You are on page 1of 9

Forest Policy and Economics 86 (2018) 4–12

Contents lists available at ScienceDirect

Forest Policy and Economics


journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/forpol

The role of government in operationalising markets for REDD + in Indonesia MARK


Henry James Boer
Adjunct Research Fellow, Centre for Governance and Public Policy, School of Government and International Relations, Griffith Business School, Griffith University,
Brisbane, Australia

A R T I C L E I N F O A B S T R A C T

Keywords: The global climate initiative Reducing Emissions from Deforestation and Forest Degradation (REDD +) initially
REDD + included carbon markets as one potential policy mechanism to finance a range of forestry projects in developing
Carbon markets countries. Indonesia was an early leader on REDD +, and set up the regulatory frameworks and monitoring
Indonesia policy systems to support demonstration projects that could trade credits in voluntary carbon markets. This article
Governmentality
applies a neoliberal governmentality framework to evaluate the development of REDD + market institutions in
Indonesia during the Readiness period between 2008 and 2013. It critiques the role of the state in this process,
and how the authority of public agencies shapes the actions of private subjects. The case of Indonesia indicates a
pivotal role for government agencies at multiple levels in integrating the operation of REDD + market activities
within a supportive regime of forest and land management. Critical to this process was legislation to trade in
forest carbon and obtain project licenses, devolved land-use planning and forest management that could support
commercial activities, and robust MRV surveillance systems to oversee on-ground activities. Despite these ef-
forts, projects were often subject to an uncertain and highly contested forest management regime, undermining
attempts to demonstrate the viability of operationalising market mechanisms at the local scale.

1. Introduction projects could offer multiple opportunities, such as income for com-
munities through payments for ecosystem services (PES), a new in-
The global climate initiative Reducing Emissions from Deforestation vestment option for local businesses, and a potential stream of revenue
and Forest Degradation (REDD+) was initially conceived as a global for governments. Markets offered a potentially large source of capital,
incentives framework to transfer resources and capital to developing primarily as offsets purchased by large emitting countries and private
countries in return for implementing measures and programs that ad- industry, and thereby providing a complementary option to multilateral
dressed forest loss (McDermott, 2014). In the lead-up to and following or bilateral funds (Ebeling and Yasué, 2008). Despite the initial en-
the UNFCCC Bali Conference in 2007, carbon markets were en- thusiasm, REDD + offsets are not tradable in global cap and trade
thusiastically promoted by NGOs, multilateral agencies and some de- markets limiting potential finance (Angelsen et al., 2017), and projects
veloped countries as one potential mechanism to source long term fi- have faced significant obstacles setting up in developing countries (Sills
nance for REDD +. At the UNFCCC negotiations held in Durban in et al., 2014). Reference to markets for REDD+ activities was also ab-
2011, Parties endorsed the decision that “…appropriate market-based sent in the Paris Agreement, with emphasis shifting to low emissions
approaches could be developed by the [Council of the Parties]COP to development integrated within nationally determined contributions
support results-based actions for REDD +” (UNFCCC, 2011). Devel- (NDCs) (UNFCCC, 2015).
oping countries were encouraged to establish the institutions and During the REDD + Readiness period, a number of countries sup-
technical infrastructure to facilitate carbon markets – in addition to ported setting up markets as one component of a broader suite of
implementing a broad range of forest management programs and social programs. Indonesia, for example, implemented specific laws to reg-
and environmental safeguards. Countries were also to host demon- ulate carbon as an ecosystem service, and regulations to establish
stration projects to trial the various components required to trade projects and share finance and co-benefits (MoF, 2008, 2009a, 2009b,
carbon credits in future international and/or regional compliance 2012). The Indonesian Government (with support from multilateral and
markets. bilateral funds) invested substantial resources to develop robust carbon
The initial attraction of markets was the potential to commercialise measurement, monitoring, reporting and verification (MRV) systems
forest carbon as a new export commodity, competing against existing that meet international standards (Satgas REDD +, 2013). At the sub-
timber and agricultural industries (Fletcher et al., 2016). REDD + national scale, several prominent REDD + demonstration projects

E-mail address: h.boer@griffith.edu.au.

http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.forpol.2017.10.004
Received 18 January 2017; Received in revised form 2 October 2017; Accepted 2 October 2017
1389-9341/ © 2017 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.
H.J. Boer Forest Policy and Economics 86 (2018) 4–12

expended considerable resources to develop the management programs and Rose, 2008). Technologies represent the various tools or mechan-
and contract agreements to attract investor finance and trade forest isms for governing such as the procedures, policies, techniques of cal-
commodities in the voluntary market (Sills et al., 2014). However, these culation, laws, or processes of analysis, that enable authorities to shape,
market projects have faced significant barriers; such as limited long direct and limit collective and individual agency (Miller and Rose,
term financing for project activities (Dixon and Challies, 2015), lack of 2008). Subjectivities or identities also symbolise how actors respond to
community support and participation, and ongoing uncertainty and particular government programs, including their implicit support and at
conflict over forest tenure and resource access (Resosudarmo et al., times resistance (Lemke, 2002).
2014). In Foucault's (2008) analysis, the state functions as an important
Considering the early emphasis on markets, there is comparatively institutional formation through which different ideas and technologies
limited analysis of the various policies and components to set up market can be appropriated into government. The state is not an aggregation of
mechanisms for REDD + in Indonesia (see Astuti and McGregor, 2015). stable institutions, but rather operates as a site where government
Empirical analysis of REDD + in Indonesia has covered the myriad of technologies are stabilised into institutional settings (Lemke, 2007).
program activities and technical components introduced at the national The state is conceptualised as a ‘transactional reality’ (Foucault, 2007),
and sub-national scales, as well as the highly contested governance constituted through a dynamic ensemble of power relations and prac-
arrangements that characterised the reform process (for example Agung tices that at the same time produce, and are reproduced by, the in-
et al., 2014; Luttrell et al., 2014; Moelino et al. 2014; van Noordwijk stitutional features of the state. Political transformation is therefore not
et al. 2014; Wibowo and Giessen, 2015; McGregor et al., 2015). To attributed to the policies of an autonomous state, but can be traced to
provide a fuller analysis of efforts to establish REDD + market in- the series of new technologies and forms of knowledge that shape
stitutions in Indonesia, this article focuses on the critical Readiness government action. In the contemporary context, the state can be seen
period between 2008 and 2013. It applies a neoliberal governmentality to operate through networks of relations found within an array of
lens to explore the rationales, practices/technologies and forms of public and private organisations (Miller and Rose, 2008, pp.56–57).
knowledge that underpin different regimes of forest and carbon gov- The modern state itself exists and functions within these wider circuits
ernment (Winkel, 2012; Arts, 2014; McGregor et al., 2015). The article of power, as part of shifting networks of public and private actors that
analyses the various legislative, land-use planning frameworks and are differentially rewarded through access to certain institutions
technical programs that contributed towards a nascent commercial re- (Jessop, 2010).
gime for trading in forest carbon. Importantly, it elaborates on the In the series of lectures presented at the College de France Foucault
critical function of the state, and the conduct and authority exercised by (2007, 2008) explored certain governmentalities of neoliberalism re-
public bureaucracies in establishing these mechanisms. presented by the repositioning of markets and economic management
The analysis recasts administrative government as an important as the focus of public policy, supported by various practices and pro-
locus of authority and capacity in facilitating carbon markets as a form grammatic knowledge driving these new functions of government. Neo-
of neoliberal conservation. In Indonesia, this required various govern- liberalism provides a systematic and comprehensive expansion of the
ment agencies to develop and coordinate an array of regulatory and market to become the organising and regulative principle underlying
monitoring practices that could effectively steer and direct the actions the state and society, and as the model for human relations in general
of private companies and NGO's engaged in project activities. Critical to (Lemke, 2002). The key thrust of neoliberalism is to create conditions
this process was legislation to trade in forest carbon and obtain project that produce competitiveness and entrepreneurial behaviour, and to
licenses, devolved land-use planning and forest management that could promote a particular type of freedom and subjectivity expressed
support commercial activities, and robust MRV surveillance systems to through individual choice. Neo-liberal government produces the eco-
oversee market transactions and on-ground activities. The state was nomic rational subject driven to maximise self-benefit and to profit
pivotal to supporting and integrating this new array of market intui- through competition. Neo-liberal subjects are therefore responsive to
tions within broader forest management systems, but projects were manipulation through incentives, and individuals can be directed to-
often subject to an uncertain and highly contested governing regime. wards socially desirable ends through appropriate incentive structures
REDD + markets are unlikely to function effectively in Indonesia (Fletcher, 2010, p.123). The neoliberal state is not governed through
without substantial further administrative reforms and policy integra- overbearing bureaucracies that direct the population, but by shaping
tion across scales in order to deliver consistent and transparent out- the possible domains and incentives through which individuals govern
comes at the local scale. their lives (Lemke, 2002).
The next section of this paper develops a theoretical framework of Foucault (2008, p.132) argues that neoliberalism works actively to
neoliberal governmentality and its application to REDD+. The fol- create the space for competition to take place, and for this reason is not
lowing sections apply this framework to assess the establishment of necessarily laissez-faire capitalism, but rather a government interven-
markets for REDD + projects in Indonesia. tion of constant vigilance and active management. Government action
is interventionist only to the extent that it sustains the conditions for
2. Theoretical framework market activity, its task being to universalise competition and invent
market like systems for the actions of individuals, groups, and institu-
2.1. Neo-liberal governmentalities tions (Lemke, 2002). Government becomes reliant on new types of
expertise from economics, accounting and financial management and
Foucault's (2008) concept of governmentality provides a flexible outsources responsibilities to the private sector or civil society (Bevir,
approach to analyse different governing practices and the exercise of 2011). This increased function of these non-state actors in mobilising
power. Governmentality enables analysis is the various practices of rule the preferences of the population and carrying-out regulatory functions
(Dean, 2010), and how these practices are applied, re-combined and is representative of the changing rationalities of neoliberal government
then reformed in particular social and political contexts. Govern- (Sending and Neumann, 2006, p.652). Non-state interests are redefined
mentality theory explores the various rationalities and technologies of from an object of government action to an active participant in, and
government, and their relationship to forms of knowledge and the co- subject of rule.
production of subjects (Dean, 2010). Rationalities comprise a collective
logic around the activities of government, and thereby sort the multiple 2.2. REDD + and neo-liberal government
legal, regulatory and bureaucratic processes into logical associations.
Whilst rationalities conceive of certain ways of governing, technologies The application of a neoliberal governmentality frame can help
enable this thinking to be operationalised and applied in action (Miller reveal how REDD + markets employ a divergent collection of

5
H.J. Boer Forest Policy and Economics 86 (2018) 4–12

technologies, subjectivities and forms of knowledge, that in turn de- single case study of was used because it enabled application of well
termine the ways in which forests can be governed. Neoliberal ap- developed theory to a new context and set of phenomena (George and
proaches to tackling environmental problems emphasise the use of Bennett, 2005). Indonesia provides a critical case for developing a
market instruments and incentives to influence individual behaviour carbon economy for forests, enabling the partial test of a neoliberal
and encourage private investment in delivering solutions (Büscher governmentality framework.
et al., 2012). The rationale is that the production of ecosystem com- Data collection involved qualitative semi-structure interviews,
modities creates a profit or price motive that drives individual max- which enabled investigation of the various insights, interpretations and
imisation of benefits (Büscher et al., 2012, p.13). In the case of defor- reasoning of key respondents (Rubin and Rubin, 2005). This is im-
estation and carbon emissions, solutions often focus on market portant, because REDD + is a highly contested political domain subject
instruments that set prices for the environmental services provided by to competing ideas and values regarding suitable approaches to manage
forests and determine the monetary value of carbon (Portela et al., forests and carbon. Interview questions were derived from key litera-
2008). When applied to REDD +, these market instruments operate by ture in the field, including primary documents from Indonesia and
inventing a new exchange value around the carbon sequestered in aimed to understand relationships between different programs and the
ecosystems, and then establishing the conditions for the operation of an role of different state and non-state actors. Interview respondents were
alternative forest economy (Corbera, 2012). recruited using a combination of purposive and snowball sampling.
Transforming forest management practices at disparate locations Interview data were collected from 35 senior practitioners engaged
around the globe into a tradable commodity involves a number of directly in REDD + in Indonesia - with 15 respondents specifically
calculative practices that measure, quantify and standardise carbon into addressing market issues including; Indonesian government agencies,
commensurable credits (Lövbrand and Stripple, 2012). Forests se- the UN-REDD Programme Indonesia, United Nations Environment
quester and store volumes of carbon dioxide, which can be converted Program (UNEP), the Australian and German Governments, World
into metric tonnes that can be sold as standardised credits in global and Wide Fund for Nature (WWF), The Nature Conservancy (TNC), do-
domestic markets. Landowners, companies and even governments can mestic NGOs, carbon companies and researchers. A list of interviewees
generate REDD + credits by undertaking numerous land-use activities and pseudonyms can be found in attached Supplementary Table 1. This
such as conservation, reforestation, sustainable forest management or research was conducted according to ethical standards and for reasons
carbon agriculture. Voluntary forest carbon markets are increasingly of confidentially the names of interviewees are not provided.
governed by these formal and informal networks of non-state or private The interview data was combined with primary and secondary
actors who assume responsibility for multiple components of the forest documents, such as legislation, REDD + program reports, departmental
carbon commodity chain (Hajek et al., 2011; Lovell, 2014). This in- strategies, and research reports. Utilising multiple documentary sources
creasing agency of private operators in the carbon economy represents is an important method for generating a critical interpretation of an
“…a transformation of politics that involves a replacement of formal issue area (McCulloch, 2004). Triangulation methods were used to
and hierarchical techniques of government with more indirect regimes combine multiple sources of documentary data with interview tran-
of economic calculation (Lövbrand and Stripple, 2012, p.659).” scripts, which helped improve reliability and validity. Triangulation
In some forest a carbon markets, by contrast, government bureau- with different data points provides corroboration and convergence
cracies have assumed significant administrative and operational con- around a particular social event or process, reducing bias in the analysis
trol. Such as Mexico's' Payment for Ecosystem Services (PES) program, (Yin, 2009). The data was analysed using a combination of coding and
which operated according to the state's mandatory regulation and thematic analysis. Coding provides a systematic method to collate and
funding of various projects (Shapiro-Garza, 2013). In Indonesia, gov- organise the data according to related topics, concepts and themes, and
ernment agencies increased their regulatory power in markets that to link the text to the theoretical framework (Saldana, 2013). The codes
certify sustainably sourced timber, by establishing national state based and frames were drawn from the primary materials, followed by a series
schemes that compete directly with international certification schemes of theory based codes, with data analysed against the codes until high-
operated by networks of NGO's and private interests (Giessen et al., level saturation was achieved.
2016). In the Clean Development Mechanism (CDM), a large bureau-
cracy operating under the UNFCCC and in national level governments is 4. Results and discussion
responsible for the detailed assessment, approval and monitoring of
project activities (Stripple, 2010). This represents the application of 4.1. REDD + in Indonesia
administrative rationalism, where professionalised government agen-
cies govern through formal rules and laws and the application of Indonesia has the world's second highest rate of deforestation and
technical knowledge to identify environmental problems and develop forest degradation, estimated at approximately 2 million hectares per
solutions (Stripple, 2010). The model of efficient administrative ra- year and is one of the top 5 global GHG emitters amongst developed
tionalism is symbolised by vertical integration, based on clearly defined and developing countries. Indonesia was also an early leader in the
roles and the concentration of decision-making authority at the apex development of REDD + in the international negotiations, and in 2007
(Keskitalo et al., 2012). However, integration is not always uniform, hosted the UNFCCC CoP 13 in Bali. In 2009, the Indonesian
and bureaucracies will often compete over resources and authority in Government announced an ambitious and voluntary pledge to cut the
the governing of public domains such as forests (Giessen et al., 2016). country's emissions between 26% and 41% by 2030, primarily by re-
ducing high rates of deforestation (Satgas REDD +, 2013). Indonesia
3. Methods subsequently attracted substantial finance and technical support from
multilateral agencies and bilateral partners such as Norway. Since
The research project adopts a qualitative, single case study method. 2007, the country has made progress on a national reform agenda and
Qualitative research generates a holistic understanding of social phe- released a National REDD + Strategy, set up a dedicated coordinating
nomena and the complex interdependence of issues, and provides rich agency, and introduced a moratorium on new forestry concessions
and detailed description of the subject matter (Denzin and Lincoln, (Satgas REDD +, 2012; Agung et al., 2014). In 2015, the government of
2011, p.5). A qualitative design suited the research as it aims to provide Joko Widodo reintegrated the REDD + agency within a newly formed
a detailed and rich description of the overlapping series of policy and Ministry of Environment and Forestry (MoEF), who were charged with
technical reforms that support REDD + markets in Indonesia. The re- responsibility to implement the national REDD + program. The result is
search also situates REDD + within the political and economic condi- a complex array of policy reforms and project activities underway at
tions that characterise forest and land management in Indonesia. A different scales, of which markets and incentives comprise a

6
H.J. Boer Forest Policy and Economics 86 (2018) 4–12

complicated and uncertain component. services, and how carbon credits are to be marketed, including provi-
sions relating to the verification of emissions reductions (Wright, 2011).
4.2. Carbon market regulations Importantly, the Licensing Decree specifics how revenues generated in
the forest carbon market are to be distributed between project devel-
The Indonesian Government adopted the rationale and discourse opers and various government agencies.
that a market based approach could resolve the market and associated The application and approval stage outlined in the government
governance problems that cause deforestation (IFCA, 2008; UNREDD, regulations is a complex, multi-stage process and projects require a
2012; MoF, 2012). Coalitions of international development agencies number of permits and licenses. In submitting an application, devel-
such as the World Bank, large international environment NGOs and opers are required to provide substantial information including the
bilateral governments actively promoted markets as a key policy me- economic feasibility of the project, biophysical and social conditions of
chanism to be developed and trialed in Indonesia (World Bank, 2009; the site, risk assessment and management and the planned on-ground
Luttrell et al., 2014). There are few existing markets for forest eco- forestry activities. Although the regulations permit a range of new
system services in Indonesia, so a new carbon commodity chain could commercial activities in forests, the MoF retained significant authority
provide economic alternatives to current land-use activities (IFCA, in the project assessment and approval stage, and in ongoing mon-
2008). At the project level, this could increase the investment and re- itoring. This indicates that various government agencies occupy a re-
turns from forest management and expand the incentives for in- latively centralised role in managing and regulating the development of
dividuals, businesses and communities to participate in conservation carbon offsets, how they operate, and how benefits are distributed. The
activities (Project Director, Australian Bilateral Partnership pers. comm. fledgling REDD+ carbon market is subject – at least on paper - to
2012). significant oversight and regulation by national, provincial and district
To support market development, sections in the Indonesian bu- authorities at successive stages of project design and operation. Carbon
reaucracy adopted a relatively strategic role, enabling new legislation market activities are subject to hierarchical bureaucratic authority at
and policies, and retaining responsibility for oversight and monitoring multiple levels to assess activities, combined with ongoing monitoring
of project activities. The initial reforms were enacted by the former functions over forest and carbon resources. REDD + in Indonesia is thus
Ministry of Forestry (MoF) but the regulatory process was subsequently similar to other carbon markets such as the CDM that rely on a level of
taken over by the REDD + Taskforce, The President's Unit for administrative rationality; where the bureaucracy exercises authority
Development Monitoring and Oversight (UKP4), the REDD + Agency, through formal rules or laws and the constant creation and application
and then returned to the MoEF (Astuti and McGregor, 2015; Wibowo of technical knowledge (Stripple, 2010).
and Giessen, 2015). Indonesia was one of the first countries to establish
the institutions, or the legal rules and supporting information systems 4.3. Carbon rights
to sell and purchase credits in the voluntary carbon market. The gov-
ernment also committed to ongoing regulatory reform to make the Forest carbon markets require the state to create property rights to
domestic market compatible with future international carbon ac- enable the privatisation of the carbon sequestration and/or storage
counting standards, and trading rules set out under the UNFCCC. The services provided by forests. In many countries, carbon forest rights do
former MoF also introduced several key regulations and one decree that not formally exist and governments are required to introduce laws to
outline the legal and administrative processes to gain government ap- allocate rights between the state and private interests, and define the
provals and operational licenses for REDD + projects (MoF, 2008; MoF, principles of ownership for any emissions reductions (Palmer, 2011).
2009a; MoF, 2009b; MoF, 2012): Processes to legalise carbon property rights are therefore an exercise of
neoliberal governmentality, a form of state activity to create new ter-
• Regulation No. 68 of 2008 on Demonstration Activities of REDD; ritories of economic intervention, and to organise the conditions for the
• Regulation No. 30 of 2009 on the Implementation Procedures of commercialisation and appropriation of new commodities (Fletcher and
Reducing Emission from Deforestation and Forest Degradation; and Breitling, 2012).
• Decree No. 36 of 2009 on Procedures for Licensing of Commercial To complement other REDD + market reforms the Indonesian
Utilisation of Carbon Sequestration and/or Storage in Production Government has created a regime of partial property rights to facilitate
and Protected Forests. commercial trading in the carbon sequestered and/or stored in forests
• Regulation No. P.20/Menhut-II/2012 replaces the procedures to (Indrarto et al., 2012). Legal issues relating to carbon tenure are cov-
apply for a permit or permission from the Ministry of Forestry for ered by several regulations, in particular Articles 25 and 33 of Gov-
REDD + activities that were found in Regulation No. P.68/Menhut- ernment Regulation No. 6/2007 on Forest Systems and the Formulation
II/2008 and Regulation No. P.30/Menhut-II/2009. of Forest Management and Use, which states that carbon capture or
sequestration is a type of forest environmental service. An entity is
The Regulations and Decree outline a number of important steps granted the right over commercial use of environmental services, and
and conditions for project proponents to gain the required approvals. also the right to trade in carbon credits through the licensing process for
The Regulations specify what type of carbon sequestration activities are a REDD+ demonstration project (Wright, 2011). Additional regula-
permitted in particular forest tenures – including forest conservation, tions promulgated in 2009 extend carbon rights to include private and
reforestation or timber plantations. The Regulations also outline stages community forest concessionaires, and to village forest managers. The
in the project development and approval phase, and the processes for extension of rights to carbon sequestration/storage is an attempt by the
registering land and carbon offset contracts with government agencies. Indonesian Government to privatise the carbon contained in forests as
Regulation No. P. 20/Menhut-II/2012, stipulates that forest carbon part of the process to further commercialise and territorialise ecosystem
projects can be implemented in state forests that have been designated services.
as either production, protection, conservation or a private/community The bureaucracy continues to administer the process in a formal and
forest. The proponents of forest carbon activities can be government legal sense, and most lands subject to REDD + activities occur on public
agencies, state-owned or private enterprises, cooperatives or a com- land, much of which is already allocated for either timber and estate
munity. The Implementation Regulation deals with REDD + projects of crop production, or for conservation purposes. As such, carbon rights to
30 years' duration. It enables national and international entities to be forests represent a partial privatisation only, and the state retains sig-
‘REDD implementers’, and the implementer holds the right to trade the nificant authority in how lands are allocated, demarcated and ad-
carbon credits created by REDD+ activities (Wright, 2011, p.127). The ministered between carbon activities and multiple other land-uses.
Licensing Decree provides details for trading in carbon ecosystem Approximately 130 million of Indonesia's 187 million ha land base has

7
H.J. Boer Forest Policy and Economics 86 (2018) 4–12

been assigned to forest zones under the jurisdiction of the MoEF and is FMUs are thus critical to REDD + delivery at the local level and im-
administered under the New Forestry Law (NFL) issued in 1999. This portantly for integrating companies, stakeholders and landholders into
means the MoEF has the authority to assign the use or management a new regime of forest carbon activities (Director MoF, Director BAP-
rights of approximately 70% of Indonesia's land base to private entities PENAS pers. comm. 2012).
and communities, but they remain de-jure state lands. Further, the To support the rollout of FMUs, the Indonesian Government through
utilisation of forest resources is subject to a complex system of forest the central planning agency BAPPENAS is also prioritising regional
concession allocation, licensing and permits, that are administered by spatial planning as a key policy instrument. Indonesia's spatial planning
agencies operating at different levels within the central, provincial and laws are based on a principle of coordinated regulatory hierarchy, in-
district governments (Brockhaus et al., 2012; Sahide and Giessen, tegrating national level policy and development goals, with land-use
2015). objectives and priorities of the provinces and districts (Brockhaus et al.,
These issues of jurisdictional authority and coordination are com- 2012; Indrarto et al., 2012). Spatial planning enables central agencies
pounded by legal uncertainty that arises from unresolved land tenure to govern through a negotiated process with sub-national governments
and rights to forest resources (Resosudarmo et al., 2014). Access and and local interests. Spatial planning establishes a series of inducements
ownership over land and forests is highly politicised and subject to and restrictions on the freedoms of individuals and communities by
regular conflict between commercial interests, local communities and determining the location, type and extent of economic opportunities,
the various government agencies (Wright, 2011; Sahide and Giessen including REDD + projects. Spatial planning operates as an instrument
2015). To resolve tenure claims under REDD +, the Indonesian Gov- of allocation and demarcation, specifying zones where certain forest
ernment proposed using existing forest delineation processes under the activities are permitted and others prohibited. In Indonesia, spatial
National Land Agency. However, the legislation and process is highly planning is a statutory requirement for district and provincial govern-
technical and legalistic, vesting significant authority in the central ad- ments to map and zone where land-use development can occur, the
ministration. These mechanisms can result in protracted legal processes location of settlements and infrastructure, in addition to designating
that lead to further uncertainty over tenure claims, and often ignore or conservation and other land-use categories. Spatial plans will thus have
limit the interests of local stakeholders. Several interviewees from na- a significant influence on where carbon market projects are located,
tional NGOs argued that these existing processes are ineffective and and how they are accommodated alongside other potentially competing
further regulatory reform will be required to establish an equitable and land-uses(Deputy Director, Indonesian Climate Agency pers. comm.
effective legal process (Project Director, National NGO pers. comm. 2012).
2012).
4.5. Monitoring and mapping
4.4. Forest management and land-use planning
The Indonesian Government and partners have invested substantial
Forest allocation in Indonesia involves a series of statutory planning resources to set up the technical infrastructure for a functioning carbon
and management frameworks that specify where certain activities are market, such as a national and sub-national MRV system, a reference
permitted, and how commercial activities are to be managed. emissions level (REL), and forest mapping systems. At the broader scale
Commercial carbon projects will be subject to the same planning and these MRV, forest inventory and mapping systems, form part of the
allocation frameworks that govern other land and forest uses. As part of surveillance apparatus of REDD + that supports the functioning of
REDD +, the Indonesian Government is expanding Forest Management multiple regulatory and market mechanisms. According to Gane
Units (FMUs or KPH), an existing legislative requirement for all public (2012), surveillance systems provide a mechanism of social discipline
forest estate areas, including production and conservation forests. FMUs and control within neoliberal governmentalities. Surveillance systems
are administered through the national planning agency BAPPENAS and operate as a post-disciplinary model of governance, which devolves
provide a localised planning, management and enforcement instrument monitoring capacities to new agents of control that emerge from the
designed to improve how forests are governed. They have multiple market (Gane, 2012, p.631). In REDD +, satellite based MRV and
objectives, such as enhancing production outcomes for commercial mapping operate as a post-disciplinary instrument of surveillance that
operators, providing benefits to local community interests, and im- enables the tracking and monitoring of forest activities on the ground,
proving conservation and management systems (Kartodihardjo et al., and by extension the people, communities and companies that conduct
2011). FMU's operate through a local statutory body that has the au- these activities. At the national level, MRV expands the state's capacity
thority to plan and regulate all activities in the forest area, covering the to monitor access to forest areas, functioning as a sophisticated in-
mapping and designation of forest areas, monitoring law enforcement, formation retrieval mechanism that extends government into all forest
and setting harvesting quotas on commercial activities (Sahide et al., areas.
2016). The development of Indonesia's MRV system and the associated
FMUs expand the capacity of the central government through the MRV Strategy (Government of Indonesia, 2012) was coordinated
planning agency BAPPENAS to regulate and monitor the forest estate through the national REDD+ Taskforce and taken over by the REDD +
through an administering instrument operating at the local level Agency. MRV systems are an important governing technology in that
(Sahide et al., 2016). They enable central agencies to govern at a dis- they regulate market performance, in addition to the performance and
tance (Arts, 2014), exercising a disaggregated and yet important form self-regulation of individuals in the marketplace (Astuti and McGregor,
of control over the disparate forest estate. They provide a decentralised 2015). Government agencies will apply MRV to assess carbon market
and devolved planning and governing mechanism that redistributes projects against national and sub-national mitigation targets (Satgas
authority to local forest services and district governments (Bupati), but REDD +, 2013). MRV also oversees how private and public entities
also to timber plantation companies and communities operating or engage in the market, in terms of generating volumes of data on credit
living in the forest area (Bae et al., 2014). FMUs operate through an transactions, and the delivery of contracts and other services. MRV and
inclusive type of forest citizenship, extending the responsibility and carbon accounting systems are thus part of creating a new market in
obligation to govern forests to a range of local stewards who become ecosystem services, and are thereby internal to the regulation of the
both subjects and objects of this governing regime. These public, pri- market itself. As an instrument of carbon governing MRV monitors the
vate and community networks establish and operate the regime to macro and micro economies of forest and land-use activities, and
which they are subjected as members. FMUs set the conditions, com- thereby operates as a tool of economic vigilance characteristic of neo-
mercial rules, management systems and the localised monitoring re- liberal government. MRV enables governments to monitor patterns and
gimes to which those interests accessing the forest areas must operate. apply probabilities to assess how efficiently the market is operating and

8
H.J. Boer Forest Policy and Economics 86 (2018) 4–12

thereby adjusting and manipulating institutions to achieve certain ends. be appropriated into government (Lemke, 2007). In neoliberal gov-
By demarcating the capacities and boundaries of government action, ernment, the state is responsible for creating the institutional conditions
the MRV system is therefore instrumental to the production and con- and expanding opportunities for entrepreneurial activities, and needs to
sumption of forest carbon commodities. create the conditions for markets and incentives to function efficiently
A key component of Indonesia's REDD + program is dedicated to (Lemke, 2007). The state in Indonesia, to some degree, provides a cri-
developing the infrastructure and human capacity to collect data on tical collection of institutions through which REDD + market inter-
forests. The aim is to develop a sophisticated and detailed under- ventions were created and then operated (Astuti and McGregor, 2015).
standing about how biochemical cycles and human interactions func- The state itself is not the actor or the agent responsible for governing
tion at different localities and scales. Across Indonesia, there are mul- REDD + or transforming land-use change, but rather offers an institu-
tiple research projects dedicated to measuring carbon fluxes of forests tional formation that enables certain types of governing programs.
to determine sequestration rates and carbon storage capacity. Research Rather than enacting reform as a powerful public entity, the state
is being conducted into the economic and social drivers of forest loss, provides a combination of institutional processes and systems of orga-
and how different industry sectors and local agents produce greenhouse nisation that facilitate new carbon market interventions. The state is
gas (GHG) emissions. REDD + demonstration projects are also creating adjusted by the introduction of markets in new ecosystem services, but
inventories of the biophysical aspects of different forest ecosystems and state institutions also inform, shape and condition how these markets
integrating this information with census data and other biophysical are governed within a particular territorial domain. At the domestic
information. For example, the GoI with support from bilateral agencies level the state needs to accommodate public institutions that are ac-
is creating the Indonesia National Carbon Accounting Systems (INCAS), countable to international rules and standards around carbon, whilst
and a forest mapping and inventory system called the One Pap Initiative operating within the confines of existing policy and planning regimes,
(OMI). These mapping systems aim to develop one integrated geo- and on-ground practices that demarcate use and access to forest re-
graphical information system for Indonesia that supports a range of sources.
cross-agency forest planning and management activities. According to Analysing markets and REDD + needs to account for the formal and
Astuti and McGregor (2015 p. 2287) the OMI operates as an important informal functions administered by different state institutions, and how
technology of carbon government that could overcome the fragmenta- this shapes and is shaped by the actions of both public bureaucracies
tion of forest spatial information and decision making, and provide a and private actors and networks. The state offers the location and re-
rationale for restructuring forest governance through the in- sources to enact political strategies by networks of state and non-state
stitutionalisation of new forms of knowledge. interests aligned to particular goals and discourses (Jessop 2010). The
state also supports a discursive and institutional space though which
4.6. Governing subjects and the state different interests can contest issues, to determine how problems should
be addressed and who should hold the responsibility and authority to
Markets for REDD + in Indonesia also construct new ideal sub- govern. Clearly this occurred in Indonesia, where various coalitions of
jectivities in the management of forests. Markets aim to encourage local public and private interests were able to utilise various parliamentary
businesses, communities and individuals to become active agents in the and bureaucratic institutions to both progress and block certain REDD
production of forest carbon, as well as the delivery of other social and + reforms (Luttrell et al., 2014). The Indonesian state is also responsive
developmental benefits. These new subjects include the carbon forest and vulnerable to numerous competing demands from public sector
manager or project operator, who participates in the production and interests, and a range of private, NGO and community stakeholders,
commercialisation of carbon to create profits and livelihoods (Stephan that constantly seek to mould and manipulate forest institutions to-
et al., 2013). In Indonesia, there are multiple carbon consultancies that wards particular objectives. Many of these interests have an active
provide services such as technical advice on carbon accounting, con- function in the governing of market activities, resulting in a contested
duct surveys and collect data, develop project design documents, as and often shifting authority over who potentially governs REDD +
well as provide training and support. Local projects also foster the local projects and the public forest estate (Director, International NGO pers.
village or household forest carbon worker, trained and employed in comm 2012).
various aspects of carbon measurement and auditing, or in forest and
land management. This represents a process of subject conversion or 4.7. Challenges to establishing market projects
diversification - such as from loggers and swidden agriculturalists to
sustainable forest managers and project operators. Despite progress on various institutional components to facilitate a
Carbon markets also foster new networks of public-private, com- carbon forest market in Indonesia, it faces significant challenges for
mercial and civil agents that act as the developers, managers, regulators further expansion. One of the major challenges is the access to finance.
and administrators of these programs. Consistent with a neoliberal REDD + credits are not incorporated into existing compliance carbon
governmentality, many of these agents assume various responsibilities markets. A new international trading framework under the Paris
in setting up and regulating the new REDD + carbon economy in Agreement is still under negotiation, and it remains uncertain whether
Indonesia. Driven by a combination of strategic self-interest and ethical REDD + activities will be included. As a result many projects have
responsibility, new coalitions form around the creation of formal and struggled to attract longer term finance despite substantial up-front
informal institutions designed to enhance environmental and carbon investment by project developers (Sills et al., 2014; Dixon and Challies,
accountancy standards, and to ensure regulatory compliance (Dixon 2015). More critically, REDD + projects do not compete against the
and Challies, 2015). These coalitions increasingly attract further opportunity costs of existing extractive industries that provide sub-
players that recognise the benefits of having all competitors meet cer- stantial economic and social returns for communities, industries and
tain performance standards and benchmarks. The expanding networks governments (Fletcher et al. 2016). If carbon markets or other sources
shape how these new market regimes operate and assume important fail to deliver private investment then resource extraction and land-use
responsibilities in the stewardship of public forests. Markets function as conversions remain potent incentives (UN-REDD, 2012). In the pro-
a prescriptive steering mechanism where the actions of various carbon vince of Aceh, for example, the government was initially very suppor-
forest subjects are shaped and defined according to the conditions and tive of REDD + as an alternative to palm oil, however finance failed to
rules set by the production, trading and management of a carbon materialise and the government proceeded to issue companies large
commodity. palm oil licenses on uncleared peat swamp forests (Tata et al., 2014).
Governmentality theory approaches the state as a dynamic and For a market to operate successfully requires high-level coordina-
composite reality, through which different ideas and technologies can tion and monitoring, which raises important questions regarding the

9
H.J. Boer Forest Policy and Economics 86 (2018) 4–12

efficacy of public institutions to operationalize the various governing when in 2009 the MoF released the regulations to support markets and
technologies needed for REDD +. A director from an international NGO revenue sharing, which were actively opposed and not endorsed by the
argued that the forest administration in Indonesia is so dysfunctional Ministry of Finance (Manager, National Climate Change Agency pers.
and under resourced that governments at multiple levels are currently comm 2012). In reality, the state in Indonesia often displays a limited or
unable to deliver the complex institutional reforms and technical sys- compromised authority over resources and their utilisation, and is
tems required for a transparent REDD + market (Director, International challenged to provide an accountable or transparent system of forest
NGO pers. comm. 2012). For example, establishing sophisticated MRV and land administration. The state has proven to be an extremely
systems requires substantial resources, in addition to the cost of pro- porous entity that enables specific economic interests to control access
curing regular field data and satellite imagery (Indrarto et al., 2012). and utilise public forest institutions for selective benefit. For decades
One of the critical challenges is developing the technical and human the state in Indonesia has operated as a suitable ensemble of laws and
capacity to accurately monitor land cover change, a critical step to mechanisms for specific political and business elites to exploit forests
building an MRV system that meets international standards (Team for selective private gain (McCarthy 2011).
Leader - German Bilateral Agency pers. comm. 2012). The Indonesian
Government and partners may be unable to verify multiple REDD + 5. Conclusion
interventions and assess how these are meeting designated GHG re-
duction targets, and thereby undermine the delivery of market based Neo-liberal type climate change approaches adopt the rationality of
payments. Critically, Indonesia's public agencies currently lack the ca- a deregulated, networked based and privatised market system as a so-
pacity to deliver a range of supportive administrative functions, or lution to deforestation. Government's intervene only to the extent that it
provide the broader governance conditions for REDD + market based fosters market expansion, with entrepreneurial activity conducted by a
projects to operate. range of private actors that assume responsibility for governing the
According to bureaucracy political theory, public agencies can often carbon supply chain, and devolved authority for managing forest eco-
display dualistic and conflicting goals, such that their interests in ad- systems. The case of Indonesia's early Readiness phase indicates a much
ministering activities is part of their formal public mandate, but they more prominent role for government agencies in governing REDD +
often seek organisational interests and compete for influence and con- markets, suggesting that neoliberal type approaches need to account for
trol over government resources across levels (Giessen et al., 2016). In the administrative functions and authority exercised by public bu-
Indonesia, a critical issue relates to the legal uncertainty over who reaucracies. Establishing a carbon market requires a functioning ad-
governs forested lands caused by the numerous and often conflicting ministrative apparatus that can deliver a range of coordination and
laws and regulations administered by competing central agencies or regulatory functions, as well as land-use planning that engages multiple
provincial and district governments(Sahide and Giessen, 2015). Whilst interests. REDD + market activities are subject – at least on paper - to
central agencies in Jakarta have responsibility for allocating forest hierarchical administrative authority at multiple levels to assess activ-
concessions, district governments often issue permits for palm oil ities, combined with ongoing forest monitoring and surveillance func-
plantations and other developments (see Setiawan et al., 2016). Spatial tions. In Indonesia, the result is a complex and contested regime of
planning remains a problematic activity, subject to numerous over- governing that engages various carbon subjects such as private com-
lapping laws, with decisions often reflecting the agency and level of panies and NGO's, but whose actions are steered and directed by the
responsibility and their political connections (Brockhaus et al., 2012, authority exercised by different sections of the public bureaucracy.
p.33). For carbon project operators this creates a high degree of reg- Critically, Indonesia was to provide the conditions to demonstrate
ulatory confusions, as does the complex system of forest delineation, how an international market for REDD+ credits could operate on the
and the various laws for obtaining the necessary licenses and planning ground. So far it remains a speculative demonstration process only and
approvals to trade in carbon credits. In reality, authority over who there has not been substantial progress towards anything resembling a
governs REDD + project activities in Indonesia is a highly contested carbon forest economy. This highlights an inherent problem at the heart
domain (Luttrell et al., 2014). of neoliberal based conservation approaches and their practical appli-
This regulatory overlap, combined with the conflicting roles of cations in developing countries. Indonesia currently lacks the institu-
different agencies has led to some significant problems with start-up tional capacity and administrative integration required for a highly
carbon projects in Indonesia. Commercial investors require legal clarity accountable carbon commodity chain. Projects have struggled to set up
over forest classification and carbon ownership, particularly as they operations, with the efficacy of new market instruments constantly
compete with other forest concessionaries and plantation developers. undermined by competing public agencies and private interests at
They also require the state to enforce the law and ensure that REDD + multiple levels. These critical challenges, combined with inherent
projects themselves, as well as other competing or compatible land-use policy uncertainty around REDD +, may discourage communities or
are complying with existing regulations and land-use planning regimes. businesses to participate in projects, and thereby fail to recruit them as
An example of the problems faced by carbon entrepreneurs is the neoliberal stakeholders in the carbon economy. REDD + markets are
65,000 ha Rimba Raya Project in Central Kalimantan, recognised as one unlikely to function effectively in Indonesia, without further and po-
of the leaders in developing offsets for the voluntary carbon market tentially wide reaching reforms to the way government agencies ad-
(Bolick et al., 2009; Indriatmoko et al., 2014). The project faced sub- minister forests.
stantial hurdles and delays in obtaining bureaucratic approvals, but The Paris Climate Agreement reaffirmed REDD + as an important
finally managed to secure the correct licenses from the MoF and began component of the international climate regime, but with a greater effort
selling carbon credits in 2013. During the application stage the district on performance based national approaches. A global trading framework
government granted a concession to a palm company over a section of remains under development but is unlikely to be in place before 2020,
the project area, and there remain ongoing legal disputes over the re- and few countries have indicated support for REDD + type offsets to be
maining areas of forest (Indriatmoko et al., 2014). included. As the case of Indonesia suggests, markets may only provide a
In REDD + countries such as Indonesia, the state clearly does not niche opportunity for certain private interests to voluntary offset
operate as a cohesive or homogenous entity nor does it necessarily emissions as a commitment to social and environmental responsibility,
provide the institutional conditions to manage forest resources ac- rather than a large scale trading mechanism to address deforestation or
cording to the broader public interests. Multiple agencies claim and global emissions. REDD + in Indonesia now resembles a government
compete for authority over forested land and mineral resources, and run forest management program rather than it's original premise of a
assume a discretionary role for all decisions regarding future allocation, market in ecosystem services and incentives. A more viable path to
use and management (Sahide and Giessen, 2015). This was highlighted meet emission reduction targets could be provided by the Indonesian

10
H.J. Boer Forest Policy and Economics 86 (2018) 4–12

Government's focus on implementation of FMUs, spatial planning and Jessop, B., 2010. Constituting Another Foucault Effect: Foucault on States and Statecraft.
In: Bröckling, U, Krasmann, S, Lemke, T (Eds.), Governmentality: Current Issues and
other forest management approaches as part of implementing low Future Challenges. Routledge, Hoboken, pp. 56–73.
emissions pathways and NDCs. Kartodihardjo, Hariadi, Nugroho, B., R Putro, H., 2011. Forest Management Unit
Supplementary data to this article can be found online at https:// Development (FMU) – Concept, Legislation and Implementation Jakarta, Indonesia:
MoF(Ministry of Forestry). Directorate of Area Management and Preparation of
doi.org/10.1016/j.forpol.2017.10.004. Forest Area Utilisation, Deutsche Gesellschaft für Internationale Zusammenarbeit
(GIZ) GmbH, FORCLIME Forests and Climate Change Programme.
References Keskitalo, E.C.H., Juhola, S., Westerhoff, L., 2012. Climate change as governmentality:
technologies of government for adaptation in three european countries. J. Environ.
Plan. Manag. 55 (4), 435–452. http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/09640568.2011.607994.
Agung, P., Galudra, G., Van Noordwijk, M., et al., 2014. Reform or reversal: the impact of Lemke, T., 2002. Foucault, governmentality, and critique. Rethink. Marx. 14, 49–64.
REDD + readiness on forest governance in Indonesia. Clim. Pol. 14, 748–768. Lemke, T., 2007. An indigestible meal? Foucault, governmentality and state theory.
Arts, B., 2014. Assessing forest governance from a ‘Triple G’ perspective: Government, Distinktion 8, 43–64.
governance, governmentality. This article belongs to the Special Issue: Assessing Lövbrand, E., Stripple, J., 2012. Disrupting the public - private distinction: excavating the
Forest Governance. For. Policy Eco. 49 (C), 17–22. government of carbon markets post-Copenhagen. Environ. Plan. C 30, 658–674.
Angelsen, A., Brockhaus, M., Duchelle, A.E., Larson, A., Martius, C., Sunderlin, W.D., Lovell, H., 2014. Climate change, markets and standards: the case of financial accounting.
Verchot, L., Wong, G., Wunder, S., 2017. Learning from REDD+: a response to Econ. Soc. 43, 260–284.
Fletcher et al. Conserv. Biol. 31 (3), 718–720. http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/cobi. Luttrell, C., Resosudarmo, I.A.P., Muharrom, E., et al., 2014. The political context of
12933. REDD+ in Indonesia: constituencies for change. Environ. Sci. Pol. 35, 67–75.
Astuti, R., McGregor, A., 2015. Responding to the green economy: how REDD+ and the McCulloch, G., 2004. Documentary research: in education, history and the social sciences.
one map initiative are transforming forest governance in Indonesia. Third World Q. Routeldge Falmer, London.
36, 2273–2293. McDermott, C.L., 2014. REDDuced: from sustainability to legality to units of carbon—the
Bae, J.S., Kim, Y.-S., Fisher, L., Moeliono, M., DeShazo, J., 2014. Promises and perils of search for common interests in international forest governance. Environ. Sci. Pol. 35,
decentralized forest governance: the case of indonesia's forest management units in 12–19.
reducing emission from deforestation and forest degradation (REDD +). Soc. & Nat. McGregor, A., Challies, E., Howson, P., et al., 2015. Beyond carbon, more than forest?
Resour. 27 (12), 1346–1354. http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/08941920.2014.945061. REDD+ governmentality in Indonesia. Environ. Plan. A 47, 138–155.
Bolick, L., Lemons, T., Reece, J., et al., 2009. The Rimba raya biodiversity reserve REDD Miller, P., Rose, N., 2008. Governing the present: Administering economic, social and
project avoided (planned) deforestation in Central Kalimantan (Borneo) Indonesia. personal life. Polity Press, Cambridge, UK.
In: Project design document (Pdd). Infinite Earth. Pt Rimba Raya Conservation. Moeliono, M., Gallemore, C., Santoso, L., Brockhaus, M., Di Gregorio, M., 2014.
Bevir, M., 2011. Governance and governmentality after neoliberalism. Policy & Polit. 39 Information networks and power: confronting the "wicked problem" of REDD+ in
(4), 457–471. http://dx.doi.org/10.1332/030557310X550141. Indonesia. Ecol. Soc. 19 (2). http://dx.doi.org/10.5751/ES-06300-190209.
Brockhaus, M., Obidzinski, K., Dermawan, A., Laumonier, Y., Luttrell, C., 2012. An MoF (Ministry of Forestry), 2012. Peraturan Menteri Kehutanan Republik Indonesia
overview of forest and land allocation policies in Indonesia: is the current framework Nomor: P. 20/Menhut-II/2012 tentang Penyelenggaraan Karbon Hutan. Jakarta,
sufficient to meet the needs of REDD +? Forest Policy Econ. 18, 30–37. http://dx.doi. Indonesia: MoFor. Accessed 11 September 2014. http://forda-mof.org/files/P.20_
org/10.1016/j.forpol.2011.09.004. 2012_PenyelenggaraanKarbon_.pdf.
Büscher, B., Sullivan, S., Neves, K., et al., 2012. Towards a synthesized critique of neo- MoF (Ministry of Forestry), 2008. Decree Number P:68/Menhut-II/2008 Demonstration
liberal biodiversity conservation. Capital. Nat. Social. 23, 4–30. Activities Implementation of Carbon Emission Reduction Deforestation and Forest
Corbera, E., 2012. Problematizing REDD+ as an experiment in payments for ecosystem Degradation. Republic of Indonesia.
services. Curr. Opin. Environ. Sustain. 4, 612–619. MoF (Ministry of Forestry), 2009a. Decree Number: .36/Menhut-II/2009/Regarding
Dean, M., 2010. Governmentality: Power and Rule in Modern Society, 2nd edition. SAGE. Procedures for Licensing of Commercial Utilisation of Carbon Sequestration and/or
Denzin, N.K., Lincoln, Y.S., 2011. Introduction: the discipline and practice of qualitative Storage in Production and Protected Forests. Jakarta: Republic of Indonesia.
research. In: Denzin, N.K., Lincoln, Y.S. (Eds.), The Sage Handbook of Qualitative MoF (Ministry of Forestry), 2009b. Ministry of Forestry Regulation No.:p.30/Menhut-II/
Research. Sage Publications Ltd, Thousand Oaks, California, pp. 1–20. 2009 on Reduction of Emissions from Deforestation and Forest Degradation
Dixon, R., Challies, E., 2015. Making REDD+ pay: shifting rationales and tactics of Procedure.: Republic of Indonesia.
private finance and the governance of avoided deforestation in Indonesia. Asia Pac. MoF (Ministry of Forestry), 2012. Forest Investment Program: Indonesia's Forest
Viewpoint 56, 6–20. Investment Plan Republic of Indonesia.
Ebeling, J., Yasué, M., 2008. Generating carbon finance through avoided deforestation van Noordwijk, M., Agus, F., Dewi, S., Purnomo, H., 2014. Reducing emissions from land
and its potential to create climatic, conservation and human development benefits. use in Indonesia: motivation, policy instruments and expected funding streams. Mitig.
Phil. Trans. R. Soc. B: Biol. Sci. 363 (1498), 1917–1924. http://dx.doi.org/10.1098/ Adapt. Strateg. Glob. Chang. 19 (6), 677–692. http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s11027-
rstb.2007.0029. 013-9502-y.
Fletcher, R., 2010. Neoliberal environmentality: towards a poststructuralist political Palmer, C., 2011. Property rights and liability for deforestation under REDD+: im-
ecology of the conservation debate. Conserv. Soc. 8, 171–181. plications for ‘permanence’ in policy design. Ecol. Econ. 70, 571–576.
Fletcher, R., Dressler, W., Büscher, B., Anderson, Z.R., 2016. Questioning REDD+ and the Portela, R., Wendland, K.J., Pennypacker, L.L., 2008. The idea of market-based me-
future of market-based conservation. Conserv. Biol. 30 (3), 673–675. http://dx.doi. chanisms for forest conservation and climate change. In: Streck, C., O'Sullivan, R.,
org/10.1111/cobi.12680. Janson-Smith, T. (Eds.), Climate Change and Forests: Emerging Policy and Market
Fletcher, R., Breitling, J., 2012. Market mechanism or subsidy in disguise? governing Opportunities. London, Chatham House, pp. 11–32.
payment for environmental services in costa rica. Geoforum 43 (3), 402–411. http:// Resosudarmo, I.A.P., Atmadja, S., Ekaputri, A.D., et al., 2014. Does tenure security lead to
dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.geoforum.2011.11.008. redd + project effectiveness? Reflections from five emerging sites in Indonesia. World
Foucault, M., 2007. Security, Territory, Population Lectures at the Collège de France, Dev. 55, 68–83.
1977–78, London Palgrave. Rubin, H.J., Rubin, I.S., 2005. Qualitative Interviewing: The Art of Hearing Data, Second
Foucault, M., 2008. In: Senellart, M., Ewald, F., Fontana, A. (Eds.), The Birth of Edition. Sage Publications Ltd, Thousand Oaks, California.
Biopolitics: Lectures at the College De France, 1978–1979. Palgrave MacMillan, New Sahide, Giessen, 2015. The fragmented land use administration in Indonesia – analysing
York. bureaucratic responsibilities influencing tropical rainforest transformation systems.
Gane, N., 2012. The governmentalities of neoliberalism: panopticism, post- panopticism Land Use Policy 43, 96–110.
and beyond. Sociol. Rev. 60 (4), 611–634. Sahide, M.A.K., Supratman, S., Maryudi, A., et al., 2016. Decentralisation policy as re-
George, A.L., Bennett, A.N., 2005. Case Studies and Theory Development in the Social centralisation strategy: Forest management units and community forestry in
Sciences. MIT Press, Cambridge, Massachusetts. Indonesia. Int. For. Rev. 18, 78–95.
Giessen, L., Burns, S., Sahide, M.A.K., et al., 2016. From governance to government: the Saldana, J., 2013. The Coding Manual for Qualitative Researchers. Sage Publications Ltd,
strengthened role of state bureaucracies in forest and agricultural certification. Polic. Thousand Oaks, California.
Soc. 35, 71–89. Satgas REDD+, 2012. National REDD+ Strategy Jakarta: National REDD+ Taskforce,
Government of Indonesia, 2012. MRV National Strategy. National REDD + Task Force. Republic of Indonesia.
Hajek, F., Ventresca, M.J., Scriven, J., et al., 2011. Regime-building for REDD +: evidence Satgas REDD+, 2013. REDD + in Indonesia: A Catalyst for Change.
from a cluster of local initiatives in South-eastern Peru. Environ. Sci. Pol. 14, Sending, O.J., Neumann, I.B., 2006. Governance to governmentality: analyzing NGOs,
201–215. states, and power. Int. Stud. Q. 50 (3), 651–672. http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/j.1468-
IFCA (Indonesia Forest Climate Alliance) and MoF (Ministry of Forestry), 2008. Reducing 2478.2006.00418.x.
Emissions From Deforestation and Forest Degradatation in Indonesia: IFCA Setiawan, E.N., Maryudi, A., Purwanto, R.H., Lele, G., 2016. Opposing interests in the
Consolidation Report Jakarta: Ministry of Forestry. legalization of non-procedural forest conversion to oil palm in Central Kalimantan,
Indrarto, G.B., Murharjanti, P., Khatarina, J., et al., 2012. The Context of REDD+ in Indonesia. Land Use Policy 58 (Supplement C), 472–481. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/
Indonesia. Drivers, Agents and Institutions. 69 Center for International Forestry j.landusepol.2016.08.003.
Research (CIFOR), Bogor, Indonesia. Shapiro-Garza, E., 2013. Contesting the market-based nature of Mexico's national pay-
Indriatmoko, Y., Atmadja, S.S., Ekaputr, A.D., et al., 2014. Rimba Raya Biodiversity ments for ecosystem services programs: four sites of articulation and hybridization.
Reserve Project, Central Kalimantan, Indonesia. In: Sills, E.O., Atmadja, S.S., de Sassi, Geoforum 46, 5–15.
C. (Eds.), REDD + on the ground: A case book of subnational initiatives across the Sills, E.O., Atmadja, S.S., de Sassi, C., et al., 2014. REDD + on the ground: a case book of
globe. Centre For International Forestry Research (CIFOR), Bogor, Indonesia, pp. subnational initiatives across the globe. Centre for International Forestry Research
348–361. (CIFOR), Bogor, Indonesia.

11
H.J. Boer Forest Policy and Economics 86 (2018) 4–12

Stephan, B., Rothe, D., Methmann, C., 2013. Third Side of the Coin: hegemony and forest-related land use politics: the Ministry of Forestry and its competitors in the
Governmentality in Global Climate Politics. In: Stripple, J., Bulkeley, H. (Eds.), REDD+ Programme and the one map policy in Indonesia. Land Use Policy 49,
Bringing Governmentality to the Study of Global Governance. Cambridge University 131–141.
Press, New York, pp. 59–76. Winkel, G., 2012. Foucault in the forests—areview of the use of ‘Foucauldian’ concepts in
Stripple, J., 2010. Weberian climate policy: administrative rationality organised as a Forest policy analysis. Forest Policy Econ. 16 (0), 81–92.
market. In: Bäckstrand, K., Khan, J., Kronsell, A. (Eds.), Environmental Politics and World Bank, 2009. Developing a market for REDD in Indonesia. In: Report on
Deliberative Democracy: Examining the Promise of New Modes of Governance. Implementation of a Learning Workshop. World Bank.
Edward Elgar, Northhamton, USA, pp. 67–84. Wright, G., 2011. Indigenous people and customary land ownership under domestic
Tata, H.L., van Noordwijk, M., Ruysschaert, D., et al., 2014. Will funding to Reduce REDD+ frameworks: a case study of Indonesia. Law, Environ. Develop. J. 7,
Emissions from Deforestation and (forest) Degradation (REDD+) stop conversion of 119–131.
peat swamps to oil palm in orangutan habitat in Tripa in Aceh, Indonesia? Mitig. Yin, R.K., 2009. Case Study Research: Design and Methods, Fourth Edition. Sage
Adapt. Strateg. Glob. Chang. 19, 693–713. Publications Ltd, Thousand Oaks, California.
UNFCCC (United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change), 2011. Durban
Platform.
UNFCCC (United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change), 2015. Paris Further reading
Agreement. Giessen, L; Krott, M; Möllmann, T; (2014). Increasing representation of states by utili-
UN-REDD Programme Indonesia, 2012. Design of a REDD+ compliant benefit distribu- tarian as compared to environmental bureaucracies in international forest and for-
tion system for Indonesia. In: FAO (Food and Agriculture Organisation of the United est–environmental policy negotiations, Forest Policy Econ., 38, 97-104.
Nations), UNDP (United Nations Development Programme), UNEP (United Nations Minang, P.A; Van Noordwijk, M; Duguma, L.A; (2014). REDD + readiness progress across
Environment Programme). countries: time for reconsideration, Clim. Pol., 14, 685-708.
Wibowo, A., Giessen, L., 2015. Absolute and relative power gains among state agencies in

12

You might also like