You are on page 1of 10

Omega 53 (2015) 11–20

Contents lists available at ScienceDirect

Omega
journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/omega

Free or bundled: Channel selection decisions under different


power structures$
Xu Chen a,n, Xiaojun Wang b,1
a
School of Management and Economics, University of Electronic Science and Technology of China, Chengdu 611731, PR China
b
School of Economics, Finance and Management, University of Bristol, Bristol BS8 1TZ, UK

art ic l e i nf o a b s t r a c t

Article history: The smart phone industry has unique supply chain relationships. Companies at all levels of the supply
Received 16 June 2014 chain compete and coordinate with each other for market share and profit. This paper examines the
Accepted 24 November 2014 impact of power structures on the decision of pricing and channel selection between a free channel and
Available online 3 December 2014
a bundled channel. We investigate the smart phone supply chain that consists of a handset manufacturer
Keywords: and a telecom service operator. Based on game theory models, the manufacturer's optimal retail pricing
Service operations policies in free and bundled channels and the telecom service operator's optimal subsidy policies in a
Channel selection bundled channel are derived under different power structures. It is demonstrated that the firm that has
Pricing higher channel power will gain more profit, and the smart phone supply chain's profit in a Vertical Nash
Power structure
(VN) power structure is higher than that in Telecom Service Operator-Stackelberg (TS) and
Game theory
Manufacturer-Stackelberg (MS) power structures. It is also shown that the smart phone supply chain
will choose a bundled channel in TS and MS power structures under certain conditions and will select a
free channel in a VN power structure.
& 2014 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.

1. Introduction involves the strategic process of coordinating companies within


the supply chain to competitively deliver both service and product
Consider a consumer looking for a new smart phone. When to the end customers.
picking a smart phone handset from various models and manu- Adding to the complexity of the decision problem, customers
facturers, the consumer has to choose a service package ranging can choose their handsets and services as a bundled package from
from “pay as you go” to various tariff contracts among different manufacturers (e.g., Apple Store), telecom service operators, and
telecom service operators. The relationship with the ultimate third party smart phone retailers, or alternatively, they can buy
customers is determined by the complete combination of product handsets from manufacturers and services from telecom service
features and telecom services offered by a unique supply chain operators separately. Here we use the terms, bundled channel and
setting [14]. On one hand, a telecom service operator cannot free channel, to describe the two different channels above,
provide good quality telecommunication and data service without respectively. In a bundled channel, a manufacture designs a smart
a good quality functioning handset produced by manufacturers. phone handset to work exclusively with a single telecom service
On the other hand, the innovative functions developed by a operator, and customers have to buy the handset and the service
handset manufacturer cannot be materialized without a fast and together from either the manufacturer or the telecom service
reliable data service provided by telecom service operators. The operator. In a free channel, the manufacturer works with multiple
handset and service package themselves and the prices charged telecom service operators and customers can buy the handset
for both the handset and service are all influential in the consumer from the manufacturer and the telecom service from a telecom
purchasing decision. Different from traditional supply chain man- service operator separately. Both bundled channel and free chan-
agement that often focuses on delivering a product or service, this nel are popular in many world leading smart phone markets
including China, the United States (US), and the United Kingdom
(UK). For example, consumers in these countries can buy iPhones

This manuscript was processed by Associate Editor Eksioglu. from Apple stores either as a standalone handset or as a handset
n
Corresponding author. Tel.: þ 86 28 83206622.
E-mail addresses: xchenxchen@263.net (X. Chen),
bundled with a service contract. Alternatively, consumers can also
xiaojun.wang@bristol.ac.uk (X. Wang). buy a bundled package from telecom service operators. However,
1
Tel.: þ44 117 928 8608. the prices consumers pay for their smart phone handsets varies

http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.omega.2014.11.008
0305-0483/& 2014 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.
12 X. Chen, X. Wang / Omega 53 (2015) 11–20

significantly depending on where they purchase handsets and After a review of the literature in Section 2, the model
which service package they choose. formulation and assumptions are presented in Section 3. In
This price variation is obscured by the bundling of product and Section 4 the pricing policy in a free channel is discussed. In
service and various subsidies in the supply chain. Furthermore, the Section 5, the pricing policies and subsidy policies in a bundled
pricing and subsidy policies of manufacturers and service opera- channel and the effect of different power structures are discussed
tors are affected by their power in the relative market and supply separately. In Section 6, we focus on channel selection policies for
chain against each other and against customers. A dominant the smart phone supply chain. The effects of channel selection
power relationship with other supply chain members not only decisions, pricing decisions and subsidy decisions on the supply
enables firms to force through their strategic and operational chain performance are analyzed. The analysis results will help
decisions from other supply chain members but also allows them firms in the smart phone industry adopt proper strategies. In
to be the driving force in the negotiation of subsidies. To manage Section 7, a numerical example is provided to demonstrate the
supply chains strategically and operationally, it is important that validity of the proposed models. Finally, we discuss managerial
power structures that exist in the supply chains are properly insights and consider directions for future work in Section 8.
understood by managers [13]. Although power issues such as
market power [30,1], channel power [23,33], and supply chain
power [13,2,6,45] were widely explored in the marketing and 2. Literature review
operations management literature, to our knowledge, the power
effect on channel selection, pricing and subsidy decisions has not The importance of channel selection and pricing to the compe-
been analyzed in a unique supply chain setting. Therefore, in this titiveness of a supply chain has been recognized in practice and
paper, three classic power structures [9,20,3]: Telecom Service literature for some time. A considerable amount of prior work has
Operator-Stackelberg (TS), Vertical Nash (VN) and Manufacturer- been conducted in the areas of competitive pricing effects e.g.,
Stackelberg (MS) are taken into consideration in examining their economic work on cross-price effects [31,19]; the literature on
influences on channel selection, pricing and subsidy decisions. price image [12,18]; price wars [37]; optimal pricing on product
Channel management has received increasing attention from decision models [15,26,27,39]; and some recent reviews on retail
scholars and practitioners in recent years. There is a stream of pricing [29,28,17]. More relevant to the setting of this research,
marketing and operations research literature on the problem of Choi [10] models price competition in a channel structure con-
channel management. There is also extensive economics literature sisting of duopoly manufacturers and duopoly common retailers.
examining firms' behavior under competition and the effect of This research finds that product differentiation helps manufac-
strategic alliance. However, to the best of our knowledge, there are turers but hurts retailers and store differentiation helps retailers
no published papers that place the channel selection problem in a but hurts manufacturers conversely. Cattani et al. [5] investigate
supply chain model in which end consumers can buy their product pricing strategies of both the manufacturer and retailer when a
and service from upstream manufacturer(s) and downstream direct internet channel in introduced by a manufacturer. Their
service operator(s), respectively, or can buy product and service finding indicates that if the retail channel is considerably more
bundled packages directly from either parties, examine the impact convenient than the Internet Channel, a consistent pricing strategy
of different power structures on these decisions, or specify pricing is appropriate.
and subsidy policies that enable manufacturers and service opera- The literature on channel selection and coordination has been
tors to coordinate decisions. In a competitive marketplace with a rich and the marketing literature on these issues also focuses on
growing need for customer orientation, both manufacturers and pricing decisions. Jeuland and Shugan [22] consider a simple
service operators should look beyond their organizational bound- channel with one retailer and one supplier and find that the
aries to develop and leverage their supply chain partners' supply chain can be coordinated by that a simple quantity
resources and capabilities to create superior value. Our objective discount. Chiang et al. [8] examine the impact of customer channel
is to contribute in addressing the aforementioned research gap by preference on dual-channel supply-chain design problems. Their
presenting an analytical model and analysis method for simulta- study finds that setting up a direct channel to compete with its
neously modeling and estimating optimal pricing and channel retailer is beneficial for a manufacturer if consumers are assumed
selection policies under different power structures. to have a common positive preference for the local retailer. Tsay
The pricing, subsidy and channel selection problems are inves- and Agrawal [36] study retail and direct channels and their finding
tigated in a supply chain setting that consists of a manufacturer indicates that both the retailer and manufacturer would benefit
and a service operator and has different power structures. The from a dual channel if the manufacturer is willing to reduce the
manufacturer may directly sell smart phone handsets to consu- whole sale price. They also suggest that the preference for an
mers in a free channel or sell them through a telecom service alternative channel is dependent on marketing capability and
operator in a bundled channel. In contrast to high prices and a supply chain efficiency. Cai [4] investigates the influence of four
huge discrepancy of handsets in the smart phone market due to a supply chain structures with and without coordination on the
short product life cycle and rapid technological development, the supplier and retailer. Their finding suggests that the channel
service price is relatively more stable. Therefore, in addition to the selection and coordination preferences depend on parameters
channel selection problem, this research mainly focuses on hand- such as channel base demand, channel substitutability and opera-
sets manufacturer's pricing policies. Several key questions are tional cost. Khouja et al. [24] analyze channel selection and pricing
addressed in this article. in the presence of retail-captive consumers. Their findings indicate
that their variables (including the customer distribution among
 What are the smart phone manufacturer's optimal retail pri- the retail-captive and hybrid segments, their channel preference
cing policies in a free channel and bundled channel under and the relative values of unit cost in the retail channel and direct
different power structures? channel) determine optimal channel choice.
 What are the telecom service operator's optimal subsidy Another relevant stream of literature looks into channel selec-
policies in a bundled channel under different power structures? tion and pricing problems from the supply chain management
 What are the smart phone supply chain's optimal channel perspective. Cohen and Whang [11] adopt a game-theoretic frame-
selection policies (free channel or bundled channel) under work to study the competition for the provision of after-sales
different power structures? service between the manufacturer and an independent service
X. Chen, X. Wang / Omega 53 (2015) 11–20 13

operator. In their paper, they mainly focus on the after-sale service Stackelberg games are used in their research to model supply
from the product point of view, which is different from the smart chains dominated by the manufacturer and retailer, respectively
phone supply chain where the telecom service operator is inde- and a Nash game is utilized to model supply chains with a
pendent. Wang [40] studies a two-echelon supply chain with balanced power structure.
multiple manufacturers and one retailer. The research focuses on Nevertheless, despite the increased attention on channel man-
decentralized production-pricing decisions on complementary agement in the marketing and supply chain literature, very few
products and how supply chain performance is affected by these studies have been carried on the basis of the smart phone industry,
decisions. Wu et al. [41] use a principal-agent framework to study which has seen the fastest growth for a decade. Moreover, few
a supply chain that consists of a newsvendor and an advertiser. papers have focused on the efficacy of different supply chain
The optimal decisions are analyzed in their research for both a power structures on the manufacturer, service provider, and entire
price-taking and a price-setting newsvendor when the advertiser supply chain under the setting of two competing channels. Our
has private information regarding its willingness to pay for paper extends the existing literature by specifically examining the
advertisements. Based on this work, Wu et al. [42] extend their impact of different power structures on pricing, subsidy and
model to multiple advertisers and discuss the impact of the channel selection decisions in the context of the smart phone
number of advertisers on the newsvendor's optimal decisions. supply chain in which both the upstream manufacturer and
Recently, Chen et al. [7] study a two-echelon supply chain, in downstream service operator face consumers directly and the
which, one manufacturer and two competing retailers are con- product and service provided by them are essential to meet
sidered with warranty period-dependent demands. In their paper, consumers' need. One distinction of our model is that a linear
the manufacturer's pricing strategies are examined in the cases of demand function depends on the product price and service price
symmetrical and asymmetrical sales cost information and the in both the free and bundled channels. Another distinction is our
warranty service also depends on the product and is not indepen- systematic consideration of optimizing pricing policies, subsidy
dent. Zhang et al. [43] examine the effects of reference-price on policies and channel selection policies to improve the profitability
the equilibrium pricing strategies for a two-echelon competitive of individual supply chain parties and the whole supply chain for a
supply chain in a bilateral monopoly setting. Dedrick et al. [14] smart phone supply chain with different power structures. The
analyze the distribution of value in the mobile phone supply chain main contributions of our work include: first, a study of the impact
based on product-level data, and find that carriers and handset of power structure on channel selection and pricing problems in
makers capture the most value from each handset. Nevertheless, the smart phone supply chain; optimal pricing and subsidy
the different power structures in mobile phone supply chains are policies for the smart phone manufacturer and telecom operator;
ignored and a qualitative approach is used in the study. Overall, an analysis of the implication of different power structures on
there is rich literature on the traditional supply chain, which prices and profits in the free and bundled channels.
consists of sequential upstream manufacturer(s) and downstream
retailer(s), but there are rare studies on supply chain models with
upstream manufacturer(s) and downstream service provider 3. Model formulation and assumptions
(s) dealing with end consumers directly.
There is also a stream of literature that studies the impacts of We consider a smart phone supply chain that consists of a handset
power structure on various aspects of channel management. Choi manufacturer and a telecom service operator. The smart phone
[9] analyses the effects of power structure on manufacturers' manufacturer's unit smart phone retail price is pm , and the unit
decisions for selling through a retailer. Ertek and Griffin [16] handset manufacturing cost is cm , pm 4cm . The telecom service
investigate the effect of power structure on price, profits and operator's unit price is po , and the unit service cost is co , po 4 co .
sensitivity of the market price in a two-stage supply chain. The The service price and cost cover the contract period of the service.
research analyses the case where the buyer has dominant bargain- In a free supply chain channel, there is only one source of
ing power and the case where the supplier has dominant bargain- revenue for the smart phone manufacturer, which is the smart
ing power. Raju and Zhang [33] look at channel coordination in the phone handset sale. In a bundled supply chain channel, the
context of a retailer Stackelberg and their finding shows that a manufacturer's revenue is the smart phone handset sale plus the
channel can be coordinated through either quantity discounts or a subsidy ρ (  pm o ρ o po ) from the telecom service operator. At the
menu of two-part tariffs to the manufacturer's benefit. Using a same time, the telecom service operator's revenue is the service
similar power structure setting, Kolay and Shaffer [25] study revenue minus the subsidy ρ ( pm o ρo po ) to the smart phone
channel coordination and contract design when an upstream firm manufacturer. Furthermore, some key model assumptions are
sells its products in a downstream market, and their finding made as follows:
indicates that quantity discounts and two-part tariffs can be
mechanisms for channel coordination under some conditions.  We consider the problem of channel selection in a sequential
From Supplier-Stackelberg, Retailer-Stackelberg, and Nash game supply chain model consisting of an upstream manufacturer and a
theoretical perspectives, Cai et al. [3] examine the impact of price downstream service operator in both a free channel and bundled
discounts and price schemes on the dual-channel supply chain channel. This assumption is widely used in the supply chain
competition. Their analysis shows that the simple price discount channel management literature and is applicable to many settings
contracts can effectively improve the performance of both the particularly those high-tech products including smart phones.
supplier and retailer, and a consistent pricing scheme can ease the  Similar to the conventional demand function, demand is
channel conflict though inducing more profit to the retailer. Using assumed to be linear and deterministic,
  which is defined by
a similar game-theory-based framework, Zhang et al. [44] study the equation D ðpm Þ ¼ α  β pm þ po , where α denotes the
the effect of products' substitutability and channel position on primary demand of the smart phone manufacturer, β repre-
pricing decision under different power structures in two dual- sents the customers' sensitivity to the smart phone retail price.
exclusive channels. Their research finding indicates that the This demand function has often been used in operations
Vertical Nash game is equilibrium for the supply chain members management and marketing research [7,21,32] and in some
and no power structure is always the best for the entire supply economics research [35,38].
chain. Shi et al. [34] examine the impacts of power structure on  The telecom service operator's unit price po , is assumed to be
supply chains with uncertain demand. Manufacturer and retailer fixed at first. This is also common in the smart phone market, in
14 X. Chen, X. Wang / Omega 53 (2015) 11–20

which the service price is relatively more stable compared to 5. Bundled channel models
the high prices and huge discrepancies of smart phone hand-
sets. Nevertheless, the impact of service unit price (po ) on In a bundled channel, the smart phone manufacturer has two
supply chain decisions has been analyzed from Insights 1 to revenue sources: sale revenue and subsidy from the telecom
4 of the analytical modeling section. In addition, numerical service operator; and the telecom service operator gains service
analysis has been provided to examine the effect of various revenue minus subsidy to the smart phone manufacturer.
service prices on the profit of the smart phone manufacturer The smart
 phone
 manufacturer's profit in a bundled channel,
and telecom service operator under different power structures. denoted π bm pm , is
 It is assumed that both the smart phone manufacturer and the        
π bm pm ¼ pm D pm cm D pm þ ρD pm
telecom service operator are rational and self-interested, that
is, each of them aims to maximize their profit. The first term is sale revenue, the second term is manufacturing
cost and the last term represents the subsidy from the telecom
service operator. Then
     
π bm pm ¼ pm þ ρ cm α  β pm þ po ð5Þ
4. Free channel models

When the smart phone supply chain selects a free channel, the The telecom service operator's profit in a bundled channel,
sequence of events is as follows. First, the smart phone manufac- denoted π bo ðρÞ, is
turer decides the smart phone retail price according to the      
π bo ðρÞ ¼ po D pm  co D pm  ρD pm
customer demand. Then, when the customer demand is realized,
the smart phone manufacturer gains sale revenue and the telecom
service operator gains service revenue. The first term is sale revenue, the second term is service cost
The smart
 phone manufacturer's profit in a free channel, and the last term represents the subsidy to smart phone manu-
denoted π fm pm , is facturer. Then
         
π fm pm ¼ pm D pm  cm D pm π bo ðρÞ ¼ po  ρ  co α  β pm þ po ð6Þ
The first term is sale revenue and the second term is manu-
facturing cost. Then Assume the smart phone manufacturer's marginal profit in a
      bundled channel is m, then m ¼ pm þ ρ cm , that is, pm ¼ m þ cm ρ.
π fm pm ¼ pm  cm α β pm þpo ð1Þ
By replacing pm in (6), the telecom service operator's profit in a
bundled channel (π bo ðρÞ) can also be written as
The
 telecom service operator's profit in a free channel, denoted
π fo pm , is    
π bo ðρÞ ¼ po  ρ  co α  β m þ cm  ρ þ po : ð7Þ
     
π fo pm ¼ po D pm  co D pm

The first term is sale revenue and the second term is service
cost. Then 5.1. Telecom Service Operator Stackelberg (TS) model
     
π fo pm ¼ po  co α  β pm þ po ð2Þ
In the case of a TS power structure, the smart phone manu-
As to the smart phone manufacturer's optimal retail price in a facturer and telecom service operator make their decisions in
free channel, denoted pfm , the following proposition is obtained: sequence. The order of events is as follows. First, the manufacturer
determines the smart phone retail price in response to the given
Proposition 1. In a free channel, pfm ¼ 2β
α
þ c2m  p2o : telecom service operator's subsidy. Then, the telecom service
operator takes the manufacturer's response function into account
This proposition means that in a free channel, the smart phone
for an optimal subsidy to maximize profit. Finally, when the
manufacturer's optimal retail price is existent and unique.
customer demand is realized, the smart phone manufacturer and
From Proposition 1, we can directly gain the following insight:
telecom service operator gain their revenue.
Insight 1. pfm is an increasing function of α and cm and is a As to the smart phone manufacturer's optimal retail price (ptm )
decreasing function of β and po . and the telecom service operator's subsidy (ρt ) in a bundled
channel and TS power structure, the following proposition is
This insight means that in a free channel, if the primary obtained:
demand of the smart phone manufacturer and the unit smart
phone manufacturing cost are high, the smart phone manufacturer Proposition 2. In a bundled channel and TS power structure,
cm co cm co α
will set a high retail price. On the other hand, if the customers' ptm ¼ 3α
4β þ 4 þ 4  po and ρ ¼ po þ 2  2  2β:
t

sensitivity to the smart phone retail price and the telecom service
This proposition indicates that in a bundled channel and TS
operator's service price are high, the smart phone manufacturer
power structure, the smart phone manufacturer's optimal retail
will set a low retail price.
price and the telecom service operator's subsidy are existent and
From Proposition 1 and (1), we obtain the smart phone
unique.
manufacturer's maximum profit in a free channel as
From Proposition 2, we can directly gain the following insight:
  
α cm po 2 Insight 2. ptm is an increasing function of α, cm and co , and is a
π fm pfm ¼ β   ð3Þ
2β 2 2 decreasing function of β and po . ρt is an increasing function of po ,
From Proposition 1 and (2), we obtain the telecom service cm and β, and is a decreasing function of co and α.
operator's maximum profit in a free channel as
 From this insight, we know that in a bundled channel and TS
    α c m po
π fo pfm ¼ β po  co   : ð4Þ power structure, if the primary demand of the smart phone
2β 2 2 manufacturer, the unit manufacturing cost, and the telecom
X. Chen, X. Wang / Omega 53 (2015) 11–20 15

service operator's service price are high, the smart phone manu- power structure as
facturer will set a high retail price. On the other hand, if customers' 
  α cm co 2
sensitivity to the smart phone retail price and the telecom service π bm pvm ¼ β   ð11Þ
3β 3 3
operator's service price are high, the manufacturer will set a low
retail price.
In addition, if the telecom service operator's service price, unit From Proposition 3 and (6), we obtain the telecom service
manufacturing cost, and customers' sensitivity to the smart phone operator's maximum profit in a bundled channel and VN power
retail price are high, the telecom service operator would give more structure as
subsidies to the smart phone manufacturer. On the other hand, if 
  α cm co 2
the service cost and primary demand of the smart phone manu- π bo ρv ¼ β   ð12Þ
facturer are high, the telecom service operator would give fewer 3β 3 3
subsidies to the smart phone manufacturer.
From Proposition 2 and (5), we obtain the smart phone Then, the smart phone supply chain's maximum profit in a
manufacturer's maximum profit in a bundled channel and TS bundled channel and VN power structure, denoted π b pvm ; ρv , is
power structure as 
  α cm co 2
 2 π b pvm ; ρv ¼ 2β   : ð13Þ
  α c m co 3β 3 3
π bm ptm ¼ β   ð8Þ
4β 4 4

5.3. Manufacturer Stackelberg (MS) model


From Proposition 2 and (6), we obtain the telecom service
operator's maximum profit in a bundled channel and TS power In the case of a MS power structure, the telecom service
structure as operator and smart phone manufacturer make their decisions in
 2 sequence. The order of events is as follows. First, the telecom
  α cm c o service operator determines the subsidy in response to the given
π bo ρt ¼ 2β   ð9Þ
4β 4 4 smart phone retail price. Then, the manufacturer takes the telecom
service operator's response function into consideration for an
optimal smart phone retail price to maximize profit. Finally, when
Then, the smart phone supply chain's maximum profit in a
  the customer demand is realized, the manufacturer and telecom
bundled channel and TS power structure, denoted π b ptm ; ρt , is
service operator gain their revenue.
 2
  α cm co As to the smart phone manufacturer's optimal retail price (pm m)
π b ptm ; ρt ¼ 3β   : ð10Þ and the telecom service operator's subsidy (ρm ) in a bundled channel
4β 4 4
and MS power structure, the following proposition is obtained:

Proposition 4. In a bundled channel and MS power structure,


3α cm co cm 3co α
m ¼ 4β þ 4 þ 4  po and ρ ¼ po þ 4  4  4β:
pm
5.2. Vertical Nash (VN) model m

In the case of a VN power structure, the smart phone manu- This proposition means that in a bundled channel and MS
facturer and telecom service operator make their decisions simul- power structure, the smart phone manufacturer's optimal retail
taneously. The order of events is as follows. The smart phone price and the telecom service operator's subsidy are existent and
manufacturer determines the response function of smart phone unique.
retail price to maximize profit given the telecom service operator's From Proposition 4, we can directly gain the following insight:
subsidy, and the telecom service operator determines the response
m is an increasing function of α, cm and co , and is a
Insight 4. pm
function of subsidy to maximize profit given the manufacturer's decreasing function of β and po . ρm is an increasing function of po ,
retail price. Finally, when the customer demand is realized, the cm and β, and is a decreasing function of co and α.
manufacturer and telecom service operator gain their revenue.
As to the smart phone manufacturer's optimal retail price (pvm ) From this insight, we can also obtain similar management
and the telecom service operator's subsidy (ρv ) in a bundled insights to that from Insight 2.
channel and VN power structure, the following proposition is From Proposition 4 and (5), we obtain the smart phone
obtained: manufacturer's maximum profit in a bundled channel and MS
power structure as
Proposition 3. In a bundled channel and VN power structure, 
α
  α cm co 2
pvm ¼ 2α cm co cm 2co
3β þ 3 þ 3  po and ρ ¼ po þ 3  3  3β:
v π bm pmm ¼ 2β   ð14Þ
4β 4 4
From this proposition, we know that in a bundled channel and
VN power structure, the smart phone manufacturer's optimal
From Proposition 4 and (6), we obtain the telecom service
retail price and the telecom service operator's subsidy are existent
operator's maximum profit in a bundled channel and MS power
and unique.
structure as
From Proposition 3, we can directly gain the following insight:

  α cm co 2
π bo ρm ¼ β   ð15Þ
Insight 3. pvm is an increasing function of α, cm and co , and is a 4β 4 4
decreasing function of β and po . ρv is an increasing function of po ,
cm and β, and is a decreasing function of co and α.
Then, the smart phone supply chain's maximum profit in a
From this insight, we can obtain similar management insights m; ρ
bundled channel and MS power structure, denoted π b pm m
, is
to that from Insight 2.  2
  α cm co
From Proposition 3 and (5), we obtain the smart phone π b pmm; ρ
m
¼ 3β   : ð16Þ
4β 4 4
manufacturer's maximum profit in a bundled channel and VN
16 X. Chen, X. Wang / Omega 53 (2015) 11–20

5.4. The effect of power structure 7. Numerical example

Now we discuss the effect of power structure on the smart In this section, a numerical example is provided to demonstrate
phone supply chain's profit in a bundled channel, and the follow- the feasibility of the mathematical models and analyze the effect
ing proposition is obtained: of the telecom service operator's price (po ) on the profit of the
 m  v     smart phone manufacturer and the telecom service operator in
 v v5. π m bp
 mt 4tπm pm 4 π bm ptm , π bo ρt 4π bo ðρv Þ 4 π bo ðρm Þ
b b
Proposition different power structures. Referring to the data of China Mobile
and π pm ; ρ 4 π pm ; ρ ¼ π pm ; ρ .
b b m m
which is the world's largest telecom operator, we specify that
α ¼ 100 unit, β ¼ 2, cm ¼ 2 thousand RMB per handset and co ¼ 1
This proposition means that the smart phone supply chain
thousand RMB per customer.  Then, we derive the smart phone
member with more channel power will gain higher profit. Because f f
manufacturer's
  profit (π m pm ) and telecom service operator's
of more intense competition, the smart phone supply chain's f f
profit (π o pm ) in a free channel. In a bundled channel,   we also
maximum profit in a bundled channel and VN power structure is
derive the smart phone manufacturer's   profit (π bm ptm ) and the
higher than that in other power structures (TS and MS). This is in
telecom service operator's profit (π bo ρt ) in a TS power structure,
line with the research finding of Zhang et al. [44] that a balanced  
the smart phone manufacturer's profit (π bm pvm ) and telecom
power structure is always the best for the whole supply chain and
service operator's profit (π o ðρ Þ) in a VN power structure, and the
b v
the Vertical Nash game is equilibrium for its members.  
smart phone manufacturer's profit (π bm pm m ) and telecom service
operator's profit (π bo ðρm Þ) in a MS power structure, as shown in
Figs. 1–3.
6. Channel selection policies for smart phone supply chain Now we discuss the effects of the telecom service operator's
price on the profit of the smart phone manufacturer and telecom
In this section, we discuss the channel selection policies for service operator in TS, VN and MS power structures. From Fig. 1,
smart phone supply chain, and gain the following proposition: we know that in a free channel, the smart phone manufacturer's
profit is a decreasing function of the telecom service operator's
Proposition 6. (1) In a TS power structure, if unit price (po ), and the telecom service operator's profit changes
α α from an increasing function to a deceasing function of the telecom
oβ o ;
2po þ cm  co ð4=3Þpo þcm  ð1=3Þco service operator's unit price (po ). Figs. 1–3 illustrate that the
telecom service operator's unit price (po ) has no effect on the
then the smart phone supply chain will select a bundled channel; if
profits of the smart phone manufacturer and telecom service
0 o β r ðα=2po þcm  co Þ, then the smart phone supply chain will
operator in a bundled channel with different power structures.
select a free channel. (2) In a VN power structure, the smart phone
Fig. 1 shows that in a TS power structure, if the telecom service
supply chain will select a free channel. (3) In a MS power structure, if
operator's unit price (po ) is higher than pto , then both the smart
α α phone manufacturer and telecom service operator will gain more
 pffiffiffi  pffiffiffi o β o  pffiffiffi  pffiffiffi ;
2 þ 2 po þ c m þ 1 þ 2 c o 2 2 þ 2 po þ c m  3 þ 2 2 c o profits in a bundled channel than those in a free channel; so, the
smart phone supply chain will select a bundled channel. If the
then the smart phone supply chain will select a bundled channel; if telecom service operator's unit price (po ) is lower than pto , then the
α smart phone manufacturer and/or telecom service operator will gain
0oβr pffiffiffi  pffiffiffi ; less profits in a bundled channel than those/that in a free channel;
2 þ 2 po þ cm þ 1 þ 2 co
so, the smart phone supply chain will select a free channel.
From Fig. 2, we derive that in a VN power structure, the smart
then the smart phone supply chain will select a free channel.
phone manufacturer and telecom service operator will gain the
From this proposition, we gain the optimal channel selection same profit in a bundled channel. At the same time, the smart
policies for a smart phone supply chain under different power phone manufacturer and/or telecom service operator will gain less
structures. In TS and MS power structures, because of different profit in a bundled channel than those/that in a free channel; so,
power structures, the competition between the smart phone the smart phone supply chain will select a free channel.
manufacturer and telecom service operator is not fierce, so the Fig. 3 indicates that in a MS power structure, if the telecom
smart phone supply chain's maximum profit is lower than that in a service operator's unit price (po ) is higher than pm o , then both the
VN power structure, which means that there is more potential in smart phone manufacturer and telecom service operator will gain
TS and MS power structures to improve the smart phone supply more profits in a bundled channel than those in a free channel; so,
chain's maximum profit. In TS and MS power structures, if the the smart phone supply chain will select a bundled channel. If the
customers' sensitivity to the smart phone retail price is high, the telecom service operator's unit price (po ) is lower than pm o , then the
smart phone supply chain will select a bundled channel. In this
case, the telecom service operator can motivate the smart phone
1000
manufacturer to reduce the retail price by providing a subsidy;
900
thus the customers' demand increases, which benefits both the
800
smart phone manufacturer and the telecom service operator under
700
certain conditions. On the other hand, in a VN power structure,
600 Πm1
because of the same or similar channel power, the competition
500 Πo1
between the smart phone manufacturer and telecom service
400 Πmt( )
operator is fierce. Therefore, to be more competitive, both parties
300
have already made an effort to improve their efficiencies; so, the Πot( )
200
smart phone supply chain's maximum profit is higher than that in 100
TS and MS power structures, which means that there is less 0
potential in a VN power structure to improve the smart phone
5 15 35 45
supply chain's maximum profit. In this case, the smart phone
supply chain will select a free channel. Fig. 1. Effect of po in a TS power structure.
X. Chen, X. Wang / Omega 53 (2015) 11–20 17

1000 t profit. On the other hand, from the whole smart phone supply
900 chain's perspective, it is important for decision makers to create a
800 balanced market environment that promotes competition
700 between supply chain parties.
600 Πm1
Observation 3. We also show that different power structures have
500 Πo1
an effect on the channel selection decisions for the smart phone
400 ( )
Πmn supply chain. For example, a bundled channel will be selected in
300
Πon
( ) TS and MS power structures under certain conditions, and, in
200
contrast, a free channel will be chosen in a VN power structure.
100
The smart phone manufacturer and telecom service operator can
0 then formulate proper channel selection policies under different
5 15 25 35 45 power structures to maximize their benefits.
Fig. 2. Effect of po in a VN power structure.
The smart phone sector is a fast growing industry with
increasing complexity in competition and dynamic power rela-
1000
tionship. While Apple and Samsung maintain their market lead in
900
the smart phone market, technology giant Google also enters the
800
700
hardware market through the acquisition of Motorola despite its
600 Πm1 growing market share with the Android System. While Microsoft's
500 Πo1
acquisition of Nokia forms a strategic force for Windows smart
400 ( )
phones, other smart phone manufacturers e.g., Blackberry have
Πmm
300 launched their own operating systems. These developments add a
(
Πom )
200 new dimension of supply chain cooperation and competition in
100 the sector. Smart phone manufacturers, operating systems devel-
0 opers, and telecom service operators have an opportunity to
5 15 25 35 45 improve profitability further by better managing the channel,
subsidy, and price relative to competition. It is expected that the
Fig. 3. Effect of po in a MS power structure.
results of our study will be used as a guideline to establish
adaptable channel selection and pricing policies for smart phone
smart phone manufacturer and/or the telecom service operator will supply chains in competitive marketplaces. Additionally, the
gain less profits in a bundled channel than those/that in a free modeling approach we suggested can be applied not only to the
channel; so, the smart phone supply chain will select a free channel. smart phone industry but also other technology and service
industries.
Similar to any other model previously published in the litera-
8. Conclusions and suggestions for further research
ture, the present model is also based on some assumptions. For
example, our model only considers the smart phone supply chain
This paper studies the pricing policies, subsidy policies and
that consists of one smart phone manufacturer and one telecom
channel selection policies for a smart phone supply chain with
service operator. While this supply chain setting simplifies the
different power structures. We take into consideration the supply
modeling and provides some interesting insights, we have to
chain that consists of a smart phone manufacturer and a telecom
acknowledge that there is often fierce competition involving
service operator. The smart phone industry has distinct supply
multiple smart phone manufacturers and telecom service opera-
chain characteristics, in which both the manufacturer and telecom
tors in more mature smart phone markets. This competition will
service operator can use price and other factors to compete and
have a knock-on effect on channel selection decisions. One key
coordinate with each other. To the best of our knowledge, this is
research direction is to consider a supply chain that consists of
the first study on the impact of the power structure on the channel
multiple smart phone handset manufacturers and multiple tele-
selection and pricing problem in the smart phone supply chain.
com service operators. Second, a linear deterministic demand is
This research provides several interesting observations.
assumed in our model. One important extension of this work is to
Observation 1. There exist unique optimal retail prices for the include stochastic demand in the model. Furthermore, although
smart phone manufacturer in the free channel and bundled the impact of the telecom service price on supply chain decisions
channel with different power structures. There are also unique and profitability are examined in the analytical and numerical
optimal subsidies for the telecom service operator in bundled analyses, respectively, the service price (po ) is assumed to be fixed
channels with different power structures. Therefore, by deriving in the model. One future extension is to analytically examine the
the optimal smart phone retail prices and the optimal subsidies in optimal service price in the case when the telecom service
different supply chain channel settings, the smart phone manu- operator selects the service price after the manufacturer and the
facturer and telecom service operator can develop their appro- case where they act at the same time. Another future research
priate pricing and subsidy policies based on our findings to direction is to examine the impacts of the manufacturer's produc-
maximize their benefits. tion capacity and life expectancy of the goods and services on the
optimal pricing and channel selection strategies.
Observation 2. Our findings also show that different power
structures have significant impact on the profit of individual firms
and the entire smart phone supply chain's profitability. For Acknowledgments
instance, the firm that has higher channel power will gain more
profit, and the profit of the whole smart phone supply chain in a The authors would like to thank the anonymous referees and
VN power structure is higher than that in TS and MS power the editor for their constructive comments on an earlier version of
structures. On one hand, from the individual firm perspective, it is the paper. The authors are supported by the Royal Society Inter-
important to enhance its supply chain power to acquire more national Exchanges cost share scheme (Ref. IE131228) with the
18 X. Chen, X. Wang / Omega 53 (2015) 11–20

National Natural Science Foundation of China (No. 71411130137). From (7), we obtain
The first author is also partially supported by the National Natural dπ bo ðρÞ     
Science Foundation of China (Nos. 71272128 and 71432003), dρ
¼
 α  β m þ cm ρ þ po þ β po  ρ  co ¼  α þ βðm þcm Þ
 
Program for New Century Excellent Talents in University (No. þ 2β po  ρ  βco ;
NCET-12-0087), Specialized Research Fund for the Doctoral Pro- 2
d π bo ðρÞ
gram of Higher Education (No. 20130185110006), and Youth ¼  2β o0;
dρ2
Foundation for Humanities and Social Sciences of Ministry of
Education of the People's Republic of China (No. 11YJC630022). so π bo ðρÞ is concave in ρ. Let ððdπ bo ðρÞÞ=dρÞ ¼ 0. We obtain
 
 α þβðm þ cm Þ þ 2β po  ρ  βco ¼ 0, that is, α þ βpm þ 2βpo  βρ
 βco ¼ 0. Then
α
Appendix A ρ ¼ 2po þ pm   co ðA3Þ
β

The Proof of Proposition 1. From (A2) and (A3), we obtain


From (1), we obtain
2α cm co cm 2co α
dπ fm ðpm Þ     pvm ¼ þ þ  po and ρv ¼ po þ   :
dpm
¼ α  β pm þ po  β pm  c m ¼ α þ βcm  βpo  2βpm 3β 3 3 3 3 3β

and
2   This completes the proof.
d π fm pm
¼  2β o 0;
dpm 2 The Proof of Proposition 4.
  From (7), we obtain
so, π fm pm is concave in pm . Let ððdπ fm ðpm ÞÞ=dpm Þ ¼ 0, we obtain
    
α þ βcm  βpo  2βpm ¼ 0, so pfm ¼ ðα=2βÞ þ ðcm =2Þ  ðpo =2Þ. This com- dπ bo ðρÞ
¼  α  β m þ cm ρ þ po þ β po  ρ  co ¼  α þ βðm þcm Þ

pletes the proof.  
þ 2β po  ρ  βco ;
2
The Proof of Proposition 2. d π bo ðρÞ
¼  2β o0;
From (5), we obtain dρ2
dπ bm ðpm Þ     so π bo ðρÞ is concave in ρ. Let ððdπ bo ðρÞÞ=dρÞ ¼ 0. We obtain  α þ
dp
¼ α  β pm þ po  β pm þ ρ cm ¼ α þ βcm  βpo  βρ  2βpm ;  
m
βðm þ cm Þ þ2β po  ρ  βco ¼ 0, that is, α þ βpm þ 2βpo  βρ
2    βco ¼ 0. Then
d π bm pm
¼  2β o 0 α
dpm 2 ρ ¼ 2po þ pm  co  ðA4Þ
  β
so, π bm pm is concave in pm . Let ððdπ bm ðpm ÞÞ=dpm Þ ¼ 0, we get Substituting (A4) into (5), we obtain
α þ βcm  βpo  βρ  2βpm ¼ 0, then 
  α   
α cm po ρ b
π m pm ¼ 2pm þ2po  co   cm α  β pm þ po :
pm ¼ þ   ðA1Þ β
2β 2 2 2
Then,
    
Substituting (A1) into (6), we obtain dπ bm ðpm Þ
dpm
¼ 2 α  β pm þ po  β 2pm þ 2po  co  αβ  cm ¼ 3α þ βcm
1    þβco 4βpo  4βpm ;
π bo ðρÞ ¼ p  ρ  co α  β po þcm  ρ :
2 o 2  
d π bm pm
Then, ¼  4β o 0;
dpm 2
dπ bo ðρÞ 1   1      
¼  α  β po þcm  ρ þ β po ρ  co so, π bm pm is concave in pm . Let ððdπ bm pm Þ=dpm Þ ¼ 0. We obtain
dρ 2 2 3α þ βcm þ βco  4βpo  4βpm ¼ 0, then pm ¼ ð3α=4βÞ þ ðcm =4Þ þðco =4Þ
m
2
α  β ðc m  c o Þ d π bo ðρÞ  po . Substitute pm
m into (A4). We obtain ρ ¼ po þ ðcm =4Þ  ð3co =4Þ
m
¼ βpo  βρ  ¼ β o 0
2 dρ2  ðα=4βÞ. This completes the proof.
so π bo ðρÞ is concave in ρ. Let ððdπ bo ðρÞÞ=dρÞ ¼ 0. We obtain βpo  The Proof of Proposition 5.
βρ  ððα βðcm  co ÞÞ=2Þ ¼ 0. Then, ρt ¼ po þðcm =2Þ  ðco =2Þ  ðα=2βÞ.    v  t 
From (8), (11) and (13), we obtain π bm pm m 4 π m pm 4 π m pm .
b b
Substitute ρt into (A1). We obtain ptm ¼ ð3α=4βÞ þ ðcm =4Þ þ
 πo ρ  4 πo ðρ Þ 4 π o ðρ  Þ. From
b t b v b m
From (9), (12) and (15), we obtain 
ðco =4Þ  po . This completes the proof. (10), (13) and (16), we obtain π b pvm ; ρv 4π b ptm ; ρt ¼ π b pm m; ρ
m
.
This completes the proof.
The Proof of Proposition 3. From (5), we obtain
dπ bm ðpm Þ     The Proof of Proposition 6.
dp
¼ α  β pm þ po  β pm þ ρ cm ¼ α þ βcm  βpo  βρ  2βpm ;
m

2   (1) In a TS power structure, to let the smart phone manufacturer


d π bm pm accept the bundled channel, the manufacturer should get
¼  2β o 0;  
dpm 2 more is, π bm ptm 4
 profit
 than that in a free channel, that 
  π fm pfm . From (3) and (8), we obtain β ðα=4βÞ  ðcm =4Þ 
so, π bm pm is concave in pm . Let ððdπ bm ðpm ÞÞ=dpm Þ ¼ 0. We obtain  2
α þ βcm  βpo  βρ  2βpm ¼ 0, then ðco =4ÞÞ2 4 β ðα=2βÞ  ðcm =2Þ  ðpo =2Þ . From Proposition 1, we
f
obtain pm ¼ ðα=2βÞ þ ðcm =2Þ  ðpo =2Þ 4 cm , that is, β o ðα=po þ
cm Þ and ðα=2βÞ  ðcm =2Þ  ðpo =2Þ 4 0. Then, we obtain ðα=4βÞ 
α cm po ρ ðcm =4Þ  ðco =4Þ 4 ðα=2βÞ ðcm =2Þ  ðpo =2Þ, that is, β 4 ðα=2po þ
pm ¼ þ   ðA2Þ
2β 2 2 2 cm  co Þ. From Proposition 2, we obtain ptm ¼ ð3α=4βÞ þ ðcm =4Þ þ
X. Chen, X. Wang / Omega 53 (2015) 11–20 19

ðco =4Þ  po 4 cm , that is, that is,


α α
βo : βo :
ð4=3Þpo þ cm  ð1=3Þco 3po þ cm  2co
Hence
α α
oβ o : So, in a VN power structure, the smart phone supply chain will
2po þ cm  co ð4=3Þpo þcm  ð1=3Þco
select a free channel.
(3) In a MS power structure, to let the smart phone manufacturer
From (4) and (9), we obtain accept the bundled channel, the manufacturer should
     2   α cm po   get
π bo ρt  π fo pfm ¼ 2β 4β
α
 c4m  c4o β po  co 2β 22 more profit
 than that in a free channel, that is π bm pm
m 4

 2 π fm pfm . From (3) and (14), we obtain


α c m c o po  
¼ 2β  þ  4 0; α cm co 2 α c m po 2
4β 4 4 2 2β   4β   :
4β 4 4 2β 2 2
then the telecom service operator will accept the bundled
channel in the TS power structure. From Proposition 1, we get
So, in a TS power structure, if α cm p
α α p fm ¼ þ  o 4 cm ;
oβ o     ; 2β 2 2
2po þ cm  co 4=3 po þ cm  1=3 co
that is,
then the smart phone supply chain will select a bundled α cm po
channel; if 0 oβ r ðα=ð2po þ cm  co ÞÞ, then the smart phone   4 0:
2β 2 2
supply chain will select a free channel.
Then, we obtain
(2) In a VN power structure, to let the smart phone manufacturer
pffiffiffi α cm co  α cm po
accept the bundled channel, the manufacturer should  get more 2   4  
 v
profit than that in a free channel, that is π b
p 4 π f
p f 4β 4 4 2β 2 2
 m m 2
m m  . From
(3) and (11), we obtain β ðα=3βÞ  ðcm =3Þ  ðco =3Þ 4 β ðα=2βÞ that is,
 ðcm =2Þ ðpo =2ÞÞ2 . From Proposition 1, we obtain pfm ¼ ðα=2βÞ þ α
ðcm =2Þ  ðpo =2Þ 4 cm , that is, ðα=2βÞ  ðcm =2Þ  ðpo =2Þ 4 0. Then, β4 pffiffiffi  pffiffiffi :
2 þ 2 po þ c m þ 1 þ 2 c o
we obtain ðα=3βÞ  ðcm =3Þ  ðco =3Þ 4 ðα=2βÞ  ðcm =2Þ  ðpo =2Þ,
that is, β 4 α=ð3po þ cm 2co Þ:
To let the telecom service operator accept the bundled channel in a
VN power structure, she should  get more profit than that in a free To let the telecom service operator accept the bundled channel
channel, that is π bo ðρv Þ 4 π fo pfm . From (4) and (12), we obtain
in a MS power structure, the telecom service operator should get
   
α cm co 2   α c m po more profit than that in a free channel, that is π bo ðρm Þ 4 π fo pfm .
β   4 β po  c o   ;
3β 3 3 2β 2 2
From (4) and (12), we obtain
 2 
that is, α cm co   α c m po
β   4 β po  c o   ;
  4β 4 4 2β 2 2
α cm co 2   α c m po
   po  co  
3β 3 3 2β 2 2 that is,
 2   2   α cm po 
α cm co   α c m co β 4βα
 c4m  c4o  β po  co 2β 22
¼    po  c o  
3β 3 3 2β 2 2  2  α c  
9 2 po co 2 α cm co
 2
þ p  co  6 ¼β 4β  4  4  po  co 2β  2m  c2o þ po  co
16 o  4 
 2 #
α cm co 3 po  co p co α cm co po  c o
¼    þ o  
3β 3 3 4 4 3β 3 3 
  2
3 po  c o p  co "
  o 2  #
4 4 α cm 3 po  c o 2
  ¼β  þ co po  pffiffiffi
α c m po c o α cm 2 4β 4 4 2
¼   þ   po þ co 4 0:  
3β 3 2 6 3β 3 3 α cm 3 po co α cm 3 p  co
¼β  þ co  po þ pffiffiffi  þ co  po  opffiffiffi 4 0:
4β 4 4 2 4β 4 4 2
From Proposition 3, we obtain
2α cm co From Proposition 4, we obtain
pvm ¼ þ þ  po 4 c m ;
3β 3 3
3α cm co
pm
m¼ þ þ  po 4 c m
4β 4 4
that is,
that is,
α c m po c o β 4
  þ 4 0: α  βcm þ co  βpo 4 0;
3β 3 2 6 3 3
Then, so
" pffiffiffi #
α cm 2 α cm 3 p  co 1 β 4 6 28  
  po þ c o 4 0  þ co po þ opffiffiffi ¼ α βcm þ co  βpo þ β po  co 4 0:
3β 3 3 4β 4 4 2 4β 3 3 3
20 X. Chen, X. Wang / Omega 53 (2015) 11–20

Then, we obtain [18] Ho H, Ganesan S, Oppewal H. The impact of store-price signals on consumer
search and store evaluation. Journal of Retailing 2011;87(2):127–41.
α cm 3 p  co
 þ co  po  opffiffiffi 4 0; [19] Horváth C, Fok D. Moderating factors of immediate, gross, and net cross-brand
4β 4 4 2 effects of price promotions. Marketing Science 2013;32(1):127–52.
[20] Huang Z, Li SX. Co-op advertising models in manufacturer–retailer supply
that is, chains: a game theory approach. European Journal of Operational Research
α 2001;135(3):527–44.
βo  pffiffiffi  pffiffiffi : [21] Ingene CA, Parry ME. Channel coordination when retailers compete. Market-
2 2 þ 2 po þ cm  3 þ2 2 co ing Science 1995;14(4):360–77.
[22] Jeuland AP, Shugan SM. Managing channel profits. Marketing Science 1983;2
So, in a MS power structure, if (3):239–72.
[23] Kadiyali V, Chintagunta P, Vilcassim N. Manufacturer–retailer channel inter-
α α
 pffiffiffi  pffiffiffi oβ o  pffiffiffi  pffiffiffi ; actions and implications for channel power: an empirical investigation of
2 þ 2 po þ cm þ 1 þ 2 co 2 2 þ 2 po þ cm  3 þ 2 2 co pricing in a local market. Marketing Science 2000;19(2):127–48.
[24] Khouja M, Park S, Cai G. Channel selection and pricing in the presence of
then the smart retail-captive consumers. International Journal of Production Economics
 phone
pffiffiffi supply chain
 will
pffiffiffi select a bundled channel; 2010;125:84–95.
if 0 oβ r ðα= 2 þ 2 po þ cm þ 1 þ 2 co Þ, then the smart phone
[25] Kolay S, Shaffer G. Contract design with a dominant retailer and a competitive
supply chain will select a free channel. This completes the proof. fringe. Management Science 2013;59(9):2111–6.
[26] Krishnan TV, Bass FM, Jain DC. Optimal pricing strategy for new products.
Management Science 1999;45:1650–63.
[27] Krishnan TV, Bass FM, Kumar V. Impact of late entrant on the diffusion of a
new product/service. Journal of Marketing Research 2000;37(2):269–78.
References
[28] Kopalle P, Biswas D, Chintagunta PK, Fan J, Pauwels K, Ratchford BT, et al.
Retailer pricing and competitive effects. Journal of Retailing 2009;85
[1] Ailawadi KL, Borin N, Farris PW. Market power and performance: a cross- (1):56–70.
industry analysis of manufacturers and retailers. Journal of Retailing [29] Levy M, Grewal D, Kopalle PK, Hess JD. Emerging trends in retail pricing
1995;71(3):211–48. practice: implications for research. Journal of Retailing 2004;80(3):xiii–xi.
[2] Benton WC, Maloni M. The influence of power driven buyer/seller relation- [30] Montgomery CA. Product-market diversification and market power. Academy
ships on supply chain satisfaction. Journal of Operations Management of Management Journal 1985;28(4):789–98.
2005;23(1):1–22. [31] Moorthy S. A general theory of pass-through in channels with category
[3] Cai GG, Zhang ZG, Zhang M. Game theoretical perspectives on dual-channel management and retail competition. Marketing Science 2005;24(1):110–22.
supply chain competition with price discounts and pricing schemes. Interna- [32] Padmanabhan V, Png IPL. Manufacturers return policies and retail competi-
tional Journal of Production Economics 2009;117(1):80–96. tion. Marketing Science 1997;16(1):81–94.
[4] Cai G. Channel selection and coordination in dual-channel supply chains. [33] Raju J, Zhang ZJ. Channel coordination in the presence of a dominant retailer.
Journal of Retailing 2010;86(1):22–36. Marketing Science 2005;24(2):254–62.
[5] Cattani KD, Gilland WG, Heese HS, Swaminathan JM. Boiling frogs: pricing [34] Shi R, Zhang J, Ru J. Impacts of power structure on supply chains with
strategies for a manufacturer adding a direct channel that competes with the uncertain demand. Production and Operations Management 2013;22
traditional channel. Production and Operations Management 2006;15(1):40. (5):1232–49.
[6] Chen LG, Ding D, Ou J. Power structure and profitability in assembly supply [35] Singh N, Vives X. Price and quantity competition in a differentiated duopoly.
chains. Production and Operations Management 2014;23(9):1599–616. Rand Journal of Economics 1984;15(4):546–54.
[7] Chen X, Ling L, Zhou M. Manufacturer's pricing strategy for supply chain with [36] Tsay AA, Agrawal N. Channel conflict and coordination in the e-commerce age.
warranty period-dependent demand. Omega 2012;40(12):807–16.
Production and Operations Management 2004;13(1):93–110.
[8] Chiang WK, Chhajed D, Hess JD. Direct marketing, indirect profits: a strategic
[37] Van HH, Els G, Koen P. Winners and losers in a major price war. Journal of
analysis of dual-channel supply chain design. Management Science
Marketing Research 2008;45(5):499–518.
2003;49(1):1–20.
[38] Vives X. On the efficiency of Bertrand and Cournot equilibria with product
[9] Choi SC. Price competition in a channel structure with a common retailer.
differentiation. Journal of Economic Theory 1985;36:166–75.
Marketing Science 1991;10(4):271–96.
[39] Wang X, Li D. A dynamic product quality evaluation based pricing model for
[10] Choi SC. Price competition in a duopoly common retailer channel. Journal of
perishable food supply chains. Omega 2012;40(6):906–17.
Retailing 1996;72(2):117–34.
[40] Wang Y. Joint pricing-production decisions in supply chains of complemen-
[11] Cohen MA, Whang S. Competing in product and service: a product life-cycle
model. Management Science 1997;43(4):535–45. tary products with uncertain demand. Operations Research 2006;54
[12] Cox A, Cox D. Competing on price: the role of retail price advertisements in (6):1110–27.
shaping store-price image. Journal of Retailing 1990;66(4):428–45. [41] Wu Z, Zhu W, Crama P. The newsvendor problem with advertising revenue.
[13] Cox A. Power, value and supply chain management. Supply Chain Manage- Manufacturing & Service Operations Management 2011;13(3):281–96.
ment: An International Journal 1999;4(4):167–75. [42] Wu Z, Crama P, Zhu W. The newsvendor's optimal incentive contracts for
[14] Dedrick J, Kraemer KL, Linden G. The distribution of value in the mobile phone multiple advertisers. European Journal of Operational Research 2012;220
supply chain. Telecommunications Policy 2011;35(6):505–21. (1):171–81.
[15] Dockner E, Jorgensen S. Optimal pricing strategies for new products in [43] Zhang J, Chiang WY, Liang L. Strategic pricing with reference effects in a
dynamic oligopolies. Marketing Science 1988;7(4):315–34. competitive supply chain. Omega 2014;44:126–35.
[16] Ertek G, Griffin PM. Supplier- and buyer-driven channels in a two-stage supply [44] Zhang R, Liu B, Wang W. Pricing decisions in a dual channels system with
chain. IIE Transactions 2002;34(8):691–700. different power structures. Economic Modelling 2012;29(2):523–33.
[17] Grewal D, Ailawadi KL, Gauri D, Hall K, Kopalle P, Robertson JR. Innovations in [45] Zhou Y, Xie J. Potentially self-defeating: group buying in a two-tier supply
retail pricing and promotions. Journal of Retailing 2011;87(1):43–52. chain. Omega 2014;49:42–52.

You might also like