You are on page 1of 10

See discussions, stats, and author profiles for this publication at: https://www.researchgate.

net/publication/327810675

Unpacking the extractivist state: The role of weak state agencies in promoting
institutional change in Peru

Article  in  The Extractive Industries and Society · September 2018


DOI: 10.1016/j.exis.2018.08.007

CITATION READS

1 62

2 authors, including:

Maria-Therese Gustafsson
Stockholm University
18 PUBLICATIONS   40 CITATIONS   

SEE PROFILE

Some of the authors of this publication are also working on these related projects:

Glocalizing Climate Governance (GlocalClim) View project

Climate change and security View project

All content following this page was uploaded by Maria-Therese Gustafsson on 28 January 2019.

The user has requested enhancement of the downloaded file.


The Extractive Industries and Society 6 (2019) 206–214

Contents lists available at ScienceDirect

The Extractive Industries and Society


journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/exis

Original article

Unpacking the extractivist state: The role of weak state agencies in T


promoting institutional change in Peru
Maria-Therese Gustafssona, , Martin Scurrahb

a
Stockholm University, Department of Political Science, Universitetsvagen 10F, SE-10691 Stockholm, Sweden
b
Instituto de Estudios Peruanos, Av Horacio Urteaga 694, Jesús María, Peru

ARTICLE INFO ABSTRACT

Keywords: When a resource boom has begun it is often challenging to develop institutions for governing natural resources in
Extractive governance an inclusive and sustainable manner. Whereas existing studies on resource-rich states have focused on political
Land-use zoning policies elites or social mobilization for explaining attempts to strengthen such institutions, we know less about the role
Peru of less influential reform-oriented agencies (e.g. environmental agencies, subnational governments), and what
Institutional weakness and change
explains how and why on rare occasions they are surprisingly effective in driving institutional change.
Mining conflicts
Theoretically, we draw on theories on institutional weakness and change. Based on 139 interviews, we analyze
the outcomes of different strategies adopted by the Peruvian Environmental Ministry (MINAM) to enforce a
participatory zoning and land-use planning (LUP) reform between 2008 and 2016. We argue that weak agencies
are dependent upon strategic ability, here referring to the skill of an agency to adapt its strategies to reigning
political opportunities, thereby contributing to defending or expanding its autonomy vis-á-vis powerful groups
and building alliances with societal actors that could defend it from opponents. By unpacking the dynamics
within a resource-rich state, we contribute with a nuanced analysis of the challenges of building and effectively
enforcing institutions in a context of expanding extractive industries.

1. Introduction subnational governments, in enforcing weak institutions. A few


scholars have emphasized the role of subnational governments (e.g.
In recent decades, governments across the globe have promoted Bebbington et al., 2018: 12; Walter and Urkidi, 2017), as well as re-
the expansion of extractive industries. In order to reduce the en- form-oriented, entrepreneurial agencies, such as the Ombudsman,
vironmental and social costs of large-scale resource extraction or le- that, despite their marginalized position in the state as a whole, have
gitimize the expansion of the extractive frontier, governments have played an important role in driving institutional change (Paredes and
increasingly given in to international and domestic pressure and De la Puente, 2017). Still, we know relatively little about the role of
adopted such institutions as free, prior and informed consent and such agencies and what explains more or less successful attempts to
public participation in environmental impact assessment (Leifsen enforce institutions for promoting inclusive development in the pre-
et al., 2017). Whereas there is a consensus about the importance of sence of mining. In particular, what are the sources of power and
such institutions for fostering inclusive development, we know much strategies that are available for weak agencies in their efforts to en-
less about how these institutions emerge, are sustained over time and force such institutions in the context of expanding extractive in-
enforced effectively (Bebbington et al., 2018: 2; Waldner and Smith, dustries? The article contributes to disentangling the power dynamics
2015). There is a burgeoning literature focusing upon the role of so- within the Peruvian state by analyzing the environmental ministry’s
cietal mobilization (e.g. Bebbington and Bury, 2009; Falleti and efforts to enforce participatory ecological and economic zoning (EEZ)
Riofrancos, 2018), political settlements (Bebbington et al., 2018; and related land-use planning (LUP) institutions. A wide range of
McCullough, 2017), and the ways in which elites or companies un- actors, such as local communities, civil society actors and the OECD
dermine or block such institutions (Aguilar-Støen and Hirsch, 2015; suggest that, by assessing different land-use alternatives and involving
Schilling-Vacaflor et al., 2018; Gustafsson, 2017). However, we know local groups in discussions about appropriate use of land, LUP would
much less about the dynamics within states and, in particular, about foster inclusive and locally sustainable resource governance in the
the role of less influential agencies, such as environmental agencies or presence of mining (Bebbington and Bury, 2009; 17300; CEPAL/


Corresponding author.
E-mail address: mariatherese.gustafsson@statsvet.su.se (M.-T. Gustafsson).

https://doi.org/10.1016/j.exis.2018.08.007
Received 3 June 2018; Received in revised form 15 August 2018; Accepted 15 August 2018
Available online 21 September 2018
2214-790X/ © 2018 Published by Elsevier Ltd.
M.-T. Gustafsson, M. Scurrah The Extractive Industries and Society 6 (2019) 206–214

OECD, 2015; FAO, 1993).1 However, as planning is likely to constrain entrepreneurial agencies with a marginalized position within the state
the expansion of resource extraction, mining companies and influen- and that lack formal authority over mining have, in many cases, in-
tial state agencies are generally skeptical about LUP, and in recent tervened in extractive governance in their efforts to represent their
years LUP has become recentralized.2 constituencies or implement policies under their authority (e.g. Walter
Recognizing the heterogeneous nature of the state and drawing on and Urkidi, 2017; Paredes and De la Puente, 2017). In the following
insights from the literature on institutional weakness and change section, we will discuss central concepts related to state strength and
(Levitsky and Murillo, 2009, 2013; Mahoney and Thelen, 2009) and strategic ability and thereafter develop a typology for studying strate-
social movements (Tarrow, 1994), the article studies the role of weak gies of weak agencies.
reform-oriented agencies in enforcing LUP. We argue that weak agen- We follow a tradition of scholarship which emphasizes the hetero-
cies are dependent upon strategic ability, here referring to the skill of an geneous nature of the state (e.g. Migdal, 2001) and try to show how the
agency to adapt the timing, speed and framing of reform efforts to state comprises different components that may establish ties with and
reigning political opportunities, and allow agencies to defend or expand intervene in the defense of various societal interests related to land and
their autonomy vis-á-vis powerful groups and build alliances with so- natural resources. As Eaton’s (2017) study of Peru, Ecuador and Bolivia
cietal actors that could defend them from opponents. Conversely, by not demonstrates, conflicts between different levels of the state have be-
acting strategically, particularly in the absence of strong, supporting come more frequent. State strength is often unevenly distributed across
coalitions, weak agencies could further reduce their existing leeway, policy areas (Skocpol, 1985: 17), and commonly conceptualized along
resulting in their further weakening. Hence, strategic ability increases two dimensions: capacity and autonomy (Bersch et al., 2017). Whereas
the likelihood of success of weak agencies, even when political oppor- capacity refers to” the organizational and bureaucratic ability to im-
tunities are adverse. plement governing projects” (Centeno et al., 2017: 3), autonomy could
Empirically, the article is based on a within-case analysis comparing be defined as the ability to” formulate and pursue goals that are not
the Peruvian environmental ministry’s (MINAM) efforts to promote LUP simply reflective of the demands or interests of social groups, classes or
during three distinct periods from 2008 until 2016, emphasizing how society” (Skocpol, 1985: 9). Importantly, capacity and autonomy do not
actors inside and outside the state with different interests and sources of necessarily vary together, but these dimensions could be combined
power blocked or supported MINAM. Whereas the first (2008–2011) differently, creating agencies that are weak in different aspects. By
and second period (2011) were characterized by relatively favorable weak agencies we, therefore, refer to an agency that is characterized by
opportunities to promote LUP, during the third period (2012–2016) either low capacity and/or autonomy.
such opportunities were limited. Variation over time in the degree of Scholars have, for instance, assessed the relation between state ca-
external support and autonomy enjoyed by MINAM in relation to op- pacity and the relative autonomy of the state from societal actors and
ponents allows us to highlight the shifting political opportunities and shown that state agencies could compensate for weaknesses in their
constraints in the face of which MINAM adopted different strategies for capacity through close ties with powerful economic groups (Evans,
implementing LUP. 1995). Strong ties with economic actors can generate resources, in-
Peru is an interesting case for studying weak agencies, as mining is formation and manpower, but also reduce such agencies’ autonomy.
an important driver of economic growth. With weak civil society actors This may also lead to the creation of powerful segments within the state
and a unified political and economic elite, Peru also offers a hard test of that are dominated by narrow interests (Centeno et al., 2017: 23) and
weak agencies’ ability to enforce contested institutions, such as LUP. that could undermine the ability of weaker state agencies to pursue
The article is based on empirical material collected during field their goals (Soifer and Vom Hau, 2008: 224). For weak agencies trying
work in 2015, 2016 and 2017 (in total 4,5 months) and that consists of to enforce institutions threatening the interests of powerful economic
written primary sources as well as 139 semi-structured interviews actors and state agencies, international support, such as that from aid
during three periods with national and regional authorities, re- agencies or transnational civil society (cf. Keck and Sikkink, 1998), as
presentatives of mining corporations, civil society and aid agencies. We well as broad-based domestic support, such as that from social move-
have also participated in national workshops, training of civil servants ments or political parties (North, 1995: 25), could constitute an im-
and information meetings, and analyzed the implementation of LUP in portant source of power and enable weak agencies to build capacity and
three regions. Thus, to reconstruct a complex political process we have counterbalance the resistance of corporate actors and political elites. To
primarily relied on the first-hand information of key actors. To avoid generate external support is, therefore, crucial for weak agencies.
biased accounts, we carefully selected informants with different Drawing on insights from the social movement literature, we argue
knowledge and interests in relation to the processes studied and com- that weak agencies need strategic ability to adapt to the pressures from
pared their statements and, when possible, also with written docu- opponents and attract available support. A commonly-held assumption
ments. We analyzed the data with the support of Nvivo. in this literature is that the success of social movements relies on their
ability to act strategically in relation to existing political opportunities,
commonly referred to as the “consistent– but not necessarily formal or
2. Studying the strategic ability of reform-oriented, weak agencies permanent – dimensions of the political environment that provide in-
centives for people to undertake collective action by affecting their
There is a tendency in the literature on resource-rich states to por- expectations for success or failure” (Tarrow, 1994: 85). Some scholars
tray the state as a unitary actor and to focus on the role of rent-seeking have demonstrated how institutional entrepreneurs with the ability to
or more progressive political elites (e.g. Karl, 1997; Haslam and build support by framing reforms in a way that is convincing among
Heidrich, 2016). This is hardly surprising given that large-scale re- groups with different interests have played important roles in driving
source projects are generally under centralized authority and political institutional change (Sweet et al., 2001; Paredes and De la Puente,
settlements between political and economic elites shape institutional 2017). However, it is unusual to study how weak agencies take ad-
outcomes in important ways (e.g. Bebbington et al., 2018). Still, vantage of such opportunities.
In the rest of this section, we draw primarily on Levitsky and
1 Murillo’s (2009: 2013) work on the enforcement of weak institutions to
Plataforma para el Ordenamiento territorial. Pronunciamiento: "Exigimos
un proceso de ordenamiento territorial descentralizado." Published September develop a typology (see Table 1) of different strategies. The typology
14, 2016. Accessed May 18, 2018, http://ordenamientoterritorialot.blogspot. elaborates on two structural variables – “external support” and “relative
se/2016/09/lima-14-de-setiembre-del-2016.html. autonomy” – that shape enforcement possibilities. External support
2
Interview with representative of mining companies’ interest organization, could play an important role in enhancing capacity, as well as providing
March 2015. political support. However, as suggested above, external support may

207
M.-T. Gustafsson, M. Scurrah The Extractive Industries and Society 6 (2019) 206–214

Table 1 three decades, including neoliberal restructuring and rapid expansion,


Enforcement strategies. provoking, as a consequence, rising social conflicts. In the early 1990’s,
Relative autonomy (vis-á-vis veto players) the authoritarian populist government of Alberto Fujimori introduced
reforms that drastically reduced the importance of state regulation and
High Low planning institutions and debilitated political parties and civil society
organizations (Wise, 2003). The state principally assumed the role of a
External support Strong Full-scale enforcement Weak enforcement
Weak Gradual enforcement Non-enforcement
promoter of private investment, in particular in the mining sector,
through attractive tax incentives and simplification of concession pro-
cedures (Bebbington et al., 2018: 45). Consequently, foreign investment
also reduce autonomy. Levitsky and Murillo ((2009): 117) define en- in mining increased rapidly and Peru is today the world’s third largest
forcement as the degree to which institutions such as LUP are “com- producer of silver, copper, and zinc, fourth largest of lead, and the fifth
plied with in practice” (Levitsky and Murillo, 2009: 117) and describe largest producer of gold.3 However, this rapid territorial transformation
different forms of enforcement of dormant institutions —from full-scale has generated overlaps with other forms of land-use, in particular those
enforcement to gradual, weak and non-enforcement. We refer to these of peasant communities, resulting in a large number of conflicts. In
as enforcement strategies. These strategies differ in terms of speed, April 2018, the Ombudsman (2018) reported 127 socio-environmental
timing, and framing of enforcement. Below we will discuss each in turn, conflicts.
focusing upon the viability of the strategies in relation to different To deal with these conflicts, the government has in recent years
degrees of autonomy vis-á-vis veto-players (e.g. mining companies) and introduced several important reforms – such as prior consultation
external support (international actors, civil society, political parties). (Schilling-Vacaflor et al., 2018), participation in Environmental Impact
Full-scale enforcement is the most ambitious but also the riskiest Assessments (Jaskoski, 2014), transference of mining revenues to sub-
strategy for rapidly enforcing a dormant institution (Levitsky and national governments (Arellano-Yanguas, 2011) and decentralized LUP.
Murillo, 2013: 105). To be successful, this strategy is expected to re- Similarly, environmental institutions have, despite weak organizational
quire a high degree of external support and autonomy. Timing and capacity, been strengthened in recent years with the creation of the
framing are also likely to be crucial. Still, the risk of miscalculating the Ministry for the Environment (2008), the Office for Environmental
preferences and power of veto-players is high (Levitsky and Murillo, Evaluation and Supervision — OEFA (2008), and the National Service
2013: 122). Gradual enforcement refers to a strategy to enforce an in- for Environmental Certification — SENACE (2012) (Orihuela and
itially weak institution over time and is expected to be viable in cases of Paredes, 2017). Overall, whereas the adoption of these institutions has
relatively high autonomy, while allowing agencies to build up coali- helped to some extent to ensure dialogue between companies and
tions over time. While a slow process provides more opportunities to communities, reduce negative impacts and distribute profits, these in-
assess the preferences of potential veto-players, there is still a risk of stitutions are generally weakly enforced and, in fact, MINAM itself was
miscalculation. One solution that would apply to both full-scale and directly weakened during the course of the Humala administration.
gradual enforcement is to include informal power holders in the process
(Levitsky and Murillo, 2013: 105). As these actors may use the inside
3.1. LUP as a route to inclusive and sustainable resource governance
position to try to block, delay or deviate institutional reforms, institu-
tional supporters also need to be incorporated (Falleti and Riofrancos,
The rapid and uncoordinated expansion of extractive industries has
2018). Another solution in the case of gradual enforcement is to care-
generated significant geographical overlaps between mining conces-
fully frame and disguise the efforts to enforce the institution (Mahoney
sions, agricultural lands and water resources (Cuba et al., 2014).
and Thelen, 2009: 25), thereby ensuring institutional stability and al-
Bebbington and Bury (2009), 17300) argue that, by involving local
lowing the agency to develop capacities and construct coalitions while
groups in discussions about appropriate use of land, LUP could help to
waiting for the right moment for full-scale enforcement. Weak en-
align mining expansion with existing local livelihoods. In Peru, LUP
forcement refers to the “softening (or elimination) of an institution’s
comprises a technical (EEZ) and a political (territorial ordering – Or-
effect on informal veto players and other potential losers” (Levitsky and
denamiento Territorial – OT) process. More specifically, EEZ is defined as
Murillo, 2013: 101) and increases the likelihood that these actors ac-
‘a participatory and concerted, dynamic and flexible process aimed at
cept rules that they otherwise would have tried to block. Finally, non-
identifying different alternatives for the sustainable use of a specific
enforcement refers to the efforts to ensure formal institutional stability
territory’ (author’s translation; DS No. 087–2004-PCM). OT is defined
(Levitsky and Murillo, 2013: 101) in cases of low degrees of autonomy
as ‘a state policy, a political and technical process for taking agreed-
and weak external support at the expense of enforcement. With regard
upon decisions among social, economic, political, and technical actors,
to weak and non-enforcement, the difference between short-term be-
for an organised and sustainable use of the territory’ (RM No.
havior and long-run strategies must be emphasized (Mahoney and
026–2010-MINAM). EEZ and OT are thus two different steps in LUP.
Thelen, 2009: 22). These are short-term strategies that allow agencies
In Peru, demands for participatory LUP have primarily emerged
to bide their time and build coalitions and capacity. In both of these
from subnational actors and civil society that are critical of the adverse
cases it is important to distinguish between actors with transformatory
effects of extractive industries.4 They emphasize the importance of
goals and so-called “parasites” that seek to preserve an institution while
binding LUPs that structure any investments in mining, hydrocarbons,
at the same time carrying out “actions that contradict the “spirit” or the
construction, or commercial agriculture. However, it is important to
purpose of the institution, thus undermining it” (Mahoney and Thelen,
recognize that in many countries LUP has been surrounded by conflicts
2009: 24). State agencies, for example, commonly use depolitization to
and undermined by political and economic elites' attempt to control
undermine the effective participation of local communities in extractive
such policies, sometimes contributing to the reinforcement of existing
projects (Schilling-Vacaflor et al., 2018). In the following sections we
power structures (Broegaard et al., 2017; Baletti, 2012).
will, after providing some background on the Peruvian case, apply this
LUP was first proposed by international development agencies in
framework to the analysis of MINAM’s efforts to institutionalize LUP
the 1990s. Between 2002 and 2003, two important laws, the Law of
between 2008 and 2016.
Decentralisation (Law No. 27,783) and the Law of Regional

3. The mining sector and planning in Peru 3


http://www.indexmundi.com/minerals/?product=leadandgraph=
production, accessed April 8, 2018.
Peru’s mining sector underwent major transformations in the last 4
See endnote 1.

208
M.-T. Gustafsson, M. Scurrah The Extractive Industries and Society 6 (2019) 206–214

Governments (Law No. 27,867), that defined regional governments’ Table 2


competencies in LUP, were adopted. The second law established that Formal and de facto planning agencies in Peru.
regional governments had the autonomy to formulate, execute and Institution Planning instrument Capacity Autonomy
approve territorial plans (article 53). In 2004, the EEZ Regulations were
adopted (DS No. 087–2004-PCM). An important aspect of this regula- MEF MMM-PB High High
MEM Mining concessions High Medium
tion is that regional governments can define and delineate headwaters
CEPLAN Strategic Development Plans Low Low
as areas of conservation (article 9). However, while regional govern- MINAM Land-use Planning Medium Low
ments have the formal authority to implement LUP under the mon-
itoring of MINAM, Peru remains a highly centralized country with weak
regional governments (Eaton, 2017). The distribution of power between for the private sector and facilitated the expansion of mining explora-
the actors that are in favor (MINAM, regional governments and civil tion. While its capacity level may be classified as high, its level of au-
society organizations) and opposed to LUP (Ministry of Economy and tonomy is less clear because, on the one hand, it is a highly technical
Finance — MEF, Ministry of Energy and Mines — MINEM, and mining agency administering an almost automatic concession system where
corporations) is thereby uneven. there is little room for discretion. On the other hand, MINEM is subject
to political pressure from the country’s most powerful political lobby
3.2. Strong and weak planning agencies in Peru where the practice of a “revolving door” operates, whereby many
ministers and high level functionaries come from or leave for the
Planning was introduced in Peru in 1962 by the creation of the mining and petroleum industries (Crabtree and Durand, 2017). The
National Planning Institute (INP) that was dissolved in 1992 by the links to the private sector (cf. Evans, 1995) as well as MEF contribute to
Fujimori government. From 1992 until the creation of the National enhancing MINEM’s capacity, illustrating how the dominance of narrow
Strategic Planning Center (CEPLAN) in 2005 there was no formal, in- interests could create uneven capacities within the state as a whole
tegrated planning mechanism in the Peruvian state. Since then, state (Centeno et al., 2017: 23).
planning of land and natural resources in Peru has mainly comprised Although CEPLAN is located within the PCM it functions more as a
two formal and two informal multi-level and multi-sectoral national high level think tank producing reports rather than as an agency in-
planning systems: the Multiyear Macroeconomic Framework (Marco fluencing government policies and decisions and determining the al-
Macroeconómico Multianual – MMM) and associated Program Budgeting location of resources.7 Nevertheless, it does oversee the development of
within MEF and the system for granting mining concessions within regional strategic plans which incorporate information from the re-
MINEM, on the one hand, and the National Strategic Planning System gional EEZ reports. In a state notorious for its focus on the short term,
directed by CEPLAN within the Premier’s Department (PCM) and re- the medium and long-term strategic plans developed by CEPLAN are
gional LUP directed by MINAM, on the other. A former director of largely ignored (OECD, 2016: 23). In an interview with CEPLAN func-
CEPLAN stated that planning “expresses not only the vision and mission tionaries in July, 2016, they acknowledged: “What clearly exists is a
of a country and its regions but also establishes the strategic guidelines, MEF which is very strong and very powerful in all respects. MEF is the
principal investment projects and national priorities” (Alarco Tosoni, center of the Government of Peru and decides how much is spent, on
2017: 28) but then went on to argue that “national strategic planning what it is spent, how it is spent, in manner and form, etc. And this is a
does not exist in Peru” (Alarco Tosoni, 2017: 35). Agreeing with this power we have not been able to break.”
assessment, we will argue that there is a high degree of institutional Finally, MINAM is responsible for monitoring the regional govern-
incoherence between these plans and that formal planning, undertaken ments in their implementation of LUP. MINAM has strengthened its
by MINAM and CEPLAN, is weak, whereas de facto planning, carried own capacity and that of regional governments to carry out LUP,
out by MEF and MINEM, is strong, resulting in selective enforcement. though this has not been without difficulties given the generally weak
These differences are also reflected in their annual budgets as a per- capacity – both technical and governance – in the regional govern-
centage of the total central government budget: MEF (14%), PCM (6%), ments. Thus, capacity building has been a slow and uneven process.
MINEM (0.7%), MINAM (0.2%), INGEMMET (0.1%) and CEPLAN Despite MINAM’s weak capacity level and reduced degree of au-
(0.01%).5 tonomy in comparison to such de facto planning agencies as MEF and
Table 2 compares the four planning institutions and the levels of MINEM, there has been a substantial public investment in the LUP
agency capacity and autonomy. process and 14 out of 25 regions are in a situation to finalize their plans.
MEF’s legitimacy is based on its ability to maintain economic sta- LUP has been by far the most controversial and conflictive planning
bility and growth (Dargent, 2015: 97). It is the ministry with the highest process precisely because it has involved an attempt by a government
concentration of internationally educated technocrats, commands a agency to enforce an institutional innovation in alliance with relatively
disproportionate share of the state’s financial resources and has devel- disempowered regional governments and in the face of opposition from
oped considerable capacity for analyzing and making proposals con- the country’s most powerful industry.
cerning the policy issues relevant to other sectors of the state (Dargent,
2015; Crabtree and Durand, 2017: 98–102).6 Technocrats within MEF
have developed a high degree of autonomy in a context of a weak po- 4. Three strategies employed to promote LUP
litical class (Dargent, 2015) and MEF is by far the most powerful
ministry with high levels of capacity and autonomy. Based on the conceptual framework we developed, this section
The second most powerful ministry within the Peruvian state is analyzes how MINAM, in a context of shifting opportunities and con-
MINEM, largely because it governs the mining and oil industries, which straints during three distinct periods between 2008 and 2016, both
have been the engines of economic growth and generators of foreign adopted different strategies for promoting LUP and demonstrated dif-
exchange and investment. Within MINEM, INGEMMET (Geological, ferent degrees of strategic ability.
Mining and Metallurgical Institute) is a highly technical agency dedi-
cated to geological research and the creation and maintenance of the
mining cadaster, which has simplified and clarified mining concessions
7
Interviews with two former directors of CEPLAN, May 2017, and, a former
5
https://www.mef.gob.pe/contenidos/presu_pub/anexo4_Ley30693.pdf. CEPLAN functionary, July 2016, two former high level functionaries of MINEM,
6
Interview with former Minister of the Environment, August 2016. July 2016, and a well-informed academic economist, July 2016.

209
M.-T. Gustafsson, M. Scurrah The Extractive Industries and Society 6 (2019) 206–214

4.1. A gradual enforcement strategy (2008–2011) opposition and attract resources important for building up its own and
regional governments’ capacity to enforce LUP. In 2010, MINAM was
During this period, the political opportunities for promoting LUP also close to the adoption of a law on LUP, an important step in its
were relatively favorable. As a new, comparatively weak ministry, institutionalization. However, the strategies adopted in the subsequent
MINAM was not perceived as a threat by technocratic and business period paralyzed and, with regard to the law proposal, dismantled the
actors and could therefore advance relatively autonomously. Thus, it advances achieved to that point.
was a time when an institutional innovation could advance in its im-
plementation. At the same time, MINAM and regional governments
4.2. A full-scale enforcement strategy in the face of mining expansion
obtained resources from both MEF and international development
(2011)
agencies that perceived LUP as an innovation in regional planning,
rather than as an instrument for opposing mining projects. Thus
At the beginning of the brief second period, given the high-level
framed, it was possible to reduce possible opposition from the mining
political support from the newly elected reformist government, there
industry. Within this context, MINAM was able to significantly improve
seemed to be a political opportunity to make more rapid advances in
its level of technical expertise and overall implementation capacity, as
LUP. In this context, MINAM employed an aggressive strategy similar to
well as advance the LUP law proposal.
that adopted by the Velasco Government in the 1970s which, for a time,
Upon his appointment in 2008 as the first Minister for the
achieved a degree of autonomy which enabled it to advance its radical
Environment, Antonio Brack was able to obtain considerable financial
reform agenda (Cleaves and Scurrah, 1980: 132-136). However, the
support from the international community.8 These resources and links
autonomous space for advancing regional LUP abruptly closed down
to the international community gave MINAM some leverage and re-
when the Cajamarca regional government, initially with support from
duced its dependence on MEF.
MINAM, employed its LUP report (OR No. 018-2010-GR.CAJ-CR) to
The promotion of LUP advanced within the new ministry as a re-
attempt to block the Conga mining project. The resulting open con-
latively invisible and autonomous activity.9 The initial, technical phase
frontation with the mining industry and its allies proved to be dama-
of LUP was not only promoted by the central government but also by
ging to the development of LUP, which was now framed as a political
NGOs with international financial support and MINAM’s accompani-
instrument to oppose mining expansion.
ment. In a manner similar to participatory budgeting and development
In his inaugural Message to the Nation on July 28, 2011, newly-
planning, one informant described LUP as an institutional innovation in
elected President Ollanta Humala announced that one of the priorities
the context of a return to democracy and a renewed effort at decen-
of his government would be “to advance profoundly in the policies of
tralization.10 Another informant claimed that MEF was supportive and
land-use planning in order to define, in a participatory way, the rational
participated in different meetings with MINAM.11 Furthermore, in-
use of our territory”.15 This, together with the unanimous passage of the
volvement of mining industry representatives in a multisectoral ad-
law approving prior consultation of indigenous peoples (Law No.
visory commission enabled MINAM to understand its opponent.
29785), passed shortly afterwards, could be interpreted as a radical
During this period, only 5 out of 25 regions completed their EEZ.
shift in government policy. During the election campaign Humala and
Two factors stand out as important explanations for the relatively slow
his advisors had argued that measures such as these were necessary to
progress. First, MINAM, as a newly created ministry, lacked the tech-
even up the balance in favor of those affected by extractive activities
nical capacity to offer training and methodological guidelines to re-
and to reduce the number and intensity of socio environmental con-
gional governments, although it was free from external interference
flicts, which were attributed in many cases to the automatic granting of
aimed at restricting its autonomy.12 Second, the implementation of the
mining concessions. LUP’s most active proponents argued publicly that
decentralization reform had been incomplete and created regional
it would enable subnational governments to develop plans which would
governments with unclear mandates, weak capacities and heavy de-
indicate zones where mining would be suitable or recommendable with
pendence on the central government for funding (Eaton, 2017). For the
conditions or restrictions and zones where it would be inadvisable or
regional governments, the development of LUP was not only a new
forbidden. In March, 2015, a lawyer at a Lima-based NGO argued that
experience but one with unclear immediate benefits. These conditions
“these plans are no longer seen as technical processes but also as social
suggested that a “slow and steady” strategy would consolidate the
and political processes involving concertation and of interest for de-
process more than a “fast and furious” one, whose risks are illustrated in
ciding the use of the territory.” Such plans would complement and
the following section.
correct the mining concession process and would be tantamount to
One important factor that enabled regional governments and
territorial reorganization.
MINAM to advance with LUP was the investment financing that was
The new Minister for the Environment and his team were viewed
obtained from 2004 onwards from MEF.13 MINAM adopted a con-
with deep suspicion by mining companies, as reflecting the views of the
ciliatory approach towards the private sector, reinforcing a perception
more radical wing of the environmental movement. In the words of a
of LUP as a promising innovation for gradually strengthening regional
mining executive in July, 2016: “To talk to a company in general about
governance rather than as a threat to the continued expansion of
EEZ and LUP, even socially responsible companies,. . . they will tell you
mining and other extractive activities.14 Hence, overall, this strategy
that they are afraid of them and of what is behind them.” This limited
was relatively successful as it enabled MINAM to neutralize possible
the room for agreement between mining companies, many of whom
were not willing to accept any limitations to the exploitation of their
8 concessions, and an environment ministry whose leadership was sen-
http://www.inforegion.pe/20590/peru-es-un-pais-importante-en-la-
conservacion-del-equilibrio-climatico-del-mundo/. sitive to the demands of the communities affected by mining. Already in
9
Interviews with functionary at MINAM, April 2015, and functionary, 2010, mining corporations had withdrawn from the Cajamarca LUP
MINAM, July 2016. technical committee and the influential Confederation of Private
10
Interview with advisor to regional governments, March 2015. Business Institutions (CONFIEP) had withdrawn from the national
11
Interview with functionary at MINAM, May 2011. multisectoral committee in protest at what they saw as manipulation of
12
Interviews with advisor to regional governments, Lima-based NGO, March the LUP in Cajamarca.16 This led to a halt in the discussions concerning
2015, and July 2016.
13
Interview with former functionary at MEF, and former Minister for
15
Agriculture and for Housing, August 2016. http://www.noticiasser.pe/15/04/2015/medio-ambiente/ordenamiento-
14
Interview with functionary at MINAM, April 2015, and functionary, territorial-la-prioridad-postergada. Accessed 20 December, 2016.
16
MINAM, July 2016. Letter from CONFIEP to MINAM, November 8, 2010

210
M.-T. Gustafsson, M. Scurrah The Extractive Industries and Society 6 (2019) 206–214

a revised law to fill the gaps in the LUP process. Humala had neither a 4.3. Securing the survival of LUP through a non-enforcement strategy
solid political coalition nor organized social support with which to (2012–2016)
defend a vigorous enforcement of LUP in the face of private sector
opposition. Thus, MINAM overestimated the political support it would In the aftermath of the Conga conflict, the political opportunities for
receive from the president.17 institutionalizing LUP were very limited. Manuel Pulgar-Vidal, who was
Those representing rural interests had expressed concern about the appointed Minister for the Environment at the end of 2011, opted for a
possible approval of mining projects in the headwaters of river basins non-enforcement strategy by creating a team in MINAM which would
and the regional government’s technical team recommended in the EEZ be seen as credible by environmental specialists and be able to con-
report that mining be allowed “with restrictions”. The regional council struct a technical defense of the ministry and its policies in bargaining
accepted these recommendations and in October 2011 approved the with private sector oriented ministries, such as MEF and MINEM, and
EEZ.18 by exercising closer control over the regional governments to improve
However, when this was followed by a Regional Ordinance (OR No. their technical capacities but also to prevent them from using these
036-2011-GR.CAJ-CR), which declared that the conservation, protec- capacities to go beyond technical reports and produce land-use plans.
tion and intangibility of all the headwaters in the Cajamarca region was During this period, the tensions inherent to the limited decentralization
in the public interest “in harmony with the national and regional sus- of the EEZ-LUP system became apparent. At the same time as the re-
tainable development plans”, the regional government and its allies in gional governments were responsible for developing land-use plans,
MINAM were seen to be using the EEZ process to support mobilizations MINAM was responsible to lead, monitor and implement the EEZ-LUP
against the Conga project,19 which was in a river basin headwater. system. This responsibility also included the development of metho-
Since most mines in Peru are located in such headwaters, the mining dological guidelines, training of technical staff, approving EEZ and
industry perceived this as a threat to its very existence and not simply other technical reports and promoting changes in the legal norms
as opposition to a particular project located in a particular Andean governing the system.22 MINAM came to use this power to depoliticize
ecosystem.20 This transformed MINAM from being perceived as sup- LUP and reduce its enforcement.
portive of the Cajamarca regional government in its technical planning A number of factors seem to have influenced this decision to adopt
process to being perceived as supportive of the Cajamarca regional such a strategy: (1) the defeat of MINAM under its previous leadership
government in its opposition to the Conga mining project and, finally, in the confrontation with the alliance between the private sector, MEF
to being perceived as in opposition to MEF and MINEM and their allies and MINEM; (2) the political weakness of other ministries (such as
in the mining sector in general. Hence, the process revealed profound Culture and Agriculture, for example) with which MINAM could find
disagreements within the central government, in particular between common ground; and (3) a fragmented civil and political society. In this
MINAM and MINEM, who took different public sides in the conflict. As context, Pulgar-Vidal and his team decided to strengthen the technical
a consequence, both ministers, as well as the Prime Minister, were capacity of the ministry, offer training and technical assistance to re-
forced to resign. gional governments and avoid a public association with social and
Since the correlation of political and financial resources clearly fa- environmental movements critical of the government’s support to the
vored the mining industry and their national and international allies, private sector.23 MINAM demonstrated that it was a loyal member of
the Humala government reached a face-saving solution, which involved the governing team by accepting and publicly defending legislation
suspension of the Conga project and the declaration by the weakening LUP. It was a strategy that eschewed “politics” and external
Constitutional Tribunal of the ordinance in defense of the river basin alliances in favor of the defense and advance of its interests behind
headwaters as unconstitutional. closed doors within the Council of Ministers and informal interactions
The conflict clearly illustrates how these types of reforms require with representatives of mining companies.24 However, in doing so, the
more than political will and that the absence of strong political parties strategy strengthened MINAM and the regional governments at the
and social movements as allies that could back up regional actors un- expense of not enforcing LUP as an institution. Planning capacities were
dermined MINAM’s full-enforcement strategy and limited the possibi- strengthened but no plans were produced and thus LUP was not en-
lities for employing LUP to challenge powerful groups within the cen- forced.
tral government and private sector. The speed with which the During 2012 and 2013, MINAM was able to make some advances
Cajamarca regional government advanced with its EEZ report and in its regional LUP agenda. The LUP directorate within MINAM was
pressured MINAM to allow it to prepare its regional LUP transformed reorganized and given a more technical orientation. Although
what had been a gradual enforcement process which might require Acuerdo Nacional No. 34,25 defining LUP as a national priority, was
adaptation into one that immediately threatened new mining projects. approved in April 2014, the discussions leading up to this decision
The timing was also poor: international development organizations that demonstrated the fragmentation and lack of consensus within the
in Peru as well as in many other countries (Broegaard et al., 2017) had state over LUP.26
supported LUP decided to reduce their support. According to one aid From late 2013 onwards, MINAM opted for attempting to increase
agency executive, this was due to pressure from MEF.21 Most important, its capacity by consolidating the technocratic nature of LUP and de-
the LUP process was now being framed both by supporters and oppo- fending its autonomy as overseer by developing additional planning
nents as a tool for legitimizing opposition to mining and for restricting instruments and monitoring and attempting to control their
the freedom of action of the private sector in general.

22
In a similar manner, the Ministry of Agriculture is the ente rector governing
the rural land titling system where the regional governments are responsible for
granting land titles.
23
Interviews with the minister and Vice Minister for the Environment,
August 2016 and May 2017.
24
Interview with high-level functionary at MINAM, August 2016.
17 25
Interview with former Minister for the Environment, May 2017. Acuerdo Nacional (National Agreement) is a set of public policies that are
18
Regional Ordinance No. 034-2011-Gr.CAJ-CR. elaborated and approved through extensive dialogues and consensus and are
19
N° 036-2011-GR.CAJ-CR. supposed to guide government decision making over the long term.
20 26
Interview with advisor to Grupo Norte, March 2015. Interviews with advisor to regional governments, Lima-based NGO, March
21
Interview with representative of international development agency, May 2015, and functionaries, Sociedad National de Minería, Petroleo e Energía
2017. (National Society of Mining, Oil, and Energy - SNMPE), April 2015.

211
M.-T. Gustafsson, M. Scurrah The Extractive Industries and Society 6 (2019) 206–214

implementation in the regions.27 Rather than abandoning LUP alto- MINAM and regional governments was significantly strengthened.
gether, MINAM engaged in a series of actions to delay and avoid the Enforcement was paralyzed as the process was stalled at the EEZ report
creation and approval of any land-use plans. In May, MINAM published point and the creation of plans halted. However, the proximity to
a methodological guide which described seven specialized studies that powerful actors prevented MINAM from taking the opportunities to
needed to be made after the EEZ report and before work could begin on advance with LUP, once they arose.
the land-use plan (MINAM, 2016). In 2012, MINAM had managed to
obtain MEF approval for a budgetary program, which could be used to 5. Conclusion
fund the final phase of LUP but in 2016 this was unilaterally canceled,
illustrating how relationships with strong agencies shape the ability of In this article, we have analyzed efforts to build and effectively
weak agencies to carry out their policies. According to a MEF func- enforce institutions aimed at fostering participation and inclusive de-
tionary, MEF tried to block MINAM several times by threatening to velopment in the presence of mining, emphasizing the role of weak
withdraw resources but, due to support from President Humala, agencies, such as environmental agencies or subnational governments.
MINAM succeeded in continuing to construct the LUP system.28 In re- More specifically, we have argued that for weak agencies, strategic
sponse, MINAM reinforced its discourse, framing LUP as a technical ability, referring to the skill to adapt the speed, timing and framing of
procedure which required increased control over the preparation of institutional strengthening to reigning political opportunities, is highly
EEZs and other documents. It also blocked the preparation or approval consequential. We recognize the profound power asymmetries and
of land-use plans in the regions to avoid provoking a reaction from the adverse structural conditions that the literature on extractive govern-
private sector and its allies. As a result, mining companies were gen- ance has carefully studied, and that institutional change is ultimately
erally satisfied with this new orientation of LUP.29 dependent on the support of political elites and transnational extractive
As mineral prices began to decline, the government became in- industry (e.g. Bebbington et al., 2016). Yet, as this literature has also
creasingly concerned about how to maintain the rhythm of large mining shown, local communities have in many cases exercised pressure and
investments. Durand (2016: 59) has demonstrated how the private sought to re-politicize formal instruments such as territorial planning
sector and its ideologues in the media began a persistent campaign, (e.g. Leifsen, 2017; Leifsen et al., 2017) and even succeeded in blocking
which identified government rules and regulations, especially those in large-scale resource projects (e.g. Paredes, 2016; Gustafsson, 2018).
defense of the environment, as the principal barrier to private invest- Our analysis suggests that the same logic could be applied to actors
ment and economic growth. MEF proposed a series of legislative within the state. Using an analogy from boxing, strategic ability may
“packages” aimed at lowering environmental standards and speeding allow weak agencies to “compete above their category” and defend or
up approval processes of mining projects, which were passed by Con- even expand their autonomy and build their capacity. Conversely,
gress. Law No. 30230, passed in July 2014, specified that regional LUPs failing to do so may significantly reduce or close future opportunities.
would only serve as guides for government policies and decisions, and Drawing on the literature on institutional strengthening and change, we
their implementation would not be obligatory. Furthermore, they conceptualized different types of enforcement strategies –from full-
would now have to be approved by the Council of Ministers, enabling scale to non-enforcement – placing them in different structural contexts
MEF, MINEM or other ministries to exercise veto power. In Durand’s with varying degrees of autonomy vis-á-vis veto-players and external
view, the adoption of 30230 is an example of state capture by the support.
business community (Durand, 2016: 56). One of the lessons from this study is that gradual enforcement is the
The minister attempted to defend the ministry by highlighting most convenient strategy for weak agencies when external support and
programs, such as global climate change, that enjoyed widespread po- autonomy from veto players is low. As Falleti and Riofranco’s (2018)
litical support, consolidating the LUP process technically, and advan- study on prior consultation in Ecuador and Bolivia demonstrates, for an
cing as many EEZs as possible (from 5 in 2011 to 14 at the end of the institution to gain strength, mobilization in the initial phase and poli-
government’s term). However, at the same time, by delaying the review tical incorporation in the second phase are crucial. Paredes and De la
and approval processes of EEZs and the specialized studies and by not Puente (2017) have similarly demonstrated that broad-based societal
exercising its prerogative to approve land-use plans, the strategy to support and involvement in international advocacy networks were
enforce LUP was subordinated to the strategy to defend MINAM itself. crucial for the Ombudsman’s successful consolidation of conflict med-
As a result of MINAM’s non-enforcement strategy, at the end of the iation institutions in Peru. In a context where social mobilization is
Humala government’s term, there had been no regional LUPs developed weak, gradual enforcement may allow weak agencies to build alliances
or approved in Peru. Thus, there were both changes in the content of over time and assess the willingness and ability of mining companies to
the institution of LUP and changes in the degree of enforcement of the block institutional enforcement. However, during the first period,
institution.30 The lack of autonomy from powerful actors inside and MINAM only made half-hearted attempts to include civil society orga-
outside the state is the most important explanation for this. However, nizations, thereby undermining its opportunities to consolidate LUP.
we also argue that MINAM failed to act strategically and take advantage With regard to full-scale enforcement, our analysis of the second period
of existing opportunities to build coalitions with subnational govern- clearly illustrates that if weak agencies are not backed up by strong
ments and civil society.31 mobilizations or international support, this strategy could destroy what
During this period, when the opportunity structures were adverse, has already been achieved and have durable negative effects on future
MINAM opted for reducing or abandoning its alliances with non-state opportunities for institutional development. This situation could be
actors, concentrated its efforts on consolidating relations with im- contrasted with the popular consultation about the Tambogrande
portant actors within the state and business community, thus reducing mining project in Peru. In this case, the regional government had strong
its autonomy, at the same time as the implementation capacity of both support from local, national and international civil society actors,
which explains its ability to halt the project (Walter and Urkidi, 2017:
269). Still, this isolated success had neither positive nor negative im-
27 pacts on the institutionalization of popular consultation in Peru, al-
Interview with LUP specialist, regional government, Cajamarca, August
though it did lead to its replication in other countries in Latin America
2016.
28
Interview with manager at MEF, July 2016. (Walter and Urkidi, 2017).
29
Interview with functionaries, SNMPE, July, 2016. The analysis also demonstrated the risks associated with employing
30
We thank one of the article’s reviewers for suggesting this distinction. the non-enforcement strategy and simultaneously engaging in close
31
In an interview in May, 2017, a former deputy environmental minister had interactions with powerful actors within the state and business com-
reached the same conclusion. munity. As illustrated during the third period, whereas this may allow

212
M.-T. Gustafsson, M. Scurrah The Extractive Industries and Society 6 (2019) 206–214

weak agencies to increase their capacity they also run the risk of being transcribed the interviews. We would also like to thank the following
co-opted and carrying out “actions that contradict the “spirit” or the persons who have taken their time to read and provide valuable com-
purpose of the institution, thus undermining it” (Mahoney and Thelen, ments on the manuscript: Anthony Bebbington; Peter Cleaves; Kent
2009: 24). The difficulties faced by the Ministry of Culture in enforcing Eaton; Manuel Glave; Steven Levitsky; Stephanie McNulty; Roger
free, prior and informed consultation of indigenous peoples in colla- Merino; Kenneth Roberts; Anders Sjögren, and two anonymous re-
boration with MINEM and mining companies provide another example viewers. Thanks also go to Marisa Remy and Natalia Gonzalez for or-
in Peru of the risks of engaging closely with powerful actors in enfor- ganizing a research seminar at Instituto de Estudios Peruanos.
cing institutions affecting those actors’ interests. Scholars have de-
monstrated the ways in which MINEM has sought to depoliticize and References
undermine consultation processes (Schilling-Vacaflor et al., 2018).
Overall, our analysis demonstrates that the ability to adapt speed, Aguilar-Støen, M., Hirsch, C., 2015. Environmental impact assessments, local power and
timing and framing to the reigning political context is highly con- self-determination: the case of mining and hydropower development in Guatemala.
Extract. Ind. Soc. 2 (3), 472–479.
sequential for weak agencies’ ability to strengthen institutions affecting Alarco Tosoni, G., 2017. Lecturas Prohibidas: Análisis y Propuestas Económicas para el
the interests of powerful actors. To develop alliances with institutional Perú. Otra Mirada, Lima.
supporters is also crucial. Arellano-Yanguas, J., 2011. Aggravating the resource curse. J. Dev. Stud. 47 (4),
617–638.
Beyond these empirical conclusions, the article has implications for Baletti, B., 2012. Ordenamento territorial: neo-developmentalism and the struggle for
on-going debates related to the governance of extractive industries. territory in the lower Brazilian amazon. J. Peasant Stud. 39 (2), 573–598.
First, it speaks to debates about the challenges associated with in- Bebbington, A., Bury, J., 2009. Institutional challenges for mining and sustainability in
Peru. Proc. Nat. Acad. Sci. 106 (41), 17296–17301.
stitution building in a context of expanding extractive industries. The Bebbington, A., Arond, E., Dammert, J.L., 2016. Explaining diverse national responses to
literature on resource-rich states typically focuses on political settle- the extractive industries transparency initiative in the Andes: what sort of politics
ments (Bebbington et al., 2018) and the role of political elites (e.g. Karl, matters? Extract. Ind. Soc. 4 (4), 833–841.
Bebbington, A., Abdul-Gafaru, A., Humphreys-Bebbington, D., Hinfelaar, M., Sanborn, C.,
1997; Nem Singh and Salah Ovadia, 2018; Haslam and Heidrich, 2016)
2018. Governing Extractive Industries: Politics, Histories, Ideas. Oxford University
and social mobilization (e.g. Falleti and Riofrancos, 2018; Bebbington Press, Oxford.
and Bury, 2009) in explaining the emergence of institutions governing Bersch, K., Praça, S., Taylor, M.M., 2017. State capacity, bureaucratic politicization, and
extractive industries in a sustainable manner. Building on this invalu- corruption in the Brazilian state. Government 30 (1), 105–124.
Broegaard, R.B., Vongvisouk, T., Mertz, O., 2017. Contradictory land use plans and po-
able scholarship we have shifted the focus to weaker agencies and to licies in Laos. World Dev. 89, 170–183.
what factors explain more or less successful attempts to strengthen in- Centeno, M.A., Kohli, A., Yashar, D.J., 2017. Unpacking States in the developing world:
stitutions that foster inclusive development. Peru, with its weak parties capacity, performance, and politics. In: Centeno, M., Kohli, A., Yashar, D. (Eds.),
States in the Developing World. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, pp. 1–31.
and social movements and unified political and economic elite, re- CEPAL/OECD, 2015. Estudio de desempeño ambiental 2003-2013. Ministerio del
presents a least likely case for successful institutional strengthening. Ambiente, Lima.
Thus, more empirical research is needed on reform-oriented agencies in Cleaves, S., Scurrah, M.J., 1980. Agriculture, Bureaucracy, and Military Government in
Peru. Cornell University Press, Ithaca.
states where the political conditions are more favorable. Theoretically, Crabtree, J., Durand, F., 2017. Peru: Elite Power and Political Capture. Zed Books,
we expect theories on institutional weakness and change could offer London.
explanatory leverage and contribute to advance on-going debates on Cuba, N., Bebbington, A., Rogan, J., Millones, M., 2014. Extractive industries, livelihoods
and natural resource competition: mapping overlapping claims in Peru and Ghana.
extractive governance. Appl. Geogr. 54, 250–261.
Second, our results also shed light on the complicated relationship Dargent, E., 2015. Technocracy and Democracy in Latin America: The Experts Running
between autonomy and capacity in resource-rich states. Some studies Government. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.
Durand, F., 2016. Cuando el poder extractivo captura el estado. Oxfam, Lima.
have analyzed the ways in which particular state agencies develop
Eaton, K., 2017. Territory and Ideology in Latin America: Policy Conflicts between
degrees of autonomy vis-á-vis political elites and the transnational ex- National and Subnational Governments. Oxford University Press, Oxford.
tractive industry (e.g. subnational governments, constitutional courts, Evans, P., 1995. Embedded Autonomy: States and Industrial Transformation. Princeton
Ombudsman) and actively support local communities (e.g. Walter and University Press, Princeton.
Falleti, T., Riofrancos, T., 2018. Endogenous participation: strengthening prior con-
Urkidi, 2017; Jaskoski, 2014; Paredes, 2016). Our analysis also illus- sultation in extractive economies. World Pol. 70 (1), 86–121.
trates how reform-oriented agencies, by reducing their autonomy vis-á- FAO, 1993. Guidelines for Land-Use Planning. Food and Agricultural Organization, Rome.
vis powerful actors, could gain access to resources and enhance their Gustafsson, M.T., 2017. The struggles surrounding ecological and economic zoning in
Peru. Third World Q. 38 (5), 1146–1163.
capacity. Still, close interactions with powerful actors also entail the Gustafsson, M.T., 2018. Private Politics and Peasant Mobilization: Mining in Peru.
risk of co-optation and depoliticization. Gaining a better understanding Springer International Publishing, Cham.
of the outcomes from such difficult strategic considerations is important Haslam, P., Heidrich, P., 2016. The Political Economy of Natural Resources and
Development: From Neoliberalism to Resource Nationalism. Routledge, London.
for explaining under what conditions institutions for governing natural Jaskoski, M., 2014. Environmental licensing and conflict in Peru’s mining sector: a path-
resources in an inclusive and sustainable manner are effectively en- dependent analysis. World Dev. 64, 873–883.
forced. Karl, T.L., 1997. The Paradox of Plenty: Oil Booms and Petro-States. University of
California Press, Oakland.
Keck, M., Sikkink, K., 1998. Activists Beyond borders: Transnational activist networks in
Conflict of interest international politics. Cornell University Press, Ithaca.
Leifsen, E., 2017. Wasteland by design: dispossession by contamination and the struggle
for water justice in the Ecuadorian amazon. Extract. Ind. Soc. 4 (2), 344–351.
The authors do not state any conflict of interest.
Leifsen, E., Gustafsson, M.T., Guzmán-Gallegos, M.A., Schilling-Vacaflor, A., 2017. New
mechanisms of participation in extractive governance: between technologies of
Funding governance and resistance work. Third World Q. 38 (5), 1043–1057.
Levitsky, S., Murillo, M.V., 2009. Variation in institutional strength. Annu. Rev. Pol. Sci.
12, 115–133.
This work was supported by the Norwegian Research Council Levitsky, S., Murillo, M.V., 2013. Building institutions on weak foundations. J. Demogr.
(Project: “Extracting Justice?”) and Anna Ahlström & Ellen Terserus 24 (2), 93–107.
Foundation, Stockholm University (Project: “Territorial Planning as a Mahoney, J., Thelen, K., 2009. Explaining Institutional Change: Ambiguity, Agency, and
Power. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.
Solution to Socio-Environmental Conflicts?”). McCullough, Aoife, 2017. Environmental impact assessments in developing countries: we
need to talk about politics. Extract. Ind. Soc. 4 (3), 448–452.
Acknowledgements Migdal, J.S., 2001. State in Society: Studying How States and Societies Transform and
Constitute One Another. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.
MINAM, 2016. Ordenamiento Territorial (OT) en el Perú (2011-2015). Ministerio del
We are grateful to all the persons that have contributed to this re- Ambiente, Lima.
search, especially to all the interviewees and to Harry Echegaray, who Nem Singh, J., Salah Ovadia, J., 2018. The theory and practice of building developmental

213
M.-T. Gustafsson, M. Scurrah The Extractive Industries and Society 6 (2019) 206–214

states in the global South. Third World Q. 39 (6), 1033–1055. 74–85.


North, D.C., 1995. The new institutional economics and third world development. In: Skocpol, T., 1985. Bringing the state back in: strategies of analysis in current research. In:
Harris, J., Hunter, J., Lewis, C. (Eds.), The New Institutional Economics and Third Evans, P. (Ed.), Bringing the State Back. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.
World Development. Routledge, London, pp. 31–40. Soifer, H.D., Vom Hau, M., 2008. Unpacking the strength of the state. Stud. Comp. Int.
OECD, 2016. Public Governance Review of Peru. Organisation for Economic Co-operation Dev. 43 (3-4), 219.
and Development, Paris. Sweet, A.S., Sandholtz, W., Fligstein, N., 2001. The institutionalization of European space.
Ombudsman, 2018. Reporte de Conflictos Sociales N°170. Ombudsman, Lima. In: Sweet, A.S., Fligstein, W., Sandholtz, N. (Eds.), The Institutionalization of Europe.
Orihuela, J., Paredes, M., 2017. Fragmented layering: building a Green State for mining in Oxford University Press, Oxford, pp. 1–38.
Peru. In: Dargent, E., Orihuela, J., Paredes, M., Ulfe, M. (Eds.), Resource Booms and Tarrow, S., 1994. Power in Movement: Social Movements, Collective Action and Politics.
Institutional Pathways: The Case of the Extractive Industry in Peru. Palgrave, Cham. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.
Paredes, M., 2016. The glocalization of mining conflict: cases from Peru. Extract. Ind. Soc. Waldner, D., Smith, B., et al., 2015. Rentier States and State transformations’. In:
3 (4), 1046–1057. Leibfried, S. (Ed.), The Oxford Handbook of Transformations of the State. Oxford
Paredes, M., De La Puente, L., 2017. The social construction of a public problem: the role University Press, New York.
of the ombudsman in building Institutions for extractive conflict. In: Dargent, E., Walter, M., Urkidi, L., 2017. Community mining consultations in Latin America
Orihuela, J., Paredes, M., Ulfe, M. (Eds.), Resource Booms and Institutional Pathways: (2002–2012). Geoforum 84, 265–279.
The Case of the Extractive Industry in Peru. Palgrave, Cham. Wise, C., 2003. Reinventing the State: Economic Strategy and Institutional Change in
Schilling-Vacaflor, A., Flemmer, R., Hujber, A., 2018. Contesting the hydrocarbon fron- Peru. University of Michigan Press, Ann Arbor.
tiers: state depoliticizing practices and local responses in Peru. World Dev. 108,

214

View publication stats

You might also like