You are on page 1of 7

553.

444/644 Introduction to Financial


Where we are
Derivatives
• Previously: Swaps, Options Analysis, Binomial Tree
Midterm 2 Review Model, Risk-Neutral Analysis, the Stochastic Process,
& Ito’s Lemma (Chapter 7, 10-11,13-14 OFOD)
• Now: Review for Midterm 2 (November 15th )
• Next: Black-Scholes-Merton Model for Options plus
Applications (Chapter 15, 17–18, OFOD)

1.1 10.2

Where we are Schedule


• Mid Term 2: November 14th, Wednesday Date 2018
Monday, October 08, 2018
Module
Swaps (M6)
Due Comments
Hull: 7

• Fall Break: November 19th – 23rd Wednesday, October 10, 2018


Monday, October 15, 2018
Swaps (M6)
Options (M7) HW 6 Hull: 10 ‐ 11
Wednesday, October 17, 2018 Options (M7)
• Last Day of Classes: Friday, December 7th Monday, October 22, 2018 Binomial (M8) HW 7 Hull: 13
Wednesday, October 24, 2018 Binomial (M8)
• Final Exam: Friday, December 14th, 9am - Noon Monday, October 29, 2018
Wednesday, October 31, 2018
Stoch Process (M9)
Stoch Process (M9)
HW 8 Hull: 14

Monday, November 05, 2018 BSM Models (M10) HW 9 Hull: 15, 17 – 18


Wednesday, November 07, 2018 Midterm 2 Review Hull: 7, 10  ‐ 14  (X12)
Friday, November 09, 2018 Section: HW Problem Review All HW Returned (NLT)
Monday, November 12, 2018 Midterm Sample Q
Wednesday, November 14, 2018 Midterm 2 Exam M6 – M9
Friday, November 16, 2018 Midterm 2 Exam Return
11/19 ‐ 11/23/2018 Thanksgiving Break

1.3 1.4

1
Schedule Assignment
Date 2018
11/19 ‐ 11/23/2018
Module
Thanksgiving Break
Due Comments • For November 5th, 26th & 28th
Monday, November 26, 2018
Wednesday, November 28, 2018
BSM Models (M10)
BSM Models (M10) • Read: Hull Chapter 15 (Black-Scholes-Merton)
Monday, December 03, 2018 Greeks (M11) HW10 Hull:
Wednesday, December 05, 2018 Greeks (M11); Fin Rev HW 11 Hull: 15, 17‐18,  • Read: Hull Chapter 17-18 (Options on Indices &
Friday, December 07, 2018 HW Problem Review All HW Returned (NLT)
Friday, December 14, 2018 Currencies + Futures Options)
9am ‐12Noon Final Exam M9 – M11
• Homework 10: Problems (Due December 3rd)
o Chapter 15 (15, 9e; 14, 8e; 13, 7e): 4, 5, 11, 13, 15, 17; 28
o Chapter 17 (17, 9e; 16, 8e; 15, 7e): 4, 22; 23*
o Chapter 18 (18, 9e; 17, 8e; 16, 7e): 7, 8, 15; 22

11.6
1.5

Assignment Midterm Review


• For December 5th
Know how to apply the two approaches to
• Read: Hull Chapter 19 (The Greeks)
valuing interest rate and currency swap
• Homework 11: Problems (Due December 7th) contracts; Know how to use swap rates to
o Chapter 19 (18, 8e; 17, 7e): 2, 10, 18; 24 bootstrap the LIBOR/Swap curve; Be able to
explain/analyze the principle of comparative
advantage for both the interest rate and
currency swap

11.7
7.8

2
Valuation of an Interest Rate Swap that is Valuation of Currency Swaps
NOT New • Like interest rate swaps, currency swaps can be valued either as the
• Interest Rate Swap can be valued as the difference between the value difference between 2 bonds or as a portfolio of forward contracts
of a fixed-rate bond and a floating-rate bond VSwap=BFIX - BFLOAT • Let the Swap be where USD is received and foreign currency is paid
• Alternatively, they can be valued as a portfolio of forward rate VSWAP  B D  S 0 B F
agreements (FRAs)
o S0 is the spot exchange rate as number of US$ per unit of currency
o where Fi = Forward rate, i>0 n
t t  • Similarly, for a portfolio of forward FX contracts where USD is received
o F0 = Current/Last LIBOR 
VSwap  L(C  Fi 1 ) i i 1 e  Ri ti
 360  VSWAP   USD(Ti )  FC (Ti ) S0 e
 R  R T   e R T
i i
f
i
o C = Swap Rate (fixed side) i 1
i i

• EXAMPLE: Consider the • EXAMPLE   


o SWAP o SWAP (legacy): 3-year tenor, annual pay
o Pay 6M LIBOR; Receive 8% PA on $100mm o Pay: USD at 8%PA on $10 million
o 15-months to go o Receive: YEN at 5%PA on Y1,200 million
o Market o Market:
o LIBOR (cc): 3M=10%; 9M=10.5%; 15M=11% o LIBOR/Swap Curve: flat in US (at 9%PA) & Japan (at 4%PA)
o 6M LIBOR 3M ago: 10.2% o FX spot market has Y110 = $1
o First Bonds then FRAs …
7.9 7.10

Using Swap Rates to Bootstrap the The Comparative Advantage


LIBOR/Swap Zero Curve • AAACorp wants to borrow $10 million for 5-years
• Suppose the 6-, 12-, and 18-month Libor/Swap zero rates have been
o Has a Comparative Advantage in Fixed Market
determined as 4%, 4.5%, and 4.8% (continuous compounding)
o 120bps better than BBBCorp
• And the 2-year swap rate (for semiannual payments) is 5%
• BBBCorp wants to borrow $10 million for 5-years
• The 5% swap rate means o Has a Comparative Advantage in Floating Market
o A bond with $100 principal and a semiannual coupon of 5% per o “Only” 70bps worse than AAACorp
annum sells for Par
o If R4 is the 2-year zero rate, then
4
1 Fixed Floating
BFIX   Ci e  Riti   5e  Riti  100e R4t4  100
i 1 2 AAACorp 4.0% 6-month LIBOR – 0.10%
 2.5e 0.040.5  2.5e 0.0451.0  2.5e0.0481.5  102.5e  R4 2.0  100
BBBCorp 5.20% 6-month LIBOR + 0.60%
 R4  4.953%
A=120bps B=70bps
• And if we have the Libor/Swap zero curve, then we can determine the One can always structure swap so the pick-up is:
successive Swap Rates (vice versa) A - B = 50bps
7.11 7.12

3
Comparative Advantage Arguments for
Final Review
Currency Swaps
• GE wants to borrow 20 million in AUD for 5-years
o Has a Comparative Advantage in USD • Know the properties of stock options;
o 200bps better than Quantas
• Qantas wants to borrow 15 million in USD for 5-years • be able to explain/develop (prove?) the
o Has a Comparative Advantage in AUD “bounding” conditions for European-style
o Only 40bps worse than GE
• Implied FX is 1.33 AUD per USD or .75 USD per AUD
option value and the condition of put-call
• Borrowing Rates for each parity;
5-year rates USD AUD • explain the considerations when
General Electric 5.0% 7.6% expanding this analysis to American-style
Quantas 7.0% 8.0% options and for dividend-paying stocks
A = 200 B = 40
Can always structure swap pick-up as A-B = 160 bps

7.13 7.14

Lower Bound for European Call Option Lower Bound for European Call Option
Price (No Dividends) Price (No Dividends)

c  max S0  Ke  rT , 0  • PF A is worth max (ST , K) at expiration
• Consider the two portfolios • PF B at expiration is worth ST
Portfolio A: One European Call option plus cash = Ke –rT • At expiration, PF A has value of at least PF B
Portfolio B: One Share • In the absence of arbitrage, this must also be
• For PF A at expiration, T true today (Discuss)
o If the cash is invested, it will grow to K at T • Hence c + Ke -rT  S0 or c  S0 – Ke -rT
o If ST > K, then the option is exercised; PF A is worth ST
o We pay for the share with the cash and have a share worth ST
• Finally, at worst the call will expire worthless, so
o If ST < K, then the option is worthless; PF A is worth K
o Hence PF A is worth max (ST , K)

c  max S0  Ke  rT , 0 
1.15 1.16

4
Final Review Generalization of the Binomial Model
• Consider the portfolio that is
• Be prepared to construct a binomial tree to
o Long  shares and
evaluate an option on a given underlying o Short 1 option S0u– ƒu
asset. S0– ƒ
• Understand the relationship of the
S0d– ƒd
probability for an up/down movement to
volatility u / d  exp   /   t   • The portfolio is riskless when S0u– ƒu = S0d– ƒd or
 
fu  f d

S 0u  S 0 d

7.17 9.18

Generalization of the Binomial Model One Last Detail e t  d


p* 
f  fd ud
• Substituting for where   u • So the variance of the stock price return is
S 0u  S 0 d
p *u 2  (1  p * )d 2  [ p *u  (1  p * )d ] 2   2 t
• We obtain • Substituting for p* from above, we get
ƒ = [ pƒu + (1 – p)ƒd ]e–rT e t (u  d )  ud  e 2 t   2 t
• Where we define p as and one solution for u and d is: u  e t

 t
d e
e rT  d
p where  is the volatility and t is the length of the time
ud
step (and when terms in Δt2 and higher powers of Δt are
x2
• This is the Generalized Binomial Model of Option Value ignored) and as t gets small (use e x  1  x   ... )
2!
• This is the approach used by Cox, Ross, and Rubinstein
• Standard practice for constructing the lattice
9.19 9.20

5
Final Review Ito’s Lemma for a Stock Price Process
• When the stock price process is an Ito Process
• Know the form for the Ito Process of a stock price
for a non dividend paying stock d S   S dt   S d z
• Know Ito’s Lemma and be able to apply to form a
• Then for a function G of S and t Ito’s Lemma gives that
process model for a function of an underlying
process  G G  2G 2 2  G
dG   S  ½  S  dt   S dz
  S  t  S 2
 S
• Know the distribution for the mean and variance
• Let’s look at how this is so …
of the state of this Ito Process and what it means
for it to be a Log-Normal Process (i.e., (14.18)-
(14.19) and/or (15.2)-(15.3))

7.21 11.22

Applications of Ito’s Lemma The Stock Price Assumption


• Let F0  S0e  F ( S , 0) be the forward price of term T on a
rT
• Consider a stock whose price is S and (as we have seen)
non-dividend paying stock follows the Ito Process,
• Or more generally for any t   0, T  : F ( S , t )  Ser (T t ) dS   S dt   S dz
• We can use Ito’s Lemma to determine the process for F where  is expected return and  is volatility (per year)
where the process for S is d S   S dt   S d z • In a short period of time of length t, the return on the
F r (T t ) 2F F
and we find S  e ;  0;   rSe r (T t ) stock can be characterized as
S 2 t
• So dF  e r (T t )  S  rSer (T t )  dt  e r (T t ) Sdz S   S t   S t
 (   r ) F dt   F dz with  ~  (0,1), the standardized normal distribution
• Like S, the forward price process F follows an Ito Process, • So it follows that ΔS/S is normally distributed as well
but has growth rate μ – r rather than μ S
o The growth rate of F is the excess return of S over the risk-free rate S

~  t ,  2 t 
11.23 11.24

6
Lognormal Property of Stock Prices The Expected Returns and −
• From Ito’s Lemma, letting G = ln S, gives G 1  2G
 ;
1
 2
 2  S S S 2 S • Suppose we have daily data for a period of several
dG      dt   dz G t  0
 2  months
• So the change in ln S between 0 and some future T is o {S0, S1 , S2 , …}
normally distributed with mean (µ - σ2/2)T and variance σ2T
• is the average of the returns in each day [=E(S/S)]
• Which we can express as 2
    • −is the expected return over the whole period
ln ST  ln S0 ~     T ,  T 
2

2 covered by the data measured with continuous


  
or compounding (or daily compounding, which is almost the
  2  
ln ST ~   ln S0     T ,  T 
2
same)
  2  
• Since ln ST is normal, ST is lognormally distributed
• And ST  2  
ln ~    
2
T ,  T 
S0  2  
11.25 11.26

The Expected Returns and −


• Consider the two representations
E ( ST )  S0 e T (from slide 11.43)
  2  
ln ST ~  ln S0     T ,  T 
2

  2  
• We can show ln[ E ( ST )]  E[ln( ST )]  0 as in Jenson’s
Inequality and as expected by the nonlinearity of ln ( . )
ln[ E ( ST )]  ln( S0 )  T
 2 
E[ln( ST )]  ln( S0 )     T
 2 
• So
  2   2
ln[ E ( ST )]  E[ln( ST )]  ln( S0 )  T  ln( S0 )     T   T 0
  2   2
11.27

You might also like