You are on page 1of 52

Fundamental Analysis Conditioned on Firm Life Cycle

Mark Anderson

Soonchul Hyun

Dongning Yu

University of Calgary

November, 2017
Fundamental Analysis Conditioned on Firm Life Cycle

Abstract

Fundamental analysis is a technique that attempts to assess the value of corporate securities
by examining key value-drivers such as earnings, growth, and competitive position. It uses
information in financial statements to gain insights about a company’s future performance.
However, a signal used in fundamental analysis may have different implications for future
earnings under different circumstances. We use firm life cycle as a conditioning variable for
fundamental analysis, and investigate how the implications of fundamental signals for evaluating
firm performance vary according to life cycle stage. Using a sample of 81,613 firm-year
observations from 1989 to 2014, we find that fundamental signals based on accounts receivable,
capital expenditure, sales per employee, inventory, SG&A costs, and gross margin, are
differentially informative about firm value across firm life-cycle stages. We find that signals that
provide information about managers’ willingness to invest are particularly informative for intro-
stage firms and that signals related to operating performance and efficiency are particularly
informative for mature-stage firms. We also find that a simple trading strategy based on
fundamental signals and firm life cycle is effective in separating winners from losers in terms of
excess stock returns. Our findings provide insights about the use of accounting data in evaluating
firms.

Key words: fundamental analysis, firm life cycle, firm performance, financial statement analysis
Fundamental Analysis Conditioned on Firm Life Cycle

I. Introduction

The question of how financial statements inform investors of firm equity value has been of

extensive research interest. Many researchers have addressed this question from the perspective

of the information content of accounting fundamentals (Brown 1993; Ou and Penman 1989; Lipe

1986; Ou 1990; Lev and Thiagarajan 1993; Fairfield et al. 1996; Nissim and Penman 2001;

Abaranell and Bushee 1997, 1998). According to Bauman (1996, p. 1), “fundamental analysis

involves inferring the value of a business firm’s equity without reference to the prices at which

the firm’s securities trade in the capital markets” and requires “an assessment of a firm’s

activities and prospects through published financial reports as well as other sources of

information concerning the firm, the product markets in which it competes, and the overall

economic environment.”

The theoretical basis for fundamental analysis comes from the informational perspective of

accounting that accounting data is relevant to equity valuation because it provides information

useful in estimating future dividends and predicting future earnings (Bauman 1996). Previous

studies have analytically and empirically investigated the value relevance of accounting

information provided in the financial statements. Lev and Thiagarjan (1993) suggest that

fundamental analysis is aimed at determining the value of corporate securities by a careful

examination of key value-drivers, such as earnings, risk, growth, and competitive position. They

identify a set of financial variables (fundamental signals) claimed by analysts to be useful in

security valuation and evaluate these claims by estimating the incremental value-relevance of

these variables over earnings. In addition, Abarbanell and Bushee (1997) investigate how

detailed financial statement data (fundamentals) enter the decisions of market participants by

1
examining whether current changes in the fundamental signals are informative about subsequent

earnings changes.

Ou and Penman (1989) observed that textbooks of financial statements analysis describe

the calculation of financial statement ratios but provide scant prescription as to how these should

be used. Nissim and Penman (2001) further argued that many empirical studies have identified

accounting attributes driving value and documented robust correlations between these attributes

and market value, but this literature has not built a structure for identifying, analyzing and

summarizing financial statement information1 and has not produced a convincing model of

financial statement analysis for equity valuation. In addition, previous empirical studies have

typically employed a cross-sectional approach, using large samples of heterogeneous firms, and

have treated the accounting attributes as equivalently informative across firms and over time.

These research studies do not explicitly consider whether financial accounting attributes may

have differential value-relevance over the life span of a firm across different circumstances that

the firm may face.

It is commonly assumed that detailed financial statement data are useful for information

users when they make investment decisions. However, the informational value would be limited

if such information as earnings, risk, growth, and competitive position could not reflect diverse

aspects of companies. For example, differences in strategic activities across life-cycle stages of a

firm may result in different patterns among the firm’s financial statement components - earnings,

sales, expenses, cash flow, assets, and so on. Risk factors might also have different influences on

firm value depending on the life cycle of the firm.


1
Ou and Penman (1989) identify accounting attributes (ratios) that predict earnings changes in the data
using a statistical approach. On the other hand, Lev and Thiagarajan (1993) identify ratios that are used
by analysts, providing economic intuition to the identification of value-relevant information.
2
Anthoy and Ramesh (1992) suggest that performance measures differ across life cycle stages and find

2
Boston Consulting Group (1986) described changes in firms’ strategic positions, indicating

that a firm maximizes revenue growth early in its life to create permanent cost or demand

advantages over competitors, but in its mature stage market growth slows and investments are

less rewarding (Porter 1980). Many researchers in management, marketing, economics as well as

accounting have incorporated firm life cycle theory into their research (Spence 1979; Jovanovic

and Macdonald 1994; Anthony and Ramesh 1992; Parsons 1975; Wernerfelt 1985).

Firm life cycle theory is an extension of the product life cycle concept. As products move

through their life cycle stages (e.g., start-up, growth, mature, and decline), firms’ developmental

processes go through life cycle stages based on their portfolios of products (Muller 1972; Smith

et al. 1985). Dickinson (2011) observes the difficulty in assessing firm-level life-cycle stages

because they are a composite of many overlapping, but distinct, product life-cycle stages. She

develops a new approach to categorize firm-level life cycle based on the predicted behavior of

operating, investing, and financing cash flows across the different stages of the firm life cycle.

According to Dickinson (2011, p. 1969), “business firms are evolving entities, with the

path of evolution determined by internal factors (e.g., strategy choice, financial resources, and

managerial ability) and external factors (e.g., competitive environmental and macroeconomic

factors). Firm life cycles are made up of distinct phases that result from changes in these factors,

many of which arise from strategic activities undertaken by the firm.” Accounting information

reflects these different strategic activities, resulting in different implications for firm

performance2 and hence firm value across life-cycle stages. Thus, accounting information that is

capturing firms’ activities and accompanying profitability and risk would have different value-


2
Anthoy and Ramesh (1992) suggest that performance measures differ across life cycle stages and find
that stock market reactions to sales growth and capital expenditure are functions of life cycle stage
(unexpected positive sales growth and capital expenditure are most (least) valued by the capital market
during the firm’s growth (stagnant) stage.

3
relevance across life cycle stages. However, to our knowledge, no research on fundamental

analysis has incorporated life cycle theory in investigating how the accounting information is

valued in the market.

We argue that components of financial statements may have different economic

significance and may need to be interpreted as differentially value-relevant under different firm

circumstances (e.g., life cycle stages). We empirically examine whether and how financial

statement data (fundamentals) are differentially informative under different stages of firm life

cycle using signals from Abarbanell and Bushee (1998). We also compare the returns that would

be generated by applying a simple trading strategy based on fundamental signals within each

life-cycle category (Piotroski 2000). Using a sample of 81,613 firm-year observations from 1989

to 2014, we find that fundamental signals, based on accounts receivable, capital expenditure,

sales per employee, inventory, SG&A costs, and gross margin, are differentially informative for

firms in different life-cycle stages. We also find that a simple trading strategy based on signals

that are informative in each life-cycle stage is effective in separating winners from losers in

terms of one-year ahead excess stock returns.

Our findings indicate that the implications of signals in fundamental analysis for evaluating

firm performance vary across firm life-cycle stages, and provide insights about the usefulness of

accounting data in evaluating firms. Incorporating firm life cycle into financial statement

analysis would make it possible to consider the value-relevance of firms’ strategic activities

characterized by life-cycle stages. By providing a more comprehensive method for evaluating

firm performance, this approach may help investors and analysts to recognize risk factors that

differ across life-cycle stages and avoid mispricing firms.

4
In the next section, we review the literature on fundamental analysis and firm life cycle. In

Section III, we develop our hypotheses. In Section IV, we describe the sample data and

methodology. Section V presents the empirical results, and Section VI concludes by

summarizing our findings and discussing implications.

II. Literature review

Fundamental analysis

Fundamental analysis involves an examination of a firm’s activities and prospects based on

information in publicly available financial reports as well as other sources, and considers the

markets in which the firm competes and the overall economic environment (Bauman, 1996).

Previts et al. (1994) suggest that analysts “base their recommendations primarily on an

evaluation of company income … [and] commonly evaluate assets and liabilities on a cost, not

market-value basis” (p. 55). Findings by Lev and Thiagarajan (1993) and Abarbanell and Bushee

(1997) indicate that fundamental signals are value-relevant, and that analysts must search for

information from these signals in order to assess the value of a firm. Consistent with these

findings, Abarbanell and Bushee (1998) document that an investment strategy based on the

fundamental signals yields significant abnormal returns. In addition, Piotroski (2000)

demonstrates that a simple accounting-based fundamental analysis strategy, when applied to a

broad portfolio of high book-to-market firms, can shift the distribution of returns earned by an

investor. Investors can use information in financial statements to forecast earnings for the

reporting entity, estimate the risk of these earnings, and ultimately make an assessment of the

intrinsic value of the firm that can be compared to observed market prices (Richardon et al.

2010).

5
Analysts generally attach a specific interpretation to a fundamental signal (e.g., a

disproportionate increase in inventory conveys bad news). However, interpretation of the

financial data in predicting corporate performance must be considered in light of the nature of a

company (Poston et al. 1994). In particular, Lev and Thiagarajan (1993) point out that a signal

used in fundamental analysis may have different implications for future earnings under different

circumstances. They examine fundamental signals used by financial analysts and find that, for

example, disproportionate increases in receivables and inventory are especially bad news for

investors in highly inflationary periods. Beneish et al. (2001) illustrate the usefulness of

contextual fundamental analysis for the prediction of extreme stock returns. Abarbanell and

Bushee (1997) suggest that the direction of firm-specific earnings news may affect the

interpretation of some signals.

Finding different implications of fundamental signals under different conditions highlights

the importance of performing conditioned fundamental analysis. Investors and analysts may

underutilize the information provided by fundamental signals if they do not consider how

fundamental signals may be differentially informative under different conditions.

Firm life cycle

Business firms are evolving entities whose fundamental economic decisions change over

their life cycles, and firm life-cycle stages have important implications for understanding the

financial performance of firms. The life-cycle concept identifies five stages in a firm’s life:

introduction, growth, maturity, shake-out and decline stage (Gort and Klepper 1982). At the

introduction stage, an innovation is first produced. The firm grows as the number of producers

increases. As the firm moves toward maturity, the number of producers reaches a maximum. As

6
the firm moves through the maturity stage, profitable investment opportunities diminish,

competition arises, and the market for the firm’s products begins to saturate. Consequently, the

firm will demonstrate lower growth rates (Mueller 1972; Grabowski and Mueller 1975). The

decline stage is typically characterized by falling sales and earnings and by increases in

unutilized production capacity.

The economics literature has addressed attributes of life cycle such as production behavior

(Spence 1977, 1979, 1981; Wernerfelt 1985; Jovanovic and MacDonald 1994), investment

(Spence 1977, 1979; Jovanovic 1982; Wernerfelt 1985), market entry and exit patterns (Caves

1998), and market share (Wernerfelt 1985) (see Dickinson 2011, p. 1970). In the accounting

literature, Richardson and Gordon (1980) suggest that different performance measures should be

used for different product life cycles because the critical tasks of manufacturing change as

products move through the life cycle. Anthony and Ramesh (1992) investigate the market

reaction to accounting performance measures in each life-cycle stage of the firm. They document

a declining stock market response to unexpected sales growth and unexpected capital investment

as the firm matures. Black (1998) examines the value-relevance of changes in operating,

investing, and financing cash flows by life-cycle stage and, in particular, documents that

investing cash flows are more value-relevant when firms are in the growth stage. Hribar and

Yehuda (2015) demonstrate that free cash flows and total accruals convey different information

at various stages of the firm’s development, by showing that the correlation between free cash

flows and total accruals is weakest in the growth stage and becomes stronger as the firm matures.

Dickinson (2011) developed and validated a firm-level life cycle proxy based on the

predicted behavior of operating, investing, and financing cash flows across different life-cycle

stages. This cash flow pattern proxy has advantages in that it uses the entire financial information

7
set contained in operating, investing, and financing cash flows rather than a single metric, such

as sales growth, capital expenditures, dividend payout, or age that are widely used in the

previous studies, to determine firm life cycle. Dickinson demonstrates that the cash flow pattern

proxy outperforms other life cycle proxies used in the literature (including age), and better

explains future profitability (both in rates of return and stock returns). This proxy for firm life-

cycle stages benefits information users by helping them to better understand how economic

fundamentals related to firm life cycle affect the level and convergence properties of future

profitability.

The firm life-cycle concept provides a setting for fundamental analysis because certain

signals may convey different information at different stages of the firm’s development (Hribar

and Yehuda 2015). Therefore, we perform conditioned fundamental analysis based on firm life

cycle to examine whether fundamental signals are differentially informative across different life-

cycle stages of the firm.

III. Hypothesis development

We follow Abarbanell and Bushee (1998) and identify seven fundamental signals: signals

based on capital expenditures, accounts receivable, sales per employee, inventory, gross margin,

SG&A expenses, and audit qualifications.3 The signals are defined such that their expected

relation with stock returns is positive under the traditional interpretation of the signals. We

further classify the signals into three categories that represent three aspects of the firm’s

condition: investment, operating performance, and reporting quality.


3
We don’t use earnings quality based on LIFO because it is no longer relevant. We exclude effective tax
rate because it constrains our sample.

8
Signals: investment

Signals that we classify under the investment category reflect the firm’s willingness to

invest in capital and customers. Indications of managerial optimism may be more important and

more informative for firms in early life-cycle stages such as introduction and growth stages.

Capital expenditure (CAPX)

The capital expenditure signal is defined as the difference between the annual percentage

change in the firm’s capital expenditures and the percentage change in the corresponding two-

digit industry capital expenditures. A positive value of the signal (i.e., firm’s growth is larger

than the industry’s) implies good news based on managers’ optimism, and therefore a positive

relation with firm performance.

An increase in capital expenditure indicates investment in long-term assets (for example,

PP&E) to fund new projects, which implies that the firm has the confidence and financial ability

to invest in itself through capital expenditures. Anthony and Ramesh (1992) argue that a growing

firm is likely to have high capital expenditures, while a declining firm is likely to have low

capital expenditures. An increase in capital expenditure is especially good news for introduction

and growth firms as a result of managerial optimism and firms making early large investments to

deter entry (Jovanovic 1982; Spence 1977, 1979, 1981). However, for mature and decline firms,

an increase in firms’ capital expenditure may indicate imprudent investment in order to sustain

the investment level (Oler and Picconi 2014), and overinvestment may result in lower profits

because of excess capacity (Porter 1980; Lieberman 1987). In addition, Dickinson and Sommers

(2012) find that firms with the highest capital intensity relative to industry peers have lower

profitability, suggesting that there is a nonlinear relation between CAPX and future performance.

9
Therefore, it might be useful to condition the interpretation of the CAPX signal on firm life

cycle.

Accounts receivable (AR)

The accounts receivable signal is defined as the difference between the annual percentage

change in sales and the percentage change of accounts receivable. Under the traditional

interpretation, a positive value of the signal (i.e., sales’ growth is larger than that of accounts

receivable) indicates good news and a positive relation with firm performance. An increase in

accounts receivable suggests that the company has difficulties in selling its products (generally

triggering credit extensions), and there is an increasing likelihood of future earnings decreases

from increases in receivables’ provisions. In addition, an increase may indicate a higher

likelihood of earnings management, as unrealized revenues are recorded as sales.

In contrast, however, an increase in accounts receivable, especially for introduction and

growth firms, may suggest that managers are confident and that the company wisely

strengthened customer relationships by offering competitive, less restrictive payment terms.

Stickney and Weil (2006) argue that firm-level variables such as accounts receivables are likely

to vary over a firm’s life cycle. Accounts receivable are expected to be built up for a new, rapidly

growing firm. In this case, increases in accounts receivable may indicate that management

expands credit to increase sales and earnings (Abarbanell and Bushee 1997). Under this

alternative investment interpretation of the accounts receivable signal, the predicted sign is

negative. Based on the investment interpretations of these fundamental signals, we make the

following first hypothesis.

10
HYPOTHESIS 1. To the extent that the capital expenditures (CAPX) and account

receivable (AR) signals provide information about managerial optimism, the

signals will be more informative for firms in early life-cycle stages.

Signals: operating performance

Signals under this category reflect information about the firm’s productivity, or efficiency in

selling, production, and cost control. As firms move to the mature stage, operating efficiency

becomes more important due to the higher number of competitors.

Sales per employee (SPE)

The sales per employee signal is defined as the annual percentage change in sales-per-

employee (the ratio of annual sales to the number of employees at year-end).

A positive value of the signal (i.e., an increase in sales-per-employee relative to prior year)

implies good news about labor productivity, and therefore a positive relation with firm

performance. Financial analysts generally comment favorably on announcements of corporate

restructuring, particularly labor force reductions. In the year of a significant labor force

reduction, wage-related expenses (e.g., severance pay) may increase but expected future labor

costs decrease. Reported earnings, in such cases, do not reflect the future benefits from

restructuring, and fundamentals such as the sales per employee signal are used to provide a better

assessment of future earnings (Lev and Thiagarajan 1993). A positive value of the signal

indicates higher efficiency of the employees in generating sales, which is more important and

informative for mature firms because of the critical role of efficiency.

Inventory (INV)

11
The inventory signal is defined as the difference between the annual percentage change of

sales and the percentage change in inventory. A positive value of the signal (i.e., sales’ growth is

higher than inventory growth) indicates higher efficiency in generating sales from inventory, and

therefore good news and a positive relation with firm performance. Alternatively, sales’ growth

that is larger than inventory growth may be due to a drawdown of existing inventory, indicating a

reversal of prior inventory build ups. In this case, the inventory signal may be less informative.

Inventory increases suggest difficulty and inefficiency in generating sales, and earnings are

expected to decline as management attempts to lower inventory levels. A disproportionate

increase also suggests the existence of slow-moving or obsolete items that will be written off in

the future. In the introduction and growth stages, sales are expected to grow rapidly (Spence

1979). As firms mature, obsolescence increases (Jovanovic 1982), and the increase in inventory

indicates that obsolete items will be written off in the future and that sales are lower than

expected. Therefore, a disproportionate increase in inventory levels relative to sales provides

unfavorable signal for the firm’s future performance, especially for mature firms.

Gross margin (GM)

The gross margin signal is defined as the difference between the percentage change in gross

margin and that of sales. A positive value of the signal (i.e., sales’ growth is smaller than that of

gross margin) implies good news about product demand, and therefore a positive relation with

firm performance.

A higher gross margin is desirable as it suggests a greater potential for earning larger profits

and may indicate that the firm has been successful in differentiating its products from its peers.

Business with higher gross margin are better equipped against unanticipated increases in the cost

of production or competition. A decrease in gross margin is viewed negatively as poor sales

12
performance (declining demand) will typically lead to lower gross margins. Since efficiency is

maximized during the mature stage through increased knowledge of operations (Spence 1977,

1979, 1981; Wernerfelt 1985), a decrease in gross margin is especially bad news for mature

firms because such firms might have to lower prices due to declining growth rates (Wernerfelt

1985), increase in competition, and reduction in market share. Moreover, given the competitive

environment, an increase in gross margin is especially favorable for mature firms as expectations

for mature firms in terms of increasing gross margin are not as high as those for introduction and

growth firms.

SG&A expenses (SG&A)

The SG&A expenses signal is defined as the difference between the annual percentage

change in sales and the percentage change of SG&A expenses. A positive value of the signal

(i.e., sales’ growth is larger than that of SG&A expenses) implies good news, and therefore a

positive relation with firm performance.

A disproportionate (to sales) increase in SG&A expenses is considered as a negative signal

as the increase suggests inefficiency and inability of managers to control costs (Lev and

Thiagarajan 1993). Stickney and Weil (2006) argue that when a firm is no longer growing, it is

likely to report increased earnings associated with reductions in cost. Consequently, a reduction

in SG&A costs relative to sales may be a more favorable signal for mature firms than for

introduction and growth firms.

Based on the above arguments, we make the following hypothesis concerning operating

performance signals.

13
HYPOTHESIS 2. Signals about operating performance, including the sales per

employee (SPE), inventory (INV), gross margin (GM), and SG&A signals are more

informative for mature firms than for firms in other stages.

Signal: reporting quality

The signal under this category reflects information about the quality of the firms’ financial

statements. The quality of financial information affects market valuation and also the cost of

capital (Healy and Palepu 2001; Francis et al. 2004; Lambert et al. 2007).

Audit Qualification (AQ)

The audit qualification signal is given a value of one if the auditor’s opinion is unqualified

with no additional language, and zero for other opinions.4 The signal with a value of one implies

good news about accounting quality, and therefore a positive relation with firm performance.

A qualified, disclaimed, or adverse audit opinion obviously sends a negative massage to

investors. Dopuch, Holthausen and Leftwich (1986) documented a significant negative stock

price reaction to qualified audit opinions. In addition, unqualified audit opinion with additional

language indicates increased financial misstatement risk (Czerney et al. 2014). Therefore, the

unqualified auditor report with no additional explanatory language indicates higher reporting

quality compared with unqualified audit opinion with additional language. Moreover, the audit

report is associated with firm specific characteristics (Bartov et al. 2001), such as firm life cycle.

The market may be more sensitive to information about accounting quality for firms in


4
Other opinions may include unqualified with additional language, unaudited, qualified, no opinion, and
adverse opinion in the Compustat data.

14
introduction and decline stages. Such firms are more fragile financially so indications of

accounting quality may have a greater impact on the capital market assessment of the firm.

This suggests that it is more valuable for firms in introduction and decline stages to receive

an unqualified audit opinion without additional language. We make the following hypothesis.

HYPOTHESIS 3. The signal of audit qualification (AQ) is more informative for firms

in introduction and decline stages.

15
IV. Sample data and methodology

Sample data

We obtained the accounting data from COMPUSTAT annual files for North American firms

for the fiscal years from 1989 to 2014. We obtained stock return data to calculate excess returns

from the Centre for Research in Securities Prices (CRSP) monthly files for the fiscal years from

1989 to 2014.

We trimmed the data by eliminating firm-year observations that lied in the top and bottom

1% for each signal in our analysis (Lev and Thiagarajan 1993). We excluded observations in

which SG&A costs exceed sales (Anderson et al. 2007). We also excluded financial services

firms (SIC 6000-6999) because of differences in interpreting financial reports between these

industries and other industries (Subramanyam 1996), and because of the capital constraints that

materially alter their cash flow structure relative to other industries (Dickinson 2011). Our

sample contains 81,613 firm-year observations.

Methodology

Following Lev and Thiagarajan (1993), we relate excess stock return (R) to current earnings

change ( ∆ EPS), and other fundamentals, which are based on inventory (INV), accounts

receivable (AR), capital expenditure (CAPX), gross margin (GM), SG&A expenses (SG&A),

sales per employee (SPE), and audit qualification (AQ). Variable definitions are presented in

Table 1.

We first estimate a baseline regression for the full sample without incorporating firm life

cycle. We estimate the model in equation (1).

16
!
𝑅!" = 𝛼 + 𝛿! ∆𝐸𝑃𝑆!" + !!! 𝛾!" 𝑆𝑖𝑔𝑛𝑎𝑙𝑠!"# + 𝜀!"

(1)

where

𝑅!" = 12-month excess market-adjusted stock return (value-weighted market return as the

benchmark) of firm i, with the return accumulation starting with the fourth month after the end of
!"# !!"#
the fiscal year, and ∆𝐸𝑃𝑆!" = !"#$%!" !"#$%!"!! , which captures current earnings change.
!"!!

We then estimate equation (1) for each life-cycle stage (introduction, growth, mature, shake-

out, and decline) separately. Finally, we estimate the expanded model (2) with life-cycle

indicators. The expansions interact current earnings change and fundamental signals with

indicators of different life-cycle stages.

𝑅!" = 𝛼 + 𝐼𝑛𝑡𝑟𝑜 + 𝐺𝑟𝑜𝑤𝑡ℎ + 𝐷𝑒𝑐𝑙𝑖𝑛𝑒 + 𝑆ℎ𝑎𝑘𝑒𝑜𝑢𝑡 + !!!! 𝛾!" 𝑆𝑖𝑔𝑛𝑎𝑙𝑠!"# + 𝛿! ∆𝐸𝑃𝑆!" +


𝐼𝑛𝑡𝑟𝑜 !"!!! 𝛾!" 𝑆𝑖𝑔𝑛𝑎𝑙𝑠!"# + 𝛿! ∆𝐸𝑃𝑆!" + 𝐺𝑟𝑜𝑤𝑡ℎ
!"
!!!" 𝛾!" 𝑆𝑖𝑔𝑛𝑎𝑙𝑠!"# + 𝛿! ∆𝐸𝑃𝑆!" +
𝐷𝑒𝑐𝑙𝑖𝑛𝑒 !!!! 𝛾!! 𝑆𝑖𝑔𝑛𝑎𝑙𝑠!"# + 𝛿! ∆𝐸𝑃𝑆!" + 𝑆ℎ𝑎𝑘𝑒𝑜𝑢𝑡 !"
!"
!!!" 𝛾!" 𝑆𝑖𝑔𝑛𝑎𝑙𝑠!"# + 𝛿! ∆𝐸𝑃𝑆!" +
𝜀!"
(2)

where Intro, Growth, Decline, and Shakeout are indicators of firm life-cycle stages of

introduction, growth, decline, and shake-out, respectively. There is no indicator for mature stage

because this stage plays the base role in the expanded model.

To identify firm life cycles, we follow the life-cycle classification method developed by

Dickinson (2011). The firm life cycle proxy is based on patterns of cash flows from operating,

investing, and financing activities, and five theoretical life cycle stages (introduction, growth,

mature, shake-out, and decline) are identified. To identify the patterns of cash flow, we use the

total cash flow in each category for a three-year rolling window, which includes the previous two

years and the current year. This method provides a more stable measurement of the firm’s life-

cycle stage, since a three-year rolling window prevents unusual events from distorting a firm’s

17
cash flow patterns. Details of the classification can be found in Table 2.

We adopt a year-by-year regression approach, as in Lev and Thiagarajan (1993), Abarbanell

and Bushee (1997), and Anderson et al. (2007) to mitigate any potential biases induced by sales

changes clustering over time.

Descriptive statistics

Table 3 provides descriptive statistics. Descriptive statistics for the full sample are presented

in panel A of Table 3, and descriptive statistics for each life cycle stage are presented in panels B

to E of Table 3. Following Dickinson (2011), we omit the shake-out stage from our analysis

because there is no economic meaning associated with the shake-out stage. Consistent with

Dickinson (2011), there are many more firms in the growth and mature stages than in the

introduction and decline stages. Also, the firms in the introduction and decline stages are much

smaller on average than the firms in the growth and mature stages.

A comparison of the signals across the four stages is useful for setting the background for

our analysis. The capital expenditures signal that measures whether new CAPX is higher for the

firm than for its industry peers has a mean (median) value of 0.339 (-0.049) for introductory

firms, is slightly larger for growth firms (mean = 0.351, median = 0.100), is smaller for mature

firms (mean = 0.114, median = -0.020), and is negative for decline firms (mean = -0.046, median

= -0.326), consistent with high CAPX for early stage companies, moderate CAPX for mature

companies and low CAPX for decline stage companies. The accounts receivable signal that

measures whether sales are growing faster than receivables has a negative mean (median) value

of -0.158 (-0.080) for introduction firms and -0.129 (-0.070) for growth firms, is less negative for

mature firms (mean = -0.032, median = -0.014), and is negligible for decline firms (mean = -

18
0.009, median = 0.035). This pattern is consistent with high investment in customers for early

stage firms that are expanding their markets.

The sales per employee signal that measures whether the sales per employee are increasing

relative to prior year has a mean (median) value of 0.116 (0.069) for introduction firms, is lower

for growth firms (mean = 0.066, median = 0.045), is lower for mature firms (mean = 0.042,

median = 0.031), and is higher for decline firms (mean = 0.123, median = 0.071). This indicates

that sales are growing faster for introduction firms, and that the number of employees is

decreasing for decline firms. The inventory signal that measures whether sales are growing faster

than inventory has a mean (median) value of -0.129 (-0.074) for introduction-stage firms, is less

negative for growth firms (mean = -0.101, median = -0.061), is negligible for mature firms

(mean = -0.016, median = -0.006), and is somewhat positive for decline firms (mean = 0.044,

median = 0.058). This is consistent with high working capital requirements for early stage firms

that are developing their markets. The gross margin signal that measures whether sales are

growing faster than cost of goods sold has a mean (median) value of 0.142 (0.080) for

introduction firms and similar values for growth firms (mean = 0.124, median = 0.089). The

corresponding values for mature firms (mean = 0.039, median = 0.030) and for decline firms

(mean = 0.038, median = -0.008) are much lower, consistent with improvements in operating

efficiency during the early stages. The SG&A signal that measures whether sales are growing

faster than SG&A costs has an inverse pattern. The mean (median) values are -0.094 (-0.072) in

the introduction stage and -0.108 (-0.085) in the growth stage. They are relatively small in

magnitude (mean = -0.032, median = -0.030) in the mature stage and are positive in the decline

stage (mean = 0.070, median = 0.062). This pattern indicates that growth in SG&A costs leads

growth in sales in the early life-cycle stages.

19
The audit qualification signal that indicates whether the firm has an unqualified audit

opinion without additional language or not is relatively stable across different life-cycle stages. It

has a mean (median) of 0.718 (1) for introduction firms, 0.727 (1) for growth firms, 0.696 (1) for

mature firms, and 0.663 (1) for decline firms.5

Table 4 provides correlations among all the variables and signals used in the empirical

analysis. With the exception of capital expenditures and accounts receivable signals, all of the

signals are significantly and positively correlated with excess stock returns.

V. Empirical results

Regression results

Tables 5 provides estimation results of model (1) for the full sample and for five subsamples

of different life-cycle stages.

We observe that, for the full sample reported in column (1), the inventory, gross margin,

SG&A expenses, and audit qualification signals are all significantly and positively related to

excess stock returns. These results indicate that sales growth that is larger than growth of

inventory and SG&A expenses and is smaller than that of gross margin is favorable for firm’s

stock market performance, and that getting an unqualified audit opinion is also favorable. The

above findings are consistent with our expectations corresponding to the traditional interpretation

of these signals. The accounts receivable signal is significantly and negatively related to excess

stock return, indicating that sales growth that is lower than accounts receivable is good news for

firm performance. The negative sign supports an investment interpretation of this signal as an


5
Auditor’s opinion on a company’s financial statements includes unaudited, unqualified, qualified, no
opinion, unqualified with additional language, and adverse opinion in the Compustat data. Unqualified
opinion with no additional language accounts for about 70% of all opinions across life-cycle stages. Thus
about 30% of audit opinions are made up of the remaining five opinions.

20
indication of managers wisely extending credit to promote sales and earnings (Abarbanell and

Bushee 1997, 1998).

Columns (2) to (6) of Table 5 report results of estimating model (1) separately for five

different life-cycle stages. As noted above, the shake-out stage is not economically meaningful

under Dickinson’s (2011) approach. For the introduction stage, coefficients on all of the signals

are significant. The capital expenditure (𝛾 = 0.012, p < 0.10), inventory (𝛾 = 0.044, p < 0.05),

gross margin (𝛾 = 0.100, p < 0.01), SG&A expenses (𝛾 = 0.297, p < 0.01), and audit

qualification (𝛾 = 0.129, p < 0.01) signals are positively related to excess stock return as

expected, and the accounts receivable (𝛾 = -0.078, p < 0.01) and sales per employee (𝛾 = -0.097,

p < 0.05) signals are negatively related to excess stock return. Though we anticipate that the sales

per employee signal would provide more information for mature firms under the operating

performance interpretation, the negative sign on the sales per employee signal supports an

interpretation of the signal as an investment signal that reflects managerial optimism in the

expansion of the firm, or their unwillingness to lay off employees as they are optimistic and

anticipating future opportunities, and therefore an increase in the number of employees relative

to sales is actually considered as good news, especially for introduction firms that are seeking

growth and expansion. Therefore, we document that the sales per employee signal is informative

for introduction firms with regard to the investment perspective reflecting the firm’s willingness

to invest in labor.

For firms in the growth stage, the coefficients on the capital expenditure and sales per

employee signals are not significantly different from zero, but the coefficient on the accounts

receivable signal (𝛾 = -0.023, p < 0.05) remains significantly negative. For firms in the mature

stage, the accounts receivable signal is not significant. Finally, the inventory signal becomes

21
insignificant in the decline stage. The gross margin, SG&A expenses, and audit qualification

signals remain significant and positive across all life-cycle stages.

Table 6 provides estimation results of the expanded model (2) with life-cycle indicators.

Each signal is interacted with indicators of different life-cycle stages except for the mature stage,

because this stage plays the base role in the model. The results provide the same information as

the separate regression results in Table 5, but the coefficients indicate differences in the

informativeness of signals across the life-cycle stages. We observe that all the separate life-cycle

indicator variables (intercept terms) are significant, suggesting that life-cycle stage is an

important conditioning variable when analyzing fundamental signals.

The coefficient on the capital expenditures signal interacted with the indicator of the

introduction stage is significantly positive (𝛾 = 0.016, p < 0.10), indicating that growth in capital

expenditure of the firm that is larger than that of the industry is more informative and is more

favorable for firms in the introduction stage than in the mature stage. The coefficients on the

accounts receivable (𝛾 = -0.066, p < 0.05) and sales per employee (𝛾 = -0.145, p < 0.05) signals

interacted with the indicator for introduction stage are significantly negative, indicating that both

signals are more informative for firms in the introduction stage relative to the mature stage, if

these signals are interpreted as investment signals reflecting managerial optimism. In the

development of our hypotheses, we classified the sales to employee signal as an efficiency

measure, consistent with the traditional theory with respect to this signal. For introduction stage

firms, the results suggest that this signal may also be interpreted as an investment signal for early

stage firms. The results confirm that indications of managerial optimism are more important

from a valuation perspective for firms in early life-cycle stages than for firms in the mature

22
stage. This is consistent with Hypothesis 1 that the signals that convey information about

investment are more informative for firms in early stages.

The coefficients on the gross margin signal interacted with the indicators of introduction (𝛾

= -0.237, p < 0.01), growth (𝛾 = -0.110, p < 0.01), and decline (𝛾 = -0.198, p < 0.01) stages are

significantly negative, and the coefficient on the SG&A expenses signal interacted with the

indicator of growth stage (𝛾 = -0.060, p < 0.05) is also significantly negative. These results

indicate that increases in gross margin relative to sales and decreases in SG&A expenses relative

to sales are more informative for firms in the mature stage than for firms in other stages. Signals

under the operating performance category reflect information about the firm’s productivity, or

efficiency in selling, production, and cost control. The results confirm that as firms move to the

mature stage, changes in operating performance become more important and more informative

about firm performance. This is consistent with Hypothesis 2 that signals about operating

performance are more informative for mature firms than for firms in other stages, and it is

especially true for the gross margin signal.

For the audit qualification signal, which reflects information about the quality of the firms’

financial statements, the coefficients on this signal interacted with indicators of introduction (𝛾 =

0.092, p < 0.01) and decline (𝛾 = 0.078, p < 0.10) stages are significantly positive. These results

confirm that the market is more sensitive to information about accounting quality for firms in

introduction and decline stages and that it is more valuable for such firms to receive an

unqualified audit opinion.6 This is consistent with Hypothesis 3.


6
As noted above, the signal for audit qualification is coded as zero if the audit opinion is unqualified with
additional language, qualified, adverse, no opinion or unaudited. Unqualified with additional language
may include indication of going concern issues but the Compustat data does not identify this separately. If
such opinions are more prevalent for introduction and decline companies, this may partially explain the
stronger coefficient for these firms.

23
Taken together, the above results indicate that the fundamental signals are differentially

informative across different stages of firm life cycle, and that it is important to incorporate firm

life cycle into the analysis of fundamental information provided in the financial statement.

Robustness

Industry effects

To control for potential industry effects on stock return, we include industry dummies in

the estimation model. The results of the estimation are qualitatively similar with the results of the

main estimation. Table 7 presents the estimation results.

Size-adjusted excess returns

Firms in the introduction and decline stages are much smaller on average than firms in

the other stages. We use size-adjusted cumulative excess stock returns and present the results in

Table 8. We find similar results to those presented in Table 5 with two exceptions. The accounts

receivable signal is marginally significant and negative for the full sample but is not significant

for the introduction and growth stage firms as it was in Table 5. The sales per employee signal is

significantly positive for firms in the mature stage, consistent with the operating efficiency

interpretation of this variable for firms in the mature stage as predicted by hypothesis 2. The

negative sign on the sales per employee signal for introduction stage firms is retained, consistent

with the investment interpretation of this signal for introduction-stage firms.

Additional analysis: a simple trading strategy based on fundamental signals

In this part, we employ a simple trading strategy based on fundamental signals (Piotroski,

2000) and firm life cycle, and compare the returns that would be generated using all seven

24
signals with the returns that would be generated using those signals that were found to be

informative for each life-cycle stage. Based on the results reported above, we infer that there are

two different ways that changes in the signals have implications for firm performance. For the

first set of signals – CAPX, sales per employee (for mature firms), inventory, gross margin,

SG&A, and audit qualification signals, an increase in a signal provides positive information

about future stock returns. For the second set of signals – accounts receivable and sales per

employee (for introduction firms) signals, a decrease in a signal provides positive information

about future stock returns. Similar to Piotroski (2000), individual signal realizations are

independently assigned a score of zero or one. If a signal in the first set is positive, then the

indicator variable for this signal will be set equal to one, zero otherwise. If a signal in the second

set is positive, then the indicator variable for this signal will be set equal to zero, one otherwise.

An aggregated signal measure, F_SCORE, is defined as the sum of the binary signals.

We classify firms with the lowest aggregated scores as low F_SCORE firms and expect

these firms to have the worst subsequent stock performance. Alternatively, firms with the highest

scores are classified as high F_SCORE firms. These firms are expected to have the best

subsequent return performance. We compare the size-adjusted excess returns of high F_SCORE

firms with those of low F_SCORE firms and test whether the former outperforms the latter.

Table 9 presents the one-year size-adjusted excess stock returns to this simple fundamental

investment strategy. For the full sample in panel A, F_SCORE is the sum of all seven signals.

Firms with the lowest F_SCOREs (0 or 1) are classified as low F_SCORE firms and firms with

the highest F_SCOREs (6 or 7) are high F_SCORE firms. As documented in panel A, there is a

nearly monotonic positive relation between F_SCORE and excess returns. High F_SCORE firms

significantly outperform low F_SCORE firms in terms of one-year ahead size-adjusted excess

25
stock returns (0.070 versus -0.136). The mean return difference of 0.206 is significant at the 1%

level, suggesting that investors would earn a mean excess return of 20.6 percent if they took a

long position in high F_SCORE firms and a short position in low F_SCORE firms for the sample

as a whole. This result is similar to Piotroski’s (2000, p. 18) finding, where he documents a 23

percent difference between the high and low score firms in terms of one-year market-adjusted

returns.

Panel B presents results for firms in the introduction stage. In addition to the F_SCORE that

is comprised of all seven signals, a second F_SCORE that is comprised of the five signals (the

sales per employee, inventory, gross margin, SG&A, and audit qualification signals) that were

found to be significant for introduction firms in Table 7 is also calculated, where the low

F_SCORE firms have a F_SCORE of 0 and high F_SCORE firms have a F_SCORE of 5.7 For

all seven signals, the high F_SCORE introduction firms earn a mean excess return of 0.121

versus -0.189 for the low F_SCORE introduction firms. This difference of 0.310 is significant at

the 1% level. For the five significant signals, high F_SCORE introduction firms earn a mean

excess return of 0.086, and low F_SCORE firms earn a mean excess return of -0.343. The

difference of 0.429 is also significant at the 1% level, indicating a mean excess return of 42.9

percent if investors go long in high F_SCORE introduction firms and go short with the low

F_SCORE introduction firms. This excess return is appreciably higher than the 20.6 percent

excess return for the full sample and the 31.0 percent excess return for the introduction firms

based on seven signals.


7
This comparison is illustrative in nature and is not intended to be a rigorous comparison. To have
reasonably comparable numbers of observations for the low and high F_SCORE firms when we moved
from seven signals to five signals, it was necessary to limit the high F_SCORE firms to those with a score
of 5 and the low F_SCORE firms to those with a score of 0.

26
Results for firms in the growth stage are reported in panel C. For all seven signals, the

growth firms with a high F_SCORE have a mean excess return of 0.051, and those with a low

F_SCORE have a mean excess return of -0.159. The mean excess return difference is 0.210 and

is significant at the 1% level. For the four significant signals (Table 7), high F_SCORE (score =

4) growth firms earn a mean return of 0.148, and low F_SCORE (score = 0) firms earn a mean

return of -0.224. The difference of 0.372 is also significant at the 1% level, and is appreciably

higher than the mean difference of 0.210 for the growth firms based on seven signals. This is

consistent with the finding that five signals are informative for firms in the growth stage and

indicates that using all seven signals may add noise.

We find similar results for the mature firms in panel D. For all seven signals, the mature

firms with a high F_SCORE have a mean excess return of 0.081, and those with a low

F_SCORE have a mean excess return of -0.156. The mean excess return difference is 0.237 and

is significant at the 1% level. For the five signals that were found to be informative in the growth

stage, high F_SCORE (5) mature firms earn a mean excess return of 0.141, and low F_SCORE

(0) firms earn a mean excess return of -0.191. The difference of 0.332 is also significant at the

1% level, and is higher than the excess return difference of 0.237 obtained for the trading

strategy that uses seven signals. This indicates that using the five informative signals for mature

stage firms may be preferable to using all seven signals.

Finally, panel E presents results for firms in the decline stage. For all seven signals, the high

F_SCORE firms have a mean return of 0.364 versus -0.149 for low F_SCORE firms. The mean

return difference of 0.364 is significant at the 1% level. For the three significant signals, high

F_SCORE (3) decline firms earn a mean return of 0.178, and low F_SCORE (0) firms earn a

mean return of -0.152. The difference of 0.330 is significant at the 1% level. In this case, the

27
excess returns generated using seven signals are similar to those generated using the restricted set

of signals.

Overall, a simple trading strategy based on the significant fundamental signals in each life-

cycle stage is effective in separating winners from losers in terms of one-year ahead excess stock

returns. Fundamentally strong firms significantly outperform weak firms, and this pattern is

consistent across all of the life cycle stages. Interestingly, the strategy is much more effective in

picking losers versus winners for introduction firms (mean size-adjusted excess return of -0.343

for low F_SCORE firms versus mean return of 0.086 for high F_SCORE firms). It is also

somewhat more effective in picking losers than winners for growth and mature firms (mean

returns of -0.224 and -0.191 for low F_SCORE firms versus mean returns of 0.148 and 0.141 for

high F_SCORE firms). But it is slightly more effective in picking winners than losers for

decline firms (mean return of -0.152 for low F_SCORE firms versus mean return of 0.178 for

high F_SCORE firms).

VI. Conclusion

In this study, we use firm life cycle as a conditioning variable for fundamental analysis, and

investigate how the implications of fundamental signals in evaluating firm performance vary

across different life-cycle stages. We find that the magnitudes of the estimated effects of

fundamental signals on excess stock returns are significantly different across firm life cycles,

consistent with the premise that the signals are differentially informative for firms in different

life-cycle stages. Our analysis of excess returns generated using a simple trading strategy also

indicates that fundamental signals are differently informative across life-cycle states.

28
By using cash flow information to classify firms into life-cycle stages following Dickinson

(2011), our study extends the use of financial statements’ information in fundamental analysis to

include more information obtained from the statement of cash flow. But, rather than using cash

flow information to define specific signals, this approach uses cash flow information to condition

the interpretation of other signals. Our study also has implications for investors and analysts. If

they partition the signals according to different firm life cycle stages, investors and analysts may

be able to better utilize the information provided by fundamental signals and develop a more

thorough understanding of the firm’s financial position.

A limitation of our study is that we only use signals that have been identified in the previous

literature. Future research may identify other signals, both qualitative and quantitative, that

enhance the conditioned analysis. Further, fundamental analysis conducted by industry might be

useful. For instance, firms in some industries may have limited capital expenditures or accounts

receivable due to the nature of their business. Finally, our trading strategy that simply identifies

whether a signal is positive or negative does not necessarily use all of the information available

from the signals. A more complex algorithm could use the magnitudes of the signals.

29
Reference

Abarbanell, J. S., and Bushee, B. J. 1997. Fundamental analysis, future earnings, and stock prices.
Journal of Accounting Research, 35(1), 1–24.

Abarbanell, J. S., and Bushee, B. J. 1998. Abnormal returns to a fundamental analysis strategy.
The Accounting Review, 73(1), 19–45.

Anderson, M., Banker, R., Huang, R., and Janakiraman, S. 2007. Cost behavior and fundamental
analysis of SG&A costs. Journal of Accounting, Auditing & Finance, 22(1), 1–28.

Anthony, J. H., and Ramesh, K. 1992. Association between accounting performance measures
and stock prices. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 15(2–3), 203–227.

Banker, R. D., and Chen, L. 2006. Predicting earnings using a model based on cost variability
and cost stickiness. The Accounting Review, 81(2), 285–307.

Bartov, E., Gul, F. A., and Tsui, J. S. L. 2001. Discretionary-accruals models and audit
qualifications. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 30, 421–452.

Bauman, M. P. 1996. A review of fundamental analysis research in accounting. Journal of


Accounting Literature, 15, 1–33.

Beneish, M. D., Lee, C. M. C., and Tarpley, R. L. 2001. Contextual fundamental analysis
through the prediction of extreme returns. Review of Accounting Studies, 6, 165–189.

Black, E. L. 1998. Life-cycle impacts on the incremental value-relevance of earnings and cash
flow measures. Journal of Financial Statement Analysis, 4(1), 40–56.

Boston Consulting Group. 1968. Perspectives on experience (BCG, Boston, MA).

Brown, L. D. 1993. Earnings forecasting research: Its implications for capital markets research.
International Journal of Forecasting, 9, 295-320.

Caves, R. E. 1998. Industrial organization and new findings on the turnover and mobility of
firms. Journal of Economic Literature, 36(4), 1947–1982.

Czerney, K., Schmidt, J. J., and Thompson, A. M. 2014. Does auditor explanatory language in
unqualified audit reports indicate increased financial misstatement risk?. The Accounting
Review, 89(6), 2115-2149.

Dickinson, V. 2011. Cash flow patterns as a proxy for firm life cycle. The Accounting Review,
86(6), 1969–1994.

30
Dickinson, V. and Sommers, G. A. 2012. Which competitive efforts lead to future abnormal
economic rents? using accounting ratios to assess competitive advantage. Journal of
Business Finance & Accounting, 39(3) & (4), 360–398.

Dopuch, N., Holthausen, R. W., and Leftwich, R. W. 1986. Abnormal stock returns associated
with media disclosures of “subject to” qualified audit opinions. Journal of Accounting and
Economics, 8(2), 93–117.

Fairfield, P. M., R. J. Sweeney, and T. L. Yohn. 1996. Accounting Classification and the
predictive content of earnings. The Accounting Review, 71, 337-355.

Fama, E. F., and MacBeth, J. D. 1973. Risk, return, and equilibrium: Empirical tests. Journal of
Political Economy, 81(3), 607–636.

Francis, J., LaFond, R., Olsson, P. M., and Schipper, K. 2004. Costs of Equity and Attributes.
The Accounting Review, 79(4), 967–1010.

Gort, M., and Klepper, S. 1982. Time paths in the diffusion of product innovations. The
Economic Journal, 92(367), 630–653.

Grabowski, H. G., and Mueller, D. C. 1975. Life-cycle effects on corporate returns on retentions.
The Review of Economics and Statistics, 57(4), 400–409.

Healy, P. M., and Palepu, K. G. 2001. Information asymmetry, corporate disclosure, and the
capital markets: A review of the empirical disclosure literature. Journal of Accounting and
Economics, 31(1–3), 405–440.

Hribar, P., and Yehuda, N. 2015. The mispricing of cash flows and accruals at different life-
cycle stages. Contemporary Accounting Research, 32(3), 1053–1072.

Jovanovic, B. 1982. Selection and the evolution of industry. Econometrica, 50(3), 649–670.

Jovanovic, B., and MacDonald, G. M. 1994. The life cycle of a competitive industry. Journal of
Political Economy, 102(2), 322–347.

Lambert, R., Leuz, C., and Verrecchia, R. E. 2007. Accounting information, disclosure, and the
cost of capital. Journal of Accounting Research, 45(2), 385–420.

Lev, B., and Thiagarajan, S. R. 1993. Fundamental information analysis. Journal of Accounting
Research, 31(2), 190–215.

Lieberman, M. 1987. Strategies for capacity expansion. Sloan Management Review, 28(4), 19–
27.

Lipe, R. C. 1986. The information contained in the components of earnings. Journal of


Accounting Research, 24, 37-64.

31
Mueller, D. C. 1972. A life cycle theory of the firm. The Journal of Industrial Economics, 20(3),
199–219.

Nissim, D., and S. H. Penman. 2001. Ratio analysis and equity valuation: From research to
practice. Review of Accounting Studies, 6, 109-154.

Oler, D. K., and Picconi, M. P. 2014. Implications of insufficient and excess cash for future
performance. Contemporary Accounting Research, 31(1), 253–283.

Ou, J. A. 1990. The information content of nonearnings accounting numbers as earnings


predictors. Journal of Accounting Research, 28, 144-163.

Ou, J. A, and S. H. Penman. 1989. Financial statement analysis and the prediction of stock
returns. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 11, 295-329.

Parsons, L. 1975. The product life cycle and time-varying advertising elasticities. Journal of
Marketing Research, 12(4), 476-480.

Piotroski, J. D. 2000. Value investing: The use of historical financial statement information to
separate winners from losers. Journal of Accounting Research, 38(Supplement: Studies on
Accounting Information and the Economics of the Firm), 1–41.

Porter, M. E. 1980. Competitive strategy: Techniques for analyzing industries and competitors.
Free Press, New York, NY.

Poston, K. M., Harmon, W. K., and Gramlich, J. D. 1994. A test of financial ratios as predictors
of turnaround versus failure among financially distressed firms. Journal of Applied Business
Research, 10(1), 41–56.

Previts, G. J., Bricker, R. J., Robinson, T. R., and Young, S. J. 1994. A content analysis of sell-
side financial analyst company reports. Accounting Horizons, 8(2), 55–70.

Richardson, P. R., and Gordon, J. R. M. 1980. Measuring total manufacturing performance.


Sloan Management Review, 21(2), 47–58.

Richardson, S., Tuna, I., and Wysocki, P. 2010. Accounting anomalies and fundamental analysis:
A review of recent research advances. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 50(2–3), 410–
454.

Smith, K. G., T. R. Mitchell, and C. E. Summer. 1985. Top level management priorities
indifferent stages of the organizational life-cycle. Academy of Management Journal, 28,
799–820.

Spence, A. M. 1977. Entry, capacity, investment and oligopolistic pricing. The Bell Journal of
Economics, 8(2), 534–544.

32
Spence, A. M. 1981. The learning curve and competition. The Bell Journal of Economics, 12(1),
49–70.

Spence, A. M. 1979. Investment strategy and growth in a new market. The Bell Journal of
Economics, 10(1), 1–19.

Stickney, C. P., and Weil, R. L. 2006. Financial accounting: An introduction to concepts, uses,
and methods (12 edition). South-Western College Pub.

Subramanyam, K. R. 1996. The pricing of discretionary accruals. Journal of Accounting and


Economics, 22, 249–281.

Wernerfelt, B. 1985. The dynamics of prices and market shares over the product life cycle.
Management Science, 31(8), 928–939.

33
TABLE 1
Definition and measurement of variablesa

Variables (Signals) Measure


Excess Stock Returns (𝑅!,! ) 12-months cumulated excess stock return
EPS!,! − EPS!,!!!
Current Earnings Change ∆𝐸𝑃𝑆!,!
Stock Price!,!!!
Inventory (INV) ∆Sales "sale" − ∆Inventory "invt"
Accounts Receivable (AR) ∆Sales − ∆Accounts Receivable "rect"
Capital Expenditure (CAPX) ∆Firm CAPX "capx" − ∆Industry CAPXb
Gross Margin (GM) ∆Gross Margin "sale" − "cogs" − ∆Sales
SG&A Expenses (SG&A) ∆Sales − ∆SG&A Expenses "xsga"
!"#$%!,! !"#$%!,!!! !"#$%!,!!!
Sales per employee (SPE) −
#!"#$%&''((""#$")!,! #!"#$%&''(!,!!! #!"#$%&''(!,!!!

Audit Qualification (AQ) 1 for Unqualified, 0 for Qualified or other "auop"


a
Adapted from Abarbanell and Bushee (1998).
b
Industry capital expenditure is measured by aggregating this item for all firms at the two-digit SIC code level.
∆ refers to percentage annual change in the variable from the average of prior two years; e.g. ∆Sales = Sales! −
E Sales! /E(Sales! ), where E Sales! = (Sales!!! + Sales!!! )/2. The signals are defined such that their expected
relation with stock returns is positive.

34
TABLE 2
Classification of firm life cyclea

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8
Introduction Growth Mature Shake- Shake- Shake- Decline Decline
Out Out Out
Predicted Sign
Cash flows
from operating − + + − + + − −
activities

Cash flows
from investing − − − − + + + +
activities

Cash flows
from financing + + − − + − + −
activities
a
Classification methodology is developed by Dickinson (2011, p. 1974) based on cash flow patterns from
operating, investing, and financing activities.

35
TABLE 3
Descriptive statistics

Panel A: Full sample (81,613)


Variables N Mean P10 P25 P50 P75 P90 S.D.
Sales 81,610 2,955.565 22.842 70.048 279.145 1,217.279 4,887.763 14,591.140
Inventory 80,946 289.217 0.000 2.415 19.482 114.682 504.000 1,323.541
Accounts Receivable 81,356 466.859 2.553 8.959 35.780 158.278 612.414 4,617.996
Capital Expenditures 80,903 209.284 0.457 2.086 11.303 61.100 285.725 1,267.161
Gross Margin 81,610 986.251 7.606 24.478 97.401 409.168 1,615.617 4,287.569
SG&A Expenses 81,610 520.068 5.982 16.579 57.914 223.395 847.098 2,246.958
# of Employees 79,853 10.780 0.115 0.349 1.403 6.000 22.100 44.142
Total Assets 81,610 3,417.955 20.292 64.672 277.181 1,285.559 5,266.445 17,717.650
Excess Stock Returns 77,877 0.050 -0.535 -0.243 0.013 0.291 0.645 0.551
∆EPS 80,394 0.015 -0.118 -0.029 0.004 0.034 0.138 0.223

Signals
Capital Expenditures 80,337 0.221 -0.638 -0.341 0.004 0.461 1.231 0.991
Accounts Receivable 80,587 -0.079 -0.465 -0.195 -0.033 0.104 0.277 0.384
Sales per Employee 78,614 0.063 -0.157 -0.046 0.039 0.135 0.290 0.224
Inventory 69,442 -0.055 -0.444 -0.184 -0.022 0.124 0.319 0.396
Gross Margin 81,490 0.082 -0.165 -0.040 0.049 0.162 0.361 0.322
SG&A Expenses 80,804 -0.062 -0.339 -0.159 -0.046 0.050 0.191 0.254
Audit Qualification 81,530 0.707 0.000 0.000 1.000 1.000 1.000 0.455

36
TABLE 3
Descriptive statistics (continued)

Panel B: Introduction (8,957)


Variables N Mean P10 P25 P50 P75 P90 S.D.
Sales 8,957 377.774 8.606 20.388 57.637 175.025 555.096 2,335.629
Inventory 8,886 80.749 0.000 1.001 6.241 26.148 96.402 501.130
Accounts Receivable 8,916 54.960 1.065 3.032 9.658 29.487 90.463 327.733
Capital Expenditures 8,863 14.201 0.131 0.424 1.588 5.915 19.278 102.821
Gross Margin 8,957 83.388 2.532 6.346 18.418 53.574 146.008 410.130
SG&A Expenses 8,957 68.371 3.382 7.255 18.828 49.498 126.921 289.806
# of Employees 8,639 1.359 0.056 0.116 0.300 0.867 2.700 5.155
Total Assets 8,956 341.313 7.433 18.169 52.872 168.669 500.069 2,059.840
Excess Stock Returns 8,479 -0.017 -0.860 -0.478 -0.083 0.339 0.900 0.775
∆EPS 8,736 0.030 -0.227 -0.067 0.004 0.079 0.310 0.314

Signals
Capital Expenditures 8,784 0.339 -0.796 -0.525 -0.049 0.718 1.917 1.338
Accounts Receivable 8,800 -0.158 -0.759 -0.347 -0.080 0.141 0.367 0.519
Sales per Employee 8,482 0.116 -0.211 -0.072 0.069 0.239 0.487 0.312
Inventory 7,623 -0.129 -0.753 -0.356 -0.074 0.170 0.451 0.541
Gross Margin 8,919 0.142 -0.290 -0.086 0.080 0.301 0.670 0.502
SG&A Expenses 8,850 -0.094 -0.555 -0.286 -0.072 0.112 0.327 0.370
Audit Qualification 8,948 0.718 0.000 0.000 1.000 1.000 1.000 0.450

37
TABLE 3
Descriptive statistics (continued)

Panel C: Growth (31,580)


Variables N Mean P10 P25 P50 P75 P90 S.D.
Sales 31,580 2,031.329 31.494 85.401 282.177 983.098 3,281.666 10,720.870
Inventory 31,237 213.568 0.000 1.679 17.224 94.300 349.779 1,078.879
Accounts Receivable 31,499 394.908 3.343 11.036 38.793 140.914 445.000 5,331.446
Capital Expenditures 31,256 196.741 1.014 3.777 15.650 67.855 281.400 1,296.610
Gross Margin 31,580 626.554 11.346 31.936 103.449 337.055 1,052.650 2,899.621
SG&A Expenses 31,580 333.155 6.802 18.420 57.404 179.637 557.786 1,485.533
# of Employees 30,831 7.900 0.144 0.418 1.431 5.156 15.500 29.101
Total Assets 31,580 2,655.961 31.329 89.588 317.241 1,187.866 4,196.885 16,068.020
Excess Stock Returns 30,407 0.032 -0.579 -0.280 0.006 0.302 0.650 0.545
∆EPS 31,019 0.000 -0.110 -0.030 0.001 0.025 0.092 0.180

Signals
Capital Expenditures 31,077 0.351 -0.582 -0.276 0.100 0.631 1.499 1.066
Accounts Receivable 31,230 -0.129 -0.571 -0.265 -0.070 0.085 0.263 0.416
Sales per Employee 30,244 0.066 -0.173 -0.051 0.045 0.150 0.309 0.229
Inventory 25,856 -0.101 -0.561 -0.253 -0.061 0.108 0.323 0.439
Gross Margin 31,540 0.124 -0.144 -0.013 0.089 0.223 0.432 0.335
SG&A Expenses 31,279 -0.108 -0.424 -0.221 -0.085 0.025 0.164 0.271
Audit Qualification 31,548 0.727 0.000 0.000 1.000 1.000 1.000 0.446

38
TABLE 3
Descriptive statistics (continued)

Panel D: Mature (33,345)


Variables N Mean P10 P25 P50 P75 P90 S.D.
Sales 33,345 4,859.647 38.076 131.725 567.824 2,401.728 9,294.300 19,700.340
Inventory 33,128 442.042 0.000 5.748 39.016 228.985 915.130 1,695.614
Accounts Receivable 33,253 654.206 3.761 14.206 63.583 289.656 1,163.000 3,371.966
Capital Expenditures 33,122 309.119 0.749 3.654 20.093 105.800 490.315 1,504.739
Gross Margin 33,345 1,683.121 12.897 43.244 198.422 838.786 3,362.000 5,844.422
SG&A Expenses 33,345 868.270 8.196 25.192 106.013 453.112 1,736.636 3,070.457
# of Employees 32,858 17.152 0.187 0.672 2.800 11.200 39.199 61.173
Total Assets 33,343 5,248.910 29.626 105.372 490.676 2,289.633 9,917.400 20,458.930
Excess Stock Returns 31,717 0.075 -0.383 -0.166 0.035 0.265 0.559 0.444
∆EPS 33,000 0.013 -0.082 -0.021 0.004 0.027 0.099 0.189

Signals
Capital Expenditures 32,949 0.114 -0.568 -0.304 -0.020 0.318 0.851 0.771
Accounts Receivable 32,939 -0.032 -0.291 -0.126 -0.014 0.094 0.232 0.288
Sales per Employee 32,490 0.042 -0.123 -0.036 0.031 0.101 0.202 0.170
Inventory 29,485 -0.016 -0.282 -0.120 -0.006 0.110 0.256 0.292
Gross Margin 33,341 0.039 -0.131 -0.038 0.030 0.099 0.203 0.207
SG&A Expenses 33,062 -0.032 -0.205 -0.103 -0.030 0.040 0.141 0.175
Audit Qualification 33,313 0.696 0.000 0.000 1.000 1.000 1.000 0.460

39
TABLE 3
Descriptive statistics (continued)

Panel E: Decline (2,883)


Variables N Mean P10 P25 P50 P75 P90 S.D.
Sales 2,880 467.906 7.737 18.415 48.757 151.586 453.711 3,741.205
Inventory 2,874 96.386 0.000 0.680 4.826 19.914 75.662 741.650
Accounts Receivable 2,859 68.215 1.022 2.738 8.034 24.308 67.821 584.179
Capital Expenditures 2,851 10.833 0.065 0.244 0.896 3.256 11.685 82.315
Gross Margin 2,880 110.045 2.302 6.177 16.538 50.188 147.540 584.524
SG&A Expenses 2,880 94.669 3.505 7.810 19.375 52.843 132.989 479.694
# of Employees 2,798 1.592 0.050 0.102 0.253 0.765 2.201 8.377
Total Assets 2,883 487.903 7.036 17.378 47.185 161.343 516.161 2,911.871
Excess Stock Returns 2,664 0.061 -0.742 -0.376 -0.025 0.387 0.951 0.784
∆EPS 2,850 0.098 -0.265 -0.069 0.029 0.203 0.586 0.402

Signals
Capital Expenditures 2,800 -0.046 -0.887 -0.664 -0.326 0.214 1.003 1.027
Accounts Receivable 2,828 -0.009 -0.472 -0.175 0.035 0.233 0.442 0.436
Sales per Employee 2,744 0.123 -0.202 -0.066 0.071 0.243 0.502 0.320
Inventory 2,410 0.044 -0.411 -0.156 0.058 0.283 0.541 0.445
Gross Margin 2,861 0.038 -0.347 -0.153 -0.008 0.160 0.473 0.456
SG&A Expenses 2,836 0.070 -0.270 -0.096 0.062 0.230 0.443 0.303
Audit Qualification 2,878 0.663 0.000 0.000 1.000 1.000 1.000 0.473

40
TABLE 4
Pearson correlation matrix
Excess
Variables Stock
(Signals) Return CAPX AR SPE INV GM SG&A AQ ∆EPS
Excess Stock
Return 1

CAPX -0.003 1
(0.469)
AR 0.005 -0.151 1
(0.190) (0.000)
SPE 0.040 0.026 0.122 1
(0.000) (0.000) (0.000)
INV 0.086 -0.130 0.209 0.211 1
(0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000)
GM 0.081 0.181 -0.163 0.110 -0.074 1
(0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000)
SG&A 0.156 -0.121 0.174 0.239 0.248 -0.218 1
(0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000)
AQ 0.034 0.050 -0.043 -0.017 -0.029 0.053 -0.027 1
(0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000)
∆EPS 0.214 -0.030 0.048 0.090 0.100 0.125 0.234 0.005 1
(0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.164)
Numbers in parentheses are p-values.

41
TABLE 5
Regression results by life cycle
(1) Full
Variables (Signals) (2) Intro (3) Growth (4) Mature (5) Decline (6) Shake-Out
Sample
0.391*** 0.412*** 0.483*** 0.422*** 0.195*** 0.219***
∆EPS
(24.55) (9.81) (11.56) (11.77) (3.23) (2.89)
0.003 0.012* 0.005 -0.004 -0.008 -0.023
CAPX
(0.57) (1.87) (0.73) (-0.57) (-0.45) (-1.51)
-0.027*** -0.078*** -0.023** -0.013 0.001 -0.112***
Accounts Receivable
(-3.14) (-2.79) (-2.37) (-1.03) (0.03) (-2.69)
-0.029 -0.097** -0.021 0.048 -0.101 0.010
Sales per Employee
(-1.23) (-2.03) (-0.68) (1.38) (-1.29) (0.22)
0.055*** 0.044** 0.050*** 0.073*** 0.003 0.095**
Inventory
(6.16) (2.50) (4.22) (3.77) (0.04) (2.54)
0.200*** 0.100*** 0.227*** 0.336*** 0.139*** 0.281***
Gross Margin
(11.56) (4.21) (9.00) (9.38) (2.77) (4.85)
0.285*** 0.297*** 0.274*** 0.334*** 0.370*** 0.302***
SG&A
(14.20) (7.43) (11.55) (10.29) (3.58) (4.63)
0.067*** 0.129*** 0.064*** 0.037*** 0.115*** 0.045
Audit Qualification
(5.40) (5.13) (3.92) (4.22) (2.88) (1.37)
-0.005 -0.116** -0.008 0.032 -0.104 0.046
Intercept
(-0.18) (-2.39) (-0.28) (1.31) (-1.60) (1.15)

N 61,500 6,550 22,940 26,365 2,049 3,596


Avg. R2 0.090 0.130 0.104 0.120 0.188 0.172
Results are from year-by-year regressions computed based on Fama-MacBeth (1973) two-step procedure. The
coefficients and t-values are the average coefficients across years.
Numbers in parentheses are t-values.
*, **, *** indicate significance at the 10 percent, 5 percent, and 1 percent levels (two-tailed), respectively.
Dependent variable: Excess stock returns.

42
TABLE 6
Regression results with life cycle interactions
Variables Variables
Coefficients t-values Coefficients t-values
(Signals) (Signals)
Intercept 0.032 1.31 Decline (D) -0.136** -2.23
∆EPS 0.422*** 11.77 ∆EPS*D -0.0227*** -2.83
CAPX -0.004 -0.57 CAPX*D -0.004 -0.21
Accounts Receivable -0.013 -1.03 Accounts Receivable*D 0.014 0.22
Sales per Employee 0.048 1.38 Sales per Employee*D -0.149 -1.56
Inventory 0.073*** 3.77 Inventory*D -0.070 -0.97
Gross Margin 0.336*** 9.38 Gross Margin*D -0.198*** -3.05
SG&A 0.334*** 10.29 SG&A*D 0.036 0.30
Audit Qualification 0.037*** 4.22 Audit Qualification*D 0.078* 1.92

Introduction (I) -0.148*** -3.92 Shake-Out (S) 0.014 0.51


∆EPS*I -0.010 -0.19 ∆EPS*S -0.204** -2.01
CAPX*I 0.016* 1.90 CAPX*S -0.019 -1.27
Accounts Receivable*I -0.066** -2.09 Accounts Receivable*S -0.099** -2.26
Sales per Employee*I -0.145** -2.48 Sales per Employee*S -0.038 -0.64
Inventory*I -0.029 -1.26 Inventory*S 0.023 0.62
Gross Margin*I -0.237*** -6.03 Gross Margin*S -0.055 -0.94
SG&A*I -0.037 -0.71 SG&A*S -0.032 -0.55
Audit Qualification*I 0.092*** 3.35 Audit Qualification*S 0.008 0.27

Growth (G) -0.040*** -2.90 N 61,500


∆EPS*G 0.061 1.32 Avg. R2 0.144
CAPX*G 0.008 1.03
Accounts Receivable*G -0.011 -0.64
Sales per Employee*G -0.069 -1.57
Inventory*G 0.061 -1.06
Gross Margin*G -0.110*** -3.71
SG&A*G -0.060** -1.99
Audit Qualification*G 0.027* 1.76
Results are from year-by-year regressions computed based on Fama-MacBeth (1973) two-step procedure. The
coefficients and t-values are the average coefficients across years.
*, **, *** indicate significance at the 10 percent, 5 percent, and 1 percent levels (two-tailed), respectively.
Dependent variable: Excess stock returns.
The mature stage is the reference group, meaning that the coefficients on the interaction terms represent the differences
in the average coefficients between the mature stage and each of the other life cycle stages.

43
TABLE 7
Regression results with industry fixed effect
(1) Full
Variables (Signals) (2) Intro (3) Growth (4) Mature (5) Decline (6) Shake-Out
Sample
0.373*** 0.392*** 0.463*** 0.405*** 0.235*** 0.445***
∆EPS
(25.08) (7.19) (10.92) (11.88) (3.05) (2.50)
0.003 0.015* 0.007 -0.005 -0.008 0.097
CAPX
(0.64) (1.81) (0.89) (-0.67) (-0.37) (0.80)
-0.025*** -0.084*** -0.024** -0.012 0.025 0.210
Accounts Receivable
(-2.89) (-3.06) (-2.25) (-1.01) (0.29) (0.73)
-0.028 -0.109** -0.018 0.055* -0.056 0.311
Sales per Employee
(-1.26) (-1.91) (-0.58) (1.77) (-0.51) (1.46)
0.048*** 0.055** 0.045*** 0.061*** -0.041 0.193
Inventory
(6.21) (2.30) (4.45) (3.29) (-0.59) (1.46)
0.193*** 0.086*** 0.215*** 0.322*** 0.017 0.444***
Gross Margin
(11.76) (3.22) (8.52) (9.48) (0.19) (2.84)
0.285*** 0.291*** 0.287*** 0.334*** 0.308*** 0.283***
SG&A
(17.30) (5.22) (12.07) (10.34) (2.53) (2.74)
0.059*** 0.108*** 0.050*** 0.029*** 0.109** 0.009
Audit Qualification
(5.47) (3.37) (4.25) (3.22) (2.09) (0.23)
-0.031 -0.027 -0.072 0.035 -0.216 -0.005
Intercept
(-1.10) (-0.27) (-1.21) (0.62) (-1.00) (-0.05)

N 61,500 6,550 22,940 26,365 2,049 3,596


Avg. Adjusted R2 0.131 0.103 0.146 0.166 0.090 0.149
Results are from year-by-year regressions computed based on Fama-MacBeth (1973) two-step procedure. The estimation model
includes industry fixed effect and considers robust adjustment of standard error by clustering industry. The coefficients and t-
values are the average across years.
Numbers in parentheses are t-values.
*, **, *** indicate significance at the 10 percent, 5 percent, and 1 percent levels (two-tailed), respectively.
Dependent variable: Excess stock returns.

44
Table 8
Regression results with size-adjusted excess stock returns
(1) Full
Variables (Signals) (2) Intro (3) Growth (4) Mature (5) Decline (6) Shake-Out
Sample
0.490*** 0.553*** 0.539*** 0.520*** 0.306*** 0.344***
∆EPS
(23.38) (9.39) (11.27) (12.47) (3.40) (4.50)
-0.002 -0.006 -0.000 -0.000 -0.040 -0.032**
CAPX
(-0.52) (-0.56) (-0.03) (-0.07) (-1.06) (-2.12)
-0.013* -0.025 -0.015 0.003 -0.154 -0.052
Accounts Receivable
(-1.77) (-1.05) (-1.39) (0.18) (-1.62) (-1.25)
0.001 -0.134** 0.006 0.080** -0.099 -0.007
Sales per Employee
(0.07) (-2.51) (0.18) (2.38) (-1.03) (-0.11)
0.062*** 0.074*** 0.056*** 0.084*** 0.118 0.108*
Inventory
(7.05) (3.97) (3.80) (4.89) (1.33) (1.94)
0.173*** 0.086*** 0.187*** 0.310*** 0.129* 0.187***
Gross Margin
(8.82) (3.31) (5.92) (7.22) (1.76) (3.37)
0.253*** 0.256*** 0.249*** 0.288*** 0.268* 0.221**
SG&A
(12.54) (4.70) (10.33) (8.82) (2.53) (2.73)
0.068*** 0.126*** 0.070*** 0.042*** 0.126** 0.060**
Audit Qualification
(6.74) (5.06) (4.71) (5.84) (2.19) (2.14)
-0.062*** -0.093** -0.073*** -0.048*** -0.074 -0.013
Intercept
(-5.12) (-2.74) (-4.75) (-3.78) (-1.53) (-0.41)

N 51,693 4,793 19,916 22,718 1,480 2,786


Avg. R2 0.093 0.1547 0.1021 0.1205 0.2418 0.1962
Results are from year-by-year regressions computed based on Fama-MacBeth (1973) two-step procedure.
The coefficients and t-values are the average coefficients across years.
Numbers in parentheses are t-values.
*, **, *** indicate significance at the 10 percent, 5 percent, and 1 percent levels (two-tailed), respectively.
Dependent variable: Size-adjusted excess stock returns.

45
TABLE 9
Returns to a fundamental analysis strategy

Panel A: Full Sample


Mean Median N
-0.022 -0.043 64,051

All Seven Signals


a
F_SCORE
0 -0.263 -0.257 186
1 -0.122 -0.138 1,618
2 -0.078 -0.087 6,790
3 -0.037 -0.058 14,225
4 -0.014 -0.035 16,486
5 0.013 -0.011 9,446
6 0.068 0.026 2,237
7 0.095 0.020 156
Low Score -0.136 -0.150 1,804
High Score 0.070 0.026

High-Lowb 0.206
t-statisticsc 15.012
(p-value) (0.000)
a
Each year, the individual signal realizations are independently ranked between zero and one. F_SCORE equals the
sum of the firm’s ranked realizations using all seven signals.
b
The High (Low) F_SCORE firm equals those with a F_SCORE of 6 and 7 (0 and 1).
c
t-statistics are based on two-tailed tests of the equality of means.

46
TABLE 9
Returns to a fundamental analysis strategy (continued)

Panel B: Introduction
Mean Median N Mean Median N
-0.040 -0.096 5,791

Five Significant Signals


All Seven Signals for Growth Firms
F_SCOREa
0 -0.424 -0.473 18 -0.343 -0.424 67
1 -0.164 -0.206 169 -0.199 -0.260 557
2 -0.157 -0.211 571 -0.082 -0.144 1,651
3 -0.049 -0.115 1,150 -0.020 -0.057 1,741
4 -0.048 -0.109 1,532 0.150 0.086 620
5 0.035 -0.006 926 0.086 0.023 64
6 0.121 0.015 203
7 0.112 0.197 15
Low Score -0.189 -0.212 187 -0.343 -0.424 67
High Score 0.121 0.018 218 0.086 0.023 64

High-Lowb 0.310 0.429


t-statisticsc 5.413 4.417
(p-value) (0.000) (0.000)
a
Each year, the individual signal realizations are independently ranked between zero and one. F_SCORE equals the
sum of the firm’s ranked realizations using all seven signals or only the five significant signals for introduction firms
(i.e., the sales per employee, inventory, gross margin, SG&A, and audit qualification signals).
b
The High (Low) F_SCORE firm equals those with a F_SCORE of 7 and 6 (0 and 1) when using all seven signals,
and equals those with a F_SCORE of 5 (0) when using the five significant signals.
c
t-statistics are based on two-tailed tests of the equality of means.

47
TABLE 9
Returns to a fundamental analysis strategy (continued)

Panel C: Growth
Mean Median N Mean Median N
-0.036 -0.050 25,944

Four Significant Signals


All Seven Signals for Growth Firms
F_SCOREa
0 -0.335 -0.349 65 -0.224 -0.234 540
1 -0.137 -0.169 508 -0.134 -0.128 4,217
2 -0.103 -0.112 2,311 -0.061 -0.065 9,400
3 -0.056 -0.071 5,359 0.032 0.007 5,591
4 -0.029 -0.043 6,576 0.148 0.099 1,212
5 -0.005 -0.018 3,983
6 0.048 0.024 915
7 0.109 0.104 53
Low Score -0.159 -0.177 573 -0.224 -0.234 540
High Score 0.051 0.027 968 0.148 0.099 1,212

High-Lowb 0.210 0.372


t-statisticsc 8.630 14.617
(p-value) (0.000) (0.000)
a
Each year, the individual signal realizations are independently ranked between zero and one. F_SCORE equals the
sum of the firm’s ranked realizations using all seven signals or only the four significant signals for growth firms
(i.e., the inventory, gross margin, SG&A, and audit qualification signals).
b
The High (Low) F_SCORE firm equals those with a F_SCORE of 7 and 6 (0 and 1) when using all seven signals,
and equals those with a F_SCORE of 4 (0) when using the four significant signals.
c
t-statistics are based on two-tailed tests of the equality of means.

48
TABLE 9
Returns to a fundamental analysis strategy (continued)

Panel D: Mature
Mean Median N Mean Median N
-0.014 -0.035 27,061

Five Significant Signals


All Seven Signals for Mature Firms
F_SCOREa
0 -0.276 -0.236 89 -0.191 -0.185 393
1 -0.141 -0.149 752 -0.120 -0.127 2,395
2 -0.087 -0.101 2,468 -0.068 -0.076 6,117
3 -0.049 -0.063 5,335 -0.006 -0.026 7,888
4 -0.011 -0.029 6,855 0.059 0.021 5,212
5 0.033 0.004 5,031 0.141 0.095 1,206
6 0.076 0.036 1,831
7 0.113 0.078 301
Low Score -0.156 -0.155 841 -0.191 -0.185 393
High Score 0.081 0.042 2,132 0.141 0.095 1,206

High-Lowb 0.237 0.332


t-statisticsc 15.158 14.451
(p-value) (0.000) (0.000)
a
Each year, the individual signal realizations are independently ranked between zero and one. F_SCORE equals the
sum of the firm’s ranked realizations using all seven signals or only the five significant signals for mature firms (i.e.,
the sales per employee, inventory, gross margin, SG&A, and audit qualification signals).
b
The High (Low) F_SCORE firm equals those with a F_SCORE of 7 and 6 (0 and 1) when using all seven signals,
and equals those with a F_SCORE of 5 (0) when using the five significant signals.
c
t-statistics are based on two-tailed tests of the equality of means.

49
TABLE 9
Returns to a fundamental analysis strategy (continued)

Panel E: Decline
Mean Median N Mean Median N
0.016 -0.035 1,765

Three Significant Signals


All Seven Signals For Decline Firms
F_SCOREa
0 -0.418 -0.465 6 -0.152 -0.160 106
1 -0.124 -0.141 65 -0.075 -0.127 494
2 -0.042 -0.091 234 0.026 -0.010 790
3 -0.025 -0.108 390 0.178 0.080 352
4 0.021 -0.032 389
5 0.068 0.005 235
6 0.230 0.139 65
7 0.055 0.046 6
Low Score -0.149 -0.151 71 -0.152 -0.160 106
High Score 0.215 0.123 71 0.178 0.080 352

High-Lowb 0.364 0.330


t-statisticsc 4.607 5.466
(p-value) (0.000) (0.000)
a
Each year, the individual signal realizations are independently ranked between zero and one. F_SCORE equals the
sum of the firm’s ranked realizations using all seven signals or only the three significant signals for mature firms
(i.e., the gross margin, SG&A, and SG&A signals).
b
The High (Low) F_SCORE firm equals those with a F_SCORE of 7 and 6 (0 and 1) when using all seven signals,
and equals those with a F_SCORE of 3 (0) when using the three significant signals.
c
t-statistics are based on two-tailed tests of the equality of means.

50

You might also like