You are on page 1of 14

Accounting, Organizations and Society 48 (2016) 17e30

Contents lists available at ScienceDirect

Accounting, Organizations and Society


journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/aos

Taxation and state-building: The tax reform under the Nationalist


Government in China, 1928e1949
Yin Xu a, *, Xiaoqun Xu b
a
School of Accountancy, Strome College of Business, Old Dominion University, Norfolk, VA 23529, USA
b
Department of History, Christopher Newport University, 1 Avenue of the Arts, Newport News, VA 23606, USA

a r t i c l e i n f o a b s t r a c t

Article history: Using primary sources and drawing on insights from the new accounting history and the new fiscal
Received 11 August 2014 sociology, this paper examines the tax reform launched by the Nationalist Government in China during
Received in revised form 1928e1949 as a case study to enrich an understanding of the relationship between taxation and state
30 October 2015
building. Among other things, the paper reveals a shift from the traditional Confucian ideology of “low
Accepted 31 October 2015
Available online 11 December 2015
taxes” to the Western-derived ideology of “good taxes,” used by the state to justify new taxes. It discusses
how the Chinese Civil War and the Sino-Japanese War differently affected the Nationalist Government's
political legitimacy and state finance and taxation. It analyzes how tax compliance was pursued by the
Keywords:
Accounting history
Nationalist Government through state-society negotiations and compromises over taxation, in the
Taxation absence of representative political institutions, as well as coercive enforcement of tax laws and regu-
State building lationsethe two approaches together actualized and delimited the new tax regime and the growing state
State legitimacy power (legitimacy and capacity). These history/culture-specific features may be understood as variations
State capacity to a general historical pattern of taxation and state building based on European-American experiences.
© 2015 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.

1. Introduction foremost in the increasing power of a central government, either a


monarchy or otherwise, to tax people and economic activities
Research on accounting history, especially “the social science- across the territory it ruled. Historically, wars and commerce played
influenced ‘new accounting history’” since the mid-1980s (Napier, a key role in the rise of the “tax states” or “fiscal states”. In the
2006, p. 468), has greatly broadened our understanding of the process of taxation, the legitimacy and capacity of the state would
role of changing accounting techniques and the rise of the ac- reinforce one another and grow hand in hand. The growing state
counting profession in, and their interactions with, the political, legitimacy involved imposing new taxes or higher rates of taxes
economic, technological, and social changes or changes in gov- and promulgating and enforcing tax laws, which taxpayers were
ernment regulations, accounting rules, economic organizations, persuaded or compelled to accept and comply with. The growing
and societies at large over time and space around the world (see state capacity was manifested in the evolution and expansion of tax
Napier, 2006; Cooper & Robson, 2006; Burchell, Clubb, & Hopwood, collection apparatus from tax farmers and other amateurish, part-
1985). In this broad scholarly development, one important but still time operators to full-time, salaried tax professionals who were
understudied area of research is taxation as accounting history. trained for and made their careers in this growing field of state
Based on primary sources, the present study is to enrich the liter- functions.1 In short, successful imposition and collection of taxes by
ature with an analysis of how tax systems developed in tandem a centralized authority was one of the essential features of state
with modern transformation of the state in early twentieth-century making or state building (e.g., Tilly, 1975, 1985; Braun, 1975;
China. Webber & Wildavsky, 1986; Brewer, 1990; Kiser & Schneider,
A body of scholarship on taxation and state building in Western
countries has formed a general historical understanding: The
emergence of modern states in Europe was manifested first and 1
A tax farmer was a private person or entity that pays the ruler or the state a fee
in return for the right to collect taxes on behalf of the ruler or the state. An alter-
native was for the private person or entity to pay in advance an amount of money
* Corresponding author. that was expected from the taxes to be collected, usually at a discount for collection
E-mail addresses: yxu@odu.edu (Y. Xu), xxu@cnu.edu (X. Xu). cost and profit.

http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.aos.2015.10.008
0361-3682/© 2015 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.
18 Y. Xu, X. Xu / Accounting, Organizations and Society 48 (2016) 17e30

1994; Bonney, 1995; Douglas, 1999; Yun-Casalilla, O'Brien, & literature.


Comin, 2012). Theoretically, the paper draws on insights and findings from the
How would this historical pattern apply to China where a “new accounting history” (Napier, 2006) and the “new fiscal soci-
centralized imperial dynasty was founded over two millennia ago ology” (Martin, Mehrotra, & Prasad, 2009) and applies them, with
and succeeded by many, but the significant transformation of state modifications, to a country-specific case to reach additional in-
and society into modern forms took place in the twentieth century? sights into the relations between taxation and state building.
If the pattern is applicable to modern China, were there any history/ Consistent with the findings in the previous literature, this paper
culture-specific features or variations? How did taxation actually explicitly treats state building as growth of state legitimacy and
interact with modern state building in the Chinese context? These capacity or state power, and treats taxation as state building (or an
questions have not been squarely addressed in the scholarship. This integral part of state building), not just for state building or vice
paper seeks to fill that lacuna by examining a crucial moment in versa. The paper engages the “theory of predatory rule” (Levi, 1988).
China's experience of taxation and state building, i.e., the tax re- On the one hand, it uses concepts from the theory such as the state/
form under the Nationalist Government during 1928e1949. ruler's bargaining power, transaction costs, and discount rate (see
After the fall of the last imperial dynasty, the Qing (1644e1911), the Literature review section below), and on the other hand, it
and the founding of the Republic of China in 1912, the promise of a differs from the theory in two important aspects illustrated by the
functioning parliamentary government was quickly turned into a Chinese case. First, it analyzes how ideology on taxation as
deep disillusionment for Chinese citizens. With the passing of the discursive resource added to the state's political resource or bar-
authoritarian presidency of Yuan Shikai in 1916, warlords domi- gaining power, and second, it analyzes how Chinese state-society
nated the political scene, fighting one another for the control of the negotiations and compromises over taxation, in the absence of
national capital and various provinces and revenues there. China's representative political institutions typical of Western experiences,
domestic disorder did not help its international standing. It failed to both actualized and delimited the growth of state power in
recover full national sovereignty from the unequal treaties with Nationalist China. At the same time, the paper supports an
Western Powers and Japan dating back to the nineteenth century. important viewpoint in the literature, i.e., how civil war and in-
Japan stepped up its encroachment on mainland China by taking ternational warein our case the Chinese Civil War and the Second
over the German leasehold in Shandong province and imposing the Sino-Japanese Waredifferently affected state legitimacy and state
Twenty-One Demands on China in 1915. China's failure to regain finance and taxation.
the German leasehold in Shandong at the Paris Peace Conference in The rest of the paper is organized as follows: Section 1 “Litera-
1919 set off a high tide of Chinese nationalist movement with twin ture on Taxation and State Building” reviews relevant literature in
goals of anti-imperialism and anti-warlordism. It culminated in a the new accounting history and the new fiscal sociology and situ-
military campaign against warlords led by the Nationalist Party and ates this study in the literature; Sections 2 “Finance & Taxation in
the founding of the Nationalist Government in 1927. In the mean- Late Imperial & Early Republican China” provides a historical
time the Chinese Communist Party (CCP) was founded in 1921 as a background for our case study; Section 3 “A New Ideology on
participant in the nationalist cause, with a Marxist-Leninist ideol- Taxation” deals with the shift from the Confucian ideology of “low
ogy. The Nationalist Party-Government initially cooperated with taxes” to the Western-derived one of “good taxes” to justify tax
the CCP (1924e1927) and then turned against it. Through a pro- reform under the Nationalist Government; Section 4 “New Taxes
longed civil war, suspended during the Second Sino-Japanese War and Revenue Increase” discusses the adoption by the state of new
(1937e1945) and resumed in 1946, the struggle between the categories of taxes and the resulting revenue increase; Section 5
Nationalist Government and the CCP resulted in the latter's victory “Taxation as State Building” looks into the growth of state legiti-
and the founding of the People's Republic of China in 1949. macy and capacity through building tax apparatus and training and
Given the turbulent history sketched above, it is not difficult to monitoring tax agents; Section 6 “StateeSociety Interactions over
understand that in the first half of the twentieth century, while Taxation” analyzes the state's efforts at tax compliance through
searching for a modern form, the Chinese state was under severe state-society negotiations as well as enforcement of tax laws and
financial strains and constantly struggling with revenue extraction. regulations, which manifested a particular political ecology in a
After the Nationalist Government came to power in 1927, it began non-Western society. A brief conclusion will summarize our
to reform the tax system, preceded by a recovery of tariff autonomy findings.
and a currency reform. From 1936 to the late 1940s the government
instituted new categories of taxes, including income tax (both 2. Literature on Taxation and State Building
personal and business), estate tax, stamp tax (for print matters),
and business tax. Tax research as accounting history benefits from the intellectual
Through examining how the tax reform unfolded, this paper concerns and theoretical approaches of the new accounting history
makes empirical and theoretical contributions to the accounting and the new fiscal sociology. As Napier (2006) has outlined, unlike
history literature. Empirically, this is another case study, based on the traditional views of accounting, the new accounting history
primary source research, of the relations between taxation and pays greater attention to the social environment with which ac-
state building in one of the major non-Western countries. In the counting interacts, manifesting several research concerns. First of
past fifteen years or so the literature has seen several studies on all, from its perspective, “accounting is not just reflective but
taxation, such as tax assessment and collection in ancient Egypt constitutive: it is not merely a passive effect of its environment but
(Ezzamel, 2002), the emergence of the Exchequer in medieval En- works to shape this environment. The constitutive power of ac-
gland (Jones, 2010), assessment and accounting of profit income tax counting arises not just in the context of the individual organiza-
in mid-nineteenth century England (Lamb, 2001), the resistance to tion, but also in a wider social context” (Napier, 2006, p. 456).
the whiskey tax of 1791 in the United States (Krom & Krom, 2013), Secondly, it re-conceives what accounting was in different histor-
and the increase of stamp tax on newspapers in Britain during the ical circumstances. With an “anti-essentialist” nature, it has “an
French Revolutionary War (Oats & Sadler, 2004). Overall, however, awareness that the bundle of practices (calculative or otherwise)
studies on “taxation framed as accounting historical research” that happened to be labeled as accounting at any point in time and
(Lamb, 2003; also see Lamb & Lymer, 1999) remain to be space is contingent (delineating a specific bundle and documenting
strengthened. The present study adds a significant piece to the the conditions of its emergence provides a problem for historical
Y. Xu, X. Xu / Accounting, Organizations and Society 48 (2016) 17e30 19

accounting research)” (Napier, 2006, p. 457). Thirdly, identifying years ago (when it was not labeled “new” yet) captured advances
accounting as social as much as technical locates accounting in and inadequacies in the field. Campbell pointed out that addressing
wider arenase“new accounting history brings into its exposition the previous neglect of tax policy, some sociologists began to pay
new actors: the state, institutions such as employer collectives and attention to the determinants and the effects of tax policy. With
trade unions, the academy, the media, and so on” (Napier, 2006. p. regard to the determinants of tax policy, several issues are of con-
458). Fourthly, such research concerns, including studying “en- cerns to this paper. First, scholars agreed that states would extract
sembles of practices and rationales,” “have tended to relocate the more revenue during the war, but public choice theorists, neo-
focus of research away from the detailed technical practices Marxists, and rational choice theorists differed on why that was
themselves to the discourses in which these practices are located at the case. Scholars were also divided on whether economic expan-
a particular point or period in time” (Napier, 2006, p. 462). sion or contraction, and fiscal crisis, would constitute determinants
One example of the new accounting history relevant here is of tax increase or decrease (Campbell, 1993, pp. 163e168). The
Miller's (1990) study on the interrelations between accounting and second issue is whether and how the state structure or political
the state. Using innovations in accounting and other practices of institutions would impact tax policy. For example, whether political
government in the “Colbert period” of Louis XIV's reign representation would increase or decrease tax revenue in relation
(1661e1683) in France as an illustration, Miller presents a key to taxpayer compliance or whether a more centralized authority
argument that the relationships between accounting and the state would be able to extract more revenue (Campbell, 1993, pp.
are not those between two given and discrete entities, but “recip- 171e172). The third issue is whether and how “ideology,” “culture,”
rocal relationships between and within two loosely assembled sets or “values” would affect tax policy. It is often unclear, in Campbell's
of practices' (p. 316). The argument is predicated on his defining view, how these key concepts were defined, and whether “culture”
“accounting” and “the state” each as a changing or evolving referred to that of political elites or citizens. He urged more precise
“complex of practices and rationales” that interacts with and definitions of such concepts before their impact on taxation might
shapes one another (p. 316). Miller further differentiates the pro- be determined (Campbell, 1993, pp. 172e173).
grammatic and technological aspects of what and how the state One of the studies in the new fiscal sociology relevant to this
would govern: the former, “political rationalities,” is made of paper is on tax revenue and state formation in developing countries
statements, claims, and prescriptions, as discursive matrices, about (Moore, 2004). Among its main findings are the following: The
the objects and objectives of government; and the latter, “tech- fiscal contract theory (“tax for representation”) based on Western
nologies,” is a body of “techniques that makes the objects and ob- European experiences did not play out in many developing coun-
jectives of the government amenable to interventions”ethe two tries, especially where state revenues did not primarily come from
aspects were also reciprocal (Miller, 1990, p. 317). With these domestic taxation on earned income, but from external exchanges
theoretical constructs, Miller demonstrates how a discourse valo- such as natural resource rents (oil or diamond) and strategic rents
rizing “order” in accounting and commerce led to innovations in (military bases or ports and facilities or foreign aid) (Moore, 2004,
administrative practicesewhat he called “government by inquir- pp. 308e310). Therefore, a governance dividende“a more negotiated
y”ethat required accounting techniques (Miller, 1990, pp. relationship between the state apparatus and society, involving an
321e333). exchange of (1) greater institutionalized societal influence over
Adding to the new accounting history, in research concerns and revenue raising and expenditure for (2) higher levels of domestic
methodologies, and more closely relating to tax research is the new taxation, with substantial quasi-voluntary compliance”ewould
fiscal sociology, a rich variety of studies in social sciences that deal depend on many political, social, and even geographical variables in
with sources of taxation, taxpayer compliance, and social conse- different developing countries (Moore, 2004, pp. 310e314).
quences of taxation from different perspectives (Martin et al., 2009, Moore's findings are consistent with a more recent study on a
pp. 11e26). The fiscal sociology of the early twentieth century went similar set of issues (Kiser & Sacks, 2009).
into decline in the mid twentieth century as a result of the growth In reviewing the field, Martin, et al. (2009) pointed to Levi's
and separation of academic disciplines. “Many questions at the (1988) work, along with Tilly's (1985), as pioneering the new fis-
intersection of these disciplines consequently fell through the cal sociology (Martin et al., 2009, p. 12). Synthesizing insights from
cracks that opened when they pulled apart” (Martin et al., 2009, p. previous scholarship, Levi put forward a model for understanding
6). Remedying the situation, the new fiscal sociology has come the relations between taxation and the statee“the theory of pred-
forward since the late twentieth century on the basis of, and by atory rule.” The word “rulers” applies to all forms of state in all ages,
integrating, several earlier scholarly traditions in separate academic from absolute monarchy to liberal democracy. “Rulers are preda-
disciplines: 1) the modernization theory that dealt with public tory in that they try to extract as much revenue as they can from the
finance as resulting from economic development, 2) the elite the- population” under their rule (Levi, 1988, p. 3), but the absolute drive
ory that addressed the issue of taxpayer consent by emphasizing a to maximize revenues are inevitably constrained by three factors:
fundamental conflict of interest between rulers and subjects and by rulers' relative bargaining powers, transaction costs, and discount
theorizing how the elite devised ways to conceal taxes and to rates. “Bargaining power” refers to the degree to which rulers
redistribute resources for the benefit of an elite minority or special- control coercive, economic, and political resources others depend
interest groups, and 3) the militarist theory that explained the rise on, versus the degree to which others control resources rulers
of taxation in the context of wars and military rivalries. In aggre- depend on. “Transaction costs” refer to the costs of negotiating an
gate, the scholarship in the new fiscal sociology pays keen attention agreement on policy and of implementing policy, such as moni-
to 1) comparative studies of varied historical contexts and idio- toring agents, learning administrative and technical practices,
syncratic developmental paths and “path dependence,” 2) informal measuring and enforcing tax compliance, punishing non-
social institutions that were involved in shaping, and were shaped compliance, and so on so forth. “Discount rate” refers to how
by, tax policies, 3) macro social-economic phenomena measured by much rulers value their future in relation to their presentea lower
the level of the society rather than the individual, and 4) relation- discount rate means that they place a higher value on their future,
ship between taxation and the big questions in social sciences such so that they are less inclined to exhaust sources of revenues or more
as the rise of the state, the development of democracy, the sources concerned about promoting economic growth for the long run; and
of social solidarity, and so on (Martin et al., 2009, pp. 12e14). vice versa. Levi's model has its critics who found that Levi sup-
Campbell's (1993) review of the fiscal sociology over twenty ported her theory with “an unremitting, and unavoidably selective,
20 Y. Xu, X. Xu / Accounting, Organizations and Society 48 (2016) 17e30

adducement of evidence” (Dryzek, 1990, p. 309) or that '[m] explain the growth of state legitimacy and capacity than the theory
easuring transaction costs is a big obstacle for testing this theory” of predatory rule alone: Ideology helps state legitimacy by justi-
(Campbell, 1993, p. 172). Our quibbles lay elsewhere, however. fying taxation, adding to its political resources; and taxation re-
Levi's model is underpinned by rational choice theory (rulers quires, and in turn expands, state capacity including institutional
and their agents and constituents are all assumed to be rational and infrastructure, administrative expertise, coercive forces, and tech-
self-interested) and, as a corollary, theory of principal-agent rela- nologies required of state functions; and properly delivered state
tionship (agents are supposed to, but do not always, work in the functions at acceptable transaction costs, i.e., state capacity, in turn
interest of the principalethe state/ruler, and due to information reinforces state legitimacy. In a sense, by “ideology” this paper calls
asymmetry, the principal's control over agents is always relative attention to the rationales for taxation as the “political rationalities”
and incurs costs). Rational choice theory is not necessarily incom- aspect of governance (Miller, 1990, p. 318), and explains the shift in
patible with other perspectives and approaches (Campbell, 2009, p. such ideologies by referring to changing political and economic
258), but an exclusive adherence to rational choice theory limits the circumstances in late imperial and early Republican China that
model's explaining power. Therefore, while using the concepts precipitated an upsurge of wider ideological currents including a
from Levi's model, this paper differs from it in two important discourse on the need for everything to become “modern” and
aspects. “scientific”.
First, Levi only considers the state's resources that have a ma- Second, Levi posits the theory of predatory rule as a static
terial base and can be quantified, and thus excludes “legitimacy, model, in that “policy choices are a consequence of a given set of
status, and authority” from political resources (Levi, 1988, p. 17). bargaining power, transaction costs, and discount rates” (Levi,
While endorsing ideology as “an additional political resource” (Levi, 1988, p. 16), whereas this paper moves beyond a static under-
1988 p. 21e22) and a factor in quasi-voluntary tax compliance standing of the state behavior by exploring the dynamic and
(Levi, 1988, pp. 50e55, 67e69), due to her exclusive adherence to continuous interactions between the state and taxpayers/social
the rational choice premise, Levi did not address how ideology actors over taxation. Such interactions intersected the relation-
might have been more than a utilitarian tool for rulers to induce ship between the state and its agents, serving as a monitoring
taxpayer compliance and how ideology might enhance legitimacy, mechanism by the state over its agents and becoming a crucial
status, and authority as political resources of the state. variable in the effects of the tax policy on state building. In the
The issue of ideology as power resource for the state is related, Chinese case, such state-society interactions also worked as an
in a general sense, to Mann's model of ideological, economic, alternative to the political representation, by which citizens and
military, and political sources of power (Mann, 2005). By “ideol- interest-groups would voice their demand on the state for
ogy” Mann refers to religions and secular meaning systems such accountability, typical of Western Europe and the United States
as liberalism, socialism, and nationalism. “Ideological power de- but non-existent in China at the time. Ultimately, by unpacking
rives from the human need to find ultimate meaning in life, to the “ensemble of practices and rationales” of the Nationalist
share norms and values, and to participate in aesthetic and ritual Government in China in adopting new taxes, this paper reveals a
practices” (Mann, 1993, p. 7). “I prefer the term ‘ideology’ to new dimension to the general pattern of taxation and state
‘culture’ or ‘discourse’ not because I view ideology as false or a building that is primarily based on European-American historical
cover for interests, as materialists tend to say. By ideology I mean experiences but has also increasingly been informed by varied
only a broad ranging system which ‘surpasses experience’” (Mann, experiences of developing nations in the non-Western world
2005, p. 345) “The creation of an alternative order requires gen- (Moore, 2004; Bra €utigam, Fjeldstad, & Moore, 2008; Kiser & Sacks,
eral ideological visions going beyond direct self-interest and 2009; Yun-Casalilla et al., 2012).
presenting a plausible way of overcoming the existing crisis”
(Mann, 2005, p. 349). Such a conception of ideology is different
3. Finance & taxation in late imperial & early Republican
from Levi's utilitarian or materialist view of ideology. On the other
China
hand, Mann's model is also macro and schematic and requires
specificity in application to idiosyncratic historical settings. For
This section outlines state finance and taxation in imperial and
example, adopting Mann's model of four sources of power in an
Republican China as a background to the changes under the
accounting study, Jones (2010) found that the source of ideological
Nationalist Government and especially the shift in the ideology on
power involved in the rise of Exchequer in twelfth-century En-
taxation.
gland came from the Church embodying Christian faith and, more
During more than two millennia of imperial China (221BCE-
specifically, from the literary and numerical skills possessed by
1911CE), dynasties drew revenues mainly from land tax, poll tax,
church scribes (Jones, 2010). This kind of specificity answered
labor tax (labor and military services), and varying kinds of levies
Campbell's (1993) call for precise definitions of “ideology,”
on handicrafts and commerce. State finance and tax apparatus
“values,” and “culture” in causal explanations. In a similar vein,
were developed early in imperial China, normally under a
this paper uses “ideology” in a narrower sense than Mann's.
centralized system extending from the national capital down to
“Ideology” in this paper refers to the state's guiding principles for
the county level (Huang, 1974; Wang, 1974; Bastid, 1985; Deng,
taxation, even though they were related to the broader kind of
2012). Imperial dynasties used both bureaucrats and tax farmers
ideologies Mann discussed.
at different levels of administrative hierarchy, since it was more
This paper treats state legitimacy as part of Chinese rulers' po-
cost-effective to use tax farmers in local society below countyethe
litical resources, and state ideology on taxation as power resource
lowest level of state bureaucracy, comparable to the case of
to enhance the ruler's legitimacy. State building was in essence to
ancient Rome (Levi, 1988, pp. 78e80). Explaining the mobile
build state legitimacy (being accepted by the ruled, even if reluc-
capital that rulers relied on for revenue and the motivation for
tantly) and state capacity (achieving state goals and delivering
rulers to adopt a more consensual way of dealing with owners of
public goods, to a certain degree at least)ethe two aspects influ-
such capital (merchants in European port cities) as taxpayers,
enced and shaped one another. Ideology as the state's power
Moore noted that to rulers whose revenue source was agriculture,
resource contributed to both. Such a formulation may better
more coercive strategy was more attractive, since peasants had
Y. Xu, X. Xu / Accounting, Organizations and Society 48 (2016) 17e30 21

few options: either armed resistance or flight from the land they Taiping Rebellion devastated half of the country. The commercial
tilled (Moore, 2004, p. 301). In imperial China, land tax was indeed tax (lijin) that was instituted during the rebellion as a stopgap
the main source of revenue for the state. In the Confucian tradition measure became a permanent tax, but it was hardly enough to
the imperial state was conceived as the patriarchal family writ restore the state financial health.2 Then the repeated defeats in
large, and therefore political representation was not even an issue. the hands of foreign powers resulted in huge indemnities, along
The people would not resist taxes for having no say in the gov- with unequal treaties, imposed on China. The worsening finance
ernment or state finance; they would launch riots or flee from in the latter one century and a half of the Qing dynasty forced the
land when taxes were actually too heavy for them to endure and government, against the ideal of “low taxes,” to raise taxes in
survive. Precisely for that reason, the Confucian tradition held the different formsewith no less than seven official tax categories, not
emperor (and officials on his behalf) as “parents of the people” to mention various local surcharges and levies (Dong, 2000, pp.
and called for “low taxes” on the people as benevolent 23e36; Wong, 2012; Wu, 1984, pp. 28e122; Zhou, 2000, pp.
governance. 120e441).3 The Qing state irreversibly sank into perpetual
As early as the Warring States period (475-221BCE), Mencius indebtedness, as it was forced to make loans to pay indemnities
(372-289BCE), who was the primary propagator of Confucius's and make new loans to pay interest and principals of old loans
(551-479BCE) ideas, advised rulers to protect the people from (Zhou, 2000).
excessive taxes (Hansen, 2010, p. 86). After the Qin dynasty (221- This precarious financial situation was what the Republic of
206BCE) was toppled by rebellions, much was said and written on China inherited. The central government under President Yuan
how excessive taxes and labor services imposed by the Qin state Shikai (1912e1916) tried to rationalize and reorganize taxation in
drove desperate people into rebellions. In response, the Han dy- the country. In November 1912 the government unveiled a tax re-
nasty that succeeded the Qin made a deliberate policy of “low form plan that would divide all taxes into national taxes and pro-
taxes,” for the sake of political legitimacy, economic recovery, and vincial taxes (to ensure the central government's revenue) and
social stability. Under different emperors, the land tax rate was institute new taxes in the near future (Wu, 1984, pp. 123e124;
targeted at one fifteenth (6.67%) or one thirtieth of produces from Dong, 2000, pp. 91e94). The Yuan government even drafted the
land, compared to the normal rate at one tenth before the Qin and regulations on income tax in January 1914 (Wu, 1984, pp. 220e221).
at one half during the Qin (Chen, 1984, pp. 48e57; Hansen, 2010, p. Yet, the central government's bargaining power was such that the
122; Wu, 1984). The ideal of “low taxes (qingfu boyao)” thus became separation of national and provincial taxes remained on paper, so
the orthodox in regard to state finance and taxation, part of the did the plan for income tax. In June 1914 Beijing replaced the 1912
Confucian discourse on “benevolent governance,” in imperial China plan with a new scheme: all taxes would be collected by provinces,
for two millennia. and some of those taxes would be forwarded as national revenue to
In reality, however, poll tax and land tax often fell short of the the central government (Wu, 1984, pp. 125e128). Yet, provincial
ideal of “low taxes.” Surcharges on taxesesupposedly a per- governments (mostly controlled by warlords) continued to collect
centage of the tax to cover costs of collecting it (and sometimes whatever revenues they could, but were rarely compelled to for-
included costs of transporting tax in kind such as rice)ewere ward any to Beijing.
often arbitrarily high. Extraordinary taxes would be collected Studies in fiscal sociology tell us that obtaining revenue from
when serious crises arose, such as military confrontations on the sources other than domestic taxation would tend to give the state
frontiers or nomadic invasions into North China (Wu, 1984). For leeway to escape the responsibilities for delivering public goods or
many dynasties in Chinese history, increasingly higher taxes managing regulatory, monetary, and other economic matters
would accompany more frequent social unrest and rebellions, (Campbell, 1993, p. 177; Moore, 2004, pp. 306e308). Indeed, to
deteriorating military situations on the frontiers, and weakening meet the financial needs of the central government, President Yuan
functions and chronicle malaises of a dynasty until its final presided over issuing domestic bonds and making new loans from
collapse. foreign banks in 1913e1915. Such measures were an easier way for
When the Qing dynasty (1644e1911) replaced the Ming dy- the Yuan government to raise revenue than collecting taxes or
nasty following the pattern noted above, it proclaimed itself to be instituting tax reforms, but they plunged China deeper into debts
a legitimate inheritor of the Mandate of Heaven to rule China than under the Qing dynasty. Foreign loans also caused China to
(e.g., Hansen, 2010, p. 394). Both as a discourse and as a lose control over its financial resources. The Reorganization Loan of
commitment, Qing emperors emphasized “benevolent gover- 1913 was secured by the Chinese Maritime Customs revenue sur-
nance” that was manifested in reducing tax burdens on the plus and the salt monopoly tax. Under the terms of the loan, the Salt
people. The first four Qing emperors exempted parts or the Administration came under foreign management, as the Chinese
whole of the country from taxes at different points of time in the Maritime Customs had been since its founding in 1854, to insure
mid seventeenth to the late eighteenth century (Wang, 1971; Wu, servicing foreign loans and indemnities (Dong, 2000, pp. 61e62;
1984; Zelin, 1984). The Qing “low taxes” policy was both based on Van de Ven, 1996, pp. 831e835). In short, the supposed benefit of
the Confucian ideology and driven by a practical (or rational) extracting revenue from sources other than domestic taxes did not
approach to revenue extraction, in the face of a damaged econ- fully realizeethe maritime customs revenue and the salt monopoly
omy due to prolonged violence associated with the dynastic tax added little to the Chinese treasury for regular state functions,
change. The policy helped economic recovery and growth during
the eighteenth century.
From the mid nineteenth century onward, the Qing finance 2
The term “lijin” is often translated as “transit tax” in English language literature,
deteriorated steadily, because of an increasing pressure of popu-
since it was designed to be collected on goods crossing provincial boundaries. In
lation growth on resources (arable land in particular) and internal reality, however, the tax was also imposed by local authorities on resident
and external wars and their consequences. The wars included the wholesale and retail establishmentsehence our translation of it as “commercial
Taiping Rebellion (1851e1864), the two Opium Wars (1839e1842, tax.”
3
1856e1860), the Sino-French War (1885), the Sino-Japanese War Land tax was traditionally the most important tax revenue for dynasties, but in
the Qing dynasty, the fiscal importance of land tax decreased, constituting three
(1894e1895), and the Boxer War (1900). The costs and destruction quarters of the total tax revenue in 1753 but only one third in 1908, because other
caused by these wars very much outstripped any benefit the dy- sources of revenues were developed, such as maritime custom duties, salt mo-
nasty might have gained by increasing taxes in wartime. The nopoly tax, and the commercial tax (Wang, 1971).
22 Y. Xu, X. Xu / Accounting, Organizations and Society 48 (2016) 17e30

and the state was more debt-ridden than ever before. taxes” was a discourse on social-economic equality. The discourse,
After Yuan's death in 1916, the political division resulting from along with the ideology of “low taxes,” can be traced to the
rivalries among warlords further damaged national finance and Confucian traditionethe idea of equity in taxation was advocated
economy. “From 1916 on they [warlords] ceased to remit to Peking by some high officials no later than the Han dynasty in the 3rd
the only substantial source of revenues, the land tax, which until century (Hou, 2008, pp. 299e300), while the dream of economic
then had remained in sole control of the central government” (Van equality was a rallying cry in peasant rebellions throughout im-
de Ven, 1996, p. 830). Warlords typically had high discount rates perial China. By the early years of the Republic, “economic equality”
and engaged in the most short-term predatory behavior. While had become part of the Nationalist Party's official ideology advo-
surcharges on taxes would surpass or go several times over taxes cated by its founder Sun Yat-sen (1866e1925). In the meantime,
themselves, some warlords were notorious for collecting taxes Chinese print media talked about income tax and estate tax that
many years in advance to squeeze the last penny from the popu- were current in the West as “good taxes” (Lin, 2005, pp. 31e40). In
lation under their thumbs. In 1928 peasants in Chengdu, Sichuan 1928 the Ministry of Finance of the Nationalist Government
province, were paying land tax for 1985 (Dong, 2000, p. 83)!4 convened a national finance conference. The meeting resulted in
This was the situation the Nationalist Government confronted, several agendas for overhauling taxation, including institution of
when it came to power in 1927e28. For one thing, China's debt new categories of taxes. The new taxes were: 1) special consump-
payments continued to be a huge burden. Yet, the largest share of tion tax that would exclude daily necessities such as grains and
the outlay in the budget was military expenditure, due to incessant home-made cloth that were important to common people's daily
warsethe civil war (1927e36), the Second Sino-Japanese War life; 2) income tax, with a progressive rate so as “to augment the
(1937e45), and the civil war again (1946e49). Prior to 1937, about obligations of the rich and lessen the burden on the poor; ” 3) estate
40%e45% of the national budget was for military purposes, about tax, again “as one of the policies to harmonize the rich and the
30% for debts, and the remainder for civil expenses; and during the poor; ” and 4) business tax, to replace traditional levies on com-
Sino-Japanese War, military expenses increased steadily, reaching modities (BSY, July 1928, pp. 9e10). The justifications for special
84.9% of the budget in 1945 (Young, 1965, p. 16).5 A larger context, consumption tax, income tax, and estate tax expressed an egali-
however, was that prior to 1937, the Nationalist Government's tax tarian goal in social-economic terms.
revenues took a relatively small percentage of GDP. In 1933, for As the tax reform was launched and implemented in the late
instance, tax revenues were 2% of GDP, and in 1936 tax revenues 1930s and 1940s, a strong discourse on “good taxes,” as opposed to
amounted to 2.8% of GDPethe total spending by all levels of gov- “bad taxes,” emerged as an ideological justification.7 The “good
ernment remained below 10% of GDP (Rawski, 1989, pp. 13e16, taxes” ideology incorporated but went beyond the notion of eco-
22e2).6 These figures show that the state capacity in revenue nomic equality. Bad taxes included the poll tax, which treated the
extraction was limited and there was an urgent need for the state to rich and the poor in the same way and therefore was fundamentally
expand sources of revenue and the ability to collect taxes. unfair, and the commercial tax, which hampered domestic trade
The Nationalist Government responded to the financial situation and stymied economic growth and often became a device for
it faced with a tax reform, preceded by two other initiatives. The corruptive local officials to fleece business people. In contrast, good
first was to recover tariff autonomy through negotiations with taxes were based on the principles of equity and ability-to-pay,
foreign powers in order to increase the maritime customs revenue which would help reduce the gap between the rich and the poor
for the state, and it had been done by 1930 (Wu, 1990, pp. 198e202; and promote economic growth and social stability. Moreover, good
Sun, 2003, p. 380). The second was to stabilize the currency market taxes were described as “scientific” and “modern,” two key words
and to control the banking industry with a currency conversion in the public discourse in early twentieth-century China (Fung,
from silver tael to yuan (¥), and it had been accomplished by 1933 2010). As income tax and estate tax were introduced for the first
(Qian & Guo, 1986, pp. 225e226; ZMHSZ, 1991; Vol. 2, pp. 91e94). time in Chinese history, the justification for them as good taxes was
Thus the stage was set for launching the tax reform. especially prominent. Ling Shumo, a professor of economics with a
Ph.D. from University of Illinois, explained why income tax and
4. A new ideology on taxation estate tax as direct taxes were good:
Since such taxes cannot be passed on [to consumers], the end
To fully account for the Nationalist Government's tax reform, it point of the taxethat is, the actual tax burdenecan of course be
is necessary to examine its ideological underpinning, for two recognized more clearly, and the government can apply pro-
points. First, as a discursive resource, ideology would justify new gressive rates and other exemptions according to taxpayers'
taxes and help compel taxpayer consent and compliance. The less a abilities, and can separate earned income and unearned income,
ruler possessed other resources, the more important to the ruler based on different kinds of sources of income, to determine
was any ideological resource as moral persuasion to help revenue lower or higher tax grades in collection. Thus direct tax fits the
extraction. Second, the use of a new ideology on taxation by the just principle of “one who has more money pays more tax, one
Nationalist Government shows the transfer of ideas about taxes who has less money pays less tax, and one who has no money
from the West to China as a case study in a global history of debates pays no tax,” and that is why it can be called the best of modern
on taxation and of the rise of the tax states or fiscal states (Nehring taxes (Ling, 1941, p. 1).
& Schui, 2007; Yun-Casalilla et al., 2012).
A related antecedent in China to the new ideology of “good
7
The tax plan was first proposed in 1928 but was not pursued due to a lack of
certain conditions, such as tariff autonomy and uniform currency, and other in-
4
In 1928 the Nationalist Government was already established, but it did not adequacies in financial data collection and management identified by the Kem-
actually control Sichuan province where warlords were in charge until 1935, which merer Commission. When income tax was finally instituted in 1936 (see below),
was indicative of the limited capacity of the central government. followed by estate tax, there was a greater and more urgent need to justify them.
5
In 1935, for example, the military expenditure claimed 34.8% of the national The discourse on good taxes presented here were from the 1940s, because they are
budget (China Weekly Review, June 29, 1935, p. 165; May 15, 1935, p. 386; Sun. the sources that we were able to find. There could have been same or similar
2003, p. 411). discourse in earlier sources, unavailable to this study. The available sources also
6
To compare, the total government expenditure in the UK took around 25% of suggest that such discourses continued in the 1940s because resistance to, or
GDP in 1924e1937 (Daunton, 2001, p. 23). evasion of, new taxes continued to occur.
Y. Xu, X. Xu / Accounting, Organizations and Society 48 (2016) 17e30 23

Western examples of income tax and estate tax to popularize the


Thus a critical ideological corner was finally turnedethe modern idea of “good taxes.” At the height of the state implementing new
concept of good taxes replaced the traditional notion of “low taxes” taxes in the early 1940s, the Direct Tax Monthly carried articles to
as benevolent governance.8 Indeed, the ideal of low taxesethe describe income tax in the United States, Canada, Great Britain,
lower the betterebeing the badge of good governance became France, Italy, Germany, and other countries (ZY, May 1941, p. 1e11;
untenable in early twentieth-century China for two historical rea- July 1941, pp. 1e10; August 1941, pp. 33e44; October 1941, pp.
sons. First, after the Qing fell into perpetual indebtedness in the 29e32). Recent research on the circulation of ideas about taxation
second half of the nineteenth century, state revenue was constantly between and among states explored how “historical actors have
insufficient to cover expenditures. Second, independent of foreign interpreted and conceptualized the challenges posed by economic,
exploitation (especially after tariff autonomy was achieved in political and social developments, and how they have framed and
1929), the Chinese state that was striving for modernization had to transferred their ideas about taxation accordingly” (Nehring &
continuously expand state functions, increase state expenditure, Schui, 2007, p. 2). The phrase “ideas about taxation” includes eco-
and extract more and more tax revenues, even if in the absence of nomic thoughts and theories, ethical judgments about taxation,
wars. Ling explained why new taxes were necessary and feasi- and administrative knowledge of and experience in taxation.
blee“under today's political organization [i.e., modern state], many Indeed, the Chinese state or tax reformers combined the technical
social projects cannot be undertaken by private entrepreneurs but and ethical lessons learned from the West and the social and moral
by the state, from building roads, promoting education, to devel- imperatives rooted in the Chinese tradition to justify new taxes.
oping health-care system. As the people benefited from such pro- Significantly, Chinese tax reformers recognized that Western tax
jects, they will gradually understand the message that ‘paying taxes systems could not be indiscriminately transplanted onto Chinese
is citizens’ natural duty'” (Ling, 1941, p. 4). This was the vision of a soil. They noted that the political and economic conditions in China
modern state and its relations with the public, modeled after were far too different from Western nations, who were somewhat
Western nations. different from one another as well, to warrant wholesale trans-
The same point was repeated by a tax official in explaining the plantation. For instance, one tax collection official wrote:
business income tax: In the past the state was responsible only for
The birth of direct taxes started with income tax in Great Britain
peace and security, and therefore required expenditure was small;
and it was followed by [similar taxes in] the United States.
“what the modern state needs to do is much more than before, from
Thereafter other kinds of direct taxes in Europe and America
birth to death all things that the people need must be taken care of
experienced the difficulties of building a system gradually up to
by the state in a collective manner....It is a totally erroneous idea to
its completion. Indeed, merits and defects of a system lies in
seek minimizing expenditure. But there should be a fair and
certain principles. What is the principle of a good system? The
reasonable way to raise the required revenue to suit the people's
establishment of a system must suit the need of a nation's
abilities” (GZY, January 31, 1947, p. 2). The author noted that besides
conditions and must be in accordance with political and eco-
the principles of equity and ability-to-pay, good taxes such as in-
nomic laws (GZD, February 1, 1947, p. 3).
come tax had other advantages: it was universal (thus creating
more sources of revenue); it was reliable; it was flexible; and it was
sustainable. He stressed that the business profit tax was good tax Another tax official spoke highly of the income tax and estate
because it was based on the ability-to-pay and a progressive rate, tax in Britain as best examples of taxation based on equity and
and was universally applied; and it would reduce the opportunity ability-to-pay, but while pointing out the shortcomings in China's
for the rich to accumulate huge fortunes and thus equalize social income tax and estate tax regimes, he said that since China had only
wealth (GZY, January 31, 1947, p. 2). Thus the egalitarian goal recently started to implement such taxes, imperfection was inevi-
expressed in 1928 continued to be upheld as a moral high ground table and improvement would have to be gradual (Ye, 1946, pp.
and was incorporated into the good taxes ideology. Chinese tax 15e17). As a matter of fact, the new taxes adopted by the Nation-
reformers (state officials and finance experts) embraced the idea alist Government went through many changes in design and
that the sensible approach to funding modernization was to make implementation, and the changes were in response to the condi-
tax burden on taxpayers equitable, and sources of tax revenue tions in Chinese economy and society and the state's capacity to
sustainable. The point made by the Chinese tax official about the deal with them.
modern state taking care of the people's needs “from birth to
death” was a promise by the state in the bargain for more taxes. The 5. New taxes and revenue increase
promise was to motivate taxpayer compliance on the one hand, and
was predicated on the state's ability to compel and enforce This section examines what taxes were introduced by the
compliance on the other hand. Nationalist Government, what conditions facilitated the adoption
The good taxes ideology was learned from the West. In fact of these taxes, and what was the result of the new taxes for state
Chinese reformers explicitly looked to Western experiences in revenue.
taxation as living lessons and justifications, since the larger Income Tax (suode shui). Per the decisions made at the 1928
discursive context at the time was that Western nations were finance conference, in January 1929 the government issued the
modern and China was yet to become modern.9 Besides print mass “Regulations on Income Tax,” based on the similar regulations that
media, in government-sponsored journals of taxation published by were issued by the previous governments in Beijing but never
tax agencies, tax officials and finance experts repeatedly cited implemented. The law again remained on paper, however, due to
oppositions from foreigners in China (see below) and other prac-
tical difficulties. Not until July 1936 did the government issue the
8
This ideological turn was not smooth and unproblematic. While debates on this “Provisional Regulations on Income Tax,” and proceed to collect the
ideological shift are not a focus for the present study, the issue is certainly worth tax. Under the law, effective on October 1, 1936, incomes from 1)
examining in the future.
9
business, 2) salaries/wages, and 3) interests on security investment
There were contemporary criticisms in the West of the principles of equity and
ability-to-pay as the foundation of fair or just tax, of which Chinese tax reformers
and savings were subject to tax; income from interests was taxed
made no mention, whether or not they were aware of such criticisms (for an by a proportionate rate of 5%, and income from business and sal-
example of the criticism, e.g., Kendrick, 1939). aries/wages by a progressive rate of 3%e20% (Sun, 2003, p. 390).
24 Y. Xu, X. Xu / Accounting, Organizations and Society 48 (2016) 17e30

After the Second Sino-Japanese War began in July 1937, the the historical trend”ehe named Great Britain, the United States,
government faced greater financial demands, especially due to the France, Germany, and Italy as examples (ZY, September 1941, pp.
loss of custom revenues to the Japanese who occupied China's port 19e20). Again, to be modern or Western-like was an important
cities (Young, 1965, p. 34). To help support military expenditures, discursive trump card in promoting new taxes.
the government issued the “Law on Income from Property Rentals Business Tax (yingye shui). Historically, the commercial tax (lijin)
and Sales” in January 1943, with a progressive rate of 10%e50% for had been a major tax revenue for provincial governments since its
agricultural land and properties and 10%e80% on other properties. establishment in the 1850s. When the Nationalist Government
A month later the “Income Tax Law” replaced the 1936 regulations finally decided to abolish the commercial tax, alternative revenue
on income tax. After the war ended in September 1945, the “Income source had to be found to offset this revenue loss for provincial
Tax Law” was revised in April 1946. The new law expanded income treasuries. In 1928 the Guidelines of Provincial Collection of Busi-
categories from three to five: 1) business, 2) salary or wages, 3) ness Tax was issued. Under the law, business tax belonged to pro-
interests on security investment and savings, 4) property rentals vincial tax revenues; it were collected by categories and grades of
and sales, and 5) one-time income. All incomes were taxed with a goods and based on business income; and tax rate would not go
progressive rate of varied grades (Sun, 2003, pp. 390e391). The beyond 2%, except for luxury goods; and brokerage tax, pawn tax,
final incarnation of the Income Tax Law was enacted in April 1948.10 slaughtering tax were superseded. In June 1931 the Business Tax
One of the challenges the Chinese state confronted in adopting Law was enacted, and the commercial tax finally ceased. The law
income tax was the opposition from foreigners and foreign busi- provided that all for-profit enterprises were subject to business tax
nesses in China (Lin, 2005, pp. 55e57). After the “Provisional Reg- except for agriculture (which was covered by land tax), and that
ulations on Income Tax” was unveiled in July 1936 (it applied to provinces would decide tax rates according to local conditions
“persons residing in the Republic for more than one year,” within a range of 2%e10% for tax assessed on sales or net profit, and
regardless of nationalities), the American, British, and Japanese 4%e20% for tax assessed on capital value. This led to widely
Embassies in China declared that their nationals in China would not different tax rates and collection methods among provinces, and
abide by the law. Their arguments were that their nationals enjoyed abuses and corruption abounded. In 1942 the central government
extra-territorial rights (they were not bound by Chinese law- took over the collection of business tax to make it standardized and
sepractically they could not be prosecuted by Chinese courts any- improved (Sun, 2003, p. 394e395).
way), and that Chinese citizens in many provinces would not pay The adoption of these new taxes by the Nationalist Government
income tax (that is, the Chinese state was unable to enforce the shows a parallel to many historical cases in Western countries
law), so they should not pay either (New York Times, September 23, where wartime was often an opportunity for rulers to expand tax
1936, p. 9). This situation reflected the Chinese state's weak bar- categories and/or raise tax rates (Braun, 1975; Brewer, 1990;
gaining powereits domestic political legitimacy was undermined Douglas, 1999, pp. 146e147; Levi, 1988, p. 33). Referring to this
by foreign nationals' defiance at its tax law. For instance, a journal stream of research, Campbell pointed out that “most researchers
published by the Shanghai Native Bankers Association commented have not distinguished between different types of war” and that
in 1936 that foreigners in China made countless profits each year revenue ratcheting tended to occur in states involved in global
but avoided paying income taxes that would not have made a dent wars, rather than more restricted interstate wars, “because global
to their profits. “If the government is unable to collect tax uniformly wars are more expensive to finance” (Campbell, 1993, p. 166). In our
[from both foreigners and Chinese], how can it face its citizens” (QY, case, the civil wars the Nationalist Government was fighting against
Sept. 15, 1936, pp. 17e18)? The issue remained unsettled until 1943 the Communists during 1927e1937 and 1946e1949 claimed
when the United States and Great Britain, after long negotiations around one third of its annual revenue, but did not help enhance its
with the Nationalist Government, renounced the extra-territorial political legitimacy. In contrast, the Second Sino-Japanese War in
rights for their nationals in China, as a good-will gesture to the 1937e45 was devastating to China's economy, which included the
wartime-ally China (Wu, 1990, pp. 544e547; Fishel, 1952). This was loss of much of maritime customs revenue to the Japanese occu-
symbolically important for the legitimacy of the Nationalist Gov- pation (Boecking, 2011), but it was a fight for the nation's survival
ernment, even though it was financially insignificant since most and leading such a war enhanced the Nationalist Government's
foreign-owned businesses were in the treaty ports under the Jap- political legitimacy. The war helped the state implement new taxes
anese occupation during 1937e1945. and compel compliance for war efforts, besides invoking the ide-
Estate Tax (yichan shui). The government issued the “Provisional ology of “good taxes.” A situation unique to the Chinese case was
Regulations on Estate Tax” in October 1938, and it was followed by the afore-mentioned relinquishing by the British and American
the “Implementing Regulations on Estate Tax” in 1939. The law governments of their nationals' extra-territorial rights in China,
applied only to Chinese citizens who inherited properties and which removed the legal ground for foreigners to resist Chinese
valuables in China and abroad. Inheritance valued at ¥5000- income tax and helped boost the Nationalist Government's
¥50,000 was taxed by a proportionate rate of 1%, and inheritance legitimacy.
valued at more than ¥50,000 by a progressive rate up to 50%. The The new taxes began to be collected step by step. In October
Regulations was replaced by the Estate Tax Law in 1946, by which 1936 the government started collection of income tax under the
the threshold for the tax was raised to ¥1 million, and a progressive “Provisional Regulations on Income Tax,” initially limiting to sal-
rate up to 60% (Sun, 2003, p. 393). Tax officials promoted estate tax aries of public servants and earned interest on the central gov-
as a modern and progressive tax to overcome the public perception ernment bonds only. In January 1937 the collection expanded to
that the tax was state invasion into private transfer of properties cover all categories of taxable income (personal, business, and se-
between generations within families that was held inviolable by curity investment incomes). With the outbreak of the war in July
the Confucian tradition. One official argued, in addition to the ne- 1937, most sources of maritime tariff revenue, salt tax revenue, and
cessity of the tax for war efforts, that “collection of estate tax has a other taxes were lost to the Japanese. In October 1938 the gov-
significant place in finances of all modern, important nations. ernment, now relocated to Chongqing, Sichuan province, issued the
Therefore to start collecting estate tax is really a great act that suits Regulations on Excess Profit Tax during the Extraordinary Period to
offset the lost revenue. This tax was assessed on business profit
more than 15% of capital or real estate rental profit more than 12%
10
For the text of the Income Tax Law of 1948, see GZD, July 1948, pp. 8e18. of property value; and the collection of the new tax started in
Y. Xu, X. Xu / Accounting, Organizations and Society 48 (2016) 17e30 25

January 1939 (and it would end in January 1947). In addition, estate well as corruption-preventing mechanismethese sites totaled
tax began to be collected in July 1939. Now that income tax, excess around three thousand in 1941 (Ling, 1941, pp. 14e15; Rao, 1941, p.
profit tax, and estate tax were all collected by the central govern- 2).11 These 230 multi-provincial, provincial, and sub-provincial tax
ment, the Income Tax Administration under the Ministry of Finance agencies, and more of them down the road, would cost resources to
was changed to the Direct Tax Administration in June 1940, and its build, maintain, and staff, even though no statistics of those costs is
provincial and regional bureaus and offices changed their names available to the present study.
accordingly. The Direct Tax Administration also took over the Economist Ling hoped the tax apparatus would be further
collection of stamp tax in 1940 and of business tax in 1942, even expanded. To illustrate the scale of the task, a few examples from a
though these were indirect taxes (Sun, 2003, pp. 390e396). long list Ling provided will suffice here. As shown in Table 1, the
The tax reform yielded measurable results in revenue increase. Yunnan Direct Tax Bureau had under its jurisdiction 128 counties or
In 1941 the central government tax revenues totaled ¥871,604,000, municipalities, but had only five branch bureausean average of one
of which stamp tax, income tax, excess profit tax, and estate tax branch bureau for twenty-five counties; the Gansu-Qinghai-
added up to 15.4% or ¥135,000,000, second only to maritime cus- Xinjiang Bureau had 162 counties and ten branch bureauseone
toms revenue (59%) and ahead of business tax (13.3%) and salt tax for sixteen; the Henan Bureau had 112 counties and five branch
(11.7%) (Ling, 1941, p. 19). In Sichuan province alone, collected bureauseone for twenty-two; the Guangdong Bureau had ninety-
business tax increased from ¥853,797 in 1936 to ¥2,840,195 in 1937, nine counties and five branch bureauseone for twenty, and so on
and then to ¥3,953,663 in the first six months of 1938 (SYSY, June so forth. Ling held that to collect taxes fully and effectively, at a
1938, p. 78). According to another source, the Direct Tax Adminis- minimum there should be one branch bureau for six counties and
tration posted a tenfold increase in receipts between 1936 and 1937 one tax office in each county (Ling, 1941, pp. 23e25).
and 1940, and further ten nine-fold increase to ¥6478 million in This was not the whole story, however. Regarding inherent
1944 (Strauss, 1998, p. 145). Importantly, the new taxes that were problems in tax collection independent of the war situation, Ling's
established during the war would stay after the war ended. diagnosis in 1941 offered some clues. In his view, in spite of the
What was the cost of collecting new taxes? In 1929 the achievements cited earlier, much more remained to be done to
Nationalist Government had engaged a seventeen-member com- improve tax collection. Financial data, especially accounting books
mission, headed by Princeton University Economics Professor in businesses, must be uniformly designed and systematically kept,
Edwin W. Kemmerer, to advise the government on state finance since the existing situation of wide varieties or incomplete nature
(New York Times, October 21, 1928, p. 39; December 14, 1929, p. 5; of accounting data caused difficulties for tax assessment and
March 30, 1930, p. 10; also Muhse, 1935). Kemmerer had advised at auditing and lent opportunities to tax evasion. For the same pur-
the time that China was not ready to adopt income tax, because a pose, registration of businesses must be vigorously undertaken, and
lack of standardized accounting records, systematic registration of property registration and residency registration be synchronized to
properties, and experience in reliable auditing would make the cost facilitate tax assessment. He emphasized that to make the good tax
of collection exceed the revenue (Ling, 1941, p. 5, 20; Young, 1965, p. actually good, i.e., for the principles of equity and ability-to-pay to
32). According to the economist Ling, however, contrary to Kem- be realized, greater efforts must be made to prevent tax evasion
merer's assumption, the cost of collecting new taxes was relatively (Ling, 1941, pp. 22e23).
low, despite the lack of systematic property registration and com- The government was aware of the issues Ling pointed out, but
plete financial data. The collection cost ranged from 4.09% to 7.17% was constrained by the involved costs. Not until 1946, after the
of new taxes collected during 1937e1941, averaging 5.75% a year Sino-Japanese War ended, did the expansion of tax agencies move
(Ling, 1941, pp. 19e20). Although it is unclear what was counted by into high gear. The provincial-level direct tax bureaus had reached
Ling as the cost of tax collection, the new tax regime was financially twenty-five across the countryetwenty were for provinces and five
viable. To explain why that was the case, two important issues are for major port cities Shanghai, Tianjin, Chongqing, Qingdao, and
analyzed in the following two sections. Hankou (GZD, April 15, 1947, p. 14). Although individual agencies
were often understaffed, the total number of tax agencies
6. Taxation as state building increased. The Guangdong Direct Tax Bureau was provided with a
personnel quota of 91, but in early 1947 it had only 50 staff mem-
The increase of tax revenue cited above was achieved by bers, while the need for at least 70 was acutely felt (GZD, April 15,
revamping and expanding tax assessment and collection apparatus, 1947, p. 4). On the other hand, in 1946 the Guangdong Bureau was
that is, by a growth of state legitimacy and capacity. Taxation is not overseeing fourteen branch bureaus, which in turn supervised
a condition of, but is part and parcel of, state building. This section seventy tax offices (GZD, January 1, 1946, pp. 27e29). This was a
examines the expansion of state capacity in taxation, both “hard- significant expansion from five branch bureaus in 1941, though part
ware”ebuilding tax apparatus, and “software”etraining and of Guangdong was under Japanese occupation during 1938e1945.12
monitoring tax agents. Some of the initiatives for effective tax collection required
The Nationalist Government did not resort to tax farming in building new institutions and facilities. In September 1940, for
collecting the newly-instituted taxes, but built and expanded state- instance, the “Regulations on Cargo Shipment Registration for
run apparatus. In 1941 within the territories under the Nationalist Direct Tax” was enacted to help collect business income tax and
Government (i.e., excluding Japanese-occupied territories), the excess profit tax. Under the regulations, a merchant residing in city
Direct Tax Administration oversaw 13 tax bureaus each responsible A who wanted to purchase goods from city B must get a license
for one or more provinces, 99 branch bureaus, and 118 tax offices. from the tax bureau in city A; when goods were purchased in city B,
These agencies only dealt with assessing taxes, and never handled he must report their quantity and value to the tax bureau there and
collection, which was designed to reduce corruption. Tax money
was remitted by taxpayers directly to the national treasury through
government and private banks and postal officesea cost-saving as 12
In August 1940 the Chongqing Direct Tax Bureau issued a public notice that
taxpayers in the occupied territories should submit taxes to tax agencies in prov-
inces controlled by the Chinese government (see ZY, August 1941, p. 70). There is no
11
Ling said tax-paying sites numbered over three thousand, and Rao said they evidence that such a requirement was enforced, and one doubts that it could have
numbered 2,835, each probably citing from different sources. been enforced in any way.
26 Y. Xu, X. Xu / Accounting, Organizations and Society 48 (2016) 17e30

Table 1
Number of tax bureaus as compared to number of counties in the country, the 1940s.

Provincial direct tax bureau Number of counties Number of branch bureau Average number of counties per branch bureau

Yunnan 128 5 25.6


Gansu-Qinghai-Xinjiang 162 10 16.2
Henan 112 5 22.4
Guangdong 99 5 19.8
Guizhou 85 5 17.0
Hunan 76 6 12.7
Jiangxi 84 7 12.0

receive certificates; the tax bureau in city B then send the dupli- good, the state had to improve tax agents' skills and fight shirk and
cates of the certificates to its counterpart in city A; and finally he corruption among them. The taxation journals published by tax
must return to the bureau in city A to have the goods verified to get agencies were designed to be educational tools for tax personnel as
a seal of permission to sell the goods. This complicated procedure well as taxpayers. Many issues of such journals contained articles
was to ensure that the tax bureau would know how much sales and discussing how to improve tax collection, including calls for tax
profits the merchant would realize in a given tax year so that it personnel to be knowledgeable of tax laws and regulations, be
would be more difficult for the merchant to evade tax. The scheme patient and tenacious in dealing with taxpayers, be careful and
required establishing inspection stations along the key trans- thorough in conducting tax assessment and investigation, and most
portation routes to check cargos passing through to verify the importantly, be honest and incorruptible in doing their jobs (e.g.,
certificates issued by tax bureaus. Thus, another set of state SYSY, July 1938, pp. 13e17; January 1939, pp. 1e2, 13e15; ZY, Sept. 1,
agencies was built. In Guangdong province, such inspection sta- 1941, pp. 44e52; Oct. 1, 1941, pp. 22e28; SY, 1944; No.3, pp. 17e19,
tions grew from seven to thirty-one within one year (September 78e79; GZD, February 28, 1947, pp. 9e11; YZT, 1947; No. 22, pp.
1941-Auguest 1942) (GZD, January 1, 1946, pp. 12e14). 5e7; No.38, pp. 5). The training of tax agents was not just “tech-
The expansion of state capacity in the form of tax agencies nical; ” it was ideological as well. In the emergence of Exchequer in
entailed training tax officers. In order to staff the entire tax appa- twelfth-century England, “literary and numerical skills became
ratus with trained personnel, the state administered exams to new ideological norms that gradually defused through society.
select candidates, and put them through further training, to be tax They provided the technical infrastructure which underpinned the
officers. For candidates, the state targeted college graduates new centralized state and facilitated the exercise of political power”
majoring in finance, economics, accounting, or statistics. The first (Jones, 2010, p. 88). In the Chinese case, the training of tax agents in
training class in 1936 graduated sixty-eight people. The second and skills of tax assessment and investigation, along with moral edu-
the third classes graduated eighty-nine in total. These people were cation in professional ethics, played the same role in taxation and in
assigned to tax offices on probation for three months, and they took the expansion of state legitimacy and capacity in general.
another exam before being officially appointed. Again, the outbreak Education and exhortation would not be sufficient to eradicate
of the war in 1937 disrupted the selection and training program. abuses and corruption, and institutional mechanisms and law
Yet, it is in the middle of the wartime, in December 1940, that the enforcement would be necessary, even if their effectiveness could
state issued the “Provisional Regulations on Special Examination only be measured in relative terms. In 1946 the Ministry of Finance
for Direct Tax Personnel” that established the criteria for candidates established a new policy: Each employee of the tax bureaus must
for senior and junior tax officers (Tan & Zhang, 1995, pp. 163e164). have a guarantor who would be held responsible for making
By June 1941 the Direct Tax Administration had a roster of 525 monetary restitution for abuse or corruption committed by the
senior officers (college graduates) and 893 junior tax officers (high employee. In one case, Mr. Zhu, an employee of the Wuxing Branch
school graduates), and 641 staff members, a total of 2,059, in the Bureau of the Jiangsu Direct Tax Bureau, was found to be extorting
country (not including occupied territories) (Ling, 1941, pp. 14e15). bribery from a tax-evading underground money shop, and he went
By the end of the Sino-Japanese War, the Ministry of Finance had into hiding before being arrested. The authorities then went after
devised a plan for increasing personnel in all tax agencies. Under Zhu's guarantor, Mr. Guo. The latter responded that he did not
the Regulations on Staffing Standards for Direct Tax Bureaus of personally know Zhu (and his current where-about) and had
1946, the Shanghai Bureau was to have a minimum staff of 400 to a offered to be Zhu's guarantor only at the earnest request of a friend
maximum of 426; the Tianjin Bureau, 300e343; the Hankou Bu- who was Zhu's relative. The Jiangsu Direct Tax Bureau asked the
reau, 150e343; and the Qingdao Bureau, 200e343. Other bureaus Shanghai Direct Tax Bureau for assistance in the case since Guo was
across the country were classified into three grades based on residing in Shanghai, but the Shanghai Bureau replied that the
population sizes: at first grade, a bureau was to have a minimum Wuxing Branch Bureau had to take care of the matter on its own
staff of 120 to a maximum of 163; at second grade, 100e129, and at (JPA, 1946). It appears that while the central government was in-
third grade, 70e95. Branch tax bureaus were classified into four ventive enough to create a system of guarantor for tax agents, such
grades: at first grade, 100e180 staff members; at second grade, a system could still be gamed or defeated by state agents to varying
50e100; at third grade, 30e60, and at fourth grade, 25e40 (GZD, degrees; and that local tax agencies were aware of many difficulties
Feb. 1, 1946, pp. 8e11). In Guangdong Direct Tax Bureau, exams (and the resulting costs they had to bear) in enforcing the rules
were administered in early 1946 to select senior tax officers (college established by the Ministry and therefore did not try very hard to
graduates majoring in economics, finance, and business) and junior enforce it. Here lies the inherent limit of the state's bargaining
tax officers (high school or specialized school graduates). Thirty- power vis-a -vis its agents.
three seniors officers and sixty-four junior officers were selected As for judicial penalties for corruption by tax agents, there were
(GZD, February 1, 1946, pp. 7e8). laws and regulations on the book. Although no systematic data is
Building state apparatus and staffing tax personnel created available to this study, an incomplete browsing of archival catalogs
principal-agent relationship, an inherent issue in state building. To suggests that corruption cases involving tax personnel prosecuted
collect tax effectively and make envisioned “good taxes” actually by courts were relatively few among all criminal cases during the
Y. Xu, X. Xu / Accounting, Organizations and Society 48 (2016) 17e30 27

time period under study. households were full-time specialized producers, unlike peasants
doing a sideline, so that they should pay full business tax without
discount (SYSY, October 1939, p. 23). This suggests that peasants
7. Stateesociety interactions over taxation
who produced pulp as a sideline were not subject to business tax.
Indeed, according to an order from the Sichuan Provincial Gov-
The relationship between the state and its agents was inter-
ernment dated July 1938, peasants who bought and sold raw silk
sected by interactions between the state and its constituents, that
were exempted from business tax, while merchants pretending to
is, taxpayers. Such state-society interactions were a vital part of
be peasants to buy and sell raw silk would be punished with fines
taxation and/as state-building taking place in Nationalist China.
when discovered (SYSY, August 1938, pp. 31e32). In a similar
The expansion of tax categories and tax apparatus was constantly
fashion, the Sichuan Provincial Government exempted peasants
contested by social actors, and state legitimacy and capacity were
selling domestic animals they kept as a sideline from business tax
tested by the ways the state dealt with such responses from society.
(SYSY, August 1938, pp. 31e32).
No matter how the state would justify new taxes by invoking the
While protecting peasants from being overburdened by taxes,
ideology of “good taxes” or the necessity of a war for national
the tax agencies did not want to let merchants or the well-to-do get
survival, taxpayers could still perceive newly-created taxes as extra
away with tax evasion. The Ministry of Finance exempted from
burdens imposed by the state, and respond accordingly.13 In the
business tax handloom-spun cotton cloth produced and consumed
best-case scenario, the state would impose and collect new taxes as
locally (typically by peasants). When the Sichuan Business Tax
much as socially, economically, and technically feasible, without
Bureau found that local tax offices also exempted non-local textiles
causing tax riots or rebellions; and social actors/tax payers would
such as wool and silk, it demanded that merchants selling textiles
resist or evade new taxes as best as they could by taking advantage
woven with sixteen or more looms or with electricity-powered
of the existing mechanisms and/or inherent flaws in the state
weaving machines, or selling wool and silk even if handmade,
system, without causing the state to resort to coercive forces. With
must be taxed according to the law, “since both producers and
given legitimacy and capacity or bargaining power, the state would
consumers of such textiles were not the poor people” (SYSY,
negotiate with and accommodate taxpayers or social actors to
October 1939, p. 23).
reach a mutually acceptable deal, so as to reduce transaction costs
These instances demonstrate that The Nationalist Government's
for tax compliance. In the end, whatever transpired in the impo-
expressed new ideology of taxationeequity (consistent with its
sition, collection, resistance, and compliance of the new taxes un-
long professed egalitarian principle) and ability-to-pay (learned
der the Nationalist Government was the net result of such
from Western countries)ewas not lip service or propaganda only,
negotiations and compromises.
but was backed up by specific tax policies, which also reflected its
The responses of Chinese taxpayers to the new taxes may be
low discount rate and therefore its concern for long-term economic
considered in two categories: One is to negotiate with the state by
growth.
presenting economic difficulties and requesting reasonable ex-
Besides policy toward a category of taxpayers such as peasants
emptions, and the other is to find ways to evade taxes in illicit
or merchants, how the state dealt with individual business entities
manners. As cases sampled below will show, the tax agencies of the
is also illuminating. In 1938 (after the war broke out the year
Nationalist Government would try to work with taxpayers in the
before) a construction company in Liangshan county, Sichuan
first category by granting or denying exemptions on the merit of
province, contracted a project to build a runway for a government-
individual cases. As for tax evaders, the authorities would try to
owned airport. The company asked for tax exemption on the
police and catch them by building state agencies and penalize vi-
ground that it was engaging in a project for national defense. The
olators according to laws, rules, and regulations on the book, even
Sichuan Provincial Government responded that the project was
though penalties varied with local authorities. Both approaches
indeed for national defense, and to “encourage” such undertakings,
actualized and delimit the expanding state powerethey manifested
the company was to pay only half of business tax (SYSY, August
the real effects of state building.
1938, p. 31). The compromise shows that the moral high ground
Of the said interactions, the state responses to requests from
of fighting the war for national survival worked both waysefor the
taxpayers asking for tax exemptions are sampled first. The policy on
state and taxpayers.
consolidated tax and business tax provided that when a business
The state-society interactions over taxation pointed to a crucial
had a monthly sales income below ¥50, it was exempted from such
development in early twentieth-century Chinaethe rise of elite
tax (SYSY, March 1939, pp. 13e14). In 1936 the Academia Sinica
organizations. Historian Wong has noted that elites in imperial
made a request to the Ministry of Finance that textiles produced at
China were not organized in any corporate fashion. “Chinese elites,
the institution for research purpose but eventually sold to textile
like European elites, were related by friendship networks and
mills be exempted from the consolidated tax (before the tax was
sometimes by marriage, but the Chinese lacked any more formal
replaced by business tax). The Ministry rejected the request,
organizations that could easily serve as bases for negotiations with
arguing that the tax the Academia was to pay ought to be counted
the central government” (Wong, 2001, p. 75). This was changing in
as part of its operating and research expenses (SG, August 1936, pp.
the early twentieth century, however, if by “formal organizations”
30e31).
one refers to more than political institutions. Recent studies have
While standing firm to an academic institution, the state's was
documented the emergence and increasing assertiveness of pro-
more considerate towards the poorer segments of the population,
fessional and social organizations in urban settings that engaged
especially peasants. In 1939 the tax office in Dazhu county, Sichuan
the Chinese state to protect or advance the group interests that they
province, reported that it was collecting business taxes from
represented but often did so in the name of the public good (e.g.,
households that produced pulp for paper-making mills at a 40%
Bun, 2001; Sheehan, 2003; Xu, 2001; Xu & Xu, 2008, 2003).
discount. The Sichuan Business Tax Bureau instructed that such
The same phenomenon was seen in the area of tax negotiations
as well. In early 1947 Zang Boyong, a Western-trained physician in
13
Shanghai, received notice from the district tax office of the
For instance, before the implementation of the direct taxes in 1936, Chinese
businesses were already complaining about the newly-created consolidated tax
Shanghai Direct Tax Bureau that he should pay income tax and
hurting Chinese-owned industries, especially the cotton yarn and tobacco in- business profit tax on the pharmacy attached to his medical office.
dustries. See Wright (1991), pp. 657e658. Zang turned to the Medical Practitioners Association of Shanghai
28 Y. Xu, X. Xu / Accounting, Organizations and Society 48 (2016) 17e30

for help. The association presented Zang's request to the tax bureau Nationalist China may be glimpsed in one report. During November
against the tax assessed on his pharmacy. Zang's argument was that 1937-December 1938, the Sichuan Business Tax Bureau audited
the small pharmacy was not for profit but for patients' convenience, 13,567 businesses in the city of Chongqing, Sichuan province, of
as it ordered medications from commercial pharmacies and stored which 384 businesses (or 2.4%) were found to be evading taxes.
them nearby. The bureau responded that it would ask for in- Most of these were in hardware or oil businesses, and tax evasions
structions from the Direct Tax Administration of the Ministry of took place most frequently in July, August, and September (SYSY,
Finance (SMA, 1947). Similarly, a Chinese native bank (called money December 1938, pp. 39e41). This was only a snap shot, but it pro-
shop) found itself being assessed business income tax higher than it vided a sense of the scale of the problemeit was not surprising. The
should be, and it turned to the Shanghai Native Bankers Associa- auditing itself, of course, was part of enforcement efforts.
tion. The latter intervened on its behalf, and the Shanghai Direct The state launched several initiatives for tax compliance. For one
Tax Bureau promised to make further investigations (SMA, 1947). thing, it began to undertake the task of collecting economic-
On another occasion, when a medicinal material store was notified, financial data to facilitate tax assessment. In preparation for in-
after it had paid income tax, that it was selected for auditing by the come tax and business tax, the government began to register
Shanghai Direct Tax Bureau, the store turned to the Association of businesses more systematically. In August 1936, for example, the
Medicinal Material Trade Association, and the latter turned to the Tax Administration (later Income/Direct Tax Administration) of the
Shanghai General Chamber of Commerce. The Chamber wrote to Ministry of Finance registered product brands, trademarks, retail
the tax bureau arguing that according to the government rules, the prices, and tax rates of cigarette companies and textile mills. The
tax agencies should consult with trade associations to decide which registration of cigarette makers and textile mills was a monthly
businesses were to be selected for auditing, and the bureau failed to exercise, with updates of new businesses and deletions of busi-
follow the rules in this case. The bureau responded positively (SMA, nesses gone under. The tax agencies in Jinan, the capital of Shan-
1947). In fact, the tax agencies routinely worked with business dong province, registered individuals who produced hand-rolled
associations and trade guilds to determine income tax and profit cigarettes at home, while the government had ordered to ban
tax rates for related businesses, because such organizations were hand-rolled cigarettes by April 1937, precisely because such pro-
much better informed of the capital investment values and profit ducers were too numerous and too scattered to regulate and tax
margins of the businesses involved. The tax agencies also cooperate effectively (SG, August 1936, pp. 21e22, 48e74).
with such entities to standardize accounting methods and books The state also issued regulations on penalty for tax evasion.
for various businesses in order to facilitate auditing and tax When the tariff autonomy was achieved in 1929, the regulations on
assessment, part of the effort to modernize financial data collection. punishing smuggling and evading custom duties was issued. Other
For instance, Chongqing Leather Industry Association drafted a regulations covered evasions of income tax, stamp tax, and busi-
standardized format of accounting books for the trade in 1939, ness tax. Tax non-compliance cases reveal that tax agencies
which was published in an official journal, the Sichuan Provincial imposed fines on hand-rolled cigarette makers who sold cigarettes
Business Tax Monthly (SYSY, February 1939, pp. 21e26). falsely using the brands of established cigarette companies to evade
These interactions and negotiations between the state and social taxes (SG, August 1936, pp. 80e93).14 As the amount of fines varied
actors reflected the state's legitimacy and capacity and its calcula- from a few yuan to dozens of yuan in most of these cases, the cost of
tion of costs in extracting revenue. The state's taxation would enforcing the tax law was more than the taxes thus recovered and
appear more legitimate or acceptable, when the state appeared the fines imposed. The enforcement was more symbolic of state
reasonable in responding to or accommodating the requests of power than for direct gain in monetary value.
taxpayers/social actors. The negotiations and compromises would
also reduce costs for tax compliance.
To grasp the actualizing effect of the state-society interactions, 8. Conclusion
such interactions should be further analyzed in the Chinese
context. On the one hand, the idea of “no taxation without repre- In the final analysis, the increased revenue from the tax reform
sentation” and formal institutions of political representation were (which was no small achievement by itself) was supposed to be
absent, and on the other hand, trade guilds and business associa- translated into economic resources and political power for the
tions played an important role in representing various social groups state, and to a certain degree it was, but the gain was still insuffi-
in their negotiations with the state over taxation (and other issues). cient in the face of the mounting and continuous military expen-
Those groups were able to act in that way because of a long- diture that the Nationalist Government incurred in the civil war of
standing and evolving cultural repertoireethe remonstrative and 1946e1949, a war that was unpopular and undermining its legiti-
representative functions of social organizations or elite groups in macy. More generally, the tax reform as revenue extraction and
dealing with the state on behalf of the “people” or the “public.” state-building was a work in progress in the 1940s, and it remained
Such interactions served to validate legitimacy for both sides. The an unfinished project when the Republican era came to an end in
state's power to impose new taxes was being accepted by social 1949.
actors, while the tax agents' mistakes or arbitrariness were being Nonetheless, this case study of the tax reform under the
checked by social actors whose public standing to do so was being Nationalist Government in China yields some important insights
accepted by the state. Such interactions intersected the state- for tax research as accounting history. First of all, the Nationalist
agents relationship and helped reduce transaction costs and in- Government intended to rule China for a long run (a low discount
crease tax legitimacy and tax compliance for the state. Thus, the rate) and, for the most part, tried not to “dry the pond to catch fish.”
Chinese case was an alternative to the negotiating mechanism of a Hence its accommodations to taxpayers or social actors in imple-
representative body (parliament and such), typical in Western na- menting new taxes. Second, from the beginning it had limited
tions, and it enriches our understanding of taxation and state
building.
14
Finally, a brief look is in order at the enforcement by the state of In 1929 makers of cigarettes (including hand-rollers) were obligated to pay a
cigarette tax, so that hand-rollers would have incentive to pretend they were not
tax laws and regulations, another aspect of state legitimacy and makers by falsely using brand names, besides being able to sell their products more
capacity and of state-society interactions. One of the enforcement easily. Falsely using a brand name or trade mark was also illegal, but apparently tax
efforts was to fight tax evasion. The incidence of tax evasion in agencies were not pursuing that matter.
Y. Xu, X. Xu / Accounting, Organizations and Society 48 (2016) 17e30 29

political and economic resources as bargaining power: It had to Various.


GZY e Guangzhou Zhijieshui Yuebao [Guangzhou Direct Tax Monthly], January 31,
honor national debts it inherited from the previous governments
1947 (p. 2).
and abide by the unequal treaties with foreign powers in order to JPA e Jiangsu provincial archives, file number 1018-42-B-2102, (1946).
be recognized as the legitimate Chinese state. Yet, the continuing Ling, S. (1941). Woguo zhijieshui zhi huigu yu qianzhan [The retrospect and pros-
foreign debts and unequal treaties did not help its domestic legit- pect of direct taxes in our country]. In Zhijie shui yuebao [Direct tax monthly],
August, 1 (1, 8) (pp. 1e6).
imacy, nor did the continuous civil war with the Communists. It is QY e Qianye Yuebao [Banking Business Monthly], Sept. 15, 1936 (16, 9), (pp. 17e18).
during the Sino-Japanese War of 1937e1945 that its political Rao, L. (1941). Woguo suodeshui zhi zhengshou [Collection of income tax in our
legitimacy was enhanced by leading a war for national survival, country]. In Zhijie Shui Yuebao [Direct tax monthly], October, 1(10) (pp. 1e9).
SG e Shuiwu Gongbao [Taxation Public Bulletin], (1936). Various.
even though its economic and financial well-being was severely SMA e Shanghai municipal archives, files number Q433-1-17, (1947).
damaged. The war made it necessary and possible for the state to SY e Shuiren Yuekan [Tax Personnel Monthly], (1944).
institute new taxes and compel tax compliance. Importantly, when SYSY e Sichuansheng Yingye Shuiju Yuebao [Sichuan Province Business Tax Bureau
Monthly], (1938e1939). Various.
the war was over, the new taxes that taxpayers complied with Tan, Z., & Zhang, S. (1995). Jiu zhongguo suodeshui chuangban chuqi renshi zhidu
during the war would stay. jianshu [Brief account of the personnel system in the early period of instituting
Within that historical context, this paper analyzes several crucial income tax in old China]. In Wenshi ziliao xuanji [Selection of sources on history
and Culture], No.30 (pp. 163e164). Beijing: China Literature Press.
developments in the transformation of both taxation and the Chi- Ye, L. (1946). Xianxing zhijieshui zhi jiantao [a review of direct taxes at the present].
nese state into modern forms, unpacking an “ensemble of practices In Guangdong zhijieshui daobao [Guangdong direct tax Herald], January (pp.
and rationales” of the Nationalist Government. First, as state finance 15e17).
YZT e Yungui Zhijieshui Tongxun [Yunnan Guizhou Direct Tax Newsletter]. (1947).
had become unsustainable with huge debts, high-level military
ZMHSZ e Zhonghua Minguo Huobi Shi Ziliao [Sources on currencies in the Republic
expenditures, and limited tax revenues, the Confucian ideology of of China]. (1991). Shanghai: Shanghai People's Press.
“low taxes” was jettisoned and replaced by the Western-derived ZY e Zhijieshui Yuebao (Direct Tax Monthly). (1941). Various
ideology of “good taxes,” which helped justify new taxes. Second,
after the state embarked upon the tax reform, taxation in turn English language primary sources:
required building tax agencies and training and monitoring tax
China weekly review (p. 386). (May 15, 1935).
agents who staffed the apparatus, an expansion that was con- China weekly review (p. 165). (June 29, 1935).
strained by transaction costs. Third, compliance with new taxes was Kendrick, M. S. (1939). The ability-to-pay theory of taxation. American Economic
pursued by the state through negotiations and compromises with Review, 29(1), 92e101.
Muhse, A. C. (1935). Taxation of foreign and domestic goods in China. Journal of
social actors or tax payers, as well as enforcement of tax laws and Political Economy, 43(2), 226e245.
regulations, which both actualized and delimited state legitimacy New York times (p. 39). (October 21, 1928).
and capacity in taxation (and other matters by extension). In the New York times (p. 5). (December 14, 1929).
New York times (p. 10). (March 30, 1930).
end, the new ideology justifying new taxes, the building of tax
New York times (p. 9). (September. 23, 1936).
apparatus and the training of tax personnel, the negotiations with
social actors/taxpayers, and the enforcement of tax laws and reg- Secondary sources:
ulations, all led to a growth of state legitimacy and capacity. In sum,
this paper contributes to the accounting history literature by Bastid, M. (1985). The structure of the financial institutions of the state in the late
emphasizing taxation as state building (a growth of state legitimacy Qing. In S. R. Schram (Ed.), The scope of state power in China. London: School of
Oriental and African Studies.
and capacity) and by illustrating two history/culture-specific vari- Boecking, F. (2011). Unmaking the Chinese nationalist state: administrative reform
ations to the familiar historical pattern of taxation and state among fiscal collapse, 1937e1945. Modern Asian Studies, 45(2), 277e301.
building based on the Western experiences: First, the shift from the Bonney, R. (1995). Economic systems and state finance. New York: Oxford University
Press.
Confucian ideology of “low taxes” to the Western-derived ideology Braun, R. (1975). Taxation, sociopolitical structure, and state building: great Britain
of “good taxes,” and second, the state-society negotiations over and Brandenburg-Prussia. In C. Tilly (Ed.), The formation of national states in
taxation in the absence of formal representative political Western Europe (pp. 243e327). Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Br€
autigam, D., Fjeldstad, O., & Moore, M. (Eds.). (2008). Taxation and state-building in
institutions.
developing countries: Capacity and consent. Cambridge: Cambridge University
As a preliminary study on the subject, this paper has obvious Press.
limitations. Future studies may investigate other related issues, Brewer, J. (1990). The sinews of power: war, money, and the English state, 1688e1783.
such as whether additional state capacities were developed, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
Bun, K. M. (2001). The salt merchants of Tianjin: state-making and civil society in late
whether the fiscal budgeting was improved, whether the collected imperial China. University of Hawaii Press.
new taxes were used in an accountable way (other than military Burchell, S., Clubb, C., & Hopwood, A. G. (1985). Accounting in its social context:
spending), whether the tax reform made the state and economy towards a history of value added in the United Kingdom. Accounting, Organi-
zations and Society, 10(4), 381e413.
more or less fragile, and how taxation as state building affected Campbell, J. L. (1993). The state and fiscal sociology. Annual Review of Sociology, 19,
economic growth as tax sources. 163e185.
Campbell, J. L. (2009). Epilogue: a renaissance for fiscal sociology? In I. W. Martin,
A. K. Mehrotra, & M. Prasad (Eds.), The new fiscal sociology: taxation in
Acknowledgments comparative and historical perspective (pp. 256e265). Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press.
Chen, D. (1984). Zhongguo tianfu shi (a history of Chinese land taxes). Shanghai:
We are grateful to the editor, David Cooper, and two anonymous Commercial Press, 1937; reprint, Shanghai: Shanghai Bookstore.
reviewers for their constructive comments and suggestions on Cooper, D. J., & Robson, K. (2006). Accounting, professions and regulation: locating
earlier versions of the paper. This study is partially funded by a the sites of professionalization. Accounting, Organizations and Society, 31(4e5),
415e444.
sabbatical leave from Old Dominion University and a faculty
Daunton, M. (2001). Trusting leviathan: The politics of taxation in Britain, 1799e1914.
development grant ($2,000) from Christopher Newport University. Cambridge University Press.
Deng, K. G. (2012). The continuation and efficiency of the Chinese fiscal state,
700BCeAD 1911. In B. Yun-Casalilla, P. K. O'Brien, & F. C. Comin (Eds.), The rise of
References fiscal states: A global history 1500e1914 (pp. 335e352). Cambridge University
Press.
Chinese language primary sources: Dong, M. (2000). Zhongguo jindai caizheng shi [a history of finance in modern China].
Kunming: Yunnan University Press.
Douglas, R. (1999). Taxation in Britain since 1660. New York: St. Martin's Press.
BSY e Beiping Shuiwu Yuekan [Peking Taxation Monthly], July 1928. Various. Drysek, J. S. (1990). Book reviews. Of rule and revenue. By Margaret Levi. The Journal
GZD e Guangdong Zhijieshui Daobao [Guangdong Direct Tax Herald], (1946e1948).
30 Y. Xu, X. Xu / Accounting, Organizations and Society 48 (2016) 17e30

of Politics, 52(1), 309e310. newspapers in the French revolutionary war. Accounting Historians Journal,
Ezzamel, M. (2002). Accounting working for the state: tax assessment and collec- 31(1), 93e128.
tion during the new kingdom, ancient Egypt. Accounting and Business Research, Qian, J., & Guo, Y. (1986). ). Zhongguo huobi shi gangyao [an outline history of Chinese
32(1), 17e39. currency]. Shanghai: Shanghai People's Press.
Fishel, W. R. (1952). The end of extraterritoriality in China. Berkeley, CA: University of Rawski, T. G. (1989). Economic growth in prewar China. Berkeley, CA: University of
California Press. California Press.
Fung, E. S. K. (2010). The intellectual foundations of Chinese modernity: Cultural and Sheehan, B. (2003). Trust in troubled times: money, banks, and state-society relations
political thought in the Republican era. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. in Republican Tianjin. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
Hansen, V. (2010). The open empire: A history of China to 1800. New York: W. W Strauss, J. (1998). Strong institutions in weak polities: State building in Republican
Norton. China, 1927e1940. Oxford University Press.
Hou, J. (2008). Zhongguo jingji shi [a history of Chinese economy]. Beijing: New Star Sun, Y. (2003). Zhongguo caizheng shi [a history of Chinese finance]. Beijing: Chinese
Press. Academy of Social Science Press.
Huang, R. (1974). Taxation and governmental finance in sixteenth-century Ming China. Tilly, C. (1975). The formation of national states in Western Europe. Princeton:
Cambridge University Press. Princeton University Press.
Jones, M. J. (2010). Sources of power and infrastructural conditions in medieval Tilly, C. (1985). War making and state making as organized crime. In P. Evans,
governmental accounting. Accounting, Organizations and Society, 35(1), 81e94. D. Rueschemeyer, & T. Skocpol (Eds.), Bringing the state back in (pp. 169e191).
Kiser, E., & Sacks, A. (2009). Improving tax administration in contemporary African Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
states: lessons from history. In I. W. Martin, A. K. Mehrotra, & M. Prasad (Eds.), Van de Ven, H. J. (1996). Public finance and the rise of warlordism. Modern Asian
The new fiscal sociology: Taxation in comparative and historical perspective (pp. Studies, 30(4), 829e868.
183e200). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Wang, Y. C. (1971). The fiscal importance of land tax during the Ch'ing period.
Kiser, E., & Schneider, J. (1994). Bureaucracy and efficiency: an analysis of taxation Journal of Asian Studies, 30(4), 829e842.
in early modern Prussia. American Sociological Review, 59(2), 187e204. Wang, Y. C. (1974). Land taxation in imperial China, 1750e1911. Harvard University
Krom, & Krom. (2013). The whiskey tax of 1791 and the consequent insurrection: “a Press.
wicked and happy tumult”. Accounting Historians Journal, 40(4), 91e114. Webber, C., & Wildavsky, A. (1986). A history of taxation and expenditure in the
Lamb, M. (2001). ‘Horrid appealing’: accounting for taxable profits in mid- Western world. New York: Simon and Schuster.
nineteenth century England. Accounting, Organizations and Society, 26(3), Wong, R. B. (2001). Tax resistance, economy and state transformation in China and
271e298. Europe. Economics of Governance, 2, 69e83.
Lamb, M. (2003). Questions of taxation framed as accounting historical research: a Wong, R. B. (2012). Taxation and good governance in China, 1500e1914. In B. Yun-
suggested approach. Accounting Historians Journal, 30(2), 175e196. Casalilla, P. K. O'Brien, & F. C. Comin (Eds.), The rise of fiscal states: A global history
Lamb, M., & Lymer, A. (1999). Taxation research in an accounting context: future 1500e1914 (pp. 353e377). Cambridge University Press.
prospects and interdisciplinary perspectives. The European Accounting Review, Wright, T. (1991). Coping with the world depression: the nationalist government's
8(4), 749e776. relations with Chinese industry and commerce, 1932e1936. Modern Asian
Levi, M. (1988). Of rule and revenue. Berkeley: University of California Press. Studies, 25(4), 657e658.
Lin, M. (2005). Xiyang shuizhi zai jindai zhongguo de fazhan [the development of Wu, Z. (1984). Zhongguo shuishou shi [a history of Chinese taxation]. Shanghai:
Western-style taxation systems in modern China]. Taipei: Institute of Modern Commercial Press, 1937; reprint, Shanghai: Shanghai Bookstore.
History, Academia Sinica. Wu, D. (1990). Zhongguo waijiao shi [a history of China's foreign relations]. In The
Mann, M. (1993). The sources of social power: The rise of classes and nation-states, period of the Republic of China, 1911e1949 (Vol. 2). Zhengzhou: Henan People's
1760e1914. Cambridge University Press. Press.
Mann, M. (2005). The sources of social power revisited: a response to criticism. In Xu, X. (2001). Chinese professionals and the Republican state: The rise of professional
J. Hall, & R. Schroeder (Eds.), An anatomy of power: The social theory of Michael associations in Shanghai, 1912e1937. Cambridge University Press.
Mann (pp. 343e396). Cambridge University Press. Xu, Y., & Xu, X. (2003). Becoming professional: Chinese accountants in early
Martin, I. W., Mehrotra, A. K., & Prasad, M. (2009). The new fiscal sociology: Taxation twentieth-century Shanghai. Accounting Historians Journal, 30(1), 129e153.
in comparative and historical perspective. Cambridge: Cambridge University Xu, Y., & Xu, X. (2008). Social actors, cultural capital, and the state: the standardi-
Press. zation of bank accounting classification and terminology in early-twentieth-
Miller, P. (1990). On the interrelations between accounting and the state. Ac- century China. Accounting, Organizations and Society, 33(1), 73e102.
counting, Organizations and Society, 15(4), 315e338. Young, A. N. (1965). China's wartime finance and inflation, 1937e1945. Harvard
Moore, M. (2004). Revenues, state formation, and the quality of governance in University Press.
developing countries. International Political Science Review, 25(3), 297e319. Yun-Casalilla, B., O'Brien, P. K., & Comin, F. C. (2012). The rise of fiscal states: A global
Napier, C. J. (2006). Accounts of change: 30 years of historical accounting research. history 1500e1914. Cambridge University Press.
Accounting, Organizations and Society, 31(4e5), 445e507. Zelin, M. (1984). The magistrate's taels: Rationalizing fiscal reform in eighteenth
Nehring, H., & Schui, F. (2007). Global debates about taxation. London and New York: century Ch'ing China. Berkeley, CA: University of California Press.
Palgrave Macmillan. Zhou, Y. (2000). Wanqing caizheng yu shehui bianqian [Late Qing finance and social
Oats, L., & Sadler, P. (2004). Political suppression or revenue raising? taxing changes]. Shanghai: Shanghai People's Press.

You might also like