indicator of administrative capacity which
ranges between 0 and 100. This indicator was calculated by In this section we discuss the econometric results obtained
the National Planning Department and takes into account from modeling the poverty headcount ratio and the average
the stability of the top (non-elected) officials, educational poverty gap. Specifically, subsection 5(a) presents the proven
attainment of local administration employees, relative use of specifications to model these two outcomes. However, since
information technologies, degree of process standardization, the results reported by our models do not correspond strictly
auditing capacity, and internal control system performance. to elasticities, in this section we analyze these results only in
Political decentralization is measured by the share of total terms of statistical significance and sign. Then, to produce
votes for departmental candidates (‘‘Asamblea”) from the elec- more policy informative results, subsection 5(b) presents the
toral pool. These are taken from the elections held in 2003. We estimated elasticity for our parameter of interest (property
use here the information on departmental elections, rather tax revenue) and 5(c) shows the results of four evaluated pub-
than the municipality ones, and provide a departmental mean lic policy counterfactual scenarios.
to account for 188 municipalities that do not have information
because of violence and the presence of illegal armed groups (a) Determinants of municipal multidimensional poverty
that prevented elections taking place. We expect this political
variable to be indirectly related to the electoral competition Table 2 includes the ordinary least squares (OLS), the
that Sanchez and Pachon (2013) have found to have a positive SARAR, and the IV-SARAR estimations for the poverty
effect on locally raised taxes. 11 headcount and the average poverty gap (S and IV-S in the
table). For the SARAR and the IV-SARAR estimations we
(ii) Other controls consider both specifications of the spatial weighting matrix,
To control for the municipalities’ economic size, we use the the contiguity-based matrix (Cont.) and the economic
urbanization rate, a dummy of population size that distin- geography-based matrix (EG).
guishes between municipalities of under 30 thousand inhabi- When regressing our two outcomes of interest, H and M1,
tants and over 30 thousand inhabitants, a dummy variable against the set of measures of fiscal, administrative, and polit-
that specifies whether a municipality belongs to the National ical decentralization—models (1) to (3) in Table 2—we found
System of Cities, a rurality index 12 and a variable that a negative and statistically significant effect of those variables
accounts for the kilometers of primary and secondary roads on both outcomes of interest. However, such an effect loses its
per squared kilometer of the municipality. In addition, we significance when we introduce our set of controls—models (4)
use two dummy variables of demographic characteristics, an to (6). Interestingly, property tax revenue, our variable of
initial state of deprivation using the 1993 rate of population interest, remains significant across all proven specifications
under the Unmet Basic Needs Indicator, a variable to account for both outcomes.
for the variability induced by the spread of violence in the ter- Furthermore, when accounting for the endogeneity embed-
ritory and the municipal per capita investments of the national ded in property tax revenue, its impact remains statistically
government in the main national poverty alleviation program, significant and is revealed as more than three times stronger
‘‘Familias en Acción,” which is a conditional cash transfer pro- than its value from previous models—models (7) and (8).
gram. We also control for the 32 possible county dummies and These results demonstrate that on average, Colombian munic-
a dummy variable that indicates whether or not the municipal- ipalities reduced both poverty incidence and gap as a result of
ity has an important presence of agricultural activities. increasing their property tax revenues. Therefore, policies that
increase the property tax revenues in Colombia are shown to
(d) The instruments serve the poor by reducing the proportion of the poor popula-
tion and the average poverty gap. These results hold when
As instruments for the per capita property tax revenues we controlling for administrative ability, political decentraliza-
use a set of variables that we argue influence the property tion, an initial level of poverty (measured by a variable of
tax revenues but not poverty: time span since the last cadastral unmet basic needs in 1993), and all the other covariates. Sec-
update in each municipality (measured as number of years) tions 5(b) and 5(c) discuss in depth the implications of these
and a set of dummies to indicate the municipalities’ year of results and the derived policy lessons.
Table 2. Determinants of multidimensional poverty (headcount ratio and gap)
Multidimensional poverty headcount ratio (H) Multidimensional average poverty gap (M1)
OLS S-Cont S-EG OLS S-Cont S-EG IV-S-Cont IV-S-EG OLS S-Cont S-EG OLS S-Cont S-EG IV-S-Cont IV-S-EG
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8)
Property tax revenues 0.161*** 0.084*** 0.106*** 0.081*** 0.053*** 0.054*** 0.209*** 0.117** 0.007*** 0.003*** 0.004*** 0.003*** 0.002*** 0.002*** 0.007*** 0.005***

PROPERTY TAX REVENUES AND MULTIDIMENSIONAL POVERTY REDUCTION IN COLOMBIA


(0.018) (0.026) (0.028) (0.012) (0.014) (0.014) (0.066) (0.047) (0.001) (0.001) (0.001) (0.001) (0.001) (0.001) (0.002) (0.002)
Transfers CMPI 0.008 0.002 0.007 0.001 0.006* 0.002 0.003 0.001 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000** 0.000*** 0.000** 0.000** 0.000*
(0.006) (0.006) (0.007) (0.004) (0.004) (0.003) (0.004) (0.004) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000)
Transfers non-CMPI 0.047*** 0.041*** 0.050*** 0.008 0.001 0.000 0.006 0.003 0.002*** 0.002*** 0.002*** 0.001* 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000
(0.010) (0.013) (0.015) (0.006) (0.006) (0.005) (0.008) (0.006) (0.000) (0.001) (0.001) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000)
Royalties CMPI 0.002 0.001 0.001 0.001 0.001 0.002 0.001 0.001 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000
(0.009) (0.007) (0.007) (0.006) (0.005) (0.004) (0.004) (0.004) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000)
Royalities non-CMPI 0.004 0.002 0.002 0.004 0.003** 0.003* 0.004*** 0.003* 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000* 0.000*** 0.000*** 0.000*** 0.000***
(0.005) (0.002) (0.002) (0.003) (0.001) (0.002) (0.001) (0.002) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000)
Administrative ability 0.150*** 0.089*** 0.087*** 0.042** 0.023 0.013 0.012 0.009 0.007*** 0.004*** 0.004*** 0.001* 0.001 0.001 0.001 0.000
(0.027) (0.028) (0.024) (0.017) (0.015) (0.014) (0.015) (0.014) (0.001) (0.001) (0.001) (0.001) (0.001) (0.001) (0.001) (0.001)
Political desc. 0.128*** 0.064** 0.072*** 0.015 0.015 0.003 0.012 0.003 0.010*** 0.006*** 0.006*** 0.002*** 0.002** 0.002** 0.002** 0.002**
(0.031) (0.028) (0.026) (0.021) (0.019) (0.018) (0.023) (0.019) (0.001) (0.001) (0.001) (0.001) (0.001) (0.001) (0.001) (0.001)
Rural index 0.166*** 0.142*** 0.155*** 0.153*** 0.157*** 0.006*** 0.004** 0.004** 0.005*** 0.004**
(0.039) (0.036) (0.037) (0.040) (0.038) (0.002) (0.002) (0.002) (0.002) (0.002)
Urbanization 0.116*** 0.145*** 0.156*** 0.150*** 0.158*** 0.006*** 0.004** 0.004** 0.005*** 0.004**
(0.013) (0.014) (0.013) (0.014) (0.013) (0.002) (0.002) (0.002) (0.002) (0.002)
Dummy pop. 30 th. Inhab 3.861*** 3.598*** 3.445*** 3.751*** 3.512*** 0.006*** 0.007*** 0.007*** 0.007*** 0.007***
(0.803) (0.792) (0.764) (0.795) (0.757) (0.001) (0.001) (0.001) (0.001) (0.001)
System of cities 2.032** 1.457 3.264*** 0.721 2.842*** 0.092*** 0.104*** 0.108*** 0.104*** 0.109***
(0.869) (0.979) (0.937) (1.144) (1.002) (0.035) (0.038) (0.037) (0.038) (0.037)
1993 Unmet basic needs share 0.318*** 0.263*** 0.239*** 0.236*** 0.228*** 0.016*** 0.013*** 0.013*** 0.013*** 0.012***
(0.022) (0.024) (0.023) (0.026) (0.025) (0.001) (0.001) (0.001) (0.001) (0.001)
National program 0.003*** 0.002*** 0.002*** 0.002** 0.002** 0.000*** 0.000*** 0.000** 0.000** 0.000*
(0.001) (0.001) (0.001) (0.001) (0.001) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000)
Roads per km2 0.459 0.147 0.148 0.097 0.118 0.002 0.016 0.018 0.017 0.018
(0.322) (0.286) (0.271) (0.306) (0.274) (0.014) (0.013) (0.013) (0.013) (0.013)
Agro-concentration 0.138 0.651 0.703 0.282 0.571 0.028 0.001 0.001 0.011 0.008
(0.590) (0.562) (0.566) (0.598) (0.583) (0.026) (0.024) (0.024) (0.024) (0.024)
Attacks 0.000 0.010 0.028** 0.007 0.026 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000
(0.017) (0.014) (0.014) (0.020) (0.016) (0.001) (0.001) (0.001) (0.001) (0.001)
Share of population between 5 and 15 22.393 32.330** 40.147*** 29.164* 38.265*** 0.546 0.879 0.929 0.820 0.848
(14.331) (14.004) (13.176) (15.115) (13.475) (0.631) (0.781) (0.714) (0.791) (0.723)
Share of population under 5 84.668*** 81.157*** 60.042*** 76.323*** 58.907*** 6.469*** 6.002*** 5.034*** 5.908*** 5.025***
(15.640) (14.036) (14.526) (14.480) (14.422) (0.688) (0.865) (0.826) (0.849) (0.817)
Constant 84.115*** 21.685*** 11.316** 43.599*** 30.323*** 13.999*** 38.064*** 17.935*** 3.060*** 1.061*** 0.706*** 0.981*** 0.749*** 0.439** 0.933*** 0.591***
(2.317) (7.664) (5.414) (3.604) (5.036) (5.230) (6.449) (5.449) (0.107) (0.210) (0.171) (0.159) (0.173) (0.170) (0.209) (0.189)
. . .. . .. . .Controlling by county dummies (32 counties). . .. . .. . .
Observations 1,060 1,060 1,060 1,060 1,060 1,060 1,060 1,060 1,060 1,060 1,060 1,060 1,060 1,060 1,060 1,060
R-squared 0.497 0.802 0.563 0.845
Lambda (spillover effect) 0.797*** 0.939*** 0.223*** 0.482*** 0.174** 0.453*** 0.742*** 0.897*** 0.190*** 0.399*** 0.156*** 0.373***
(0.077) (0.065) (0.074) (0.063) (0.077) (0.064) (0.056) (0.055) (0.050) (0.050) (0.055) (0.049)
Rho 0.470*** 0.013 0.381*** 0.697*** 0.297*** 0.672*** 0.504*** 0.332** 0.274*** 0.399*** 0.236*** 0.337***
(0.107) (0.155) (0.069) (0.054) (0.061) (0.059) (0.094) (0.130) (0.065) (0.095) (0.062) (0.110)
Note: Alternative estimations were carried out using instead of 2003 per capita property tax revenue and 2003 national transfers, the total for 2002, 2003, and 2004 per capita variables and the results do
not differ significantly from the ones reported above.

415
416 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

On the other hand, in terms of the geographical pattern, are those that did not suffer violent events that could prevent
when we test for spatial spillovers of deprivation across neigh- elections taking place.
boring municipalities we find a statistically significant effect (k- On the other hand, economic geography variables have a
lambda coefficient) for all proven specifications. The specifica- significant relationship with poverty and the expected sign:
tions that use the economic geography-based matrix for the more rural municipalities (measured by the Rurality Index)
spatial interrelation among municipalities capture a greater tend to have a higher headcount ratio and a higher average
spillover effect than the specifications that use a simple gap. This means that municipalities with lower population
contiguity-based relationship among municipalities. Addition- density and/or which are more distant from cities are, on aver-
ally, despite the fact that we control for possible unobservables age, more deprived than other municipalities, and that their
that vary at the departmental level through a set of 32 county poor population is, on average, further from achieving those
dummies, we still find positive and statistically significant geo- social minimums than the other municipalities.
graphical effects in the error term (q-rho coefficient). At the same time, the urbanization ratio (i.e., the share of
The strong spatial positive transmission effect of deprivation the population living in the urban areas of the municipality)
across neighboring municipalities (k-lambda coefficient), along correlates negatively with both the poverty headcount and
with the results concerning the q-rho coefficient, are present gap. Additionally, municipalities with a greater population
across the two different specifications of the spatial weighting have a lower poverty headcount and gap. The results also
matrix. However, our results suggest that modeling the spatial show a negative correlation between poverty incidence and
relation among municipalities using only a contiguity criterion membership of the NSC. This means that to be part of this
could downward bias the captured geographical effect. Opera- system of cities in Colombia could be a ‘‘bonus” to decreasing
tionalizing the municipalities’ relationship in economic-based poverty incidence, although this effect is not statistically signif-
terms rather than by a simple contiguity-based relationship icant for the case of the poverty gap.
seems to capture in a better manner the geographical pattern Finally, the most important national program of conditional
of deprivation. cash transfer to alleviate poverty (Familias en Acción) appears
When analyzing the regression results derived from the to be positively and significantly related with both the multidi-
other set of covariates included within the estimations, we find mensional poverty and gap but with a lower impact for the
that policies oriented toward transferring resources from the gap. This result probably reflects the targeting of the program
central government to the territories that have funded activi- on the poor population which, as we have seen, is not ran-
ties related to the CMPI dimensions such as education, health, domly distributed in space but tends to concentrate in some
and drinkable water and sanitation, show statistical signifi- regions more than in others.
cance only in one of the poverty incidence models. However,
they show statistically negative effects over all the proven spec- (b) The impact on poverty of municipalities’ property tax
ifications for the poverty gap. This result indicates that gov- revenues
ernmental transfers in sectors related to CMPI dimensions
are negatively associated with reductions of the depth (or To provide policy informative figures of the impact of a
gap) of poverty—models (4) to (8)—suggesting that reductions property tax revenue increment in each municipality over
in the distance of the deprivation degree between poorer and our two outcomes of interest, we calculated the elasticity from
less poor households could be associated with these central an increment of one thousand Colombian pesos in per capita
government transfers. Since these transfers are allocated using property tax revenue across the 1,060 municipalities under
a poverty criterion, this result might be suggesting the effec- study. This increment represents approximately an increase
tiveness of using a poverty criterion to target these resources of 40 trillion Colombian pesos (around US$ 13 billion at the
as the most deprived could be found to be less deprived by vir- average exchange rate of 2016) in locally raised taxes. We eval-
tue of these transfers. uated such a scenario on the results of the IV-SARAR model
In addition, governmental transfers for uses different than that uses an economic geography weighting matrix (model 8 in
the CMPI sectors are found to be statistically significantly cor- Table 2).
related with the incidence of poverty and its gap, but the Table 3 below presents the total effect and its decomposition
strength of this relationship diminishes after taking into into direct and indirect effects. While the direct effect reflects
account the spatial correlation of poverty and it vanishes after the reduction in each municipality of poverty given by the
including additional control covariates. increment in its property tax revenues, the indirect effect
The degree of political participation shows a strong and neg- reflects the reduction in multidimensional poverty given by a
ative correlation with the average gap but does not show a sta- reduction in multidimensional poverty in the neighboring
tistically significant effect on incidence after including the municipalities—the spillover effect.
remaining set of covariates. Municipalities with higher citizen We found that an increment of one thousand Colombian
participation in the electoral process tend to have a lower pov- pesos in per capita terms of property tax income produces
erty incidence, and their population in poverty tends to be less 0.214 percentage points of reduction in the average poverty
poor than municipalities with lower political participation. headcount and 0.008 percentage points of average reduction
Since for the case of the headcount this effect disappears when in the average gap. Out of those 0.214 points of reduction in
introducing the remaining set of covariates, political decentral- the incidence of poverty, 45% of the total effect is given by
ization seems to be playing a more important role in reducing the spillover effect. These results are statistically significant
the gap rather than preventing deprivation. and suggest that public policies that seek to strengthen the
When using two alternative political decentralization vari- municipality property tax revenues have an important impact
ables to describe directly the level of political competition at in reducing poverty and achieving convergence toward social
the municipality level, we find no statistically significant effect minimums. More than two-thirds of the total effect associated
(after controlling for the other covariates) of such political with increments in the property tax revenues would redound
competition on the multidimensional poverty and gap. These on reductions of poverty in the spatially interrelated munici-
results are available for a sample of 872 municipalities, which palities.
PROPERTY TAX REVENUES AND MULTIDIMENSIONAL POVERTY REDUCTION IN COLOMBIA 417

Table 3. Total, direct, and indirect impact of property tax revenues the 300 municipalities that are the most spatially correlated
Direct effect Indirect effect Total effect but that do not belong to the National System of Cities. This
Policy D would mean a 20% direct increment of the per capita
Multidimensional 0.117** 0.097** 0.214** property tax revenue in those municipalities.
headcount ratio (0.047) (0.037) (0.083)
Table 4 below presents the results of these counterfactual
Multidimensional 0.005*** 0.003*** 0.008***
policy scenarios. The table shows across rows the mean multi-
average gap (0.002) (0.001) (0.003)
dimensional headcount and gap before any policy and the sim-
ulated change effect from each tested policy scenario. Columns
(1)–(4) report the simple mean and the effect of the policies,
This important size of the obtained indirect effect highlights calculated across different subgroups of municipalities. When
the relevance of policies that take into account the geograph- comparing the effect produced across policies, we found that
ical relationship of deprivation among municipalities. We test the least effective policy in reducing multidimensional poverty
this policy implication in the next subsection below. corresponds to Policy B. Indeed, concentrating the fiscal effort
in the 18 most important Colombian cities (Policy B) does not
(c) Counterfactual policy scenarios produce a greater mean reduction either in multidimensional
headcount ratio or in the average gap. This means that efforts
In this section we analyze the possible effects of three alter- concentrated only on the most developed municipalities are
native geographically differentiated policies compared with a not enough to produce significant reductions in deprivation
policy that does not take into account the geographical rela- across all the territories.
tionship among municipalities. For this purpose we imple- The same fiscal effort, but concentrated over the most spa-
mented four different counterfactual policy scenarios. The tially deprivation correlated municipalities (Policy C), registers
first scenario (Policy A) corresponds to the non- an important effect not only in the shocked municipalities but
geographically designed policy, which is based on an incre- also in the remaining 760 municipalities that comes from the
ment of 1.5% of the per capita property tax revenue per each spillover effect. However, the aggregated effect of such a policy
municipality in the country. The subsequent three scenarios does not exceed the one produced by Policy D or the result
correspond to geographically sensitive policies. On one hand, obtained from a geographically mute policy (Policy A).
the first geographically differentiated scenario (Policy B), By all means and as expected, the most effective policy in
focuses on main urban areas, concentrates the same total reducing multidimensional poverty across all municipalities
increment of per capita tax revenue as Policy A but takes place (column 1) is Policy D. Such a policy has an effect of 0.167 per-
in the centroids of the National System of Cities (the biggest centage points of incidence reduction on average over all 1,076
18 cities); this corresponds to an increment of 2.4% of per cap- municipalities, 0.283 percentage points of incidence reduction
ita property tax revenue in each of these 18 cities in the coun- over the 300 shocked municipalities and when calculating the
try. spillover effect of this policy over the 760 other municipalities
The second spatially differentiated policy, Policy C, concen- that were not subject to the policy, multidimensional incidence
trates the same fiscal effort as Policy A and Policy B, but now is reduced on average 0.121 percentage points. Notice that this
over the 300 most spatially correlated municipalities in terms policy is targeting the most geographically correlated in depri-
of poverty. According to this policy, those 300 municipalities vation but excluding the big cities.
increase their per capita property tax revenue by 2.1%. Finally, These policy simulations illustrate the direct and indirect
Policy D tests the same fiscal effort but now concentrates on effects of the introduction of the same increase in property

Table 4. Mean change effect of each simulated policy over multidimensional poverty
All municipalities The 18th centroids The 300 most correlated The 300 most correlated
municipalities municipalities (NSC+)
(1) (2) (3) (4)
H Simple mean 73.702 39.553 70.787 78.495
(15.322) (6.952) (23.846) (18.478)
Difference Policy A 0.0515*** 0.0790*** 0.0492*** 0.0385***
(0.0010) (0.0047) (0.0023) (0.0020)
Policy B 0.0031*** 0.0484*** 0.0055*** 0.0005
(0.0003) (0.0035) (0.0009) (0.0004)
Policy C 0.0231*** 0.0739*** 0.0443*** 0.0249***
(0.0011) (0.0070) (0.0028) (0.0021)
Policy D 0.1668*** 0.0008 0.2477*** 0.2833***
(0.0074) (0.0481) (0.0165) (0.0155)
M1 Simple mean 0.239 0.112 0.244 0.273
(0.076) (0.024) (0.119) (0.101)
Difference Policy A 0.0019*** 0.0029*** 0.0018*** 0.0014***
(0.0000) (0.0001) (0.0000) (0.0000)
Policy B 0.0001*** 0.0018*** 0.0002*** 0.0000
(0.0000) (0.0001) (0.0000) (0.0000)
Policy C 0.0008*** 0.0027*** 0.0016*** 0.0009***
(0.0000) (0.0002) (0.0001) (0.0000)
Policy D 0.0062*** 0.0000 0.0092*** 0.0105***
(0.0002) (0.0018) (0.0006) (0.0005)
Note: +NSC refers to municipalities not included within the system of cities.
418 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

tax revenues, but looking at its differentiated effect regarding tive when focused on municipalities exhibiting relative larger
the targeted municipalities. The results suggest that policies geographical interconnection of their deprivation levels with
targeted using as a criterion of selection levels of deprivation their neighbors. Municipalities with greater autonomy and a
but also a geographical correlation criterion produce more greater capability to increase their own locally raised taxes
effective results than policies that do not take into account this are more successful at reducing poverty. As such, public poli-
important feature of poverty. cies that strengthen municipalities’ autonomy to set their own
programs with the corresponding responsibility toward their
own citizens are urged to be included on the national develop-
6. CONCLUDING REMARKS ment agenda. A reform in the design of the transfer system is,
therefore, in order for the Colombian case, as has been exten-
This paper disentangles the impact of locally raised taxes on sively discussed by Bird (2012). The purpose in this reform
poverty reduction in Colombia. We assess the causal effect of could be the design of a transfer system that increases the
per capita property tax revenues over the multidimensional share of locally raised taxes at subnational level, while taking
poverty headcount ratio and gap. This paper goes beyond into account the potential revenue-raising capacity of each
establishing that richer municipalities are those that have municipality and does not disincentive its own fiscal effort.
greater property tax revenues in per capita terms and lower To evaluate the potential effect on poverty of alternative
levels of incidence of poverty, but rather our results demon- policies to strengthen the capacity of local governments via
strate that an additional per capita revenue of property tax increments in their property tax revenues, this paper analyzed
reduces poverty incidence and gap, and we quantify the four counterfactual policy scenarios. The results of these sce-
amount by which this reduction occurs. narios suggest that policies targeted to municipalities strongly
Although in this study we only use a cross-section of data correlated to their neighbors and with high deprivation levels
from the 2005 census, in a related paper, Ramirez et al. are more effective in poverty alleviation than national strate-
(2016) explore the intertemporal relationship between poverty gies applied uniformly to municipalities disregarding these fea-
and locally raised taxes in the period 1993–2005. While data tures.
limitations make it difficult to identify a causal relationship In terms of other decentralization aspects, our results indi-
between poverty and locally raised taxes, the conclusions of cate a negative and significant correlation of political decen-
Ramirez et al. (2016) support the main finding of this paper tralization (measured by citizen participation in local
regarding the critical role of municipalities’ property tax rev- elections) and governmental transfers for education, health,
enues in reducing poverty. and water and sanitation, with the poverty gap but not the
To obtain these results, we model poverty as a phenomenon poverty headcount. Although these results are entirely correla-
with spatial interactions, as poverty was found not to be ran- tional and do not constitute causal inference, they still high-
domly distributed in the Colombian territory. Peripheral areas light the need for further research to disentangle the causal
tend to concentrate a greater poverty headcount ratio and gap effects of these features of the decentralization process on pov-
than those more central areas of the country (although almost erty reduction.
half of the poor population lives in cities and the surrounding Finally, we found that economic geography strongly corre-
towns). Then, we use a spatial econometric approach that lates with poverty incidence and gap. Higher incidence and
accounts for spillover effects and for spatial correlation of gap are associated with: (a) a higher degree of rurality (lower
the errors. The results of these econometric estimations show, population densities and/or larger distances to cities); (b) a
consistently across all the specifications, that the strong nega- lower urbanization rate; (c) municipalities that are not part
tive causal impact on poverty of the per capita property tax to the Colombian National System of Cities. These results
revenue is accompanied by a substantial spillover effect across support the conclusion that the main difference in terms of
municipalities. This effect is robust under our entire set of con- poverty incidence in Colombia is not between urban and rural
trol variables. areas, but between municipalities with higher densities or clo-
The findings of the paper also suggest some topics that ser to cities and municipalities with low densities and far from
should be part of an agenda for adjusting and reforming cities. These results highlight the need for strategies to over-
decentralization models. One of them is the need to strengthen come poverty designed using a territorial approach. Spatially
the subnational revenue system to increase the per capita differentiated policies, and decentralization designs that take
locally raised taxes, even at the bottom of the municipal hier- into account the heterogeneity of regions and municipalities,
archy, which, for practical purposes, could be achieved by are urged to improve social convergence to minimums mainly
improving the property tax system, including incentives from in the territories at the bottom of the distribution. The role of
the central government to the municipalities to update the economic geography variables has proven to be crucial in the
cadastral register and to increase their rather low rates in the design of such policies.
case of many municipalities. This policy would be more effec-

NOTES

1. Source: 2003 Colombian National Planning Department figures on municipalities. Using the 2005 census, the system represents 66.0% of total
municipalities’ income and expenditure. population and 79.1% of urban population in the country. A complete
description of this system and its design can be seen in DNP (2014).
2. The NSC includes 151 municipalities (out of 1,111 municipalities),
mainly cities and towns around them for which there are significant 3. For a comprehensive review of the impact of fiscal decentralization on
commuting flows. This system was devised by the Colombian National a myriad of economic, social, and political factors see Martinez-Vazquez
Planning Department to enhance territorial synergies among nearby et al. (2015).
PROPERTY TAX REVENUES AND MULTIDIMENSIONAL POVERTY REDUCTION IN COLOMBIA 419

4. The population and housing Census was made mainly of two 9. In particular, as proposed by Kelejian and Prucha (1999, 2004) and
questionnaires, the first one applied over each of the respondent Arraiz, Drukker, Kelejian, and Prucha (2010) for the SARAR model, we
households including dwelling conditions and household composition first use as valid instruments for the endogenous lagged dependent
questions. The second questionnaire, an extended version of the first one, variable the spatial lags of the variables contained in X , then we estimate
was applied over a probabilistic subsample of conglomerates with a the instrumented specification by the generalized method of moments and
household Bernoulli selection procedure. The extended questionnaire finally we perform a spatial Cochrane–Orcutt transformation to obtain
included information regarding education and labor conditions for each of more efficient estimates for b and k.
the household members and allows for municipality estimations.
10. For a comprehensive explanation of the Durbin–Wu–Hausman test
5. The official methodology to calculate the CMPI uses the 2003, 2007, see Cameron (2005).
and 2010 Colombian Living Conditions Survey (CLCS). The main
difference of the CMPI constructed for the purposes of this paper with 11. Additional to this indicator of political participation of the electoral
respect to the official CMPI is that we transform some of the indicators of census on the departmental elections, we test two alternative measures of
the household education conditions and access to public utilities and political decentralization at the municipality level. First, a Herfindahl
housing conditions, in a way that they can be measured in a cardinal scale, index for the election of majors. This variable was used by Sanchez and
rather than just indicating the presence or absence of a certain attainment. Pachon (2013) as an indicator of electoral competition. It corresponds to
That was not the case with the official CMPI. For a complete description the total number of votes from each candidate divided by the total number
of the methodology to construct the 2005 census-based CMPI that we use of valid votes for the major’s election. Then, the quadratic version of these
and the transformations done over the official CMPI see Ramirez, Bedoya, proportions is added. Values close to one of this index correspond to
and Diaz (2016). municipalities where a single candidate obtained a very large share of the
total votes. The second alternative political decentralization variable that
6. With the constitutional reform to royalties in 2011, the distribution of we use was a Herfindahl index for the municipal council’s elections. This
these resources among subnational governments changed drastically. With second index is built similarly to the previous case, but here we account for
the former regime 20% of municipalities and counties received 80% of the shares obtained by each political party to the council, rather than for
royalties; with the new regime their share has decreased to 20%. the share of candidates to be major. These two variables are available for a
sample of 872 municipalities.
7. The national agency that updates the cadastral register is the IGAC
(Colombian Geographical Institute Agustin Codazzy). 12. To obtain the rurality index for each n-municipality, we combine
population density and the four indicators of distance: (i) distance to the
8. Each ij-element of the W -spatial weighting matrix describes the closest municipality of at least 1 million inhabitants; (ii) distance to the
relationship among the ij-pair of municipalities. Section 4(b) describes in closest municipality between 400 thousand and 1 million inhabitants; (iii)
detail the two alternative W -spatial weighting matrices that we use in our mean distance to municipalities between 200 and 399 thousand inhab-
estimations. itants, and (iv) mean distance to the 50% closest municipalities between
100 and 199 thousand inhabitants. We express density as the number of
inhabitants per squared kilometer in each k-municipality. Further detail
on the construction of this index can be found in Ramirez et al. (2016).

REFERENCES

Acemoglu, D., Garcı́a-Jimeno, C., & Robinson, J. A. (2015). State Bird, R. M. (2012). Fiscal decentralization in Colombia: A work (Still) in
capacity and economic development: A network approach. American progress. International Center for Public Policy (formerly the Interna-
Economic Review, American Economic Association, 105(8), 2364–2409. tional Studies Program), Andrew Young School of Policy Studies,
Alkire, S., & Foster, J. (2011). Counting and multidimensional poverty Georgia State University.
measurement. Journal of Public Economics, 95(7), 476–489. Bird, R., & Rodriguez, E. R. (1999). Decentralization and poverty
Angulo, R., Diaz, B. Y., & Pardo, R. (2015). The Colombian multidi- alleviation. International experience and the case of the Philippines.
mensional poverty index: Measuring poverty in a public policy context. Public Administration & Development, 19(3), 299.
Social Indicators Research, 1–38, Springer. Bird, R., & Vaillancourt, F. (2008). Fiscal decentralization in developing
Anselin, L., & Florax, R. J. (1995). Small sample properties of tests for countries. Cambridge University Press.
spatial dependence in regression models: Some further results. In New Bruecker, J. K. (2006). Fiscal federalism and economic growth. Journal of
directions in spatial econometrics. Springer. Public Economics, 90(10), 2107–2120.
Arraiz, I., Drukker, D. M., Kelejian, H. H., & Prucha, I. R. (2010). A Cameron, A. C. (2005). Microeconometrics: Methods and applications.
Spatial cliff-ord-type model with heteroskedastic innovations: Small Cambridge University Press.
and large sample results. Journal of Regional Science, 50, 592–614. Careaga, M., & Weingast, B. (2003). Fiscal federalism, good governance,
Ballet, C., & Llop, J. M. (2000). Ciudades intermedias y urbanizacion and economic growth in Mexico. In In search of prosperity: Analytical
mundial. Ciudades intermedias y urbanizacion mundial (pp. 325–327). narratives on economic growth (pp. 399–435).
Lerida: Editorial Milenio. Crawford, G. (2008). Decentralization and the limits to poverty reduction:
Bardhan, P. (2002). Decentralization of governance and development. The Findings from Ghana. Oxford Development Studies, 36(2), 235–258.
Journal of Economic Perspectives, 16(4), 185–205. Dethier, J. (Ed.) (2000). Governance, decentralization and reform in China.
Bardhan, P., & Mookherjee, D. (2005). Decentralizing antipoverty India and Russia: Kluwer Academic Publishers and ZEF.
program delivery in developing countries. Journal of Public Economics, DNP (2014). Polı́tica nacional para consolidar el Sistema de Ciudades en
89(4), 675–704. Colombia. , Conpes 3919. Bogotá. https://colaboracion.dnp.gov.co/
Bardhan, P., & Mookherjee, D. (2006). Decentralisation and account- CDT/Conpes/Econ%C3%B3micos/3819.pdf.
ability in infrastructure delivery in developing countries. The Economic Drukker, D. M., Egger, P., & Prucha, I. R. (2013). On two-step estimation
Journal, 116(508), 101–127. of a spatial autoregressive model with autoregressive disturbances and
Berdegue, J., Carriazo, F., Jara, B., Modrego, F., & Soloaga, I. (2015). endogenous regressors. Econometric Reviews, 32, 686–733.
Cities, territories, and inclusive growth: Unraveling urban-rural Faguet, J. P., & Sanchez, F. (2008). Decentralization’s effects on
linkages in Chile, Colombia, and Mexico. World Development, 73, educational outcomes in Bolivia and Colombia. World Development,
56–71. 36(7), 1294–1316.
420 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

Jutting, J. P., Kauffmann, C., McDonnelll, I., Osterriender, H., Pinaud, national politics matter? IDB Publications (working papers) 81418.
N., & Wegner, L. (2004). Decentralization and poverty in developing Inter-American Development Bank.
countries: Exploring the impact. . Satterthwaite, D., & Tacoli, C. (2003). The urban part of rural develop-
Kelejian, H. H., & Prucha, I. R. (1999). A generalized moments estimator ment: The role of small and intermediate urban centres in rural and
for the autoregressive parameter in a spatial model. International regional development and poverty reduction. International Institute for
Economic Review, 40, 509–533. Environment and Development, Working Paper Serie No 9.
Kelejian, H. H., & Prucha, I. R. (2004). Estimation of simultaneous Sepulveda, C. F., & Martinez-Vazquez, J. (2011). The consequences of
systems of spatially interrelated cross sectional equations. Journal of fiscal decentralization on poverty and income equality. Environment
Econometrics, 118, 27–50. and Planning C: Government and Policy, 29(2), 321–343.
Martinez-Vazquez, J., Lago, S., & Sacchi, A. (2015). The impact of fiscal Tolbert, C. M., & Killiam, M. S. (1987). Labour market areas for the
decentralization: A survey International Center for Public Policy United States. Washington, D.C.: Economic Research Service (DOA),
Working Paper. . August. Technical report No. 870721.
Martinez-Vazquez, J., & McNab, R. M. (2003). Fiscal decentralization Tresisman, D. (2006). Fiscal decentralization, governance, and economic
and economic growth. World Development, 31(9), 1597–1616. performance: A reconsideration. Economics & Politics, 18(2), 219–235.
Oates, W. (1993). Fiscal decentralization and economic development. Von-Braun, J., & Grote, U. (2000). Does decentralization serve the poor?
National Tax Journal, 46(2), 237–243. In: International Monetary Fund conference on fiscal decentralization,
Ramirez, J. M., & Bedoya, J. G. (2014). Regalı́as directas por hidrocar- Washington, DC, November (pp. 20–21).
buros y esfuerzo fiscal municipal en Colombia. In Coyuntura
Económica y Social. Fedesarrollo.
Ramirez, J. M., Bedoya, J. G., & Diaz, B. Y. (2016). Geografı́a económica,
descentralización y pobreza multidimensional en Colombia, Cuadernos
Fedesarrollo, No. 54. Fedesarrollo.
Sanchez, F., & Pachon, M. (2013). Decentralization, fiscal effort and social ANNEXES
progress in Colombia at the municipal level, 1994-2009: Why does

Table 5. Dimensions, variables, weights and cut off points of the implemented CMPI
Dimension Variable Indicator Cutoff point (%)
Household education Educational achievement (0.1) Percentage of people living 15 and older who holds at 100
conditions (0.2) least 9 years of education
Literacy (0.1) Percentage of people living in a household 15 and 100
older who know how to read and write
Childhood and youth School attendance (0.05) Percentage of children between the ages of 6 and 16 in 100
conditions (0.2) the household that attend school
No school lag (0.05) Percentage of children and youths (7–17 years old) 100
within the household that are not suffering from
school lag (according to the national norm)
Access to childcare services (0.05) Percentage of children between the ages of 0 and 5 in 100
the household who simultaneously have access to
health, nutrition and education
Children not working (0.05) Percentage of children between 12 and 17 years old in 100
the household that are not working
Employment (0.2) Absence of long-term unemployment (0.1) Percentage of household members from the economic 100
active population that are not facing long-term
unemployment (more than 12 months)
Formal employment (0.1) Percentage of employed household members that are 100
affiliated to a pension fund (formality proxy)
Health (0.2) Health insurance (0.1) Percentage of household members over the age of 5 100
that are insured by the Social Security Health System
Access to health services (0.1) Percentage of household members that had access to a 100
health institution in case of need
Access to public utilities and Access to dwelling services (0.1) Percentage of dwelling services that the household has 100
housing conditions (0.2) access to; this out of (i) water source, (ii) elimination
of sewer waste, (iii) adequate external walls* (iv)
adequate floor++
No critical overcrowding (0.1) Percentage of absence of critical overcrowding** 100
Source: Angulo et al. (2015) and Ramirez et al. (2016). Notes: The weight assigned to each dimension and variable is shown in parenthesis. *Urban
households are considered deprived in water source if they are lacking of public water system. In elimination of sewer waste if they lack a public sewer
system. In adequate external walls if the exterior walls are built of untreated wood, boards, planks, guadua or other vegetation, zinc, cloth, cardboard,
waste material or when no exterior walls exist. Rural household are considered deprived in water source if the water used for the preparation of food is
obtained from wells, rainwater, spring source, water tank, water carrier, or other sources. In adequate elimination of sewer waste if they use a toilet
without a sewer connection, a latrine or simply do not have a sewage system. In external walls if the exterior walls are built of guadua or other vegetation,
zinc, cloth, cardboard, waste materials or if no exterior walls exist. ++Households (both urban and rural) with dirt floors are considered deprived in
adequate floor. **Deprivation is considered for: urban households with three or more persons per room or rural households with more than three persons
per room.
PROPERTY TAX REVENUES AND MULTIDIMENSIONAL POVERTY REDUCTION IN COLOMBIA 421

Table 6. Descriptive statistics


Variable N Mean Std. dev Min Max Units Source
Dependent variables
Multidimensional Incidence 1,113 69.5 16.4 14.3 100.0 Percentage share (0–100) 2005 Census
poverty Gap 1,113 0.2 0.1 0.0 0.7 Percentage points 2005 Census

Independent variables
Locally raised taxes Per capita property tax revenue 1,075 15.35 19.68 0.00 295.09 Per capita thousand Colombian NPD, 2003
pesos
Other decentralization Per capita investment financed by SGP 1,094 214.70 132.57 0.00 1,063.45 Per capita thousand Colombian NPD, 2003
indicators (governmental transfers) pesos
Per capita investment financed by 1,094 29.58 166.91 0.00 3,838.00 Per capita thousand Colombian NPD, 2003
royalties pesos
Administrative ability 1,098 51.66 18.84 0.00 85.48 Index that ranges from 0 to 100 NPD (Overall performance
index)
Share of total votes over electoral 1,111 58.00 14.40 0.20 96.4 Percentage share (0–100) National Registry
potential Department, 2003
Location and size Urbanization 1,111 43.10 24.70 0.00 100.00 Percentage share (0–100) 2005 Census
Dummy of population size 1,111 0.06 0.23 0.00 1.00 Dummy, 1 = Municipality with 2005 Census
30.000 or more inhabitants.
0 = Municipalities with less than
30.000 inhabitants
National System of cities 1,111 0.14 0.34 0.00 1.00 Dummy, 1 = belongs to the System of cities mission
system of cities. 0 = Do not report
belong
Rurality index 1,111 46.68 12.58 0.00 100.00 Index from 0 to 100 2005 census and
geographical information
a. Population density 1,092 140.59 576.70 0.16 10,682.55 Inhabitants per squared 2005 Census
kilometer
b. Distance to the closest municipality 1,092 165.88 102.90 0.00 955.54 Kilometers Euclidean distances based
of at least a million inhabitants on map information
c. Distance to the closest municipality 1,092 151.07 117.49 0.00 980.37 Kilometers
between 400 and 1000 thousand
inhabitants
d. Mean distance to municipalities 1,092 399.12 107.81 270.41 1,147.87 Kilometers
between 200 and 399 thousand
inhabitants
e. Mean distance to the 50% closest 1,092 244.72 84.94 155.61 1,007.62 Kilometers
municipalities between 100 and 199
thousand inhabitants
Connectivity/ Agro-concentration 1,111 0.20 0.40 0.00 1.00 Dummy, 1 = municipalities with NPD
development greater concentration of
agricultural activity.
0 = municipalities without
agricultural vocation
Kilometers of primary and secondary 1,096 1.23 0.88 0.00 13.33 Kilometers IGAC and System of cities
roads per squared kilometers of the
municipality
Demography Share of population 5–15 years old 1,097 22.80 2.61 12.43 30.68 Percentage share (0–100) 2005 census
Share of population under 5 years old 1,097 11.11 2.74 5.51 26.70 Percentage share (0–100)
Other controls Population share with unmet basic 1,103 53.85 19.44 9.20 100.00 Percentage share (0–100) DANE
needs, 1993
Violence. Number of attacks from 1,111 7.34 15.70 0.00 219.00 Number National Police
FARC, ELN and paramilitary groups
from 1998 to 2002
Central government investment. 1,111 178.67 306.60 0.00 2,609.27 Number NPD, 2003
Number of beneficiary families to the
national conditional cash transfer
program: Familias en acción
Acronyms: NPD refers to Colombian National Planning Department. DANE refers to the Colombian National Institute of Statistics. IGAC (Colombian
Geographical Institute Agustin Codazzy). FARC (The Revolutionary Armed Forces of Colombia). ELN (Colombian National Liberation Army). SGP
(Colombian central government transfers to municipalities).

Available online at www.sciencedirect.com

ScienceDirect

You might also like