You are on page 1of 16

Strategic Management Journal

Strat. Mgmt. J., 20: 655–670 (1999)

PRODUCT INNOVATION, PRODUCT–MARKET


COMPETITION AND PERSISTENT PROFITABILITY IN
THE U.S. PHARMACEUTICAL INDUSTRY
PETER W. ROBERTS*
Graduate School of Industrial Administration, Carnegie Mellon University, Pitts-
burgh, Pennsylvania, U.S.A.

Increasingly, strategy scholars are exploring the relationships between innovation, competition,
and the persistence of superior profits. Sustained high profitability may result when a firm
repeatedly introduces valuable innovations that service previously unmet consumer demands.
While the returns to the firm from each innovation may erode over time, innovation ensures
that, overall, the firm maintains a high performance position. At the same time, sustained high
profitability may also accrue to firms that innovate less often, but effectively avoid the
competition that otherwise erodes high returns. This paper elaborates these relationships before
presenting an empirical analysis of the effects of differential innovative propensities and
differential rates of competition on pharmaceutical firms’ abilities to sustain profit outcomes
that are above those earned by competing firms. The analysis, which is situated within the
U.S. pharmaceutical industry, finds support for the expected relationship between high innovative
propensity and sustained superior profitability, but no support for a link between persistence
and the ability to avoid competition. Copyright  1999 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd.

Strategy scholars are trying to understand the researchers observe considerable variance in the
factors that allow some (but not all) firms to extent to which abnormal profits persist over time
sustain relatively high profit levels over time (see also Hunt and Morgan, 1995). Following
(Hunt and Morgan, 1995; Jacobson, 1988; Porter, these observations, the task becomes one of
1985; Rumelt, 1991). Borrowing from industrial explaining the general tendency for relatively high
organization economics, the theories adhered to profits to fall back to normal levels, as well as the
suggest that, unless otherwise impeded, competi- factors which account for the interfirm variance in
tive forces should drive abnormally high profits profit persistence.
toward more normal levels (Jacobson, 1988; This paper develops and tests a framework for
Mueller, 1986; Rumelt, 1987, 1991). The problem firm-level profit persistence that embraces product
is that empirical research undertaken by persistent innovation, product–market competition and,
profitability researchers indicates that while more importantly, the prospect that numerous
abnormal profits do tend to dissipate over time, product innovations may be embodied within a
there are documented exceptions to this trend single firm. Formal recognition of this latter fact
(Mueller, 1986, 1990). Stated differently, opens the door to two competing explanations for
firm-level persistent profitability: an innovation
explanation and an anti-competition explanation
Key words: innovation; competition; persistent prof- (Roberts, forthcoming). While these two expla-
itability; sustained superior performance nations are juxtaposed for analytical purposes, it
*Correspondence to: Prof. Peter Roberts, Graduate is possible that both are operational to varying
School of Industrial Administration, Carnegie Mellon degrees. Firms may differ both in their propensity
University, Pittsburgh, PA 15213-3890, U.S.A. to innovate, as well as in their ability to sustain

CCC 0143–2095/99/070655–16 $17.50 Received 13 October 1996


Copyright  1999 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Final revision received 18 June 1998
656 P. W. Roberts

the competitive position of each innovation over and eventually fall off as competition intensifies,
time (Rumelt, 1987; Williams, 1992). he does not suggest that the profit profile of a
The next section describes how a coherent firm must necessarily follow the same course.
analysis of firm-level profit dynamics must recog- The direct connection between product-level com-
nize that firms represent evolving portfolios of petitive dynamics and firm-level profit dynamics
products. The framework that is presented indi- is severed if one allows for multiproduct firms.
cates how variability in the propensity to inno- Schumpeter (1950) himself argues that large firms
vate, as well as the ability to avoid competition, are responsible for a disproportionate share of
combine to explain why firms experience persis- innovative output. This conjecture has spawned a
tent profitability to differing degrees. The ensuing large volume of empirical research, the results of
sections present an empirical analysis of the which are mixed (see Cohen and Levin, 1989;
relationship between innovative propensity, Kamien and Schwartz, 1982). What is important
product–market competition, and firm-level per- for current purposes is not whether larger or
sistent profitability in the U.S. pharmaceutical smaller firms are more innovative per se, but
industry. More specifically, it demonstrates that rather the recognition that multiple innovations
profit persistence is evident in the U.S. pharma- may be embodied within a single firm. Extending
ceutical industry, but that it varies across firms. this, one expects that firms may introduce inno-
It also demonstrates that firms vary in the two vations at different points in their respective his-
key dimensions which are thought to affect the tories and that their profitability at any point in
degree of persistence: innovative propensity and time is related to each of the innovations that
the ability to avoid competition. Finally, the have been introduced. Those introduced recently
analysis quantifies the impact of innovative pro- may still be in relative monopoly positions while
pensity and the severity of competition on profit older products may be exposed to much greater
persistence. The findings provide support for a levels of competition.
relationship between high innovative propensity Therefore, researchers interested in firm-level
and sustained superior profitability. However, no persistent profitability need to go inside the firm
significant relationship is found between the and examine how the firms’ product portfolios
ability to avoid competition and persistent prof- change over time. The following paragraphs out-
itability. The closing section summarizes the line a dynamic framework which recognizes that
implications of the paper and points toward firms may differ in their propensity to generate
avenues for further research. valuable innovations, as well as their ability to
buffer those innovations from competition. In
other words, it is assumed that firms are hetero-
INNOVATION, COMPETITION AND geneous with respect to both of Schumpeter’s
PERSISTENT PROFITABILITY dynamics and that this explains the observed
pattern of firm-level persistent profitability.
An understanding of firm-level persistent prof- As suggested, relatively high profits flow from
itability must address two questions: Where do innovations (Geroski, Machin, and Van Reenen,
relatively high profits come from? and What fac- 1993). Once attained, high profits may persist in
tors operate in favor of their persistence (Mueller, one of two ways. According to an anti-
1986)? Schumpeter (1934, 1950) provides competition explanation, a firm may introduce an
answers to both questions (Nelson, 1986). An innovative product (or group of products) that is
innovative new product tends to face low compe- buffered from the competition that otherwise
tition at the point of introduction and therefore erodes the high profits associated with its intro-
earns relatively high profits. These high profits duction. This argument is consistent with the
attract imitators, which increase the level of com- position taken by industrial organization econo-
petition faced by the product as time passes. mists, whereby persistent profitability is thought
Finally, this increased competition translates into to imply anti-competitive (or entry-deterring)
reduced profits for the firm producing the new behavior on the part of firms. It is also consistent
product. with observations made by Williams (1992), who
Whereas Schumpeter suggests that the returns notes that some products depend on slow-cycle
to an innovative new product will be high initially resources and are isolated from the effects of
Copyright  1999 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Strat. Mgmt. J., 20: 655–670 (1999)
Innovation and Persistent Profitability 657

imitation for longer periods of time, and by of firm profits. Such a movement has already
Rumelt (1987) in his discussion of isolating occurred within the industrial organization eco-
mechanisms. nomics literature, spurred by scholars interested
On the other hand, an innovation explanation in the persistent profitability question. Mueller
recognizes that relatively high profits may persist (1986) suggests that the dynamic behavior of
at the firm level even though competition is firm profits may be examined by estimating the
relatively intense. In such a case, the excess autoregressive properties of the profit time series
profits associated with any single innovation are (see also Geroski, 1990):
transitory, but firms successfully introduce multi-
ple innovations over time. Whereas in the former ␲it = ␣ + ␤ × ␲it−1 + ⑀it (1)
case, persistent profitability accrues to firms with
unchanging product portfolios, these latter firms where ␲it is the relative profitability of firm i in
sustain above-normal profits with rapidly chang- year t: ␲it = (⌸it − ⌸avg,t )/⌸avg,t (⌸it is the profit
ing product portfolios. Note how this innovation rate of firm i in year t, and ⌸avg,t is the average
explanation is consistent with the following profit rate earned across all firms). As Geroski
description of Sony Corporation: (1990) explains, this autoregressive profit model
is a reduced-form representation of a more com-
After it introduces each new product, Sony plex dynamic model wherein high profits attract
experiences a rapid increase in sales and profits entry, which subsequently lowers profitability.
associated with that product. However, this leads Therefore, empirical findings which indicate a
other firms to reverse engineer the Sony product
and introduce their own version. Increased com- high degree of persistence are interpreted as evi-
petition leads the sales and profits associated dence of impediments to competitive entry.
with the new product to be reduced. Thus, at the In Equation (1), ␣ and ␤ jointly describe the
level of individual products introduced by Sony, dynamics of firm profits. The ␤ estimate (the
Sony apparently enjoys only very short-lived persistence parameter) indicates the rate at which
competitive advantages. However, by looking at
the total returns earned by Sony across all of its abnormal profits converge upon long-run levels.
products over time, the source of Sony’s sus- As shown in Figure 1, the path of profit conver-
tained competitive advantage becomes clear % gence depends critically on the range into which
Sony is able to constantly introduce new and the estimated value of ␤ falls. Eventual conver-
exciting personal electronics products. No one of gence is assured only when ␤ falls within the −1
these products generate a sustained competitive
advantage. However, over time, across several to +1 range. Parameter estimates outside of this
such product introductions, Sony’s capability range imply increasingly divergent profit out-
advantages do lead to a sustained competitive comes over time, an outcome that economic theo-
advantage. (Barney, 1995: 55) rists find problematic. Fortunately, in the vast
majority of previous studies, ␤ estimates fall
Development of an innovation explanation for within the 0 to +1 range. A ␤ estimate that
profit persistence is also supported by Montgom- is not significantly different from 1 indicates a
ery (1995: 263), who argues that strategy forestalling of the convergence process. In such
researchers have long overemphasized equilibrium cases, abnormal profits persist indefinitely. More
rents, paying less attention to ‘Schumpeterian generally, the higher is ␤, the more persistent are
rents, and resources and advantages that erode the abnormal profit outcomes.
through time.’ The ␣ and ␤ also combine to indicate the
level upon which firm profits converge in the
long run. If the long run is the point at which
PERSISTENT PROFITABILITY period-to-period changes in profitability cease,
RESEARCH then an indicator of the long-run rate of return
( ␲lr ) may be obtained by setting ␲it equal to
The impetus for this research stems from a desire ␲it-1 (Schohl, 1990: 391): ␲lr = ␣ /(1-␤ ). When
to understand the dynamics of firm-level prof- ␲lr is not significantly different from zero, high
itability. It is therefore necessary to move away and low profits converge upon normal levels in
from cross-sectional analysis and towards a the long run. Conversely, an estimate that is
method that captures the intertemporal behavior significantly greater than zero indicates that
Copyright  1999 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Strat. Mgmt. J., 20: 655–670 (1999)
658 P. W. Roberts

Figure 1. Four possible time paths of the normalized profit series adapted from Schohl (1990)

firms earn relatively high profits, even into the


Modeling the effects of innovation and
long run.
competition
Equation (1) is the modal approach taken by
persistent profitability researchers (e.g., Geroski Persistent high profitability may be linked to a
and Jacquemin, 1988; Mueller, 1986; Schohl, firm’s ability to innovate. In such a case, one
1990; Waring, 1996). In this analysis, industry- expects abnormally high profits to demonstrate
wide and firm-specific regressions are estimated. greater persistence and converge upon higher
In the industry-wide regression, the ␣ and ␤ long-run levels if the extent of innovation is
coefficients are forced to be the same across all higher over the sample period. More formally,
firms. Estimation uses the information contained we hypothesize that:
in all the firms’ profit time-series to characterize
overall industry profit dynamics. These results Hypothesis 1a: Profit persistence ( ␤ ) is posi-
are complemented by examining profit dynamics tively related to firm innovative propensity.
in regressions wherein the ␣ and ␤ estimates are
allowed to vary across firms. These regressions Hypothesis 1b: Long-run profit rates ( ␣ /1−␤ )
identify those firms for which persistence and are positively related to firm innovative pro-
long-run profit levels are different from overall pensity.
average. Finally, note that Equation (1) exam-
ines the path of convergence followed by all The above framework also leads us to expect
abnormal profit outcomes, including those that that differences in the extent to which innovative
are below normal. However, the discussion in new products are buffered against competition
the preceding section refers to the persistence explain some of the variance in firm-level profit
of above-normal profit outcomes. It says persistence. More specifically, more intense com-
`
nothing about expectations vis-a-vis the petition faced by innovative products over time
dynamic path taken by abnormally low profits should lead to less profit persistence and lower
(this is not to say that the persistence of below- long-run profit levels:
normal returns is not an interesting topic of
study). As such, a variant of Equation (1) is Hypothesis 2a: Profit persistence ( ␤ ) is nega-
estimated using only those observations for tively related to competition intensity at the
which ␲it−1 is greater than zero. product level.
Copyright  1999 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Strat. Mgmt. J., 20: 655–670 (1999)
Innovation and Persistent Profitability 659

Hypothesis 2b: Long-run profit rates ( ␣ /1−␤ ) after-tax return on assets (ROA) as a measure of
are negatively related to competition intensity firm-level profitability. According to Scherer and
at the product level. Ross (1990: 416), ‘profit is the surplus of revenue
over cost, including the cost of attracting capital
These four hypotheses refer to the effects of from other uses.’ Although ideal measures are
innovative propensity and competition intensity difficult to attain, they suggest three ‘second-best’
on the persistence of abnormal firm-level profits. profitability measures: accounting rates of return
We test for such effects by estimating an elabo- (e.g., ROA), Tobin’s q ratio, and the price–cost
rated version of Equation (1): margin. The correlations between accounting rates
of return and Tobin’s q are typically quite high
␲it = ␣ + ␣1 × INi + ␣2 × LCi + ␤ × ␲it−1 + (2) and ‘neither measure is innately superior to the
other in detecting supra-competitive profits’
␤1 × INi × ␲it−1 + ␤2 × LCi × ␲it− 1 + ⑀it
(Scherer and Ross, 1990: 417). Mueller (1990)
agrees, suggesting that the primary difference
where INi reflects a firm’s innovative propensity,
between the two is that Tobin’s q tends to capture
and LCi captures a firm’s ability to avoid compe-
future economic returns, while ROA measures
tition (the operationalization of these variables is
only current returns. The goal of this research is
discussed in the next section). Equation (2)
to analyze the period-to-period dynamics of cur-
allows for tests of whether these variables have
rent profitability that are attributable to innovative
a significant impact on the ␣ and ␤ estimates
propensity and product–market competition. As
from Equation (1). More specifically, Hypothesis
such, it is not desirable to have current and future
1a (2a) suggests that ␤1 ( ␤2 ) should be positive,
returns confounded in the same profit measure.
while Hypothesis 1b (2b) implies positive esti-
As such, ROA (defined as the ratio of net income
mates for ␣1 ( ␣2 ).
to total assets) is preferred as the measure of
firm profitability. In support of this decision, note
that accounting rates of return are used exten-
DATA AND ANALYSIS
sively by scholars examining the dynamics of
firm profitability.1
The pharmaceutical industry is an ideal site for
this research. Questions about the sources of per- 1
Much of the concern about using accounting rates of returns
sistent above-normal pharmaceutical firm prof- to indicate economic profitability relates to accountants’
itability have dominated academic debates decisions to expense, rather than capitalize R&D and advertis-
(Comanor, 1986). Moreover, discussion about ing expenditures (Brownlee, 1979; Scherer and Ross, 1990).
Because these expenditures contribute to the development of
pharmaceutical industry competition inevitably a firm’s intangible asset base, the argument is that they should
points to the inadequacy of static models of price be capitalized and subsequently expensed according to an
competition and to the need for analysis to be appropriate depreciation schedule. This issue is critical to the
measurement of pharmaceutical firm profitability because R&D
grounded in dynamic notions of product compe- and advertising outlays represent a very large component of
tition (Cocks, 1975; Comanor, 1986). Finally, overall expenditures. Those attempting to revise reported rates
Henderson (1994) argues that, given the role that of return in accordance with this concern explain away a
great portion of the pharmaceutical industry’s abnormally high
innovation has always played in the pharmaceu- profits (e.g., Schwartzman, 1976). There are several responses
tical industry, such firms should serve as models to this concern. First, the ability to explain away interindustry
for firms in other industries who must compete in profit differentials is not universal. Menga and Mueller (1991),
for example, find that considerable differences remain even
increasingly dynamic competitive environments. after accounting for differential R&D and advertising propen-
Before proceeding, it is necessary to address sities. Second, the assumptions made about the economic
the issues of measuring firm profitability and lives of R&D and advertising investments and about their
depreciation profiles are, to a large degree, arbitrary (Clarkson,
normal profitability. Debates about performance 1979: 119). This suggests that although revised rates of
measurement are found in the strategy literature return may be different than those reported in firms’ financial
(Venkatraman and Ramanujam, 1986), the eco- statements, they are not necessarily more accurate in any
absolute sense. Third, most of the discussion on this issue
nomics literature (Scherer and Ross, 1990), and has been in the context of interindustry profitability compari-
the pharmaceutical economics literature sons. The current interest, however, is in intraindustry profit
(Schwartzman, 1976). While recognizing the comparisons. To the extent that the firm-to-firm variance in
R&D and advertising propensities is likely lower within,
importance of such debates, the primary aim of as opposed to across, industries, the above concern is not
the following comments is to provide support for as significant.

Copyright  1999 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Strat. Mgmt. J., 20: 655–670 (1999)
660 P. W. Roberts

Equations (1) and (2) model the autoregressive criterion. Although a large number of products
properties of normalized profit series. Mueller are not included, the sampled products account
(1986) argues for the necessity to control for for more than 95 percent of total U.S. pharmaceu-
overall economic trends in order to capture the tical sales in any one year.
extent to which firms earn persistent abnormal At the firm level, annual accounting data (net
returns. That is, abnormal should be specified in income and total assets) describing publicly-
relation to some indicator of normal profits. In traded pharmaceutical firms are available from
all preceding persistent profitability research, the Compustat (for U.S.-listed companies) and
samples were comprised of firms from a number GlobalScope (for non-U.S.-listed companies) data
of different industries. As such, each researcher bases. Uninterrupted time series of data (ranging
used some measure of economy-wide average from 5 to 17 years) were available for 42 firms
profitability as the indicator of normal profits. that were in the top 40 (according to U.S.
However, the same group of researchers also pharmaceutical sales) in any one of the sampled
distinguish between economy-wide average, years. These firms were responsible for 1070 new
industry average, and firm-specific returns product introductions over the 1977–93 period.
(Cubbin and Geroski, 1987; Mueller, 1986; The remaining products in the above data file
Rumelt, 1991; Waring, 1996). While certain were either introduced by nonsampled firms,
elements of industry structure (Porter, 1985) are introduced prior to 1977, or did not report intro-
hypothesized to cause industry returns to deviate duction dates.
from the economy-wide average, these effects are
distinguishable from those factors that cause firm-
Innovative propensity
level returns to deviate from their respective
industry averages (Grant, 1991). This research is Hypotheses 1a and 1b posit a relationship
interested in the extent to which pharmaceutical between innovative propensity and profit persis-
firms earn profits that are persistently higher than tence. This section describes an approach that
those earned by competing pharmaceutical firms. generates the innovative propensity variable (INi ).
As such, the measure of normal profitability As suggested above, the firms in this study
(asset-weighted average ROA across the sampled brought a total of 1070 new drug products to
firms) used is an intraindustry measure (see War- market during the sample period. However, not
ing, 1996). all of these drugs should be considered inno-
vative; new pharmaceutical products range from
being highly innovative at one extreme to highly
Data
imitative at the other (Kemp, 1975). Following
The analysis combines data collected at the firm this observation, an approach is required that
level with that collected at the product level. The identifies a subset of more innovative new drug
product-level data are supplied by Intercontinental
Medical Statistics America (IMS), who have col-
lected pharmaceutical product data for at least 2
The following table illustrates the market structure used by
the last 30 years (data from 1977 through 1993 IMS to organize their pharmaceutical products data. As the
are used in this analysis). These IMS data include table shows, products are organized into a hierarchical struc-
the year of product introduction, annual product ture that is similar to the Standard Industrial Classification
system that is used to organize firms into industries:
sales, therapeutic market (and submarket) mem- 30000 Cancer/Transplant Therapy
bership, and total therapeutic market (and 30100 %
submarket) sales.2 In any year, a pharmaceutical 30200 %
30300 %
firm may sell in excess of 100 different drug 31000 Cardiovascular Therapy
products. Moreover, a firm’s portfolios of prod- 31100 Antihypertensive Drugs
ucts change from one year to the next. In order 31110 %
31120 %
to keep the project manageable, only those prod- 31130 %
ucts that achieved at least $1 million in sales in 31140 Ace Inhibitors
some year during the sample period (i.e., all 31141 Ace Inhibitors, Alone
(Submarket)
significant product offerings) are considered. A 31142 Ace Inhibitors with Diuretic
total of 4914 drug products meet this sampling (Submarket)

Copyright  1999 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Strat. Mgmt. J., 20: 655–670 (1999)
Innovation and Persistent Profitability 661

introductions. The one taken herein involves and will have a smaller impact on Herfindahl and
examining the products’ initial market shares: entropy measures (which assign lower weightings
to lower-share incumbents).
MSj0 = (SALj0 /MKTSALj0 ) × 100 There may, however, be some concern that
initial market share is not a clean indicator of
where SALj0 is the sales of product j in its first the innovativeness of a new product. In their
full year on the market, and MKTSALj0 is the study of the factors that influence new product
sales of all products within the same therapeutic success in the pharmaceutical industry, Gatignon,
submarket in that same year (see footnote 2).3 Weitz, and Bansal (1990) found that the initial
Products introduced with relatively high initial market share of a new drug is affected by, among
market shares are considered more innovative. other things, the detailing efforts of the introduc-
Initial market shares range from 100 when a ing firm. Because we take market-based (and not
product is introduced into a true monopoly posi- a technology-based) approach to innovation, it is
tion (i.e., no other products possess sufficiently not inconsistent that an innovator may undertake
similar attributes to be considered competitors) activities such as product detailing or advertising
to zero when the sales of all competitors dwarf to enhance the perceived attractiveness of the
its own sales. In this respect, the two extremes differentiated new offering (Kirzner, 1973; Pen-
of the initial market share continuum correspond rose, 1959: 80). Moreover, Gatignon et al. (1990)
precisely to the above notions of extremely low stress that demand conditions within the pharma-
and extremely intense competition. Moreover, ceutical industry are such that, all else equal,
there is a broader correspondence between the relative price has little impact on the initial mar-
initial market share of a new product and its ket share of a new drug product (see also
impact on market-level competition measures. Gorecki, 1986). This suggests that pharmaceutical
Previous attempts to operationalize competition firms have little scope to gain significant initial
levels have looked at indicators of market concen- market shares without some degree of actual
tration, such as three-, four-, or eight-firm concen- product differentiation, or product innovativeness
tration ratios, Herfindahl indices, or entropy meas- (Robinson, 1990). However, in light of the find-
ures of concentration (Jacquemin, 1987). Linking ings of Gatignon et al. (1990), we bias our
with this research, an innovative new product categorization of innovative towards the
may be considered one that reduces the overall extremely high end of the initial market share dis-
level of competition experienced within a market, tribution.
and thereby increases reported concentration lev- The next task is to set the cut-off MSj0 level
els. Because each of these concentration measures that distinguishes the innovative products in our
is calculated based on the market shares of sample. According to an oft-cited Booz, Allen
incumbent products, it follows that a new product and Hamilton survey of new product introduc-
with a higher initial market share will exert a tions, roughly 10 percent of all products intro-
more positive impact on observed concentration duced to the market may be considered ‘new-to-
levels. On the other hand, a new product with a the-world’ products (cf. Ali, 1994). The 90th
very low initial market share may not figure into percentile of the initial market share (MSj0 ) distri-
three-, four-, or eight-firm concentration ratios, bution for all products in the product-level data
file is 15.6 percent. As such, innovative products
3
According to Schumpeter, innovative new products are intro- are those introduced with market shares in excess
duced to relatively low levels of competition. One way to of 15.6 percent. Using this approach, 145 of the
assess the initial level of competition is to take a highly 1070 products introduced by the sampled firms
restricted view of what constitutes a product’s competitors.
Within the pharmaceutical industry, patents are available and are innovative.
are generally found to be effective (Levin et al., 1987). Under Returning to the above comment on the market
such a regime, one may consider only those products that are share ranking of these products (with higher-
generic versions of the focal product to be its competitors.
However, such an approach may not adequately capture the ranked products having a greater impact on meas-
nature of product competition. As Weston (1979: 93) suggests, ures of market concentration), each of the 145
‘the appearance of similar drugs introduces competition before innovative products is introduced into one of the
the expiry of the seventeen-year patent period.’ To the extent
that such claims are valid, assuming that the only competition top three rankings in its submarket, with the
for products comes from direct copies is erroneous. median product occupying the top position. On
Copyright  1999 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Strat. Mgmt. J., 20: 655–670 (1999)
662 P. W. Roberts

the other hand, only 12.8 percent of the remaining innovative products into an indicator of inno-
products occupy one of the top three rankings, vative propensity (see Table 1). Firms with rela-
with the median product occupying the ninth tively high innovative propensities should derive
position in its first full year on the market. This a greater proportion of their sales from innovative
suggests that every one of the innovative new products. In each year, we compute the ratio of
products would exert some positive influence on innovative product sales to total pharmaceutical
the three-, four-, and eight-product concentration sales for each firm before subtracting the corre-
ratios, while the median imitator product would sponding industry average. The innovative pro-
not figure in any of these measures of market pensity of each firm is then indicated by its
concentration. Linking with Dranove and Melt- average of this ratio calculated across the years
zer’s (1994) market importance indicator, we find for which the firm is in the sample (a value of
(not surprisingly) that the innovative products zero suggests that the firm in question demon-
have average annual sales of $71.7 million, strates average innovative propensity). Using this
roughly six times greater than the $12.1 million approach, Amgen, Glaxo, Pfizer, Merck, and
average for the remaining products. Finally, in Marion Merrell Dow are the most innovative
response to concerns that this list of innovative firms, while Forest, Boots, Genentech, Boehringer
products may contain (successful) generic copies Mannheim, and Allergan are the least innovative.
of existing therapies, we obtained a copy of an
FOI Services, Inc. publication entitled The NDA
Avoiding competition
Book (FOI Services, 1996). This source provides
information on roughly 28,000 drugs that have Hypotheses 2a and 2b relate the intensity of
been approved by the U.S. Food and Drug competition faced by a firm’s innovative new
Administration since 1938. More specifically, it
indexes each drug according to its trade name,
as well as its generic name. We located 80 of Table 1. Innovative propensitya
the innovative products in the trade name index.
Of these, 79 were either the only product having Maximum 0.70 (Amgen)
its specific generic name, or the first product Minimum −0.29 (Allergan)
introduced to the market with that specific generic Average −0.06
name. This suggests that roughly 98 percent of Firms with above- Amgen, Glaxo, Pfizer,
average innovative Merck, Marion Merrell
the innovative product introductions are not ge- propensity Dow, Miles, ICI, Squibb,
neric copies of products already sold on the SmithKline Beecham,
market (in the only other case, the preceding Hoescht, Johnson &
product with the same generic name was intro- Johnson, Wellcome,
duced by the same firm). These data do not Cooper, Schering-Plough,
Ciba-Geigy
necessarily indicate that all of these innovative Firms with below- Sterling Drug, Searle,
products were radically different from existing average innovative Lyphomed, Warner-
offerings at the time that they were introduced. propensity Lambert, Key, Lilly,
They do, however, suggest that the initial market- American Cyanamid,
share approach to identifying innovative new Abbott, Robins, Bristol
Myers Squibb, Syntex,
drugs does not arbitrarily pick up undifferentiated Pennwalt, Thompson,
generic competitors. As a comparison, we also Procter & Gamble,
located 103 of the 145 new products that were American Home Products,
introduced with the lowest initial market shares. Upjohn, Rhone-Poulenc
Only 28 percent of these products were either Rorer, Carter-Wallace,
Sandoz, Block, Fisons,
the only product having its specific generic name, Roche, Forest, Boots,
or the first product introduced to the market Genentech, Boehringer
with that specific generic name. This comparison Mannheim, Allergan
suggests that the large majority of products with
very low initial market shares are generic copies Source: IMS America
a
Average across years in sample of the share of total sales
of products already on the market. coming from innovative products relative to corresponding
The final task is to turn this categorization of industry average.

Copyright  1999 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Strat. Mgmt. J., 20: 655–670 (1999)
Innovation and Persistent Profitability 663

products over time to profit persistence. This attention to issues surrounding the order-of-entry
section describes the market share approach that question (e.g., Lieberman and Montgomery, 1988;
is used to generate the low-competition (LCi ) Robinson, Kalyanaram and Urban, 1994). This
variable. Just as innovative was operationalized research tends to focus on the costs and benefits
with reference to the initial market share of a of market pioneering versus those associated with
new product, the intensity of competition faced later entry. At a conceptual level, Lieberman and
by a new product over time is operationalized Montgomery (1988) note that first movers may
with reference to the average market share change be advantaged over later entrants because of their
over its term on the market.4 More specifically, technological leadership position, their ability to
we calculate the slope of the regression line preempt valuable assets, and/or their ability to
relating market share to elapsed time ( ␭1 ) for establish consumer switching costs. Empirically,
each new product: there is considerable evidence—including some
from the pharmaceutical industry (Gorecki, 1986;
MSjt = ␭0 + ␭1 × ELAPSEjt + ⑀it (3) Grabowski and Vernon, 1992)—that ‘market pio-
neers tend to maintain market share advantages
where MSjt is defined as above and ELAPSEjt is over later entrants’ (Robinson et al., 1994: 2).
the number of years between year t and the Order-of-entry researchers are concerned with
product’s first full year on the market. One the extent to which advantageous market positions
expects qualitatively different relationships are sustained over time, but have tended to look
between the intensity of competition faced by a exclusively at market share dynamics. Our analy-
product (as indicated by its market share change) sis goes one step further by relating a firm’s
and elapsed time for the different types of product ability to sustain advantageous product–market
introductions. Assuming that Schumpeter’s con- positions with its firm-level profit dynamics.
jecture about innovative products holds, imitating Tying these two approaches together, Lieberman
products serve to increase the level of competition and Montgomery (1988) remind scholars that
faced by innovative new products. That is, suc- order-of-entry research is ultimately concerned
cessful imitators move from having no market with the profit implications of moving first into
presence at all to establishing (often small) foot- markets and sustaining the associated benefits.
holds for themselves as time passes. Data limitations have tended to preclude the use
Across all products, the average slope of the of profitability as a dependent variable and
regression line relating market share to elapsed researchers tend to employ market share and/or
time is not significantly different from zero. How- firm survival. Similarly, Robinson et al. (1994)
ever, a t-test confirms that the average slope note that the combination of the entry order–
estimates differ significantly across the two types market share results and the market share–
of products. Innovative products tend to experi- profitability results attest to a positive relationship
ence erosion in their market shares as time between market pioneering and firm profitability.5
elapses, while imitative products tend to make By construction, the innovative products in this
slight gains. Before examining how the erosion study are introduced with relatively high market
rates for innovative products vary across firms, shares. The question now is to determine whether
we first note the correspondence between this the sampled firms are differentially able to sustain
approach to operationalizing changes in compe-
tition and research examining first-mover advan- 5
This study stops short of fully addressing the entry timing
tage. Researchers have devoted considerable issue as the products have not been explicitly identified as
pioneers, early followers or late followers. Rather, it may be
assumed that pioneering products are those with high initial
4
Note that it was not feasible to use a count of subsequent market shares, while followers are the lower share entrants.
product introductions as an indicator of the extent of compe- This empirical strategy is necessary because IMS’s therapeutic
tition as we do not have data for all products introduced markets have, in most cases, longer lives than each generation
during the sample time period (i.e., those that failed to reach of pharmaceutical products that they subsume. Future research
the $1 million annual sales threshold are excluded). Including may examine the evolution of specific therapeutic markets in
all of these products would have dramatically increased the order to determine the dynamic relationship between the
resources required for data entry. However, IMS does provide innovative products that have been identified and the various
data on total therapeutic market sales, which ensures that classes of follower products (including imitators). With more
these products, although not represented individually, are rep- precise timing data in hand, one would be in a better position
resented in the denominator of the market share figure. to examine the order-of-entry questions.

Copyright  1999 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Strat. Mgmt. J., 20: 655–670 (1999)
664 P. W. Roberts

the market share advantages associated with prod- RESULTS


uct innovation. Relatively speaking, firms with
greater average ␭1 estimates (for their innovative Across the 515 observations, the mean value of
products) are better at avoiding competition. ␲it is 0.20, while the minimum and maximum
Although the market shares accruing to innovative values are −2.74 and 2.24, respectively. This
products tend to decrease as time elapses, Table suggests that the observed profit outcomes range
2 demonstrates that firms are differentially able from roughly 275 percent below the weighted
to preserve the benefits associated with product industry average to roughly 225 percent above.
innovation. ICI, Sandoz, Glaxo, Searle, and Syn- For the 308 high profit observations (those for
tex experience relatively large gains in the market which lagged normalized profit is positive), the
shares of their innovative products as time elapses mean, minimum, and maximum values are 0.54,
and are considered relatively good at avoiding −2.74, and 2.24, respectively. Table 4 presents
competition. At the other extreme, market share the results from regressions run on Equation (1).
erosion is most rapid for Lilly, Squibb, Roche, The first column is based on all observations.
Wellcome, and Rhone-Poulenc Rorer. This com- The persistence parameter ( ␤ ) is significantly less
pletes the discussion of the dependent and inde- than 1, indicating that relatively high and low
pendent variables used in this study (Table 3 profit outcomes do eventually dissipate. At the
provides a brief summary). same time, the long-run profit estimate is signifi-
cantly greater than zero, suggesting that abnormal
firm-level ROA tends toward a long-run rate that
is greater than the weighted industry average. The
results change somewhat when focus is placed
exclusively on the relatively high profit outcomes.
The second column of Table 4 shows that the
Table 2. Average relationship between market share
and elapsed time (innovative product-specific
regressions)a
Table 3. Summary of variables and coefficients
Maximum 4.52 (ICI)
Minimum −15.74 (Rhone Poulenc Variables and Symbol Description
Rorer) coefficients
Average −2.16
Firms with above- ICI, Sandoz, Glaxo, Normalized profit ␲it Firm ROA less
average ability to avoid Searle, Syntex, American rate weighted industry
competition Home Products, Pfizer, average ROA divided
Sterling, Hoescht, Abbott, by weighted industry
Procter & Gamble, Fisons, average ROA
Schering-Plough, Lag of ␲it−1
Johnson & Johnson, normalized profit
Lyphomed, Marion Merrell rate
Dow, Cooper Innovative INi Relative proportion of
Firms with below- Merck, Robins, Bayer, propensity firm pharmaceutical
average ability to avoid Warner-Lambert, Bristol sales derived from
competition Myers Squibb, Amgen, innovative new products
Ciba-Geigy, Upjohn, (see discussion
SmithKline Beecham, surrounding Table 1)
American Cyanamid, Lilly, Low competition LCi Extent to which
Squibb, Roche, Wellcome, innovative products
Rhone-Poulenc Rorer avoid market share
Firms with no Allergan, Genentech, erosion over time (see
innovative products Boehringer Mannheim, discussion surrounding
Boots, Forest, Block, Table 2)
Carter-Wallace, Thompson, Persistence ␤1 Higher persistence as
Pennwalt, Key parameter ␤1 approaches 1
Long-run profit ␲lr =
a
Coeffficients not available for products with less than 2 years rate ␣1 /1−␤1
of data.

Copyright  1999 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Strat. Mgmt. J., 20: 655–670 (1999)
Innovation and Persistent Profitability 665
Table 4. Results from autoregressive profits models Table 5. Effects of innovative propensity and compe-
(standard errors in parentheses) tition on profit dynamics (standard errors in
parentheses)
All High
observations profits All High
observations profits
Constant 0.07a 0.04
(0.02) (0.04) Constant 0.07a 0.09a
Lagged profits ( ␲it−1 ) 0.70 0.87 (0.02) (0.04)
(0.03) (0.05) High innovation (INi ) 0.17 0.68a
N 515 308 (0.15) (0.26)
Adjusted R2 0.54 0.51 Low competition (LCi ) 0.00 −0.00
Long-run profits ( ␲lr ) 0.23a 0.31b (0.01) (0.01)
(0.07) (0.20) Lagged profits ( ␲it−1 ) 0.73a 0.84a
(0.03) (0.05)
a
p⬍0.01; bp⬍0.10 INi × ␲it−1 0.71a −0.32
(0.16) (0.26)
LCi × ␲it−1 0.01 0.02
(0.01) (0.02)
degree of persistence of relatively high profits is
a
greater than that for relatively low profits. In p⬍0.01; bp⬍0.10
addition, the level upon which profits converge
in the long run is significantly greater than zero
for high profit outcomes. Comparing across col- persistence parameter is significant. At the same
umns, high profits tend to converge at a slower time, the low competition variable exerts no sig-
rate (the persistence parameter equals 0.87 vs. nificant effect on either the constant term or the
0.70) toward slightly higher long-run levels (the persistence parameter. The results in the second
long-run profit rate equals 0.31 vs. 0.23) than do column are from the model which isolates the
all profits taken together. relatively high lagged profit outcomes. This time,
Next, the model’s parameter estimates are the model’s intercept term is positively and sig-
allowed to vary across firms, and the firm-specific nificantly affected by innovative propensity. How-
␣ and ␤ estimates are combined to calculate ever, the persistence parameter decreases (albeit
estimates of each firm’s long-run profit rate not significantly) if a firm is highly innovative.
( ␣ /1−␤ ). Separate F-tests reject the equality of Once again, no significant effects are found for
the ␣ and ␤ estimates across firms, confirming the low competition variable.
that there is significant variance across firms in Table 6 gauges the overall effects of innovative
the extent to which abnormal profit outcomes propensity on the long-run profit rate estimate
persist over time. More specifically, 10 firms (which is a function of both the intercept term
return long-run profit estimates that are signifi- and the persistence parameter). The upper row
cantly greater than zero (p⬍0.10), while eight represents the long-run profit rate of a
firms return estimates that are significantly less
than zero. Similar results were obtained from the
Table 6. The effects of innovative propensity on long-
regression which isolates the high profit obser- run profits
vations. Once again, separate F-tests reject the
equality of the ␣ and ␤ estimates across firms. All High
This time, all but one of the firms report long- observations profits
run profit estimates that are greater then zero. In
12 cases, these positive estimates are significant. High innovationa 0.40 0.73
Results from models testing for the effects of Low innovationb 0.08 −0.22
Difference −0.32 −0.96
innovative propensity and competition intensity
are found in Table 5. The results in the first a
One standard deviation above the mean of the innovative
column treat all profit observations symmetrically. propensity variable evaluated at the mean of the low compe-
Relatively high innovative propensity increases tition variable.
b
One standard deviation below the mean of the innovative
the constant term, but the increase is not sta- propensity variable evaluated at the mean of the low compe-
tistically significant. However, the increase in the tition variable.

Copyright  1999 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Strat. Mgmt. J., 20: 655–670 (1999)
666 P. W. Roberts

(hypothetical) firm that is one standard deviation vative propensities across competing firms. There
above the mean of the innovative propensity vari- are also positive correlations between long-run
able, evaluated at the mean of the low compe- profit rates and the firms’ ability to avoid compe-
tition variable. The lower row repeats this calcu- tition; the correlation in the high profits case
lation, this time for a firm that is one standard being significant at a 0.10 level of significance.
deviation below the mean of the innovative pro-
pensity variable (again, evaluated at the mean of
the low competition variable). Using the results DISCUSSION AND CONCLUSION
based on all observations, we see that the long-
run profit rate falls from 0.40 to roughly 0.08 as This analysis clearly demonstrates that innovative
the firm moves from the upper to the lower end propensity influences the extent to which abnor-
of the innovative propensity variable. Considering mal profit outcomes persist over time. This is
only the high-profit observations, the long-run consistent with a theoretical framework within
profit rate falls from 0.73 to −0.22. These results which high innovative propensity yields a series
provide support for the hypotheses relating inno- of temporary monopoly positions at the product
vative propensity to firm-level profit persistence. level which, when aggregated to the firm level,
Long-run profit levels and the rates at which translate into persistent profitability (see also
abnormally high profits converge on those levels D’Aveni, 1994). On the other hand, the ability
are both influenced by innovative propensity. to avoid competition implies a stronger corre-
However, there is little empirical support for the spondence between product-level competitive
avoiding competition hypotheses. dynamics and firm-level profit dynamics, yielding
The practical significance of the innovation an explanation for firm-level persistent prof-
findings is demonstrated in Figure 2, which illus- itability that mirrors the monopoly-based argu-
trates the (hypothetical) paths of convergence for ments popular within industrial organization eco-
the above-average and below-average innovative nomics. However, the analysis provides very
firms from Table 6. Using the parameter estimates weak support for the anti-competition thesis as
based on all observations, an ROA outcome that the coefficients on the low-competition variables
is 224 percent above average in year 1 (i.e., the were insignificant in both regression models.6 The
highest in our sample of profit observations) only significant supporting finding is a positive
erodes rather quickly if the firm in question is correlation between a firm’s ability to avoid com-
not highly innovative. However, if the firm dem- petition and the persistence of its above-normal
onstrates above-average innovative propensity, profit outcomes (see Table 7).
abnormal profits demonstrate a much higher This research complements the resource-based
degree of persistence. That firm is still earning perspective that is gaining prominence within the
returns that are 110 percent above average in strategy literature. Although we present concep-
year 5, and 60 percent above average in year 10. tual arguments and empirical evidence relating a
The lower panel of Figure 2 demonstrates that firm’s innovative propensity and (to a much lesser
similar time path differences are observed if we extent) its ability to avoid competition to the
use parameter estimates that are based on the evolution of its financial performance over time,
high profit observations only. we say very little about the precise nature of the
Table 7 shifts to the firm level to demonstrate underlying firm capabilities that support inno-
how persistently profitable firms are distinguished vation and/or slow competition. In this sense, the
from their less successful counterparts by their framework deals with only part of the overall
innovative propensities and their ability to avoid
competition. There are positive and significant 6
In respect of the surprising null result for the competition
correlations between long-run profit rates and firm hypotheses, we reran the analysis using several different
innovative propensity scores (based on all obser- specifications of the low competition variable (including one
based on market share changes experienced by all new prod-
vations, as well as high profit-only observations). ucts, and one that controlled for the initial market share level
These findings corroborate the overall regression of each innovative new product). We also tried a specification
results in Tables 5 and 6 and provide further based on product market concentration ratios (a more tra-
ditional measure of market-level competition intensity). How-
support that persistent profitability in the pharma- ever, the null result for the competition hypothesis was repli-
ceutical industry is driven by the differential inno- cated across each of these specifications.

Copyright  1999 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Strat. Mgmt. J., 20: 655–670 (1999)
Innovation and Persistent Profitability 667

Figure 2. Normalized profit series for above-normal and below-normal innovative firms

problem of understanding firm-level persistent ations, component competence (i.e., unique disci-
profitability. In addition to calling for an exten- plinary expertise), and architectural competence
sion of this research project, it is useful to refer (the ability to access and integrate various types
to other research that illuminates the missing of expertise). In addition, Gatignon et al. (1990)
pieces of the framework. Henderson and suggest that the impact of a relatively innovative
Cockburn (1994, 1996) present the results of new drug may be enhanced by the detailing
research which tries to understand the causes of efforts of the introducing firm. If these insights
relatively high innovative propensity among U.S. are combined with the current findings, one
pharmaceutical firms. The factors that these may begin to trace the path from a firm’s
authors look to include firm size, scope of oper- innovative capabilities through its innovative
Copyright  1999 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Strat. Mgmt. J., 20: 655–670 (1999)
668 P. W. Roberts
Table 7. Innovation, competition and long-run prof- high innovation rates of incumbent pharmaceu-
itability by firm (correlations) tical firms. The findings of this research, which
come from a firm-level (not an industry-level)
All High
N observations profits analysis of profit persistence, suggest that such a
bifurcated debate may miss the true nature of the
Innovative 42 0.45a 0.40b phenomenon. Because pharmaceutical firms differ
propensity in the extent to which they develop valuable
Avoiding 26 0.13 0.32b product innovations and resist competition, one
competition should be wary of simplistic either/or expla-
a
p⬍0.01; bp⬍0.10
nations of pharmaceutical firm profitability
(having said this, there is much stronger empirical
support for the innovation argument).
outputs to the persistence of its above-normal As it stands, this project only makes limited
profit outcomes. and indirect inferences about interindustry profit
Having said this, one should be cautious not differentials, as it looks at the extent to which
to expect the innovative capability–innovation– intraindustry differences in profit persistence are
persistent profitability path to be followed in all attributable to differential innovation and compe-
cases. Superior financial performance results from tition rates across firms. Therefore, the analysis
the more-or-less temporary monopoly positions itself cannot explain the observed differences
that correspond with the introduction of valuable between pharmaceutical and non-pharmaceutical
innovations to the market. It is sustained at the industry profit dynamics. However, the logic that
firm level only when innovation is repeated or is used to understand intraindustry profit differen-
when competition is weak. However, a valuable tials may be extended to understand interindustry
product innovation may arise as the result of an differentials. In several places, it has been sug-
underlying innovative capability, or it may be the gested that pharmaceutical firm innovation rates
result of a chance event. Similarly, competition tend to be higher than corresponding rates for
may be avoided because a firm systematically nonpharmaceutical firms (e.g., Henderson, 1994).
applies an isolating capability, or because it was It has also been argued that—because of demand
fortunate enough to stumble upon an innovation characteristics and/or a more effective patent
that resists competitor imitation. A firm might regime (Caves, Whinston, and Hurwitz, 1991;
therefore be persistently profitable although it Mansfield, Schwartz, and Wagner, 1981)—
lacks any underlying, valuable capabilities, its competitor imitation may be less intense within
performance being due to the interaction of two the pharmaceutical industry than without. If either
chance events. (or both) of these conjectures stand up to empiri-
This research also makes contributions to the cal scrutiny, one may generate a Schumpeterian
pharmaceutical economics literature. Treating explanation of interindustry differences in profit
pharmaceutical firms as evolving portfolios of persistence. Profit persistence may be greater
products generates a framework that jointly within the pharmaceutical industry because
embraces the innovation and monopoly arguments pharmaceutical firms tend to be more innovative
that have been put forth as explanations of the and/or better able to resist competition than their
persistently high profits earned in the pharmaceu- nonpharmaceutical counterparts. This suggests a
tical industry (Comanor, 1986). Moreover, we valuable line of further inquiry.
provide empirical evidence that contributes to the In closing, we offer several extensions to this
ongoing debates about persistently high pharma- research. First, the discussion surrounding the
ceutical profits. As many commentators note, the creation of the innovation and competition vari-
profits earned within the pharmaceutical industry ables suggests that future research might wish to
are consistently well above those earned in the juxtapose the current market-share approach
next highest earning industry (Office of Tech- against other possible approaches. Potential candi-
nology Assessment, 1993). Commentators tend to dates would include Dranove and Meltzer’s
argue that such interindustry profit differentials (1994) various indicators of therapeutic (as
either suggest the presence of relatively strong opposed to market) importance—including FDA
monopoly positions or are due to the relatively indicators of therapeutic novelty and subsequent
Copyright  1999 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Strat. Mgmt. J., 20: 655–670 (1999)
Innovation and Persistent Profitability 669

citations in medical journals. In such efforts, Bond, R. and D. Lean (1977). Sales, Promotion and
researchers should follow Schumpeter and keep Product Differentiation in Two Prescription Drug
Markets. Staff Report to the Federal Trade Com-
the distinction between technological novelty and mission. Federal Trade Commission, Washington,
importance and successful innovation firmly in DC.
mind (the latter being a market-based activity). Brownlee, O. (1979). ‘Rates of return to investment in
While Trajtenberg (1990) does demonstrate a the pharmaceutical industry: A survey and critical
significant correspondence between citation- appraisal’. In R. Chien (ed.), Issues in Pharmaceu-
tical Economics. Lexington Books, Lexington, MA,
weighted patent counts and the social value of pp. 129–141.
CT scanner innovations, Dranove and Meltzer’s Caves, R., M. Whinston and M. Hurwitz (1991). ‘Pa-
(1994) research in the pharmaceutical industry tent expiration, entry, and competition in the U.S.
shows that the correlations between indicators of pharmaceutical industry’, Brookings Papers on Eco-
therapeutic and market importance are far from nomic Activity. Brookings Institution, Washington,
DC.
perfect. Another approach might involve survey- Clarkson, K. (1979). ‘The use of pharmaceutical prof-
ing doctors or pharmacists, asking them to iden- itability measures for public policy actions’. In R.
tify products as innovative (see Banbury and Chien (ed.), Issues in Pharmaceutical Economics.
Mitchell, 1995: 162). Relatedly, researchers might Lexington Books, Lexington, MA, pp. 105–124.
wish to scrutinize the level at which inter-product Cocks, D. (1975). ‘Product innovation and the dynamic
element of competition in the ethical pharmaceutical
competition is modeled in this paper. While we industry’. In R. Helms (ed.), Drug Development and
explicitly adopt an approach that is broader than Marketing. American Enterprise Institute, Wash-
the patented product vs. generic competitor ington, DC, pp. 225–254.
approach taken by, among others, Bond and Lean Cohen, W. and R. Levin (1989). ‘Empirical studies of
(1977), Caves et al. (1991), and Gorecki (1986), innovation and market structure’. In R. Schmalansee
and R. Willig (eds.), Handbook of Industrial
future research might wish to revisit this decision. Organization, Vol. II. Elsevier, North-Holland,
If the current findings hold across these different pp. 1059–1107.
operationalizations of the innovative product con- Comanor, W. (1986). ‘The political economy of the
struct, we will have increased confidence in the pharmaceutical industry’, Journal of Economic
robustness of the findings. Literature, 24, pp. 1178–1217.
Cubbin, J. and P. Geroski (1987). ‘The convergence
Finally, this research focuses explicitly on one of profits in the long run: Inter-firm and inter-
type of innovation—product innovation. While industry comparisons’, Journal of Industrial Eco-
the pharmaceutical industry emphasis on new nomics, 35, pp. 427–442.
drug products allows us to credibly overlook other D’Aveni, R. (1994). Hypercompetition: Managing the
types of innovations in this empirical setting, the Dynamics of Strategic Maneuvring. Free Press,
New York.
same may not hold for other industries. Future Dranove, D. and D. Meltzer (1994). ‘Do important
research should try to move the analysis beyond drugs reach the market sooner?’, RAND Journal of
the study of products only in order to embrace the Economics, 25, pp. 402–423.
several types of innovation to which Schumpeter FOI Services (1996). The NDA Book, 1996. FOI Ser-
alludes (e.g., process innovations, organizational vices, Gaithersburg, MD.
Gatignon, H., B Weitz and P. Bansal (1990). ‘Brand
innovations, new sources of input supply, and the introduction strategies and competitive environ-
introduction of existing products to new markets). ments’, Journal of Marketing Research, 27,
pp. 390–401.
Geroski, P. (1990). ‘Modeling persistent profitability’.
REFERENCES In D. Mueller (ed.), The Dynamics of Company
Profits. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge,
Ali, A. (1994). ‘Pioneering versus incremental inno- MA, pp. 15–34.
vation: Review and research propositions’, Journal Geroski, P. and A. Jacquemin (1988). ‘The persistence
of Product Innovation Management, 11, pp. 46–61. of profits: A European comparison’, Economic Jour-
Banbury, C. and W. Mitchell (1995). ‘The effect of nal, 98, pp. 373–389.
introducing important incremental innovations on Geroski, P., S. Machin and J. Van Reenen (1993).
market share and business survival’, Strategic Man- ‘The profitability of innovating firms’, Rand Journal
agement Journal, Summer Special Issue, 16, pp. of Economics, 24, pp. 198–211.
161–182. Gorecki, P. (1986). ‘The importance of being first: The
Barney, J. (1995). ‘Looking inside for competitive case of prescription drugs in Canada’, International
advantage’, Academy of Management Executive, 9, Journal of Industrial Organization, 4, pp. 371–395.
pp. 49–61. Grabowski, H. and J. Vernon (1992). ‘Brand loyalty,
entry, and price competition in pharmaceuticals after
Copyright  1999 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Strat. Mgmt. J., 20: 655–670 (1999)
670 P. W. Roberts
the 1984 Drug Act’, Journal of Law and Economics, Nelson, R. (1986). ‘Institutions supporting technical
35, pp. 311–350. advance in industry’, American Economic Review,
Grant, R. (1991). ‘The resource-based theory of com- 76, pp. 186–189.
petitive advantage: Implications for strategy formu- Office of Technology Assessment (1993). Pharmaceu-
lation’, California Management Review, Spring, tical R&D: Costs, Risks and Rewards. U.S. Govern-
pp. 114–135. ment Printing Office, Washington, DC.
Henderson, R. (1994). ‘Managing innovation in the Penrose, E. (1959). The Theory of the Growth of the
information age’, Harvard Business Review, 72(1), Firm. Wiley, New York.
pp. 100–105. Porter, M. (1985). Competitive Advantage. Free Press,
Henderson, R. and I. Cockburn (1994). ‘Measuring New York.
competence? Exploring firm effects in pharmaceu- Roberts, P. (forthcoming). ‘Innovation and firm-level
tical research’, Strategic Management Journal, persistent profitability: A Schumpeterian frame-
Winter Special Issue, 15, pp. 63–84. work’, Managerial and Decision Economics.
Henderson, R. and I. Cockburn (1996). ‘Scale, scope Robinson, W. (1990). ‘Product innovation and start-up
and spillovers: The determinants of research produc- business market share performance’, Management
tivity in drug discovery’, RAND Journal of Eco- Science, 36, pp. 1279–1289.
nomics, 27, pp. 32–59. Robinson, W., G. Kalyanaram and G. Urban (1994).
Hunt, S. and R. Morgan (1995). ‘The comparative ‘First-mover advantages from pioneering new mar-
advantage theory of competition’, Journal of Market- kets: A survey of empirical evidence’, Review of
ing, 59, pp. 1–15. Industrial Organization, 9, pp. 1–23.
Jacobson, R. (1988). ‘The persistence of abnormal Rumelt, R. (1987). ‘Theory, strategy and
returns’, Strategic Management Journal, 9(5), entrepreneurship’. In D. Teece (ed.), The Competitive
pp. 415–430. Challenge: Strategies for Industrial Innovation and
Jacquemin, A. (1987). The New Industrial Organiza- Renewal. Ballinger, Cambridge, MA, pp. 137–157.
tion: Market Forces and Strategic Behavior. MIT Rumelt, R. (1991). ‘How much does industry matter?’,
Press, Cambridge, MA. Strategic Management Journal, 12(3), pp. 167–185.
Kamien, M. and N. Schwartz (1982). Market Structure Scherer, F. and D. Ross (1990). Industrial Market
and Innovation. Cambridge University Press, Cam- Structure and Economic Performance. Houghton
bridge, U.K. Mifflin, Boston, MA.
Kemp, B. (1975). ‘The follow-on development process Schohl, F. (1990). ‘Persistence of profits in the long
and the market for diuretics’. In R. Helms (ed.), run: A critical extension of some recent findings’,
Drug Development and Marketing. American International Journal of Industrial Organization, 8,
Enterprise Institute, Washington, DC, pp. 255–276. pp. 385–404.
Kirzner, I. (1973). Competition and Entrepreneurship. Schumpeter, J. (1934). The Theory of Economic Devel-
University of Chicago Press, Chicago, IL. opment. Harvard University Press, Cambridge, MA.
Levin, R., A. Klevorick, R. Nelson and S. Winter Schumpeter, J. (1950). Capitalism, Socialism and
(1987). ‘Appropriating the returns from industrial Democracy. Harper, New York.
research and development’, Brookings Papers on Schwartzman, D. (1976). Innovation in the Pharma-
Economic Activity, pp. 783–820. ceutical Industry. Johns Hopkins University Press,
Lieberman, M. and D. Montgomery (1988). ‘First- Baltimore, MD.
mover advantages’, Strategic Management Journal, Trajtenberg, M. (1990). ‘A penny for your quotes:
Summer Special Issue, 9, pp. 41–58. Patent citations and the value of innovations’, RAND
Mansfield, E., M. Schwartz and S. Wagner (1981). Journal of Economics, 21, pp. 172–187.
‘Imitation costs and patents: An empirical study’, Venkatraman, N. and V. Ramanujam (1986). ‘Measure-
Economic Journal, 91, pp. 907–918. ment of business performance in strategy research:
Menga, P. and D. Mueller (1991). ‘Profit rates and A comparison of approaches’, Academy of Manage-
intangible capital’, Review of Economics and Sta- ment Review, 11, pp. 801–814.
tistics, 73, pp. 632–642. Waring, G. (1996). ‘Industry differences in the persis-
Montgomery, C. (1995). ‘Of diamonds and rust’. In C. tence of firm-specific returns’, American Economic
Montgomery (ed.), Resource-Based and Evolution- Review, 86, pp. 1253–1265.
ary Theories of the Firm. Kluwer, Boston, MA, Weston, J. (1979). ‘Pricing in the pharmaceutical indus-
pp. 251–268. try’. In R. Chien (ed.), Issues in Pharmaceutical
Mueller, D. (1986). Profits in the Long-Run. Cambridge Economics. Lexington Books, Lexington, MA,
University Press, Cambridge, U.K. pp. 71–94.
Mueller, D. (1990). The Dynamics of Company Profits: Williams, J. (1992). ‘How sustainable is your competi-
An International Comparison. Cambridge University tive advantage?’, California Management Review,
Press, Cambridge, U.K. Spring, pp. 29–51.

Copyright  1999 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Strat. Mgmt. J., 20: 655–670 (1999)

You might also like