You are on page 1of 18

See discussions, stats, and author profiles for this publication at: https://www.researchgate.

net/publication/227348790

Agribusiness Economics and Management

Article  in  American Journal of Agricultural Economics · March 2010


DOI: 10.1093/ajae/aaq009 · Source: RePEc

CITATIONS READS

39 11,580

4 authors:

Robert P. King Michael Boehlje


University of Minnesota Twin Cities Purdue University
127 PUBLICATIONS   1,882 CITATIONS    206 PUBLICATIONS   1,632 CITATIONS   

SEE PROFILE SEE PROFILE

Michael Lee Cook Steven T. Sonka


University of Missouri University of Illinois, Urbana-Champaign
77 PUBLICATIONS   2,841 CITATIONS    138 PUBLICATIONS   1,578 CITATIONS   

SEE PROFILE SEE PROFILE

Some of the authors of this publication are also working on these related projects:

Cooperative Governance Research View project

Systemic Approaches to Organizational Costs in Cooperatives View project

All content following this page was uploaded by Michael Boehlje on 01 June 2014.

The user has requested enhancement of the downloaded file.


AGRIBUSINESS ECONOMICS AND MANAGEMENT
ROBERT P. KING, MICHAEL BOEHLJE, MICHAEL L. COOK, AND STEVEN T. SONKA

Agribusiness scholarship emphasizes an integrated view of the food system that extends from research
and input supply through production, processing, and distribution to retail outlets and the consumer.
This article traces development of agribusiness scholarship over the past century by describing nine
significant areas of contribution by our profession:(1) economics of cooperative marketing and manage-
ment, (2) design and development of credit market institutions, (3) organizational design, (4) market
structure and performance analysis, (5) supply chain management and design, (6) optimization of
operational efficiency, (7) development of data and analysis for financial management, (8) strategic
management, and (9) agribusiness education.

Downloaded from ajae.oxfordjournals.org at University of Missouri-Columbia on May 10, 2010


Key words: agribusiness, cooperative, credit market, business organization, market structure, supply
chain, operations, strategy, education.

JEL codes: L10, M10, M20, Q13, Q14.

In January 1956 John H. Davis, director reviews in ten journals, ranging from the Jour-
of the program in agriculture and business nal of Farm Economics and the American Eco-
at the Harvard Business School, published nomic Review to Agricultural History and the
“From Agriculture to Agribusiness” in the Journal of Marketing.
Harvard Business Review (Davis 1956). The The key insight articulated by Davis and
following year Davis and Ray A. Goldberg Goldberg was that the food system needs
published A Concept of Agribusiness. These to be viewed as an integrated system. Man-
two publications introduced and defined the agement strategies and public policy initia-
term “agribusiness” as tives designed to address problems in the
food system would be doomed to failure if
the sum total of all operations they focused on only one portion or segment
involved in the manufacture and dis- of that integrated system. Their work stim-
tribution of farm supplies; produc- ulated new interest in the linkages between
tion operations on the farm; and segments of the food system, in coordination
the storage, processing, and distribu- across segments, in systemwide performance,
tion of farm commodities and items and in strategy formulation in a context of
made from them. Thus, agribusiness interdependence.As Cook and Chaddad (2000,
essentially encompasses today the pp. 209–210) note:
functions which the term agriculture
denoted 150 years ago. [A]gribusiness research evolved
(Davis and Goldberg 1957, p. 2) along two parallel levels of anal-
ysis: the study of coordination
By the end of 1959, the term had appeared between vertical and horizontal
in at least forty published articles and book participants within the food chain,
known as agribusiness economics,
and the study of decision-making
Robert King is a professor of Applied Economics, University of
within the alternative food chain
Minnesota; Michael Boehlje is the Distinguished Professor of Agri- governance structures, known as
cultural Economics, Purdue University; Michael L. Cook is the agribusiness management.
Robert D. Partridge Chair in Agricultural Economics, Univer-
sity of Missouri; and Steven T. Sonka is a professor in Agricul-
tural and Consumer Economics and Interim Vice Chancellor of In 1956 our association was approach-
Public Engagement, University of Illinois. Authorship is equally
shared.Preparation of this manuscript was coordinated by Robert ing its fiftieth anniversary. Though the term
King. “agribusiness” had not been used prior to that

Amer. J. Agr. Econ. 92(2): 554–570; doi: 10.1093/ajae/aaq009


Received December 2009; accepted January 2010

© The Author (2010). Published by Oxford University Press on behalf of the Agricultural and Applied Economics
Association. All rights reserved. For permissions, please e-mail: journals.permissions@oxfordjournals.org
King et al. Agribusiness Economics and Management 555

time, agricultural economists had been making of the North Central Regional Project 117
significant contributions on issues related to (NC-117), “Organization and Control of
agribusiness for many years. As early as 1913, the U.S. Food Production and Distribution
Charles J. Brand (1913, pp. 85–86) noted that System.”
the farmer needed “suitable and convenient The 1980s also was a time for questioning
arrangements for securing credit” and “assis- the place of agribusiness scholarship within
tance in the establishment of a marketing sys- the agricultural economics profession. The
tem which will return him the true value of first issue of a new journal, Agribusiness,
the particular qualities of the various crops appeared in 1985. Sonka and Hudson (1989)
that he produces, minus reasonable charges subsequently provided a conceptual assess-
for handling, transportation and the legiti- ment of the need for agribusiness scholarship
mate profits of middlemen.” These concerns from both academic and industry perspectives.
led to significant work on farm credit and The interplay emanating from the cultural,
cooperative marketing in the 1920s, as well biological, and political aspects of food and the

Downloaded from ajae.oxfordjournals.org at University of Missouri-Columbia on May 10, 2010


as articles on vertical integration, the organi- differing competitive market structures along
zation and operation of marketing firms, and the agricultural supply chain were noted as
the role of business economics in our teach- particularly distinctive features of the sector.
ing programs. New concerns emerged dur- This article articulated the need for use of a
ing the 1930s, including the structure of the broader range of behavioral sciences within
food distribution system and marketing mar- agribusiness scholarship, while recognizing
gins. Other new issues related to agribusiness the continued value of economic analysis.
emerged during the 1940s and early 1950s. In 1990 the International Agribusiness Man-
These included the rapid growth and concen- agement Association (IAMA) was formed
tration of food processing and retailing busi- under the leadership of Ray Goldberg with
nesses, analysis of costs and efficiency in food the objective of extending the range of disci-
processing plants, and the dynamics of food plines contributing to agribusiness research
retailing. and to foster more interaction between
Building on this previous work and stimu- the academic and industry practitioner
lated by changing economic circumstances and communities.
important new conceptual and methodological This article traces the development of
developments in economics, the publications agribusiness scholarship over the past 100 years
by Davis and Goldberg helped initiate a rapid by describing nine significant areas of contribu-
expansion and redirection of agribusiness tion by members of our profession—five asso-
scholarship during the association’s second half ciated with agribusiness economics and four
century. In the late 1950s and early 1960s, linked to agribusiness management.Work in all
annual meetings included sessions on cooper- nine of these areas began before the publica-
atives, farm supply markets, industrial organi- tions by Davis and Goldberg and has continued
zation, vertical integration, market power of in subsequent years. Our review of key con-
food processing and farm supply firms,antitrust tributions cannot possibly be comprehensive,
decisions, and bargaining. In the mid-1960s but we believe it does characterize the evolu-
the National Commission on Food Market- tion of work in this important area. In doing
ing was established “to study and appraise so, it also establishes a platform for looking
the changes taking place in the ‘marketing ahead to future challenges and opportunities
structure’ of the food industry and where in agribusiness.
they might lead; efficiency; services to con-
sumers; market power; regulatory activities;
services such as market news; and the effects of
imports” (Brandow 1966, p. 1319). Key papers Agribusiness Economics
on cooperative theory and agricultural finance
also appeared during the 1960s. Research on Agribusiness economics is concerned with
the evolving sector structure continued in the understanding how institutions, organizations,
1970s along with discussions about how well and markets affect vertical and horizontal coor-
teaching programs were serving the needs of dination within the food system. This section
the rapidly growing nonfarm segments of the describes five significant contributions that
food system. Work on food system structure members of our profession have made to the
and performance continued into the 1980s, design and analysis of institutions, organiza-
leading to landmark publications by members tions, and markets.
556 April 2010 Amer. J. Agr. Econ.

Contribution #1: Agricultural economists have school defined a cooperative as a collection


played important roles in introducing of profit-maximizing economic enterprises
economic reasoning and pioneering theoretical engaged in economic activity involving the use
advances in the study of agricultural of a common set of productive assets and inter-
cooperative marketing and management acting in Cournot-like fashion in response to
individual sets of marginal cost and benefit
In the first major paper on cooperatives in the relationships—in other words, a cooperative is
newly published Journal of Farm Economics, an extension of the farm. The second school
Asher Hobson (1921) struck a theme that agri- was initiated by the models of Helmberger
cultural economists would continually restate and Hoos (1962). Their work identified the
for the next 50 years—the importance of under- agricultural cooperative as an economic enter-
standing basic economic principles in farmer prise consisting of a production function, an
decision making when initiating joint verti- efficiency-maximizing criterion, and a rule that
cal integration. Emphasizing scale economies, distributes the economic surplus to the suppli-

Downloaded from ajae.oxfordjournals.org at University of Missouri-Columbia on May 10, 2010


asymmetric information, and other market fail- ers of one of the input resources. In their model
ure elements as rational economic reasons for the cooperative is a firm.
forming cooperatives, agricultural economists In his summary of the seminal study
often confronted the advocacy frenzy of politi- Cooperative Theory: New Approaches (Royer
cians and farm leaders rushing to organize 1987), Staatz (1989) credits Emelianoff (1942),
producers into agricultural cooperatives in the Robotka (1947), and Phillips (1953) as the
post–World War I depression (Nourse 1922; original formal modelers viewing cooperatives
Erdman 1924). They also published warnings as a form of vertical integration. They argue
of the dangers of moving too quickly without that the principle of “service at cost” implied
understanding market structure forces or the that only cooperative members incurred profits
debilitating implications of inadequate capital or losses. Consequently each member deter-
and human resources. mined her optimal level of output by equating
During these early years, agricultural the sum of the marginal costs in all plants
economists advanced understanding of mar- (farm and cooperative) with the marginal rev-
ket coordination through detailed descriptions enue in the plant from which the product was
of market functions and the costs of partic- marketed. The heroic Cournot–Nash assump-
ipating privately or collectively in specific tion implied in the model, applied only to
supply chains. Their emphasis on analyzing marketing cooperatives, is the major criticism
the performance and welfare role of mar- of this “multi-plant firm modeling” approach.
keting cooperatives relative to multipurpose The cooperative-as-a-firm approach draws on
cooperatives continues today. Enke’s (1945) work on consumer cooperatives.
In addition to the competitive yardstick Enke’s theory posits simply that the welfare of
function and coordination role, agricultural cooperative members and society is optimized
marketing economists concentrated primarily if a cooperative maximizes the sum of the
on (a) the role of cooperatives in control- cooperative’s producer surplus and the mem-
ling agricultural supply (Erdman 1927), (b) bers’ consumer surplus. This approach needs a
the importance of cooperatives in establishing hierarchical decision maker or coordinator—
quality standards (Nourse 1922), and (c) micro- similar to the role assumed by the CEO or
analysis of organizational design (Jesness general manager of an investor-owned firm.
1925). Three insightful diagnostic annual meet- The major criticism of this approach is that
ing proceedings articles by Erdman (1950), it does not lead to a stable equilibrium. In
Knapp (1950), and Koller (1950) indicate a advancing this work, Helmberger and Hoos
major turning point in the form of contribu- (1962) convert Enke’s logic to explain mar-
tion made by agricultural economists regarding keting cooperatives’ decision making. Based
the study of this complex governance struc- on the assumptions of a known net revenue
ture. These articles would be the last of the function, price taking, and zero surplus objec-
descriptive stage of cooperative analysis. For tive function,the Helmberger–Hoos marketing
the next twenty years, agricultural economists concept of the cooperative as a firm suffers
introduced a stream of more rigorous neoclas- from the same equilibrium shortcomings as the
sical frameworks to inform the understand- Robotka/Phillips approach.
ing of the agricultural cooperative. Bodies of By the 1980s, economic theories and deci-
theoretical work evolved around two struc- sion models designed to address more complex
tural design camps. First, the Robotka/Phillips intra-firm relationships began to emerge. New
King et al. Agribusiness Economics and Management 557

approaches such as agency theory, behavioral with the 1916 Federal Farm Loan Act and
theories of the firm, incomplete contract the- eventually culminating in the Farm Credit Act
ory, transaction cost economics, and property of 1933 formed the base for the current Farm
rights approaches allowed for more detailed Credit System (FCS), which today is a major
investigation between inter- and intra-firm supplier of credit to farmers, farmer coopera-
coordination decision making. tives, and rural homeowners.
The following twenty years saw advances uti- William I. Myers’ role in the development of
lizing new institutional economic approaches the FCS in its formative years is legendary; he
by Fulton (2001), Cook (1995), Hendrikse and served as governor of the Farm Credit Admin-
Veerman (2001), and Hendrikse and Bijman istration from 1933 to 1938. At the annual
(2002), among others. Additionally, advances meetings of the American Farm Economic
in neoclassical frameworks increased under- Association, he emphasized the cooperative
standing of the role of cooperatives not only nature of the system and that “generally speak-
in remaining as a competitive yardstick but ing the Farm Credit System is not lending

Downloaded from ajae.oxfordjournals.org at University of Missouri-Columbia on May 10, 2010


also in laying the groundwork for advances in government money…. [I]ts object is to set up
the cooperative organizational design. Sexton machinery through which farmers may obtain
(1990), building on the Helmberger–Hoos find- funds for financing their farm businesses from
ings, used neoclassical theory to model spatial the investment markets at the lowest possible
competition in agricultural marketing indus- cost” (Myers 1934, p. 36).
tries. The model derives price-output equilibria Following the recovery of the agricultural
for investor-oriented firms and cooperative sector from the Depression, the issue of the
processors in oligopsonistic spatial markets role of public credit institutions relative to
focusing on the pro-competitive effects of private sector lenders became the focal point
cooperatives by formally establishing the con- of the debate over the appropriate insti-
ditions and magnitude of the cooperative yard- tutional structure of the agricultural credit
stick effect in oligopsonistic markets. This work markets. Benedict (1945) argued that com-
has interesting and controversial public pol- mercial banks should be the principal source
icy implications. Its findings support favorable of short-term credit; the FCS lenders should
public policy toward open-membership coop- be self-supporting and charge competitive
eratives, but similar pro-competitive effects but not-lower-than-market interest rates, since
cannot be claimed for restricted membership “[a]rtificially low interest rates on farm mort-
cooperatives. gages tend to be translated to high land val-
ues without long-term advantage either to the
Contribution #2: Agricultural economists have farmer or the public” (p. 103). Moreover, loans
played a key role in the development and for emergencies must be evaluated by com-
design of institutions that are the foundation paring the costs with the “social values result-
for agricultural credit markets ing from the loans” (ibid). The result of this
debate was the formation of the Farmers Home
Surveys and analyses initiated early in the Administration (FmHA) in 1946 to provide
twentieth century on agricultural credit condi- supervised credit to farmers unable to obtain
tions and markets showed that “farmers were commercial credit. The farm lending activi-
not being adequately supplied with capital for ties of the FmHA expanded modestly during
certain types of farm operations…. [T]he com- the 1950s and 60s (Herr 1969). Authorities
mercial banking machinery of the country was were added in the 1970s to finance selected
ill-adapted to making certain loans for the peri- rural infrastructure such as housing, water sup-
ods required by the farmer…, and the cost of ply, and waste disposal, as well as rural busi-
farm loans was disproportionately high in com- ness and industrial development (Brake and
parison with the loans acquired for operating Melchar 1970, p. 455). More recently these pro-
purposes in other industries”(Lee 1925,p. 425). grams have been administered by the Farm
Congressional discussions and debate con- Services Agency (FSA), with increased empha-
cerning the appropriate response to the prob- sis on guaranteed rather than direct loans and
lems identified by Lee included formation loans to beginning and socially disadvantaged
of cooperative or joint-stock banks, with an farmers (Ahrendsen et al. 2005).
exclusive focus on agricultural loans, and the Farm sector debt increased significantly dur-
issuance of long-term bonds to finance amor- ing the 1950s, 1960s, and 1970s. Declining
tized loans for the purchase of farmland and incomes in the early 1980s, combined with
other capital assets. Legislation originating the increased debt load, resulted in significant
558 April 2010 Amer. J. Agr. Econ.

debt service problems by the mid-80s. Jolly Contribution #3: Agribusiness scholars
et al. (1985, p. 1114) indicated that based on utilizing interdisciplinary approaches and new
data from the USDA Farm Costs and Returns economic frameworks have become
Survey, “about 50% of farm operators and instrumental in diagnosing and understanding
assets did not have a positive cash flow and the incentives/disincentives embedded in
that 64% of debt was not fully serviced in agribusiness organizational architecture and
1984.” Much of the early debate about the complementary networks
appropriate response focused on how lend-
ing institutions and their farmer-borrowers A graph of our profession’s interest in orga-
might resolve debt-servicing problems and pre- nizational design of agribusiness enterprises
vent foreclosures or bankruptcy filings. But as might look like a U-shaped curve. In the early
evidence began to mount that the problems days of the profession, agricultural economists
were more serious than originally thought, the offered many thoughtful observations about
debate turned to the appropriate public sec- the recommended or optimal form that agri-

Downloaded from ajae.oxfordjournals.org at University of Missouri-Columbia on May 10, 2010


tor response. Harl (1990) strongly advocated cultural trade organizations, processing firms,
a public sector debt restructuring/principal and agricultural cooperatives might take. Their
write-down/federal guarantee program (p. 44). insights into aligning residual claim and resid-
Passage of the Agricultural Credit Act of 1987 ual control rights and efficient allocation of
included (a) debt restructuring requirements incentive-driven decision authority were uti-
for FCS (as well as FmHA) for debt in default, lized as benchmarking tools for organizers of
(b) an insurance program along the lines of said entities (Jesness 1925). But as formal mod-
the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation eling advanced utilizing neoclassical economic
and modifications to joint and several liability theories which tentatively treated the firm as a
obligations of all FCS banks for system obli- “black box,” additional work on organizational
gations, (c) and federal assistance to the FCS design did not appear until more intra-firm
in the form of government loans to recapi- incentive models came into practice beginning
talize FCS institutions experiencing financial in the late 1980s.
problems. The system obtained $1.261 bil- By the mid-1990s numerous conceptual
lion of U.S. Treasury guaranteed bond funds pieces, including those of Moore and Noel
subsequent to this legislation and repaid the (1995), Fulton (1995), Hind (1994), Chaddad
federal government (principal plus) interest and Cook (2004) and Hendrikse and Veerman
in 2005. (2001), began to appear in the American
Agricultural economists also contributed to Journal of Agricultural Economics and related
the development of more efficient and effec- journals. Empirical pieces soon followed.
tive capital and financial markets and insti- For example, Holland and King (2004) and
tutions to serve the agricultural sector in Detre, Wilson, and Gray (2007) explored
developing countries. Adams, Graham, and why producer-owned hybrids which are more
von Pischke (1984) focused on the develop- investor driven than previous patron-driven
ment of viable credit institutions for farmers forms of collective action were increasing as
to obtain financing for fertilizer, seed, and an organizational form favored by agricultural
chemical purchases. In essence, their work indi- producers. Examination of the Hendrikse
cated that government/state-owned financial and Bijman (2002) analysis expands on these
institutions frequently encountered long-term conceptual advances as producers address
viability problems, in large part because of complex governance structure choices. Their
the political pressure to forgive loan obliga- approach analyzes the impact of ownership
tions of borrowers in default. They were also and control structure on investments in a
critical of the common policy of government- multiple tier net chain utilizing a property
run financial institutions of charging below- rights–incomplete contract framework. They
market interest rates, argued that informal continue the quest to determine under what
lenders often provided more valuable services market and incentive structures it is benefi-
than is generally perceived, and suggested that cial for producers to integrate downstream
financial institutions in developing countries through their own investment. Employing
should emphasize mobilization of local savings game-theoretic models and analyzing scenar-
as a key source of funds rather than relying ios with distribution of bargaining power as
on international funding agencies such as the the variant, the authors generate first-best
World Bank and the International Monetary efficient ownership structures given alternate
Fund. investment situations. Using comparative
King et al. Agribusiness Economics and Management 559

statics with the incorporation of residual It is probably correct to say that


claim levels, optimal ownership structures are the organization of agricultural mar-
derived. The contribution of the incomplete kets has changed more in the last
contract approach to governance structure 25 years than during the preceding
choices is evident. Attempting to advance century…. From a system comprised
understanding and utilization of these deduc- almost wholly of small, functionally
tively generated set of hypotheses, Chaddad specialized business enterprises there
and Cook (2004) identify a typology of dis- has been a transition to vertically
crete organizational models ranging from integrated concerns operating on a
traditional open-membership cooperatives regional and even a national basis.
described and analyzed by the first generation (p. 162)
of agricultural economists to complex hybrids
to investor-owned organizational forms. Their Hoffman described the emergence of mass
ownership rights typology challenges the next

Downloaded from ajae.oxfordjournals.org at University of Missouri-Columbia on May 10, 2010


retailing and the then-recent appearance of
generation of agribusiness scholars studying the supermarket. He went on to discuss size
the performance of food and agribusiness economies, the limits of management con-
net chains and their participants. Organiza- trol in large organizations, vertical integra-
tional design studies continue to diminish the tion, and the problems created by monopoly
concept of the cooperative as a black box. power in food retailing. He also observed
that forces leading to consolidation and mar-
Contribution #4: Agricultural economists have ket power in retailing were also likely to
documented, developed, and applied theories be seen in food manufacturing. In that same
to explain changes in market structure and issue of the Journal, William H. Nicholls
performance in the food system (1940) published “Market-Sharing in the Pack-
The structure and performance of the process- ing Industry,” another foundational paper on
ing, distribution, and retailing segments of the industrial organization of the food system.
food system have been a focus of inquiry since Nicholls drew on recently developed theo-
the early days of our association. In a paper pre- ries of imperfect competition to explain how
sented at the 1922 annual meeting, Price (1923, observed patterns in packers’ purchase shares
p. 129) noted that marketing systems could be in terminal markets were consistent with col-
studied from the perspective of “inter-unit” or lusion that would likely harm farmers and
“intra-unit” organization. The former focuses consumers.
on the number of intermediary firms between The trends identified by Hoffman (1940)
the farm and the consumer and the economic continued over the next several decades,
relationships among these firms. The latter prompting establishment of the National Com-
focuses on the internal organization of mar- mission on Food Marketing in the 1960s
keting businesses.1 Price focused on intra-unit (Brandow 1966), lively debates on the struc-
organization, presenting operating cost infor- ture of the food system during the 1970s, and
mation for butter plants and grocery stores. the establishment of NC-117, “Organization
There was also much interest in inter-unit and Control of the U.S. Food Production and
organization. For example, in 1930 an annual Distribution System.” This remarkable project
meeting session organized by Miller (1930) brought together a strong team of researchers
examined the evolving structure of the food who combined insights from emerging theo-
distribution system. Several years later Waugh ries in the field of industrial organization with
(1934) published his important paper on “Mar- careful observation, data collection, and empir-
gins in Marketing,” which presented estimates ical analysis to investigate the structure of
of farm–retail price spreads and outlined the food system, the forces driving change in
key issues for future research on marketing the structure, the effects of alternative laws
margins. and regulations on that system, and the con-
In 1940,A. C. Hoffman (1940) began a paper sequences of alternative public policies and
on the “Changing Structure of Agricultural private actions on its performance. An arti-
Markets” by noting: cle by Shaffer (1980) explores the concep-
tual framework for the project’s efforts, and
many key findings of NC-117 are summa-
1
This is a distinction not unlike that between agribusiness eco- rized in three widely cited books: The Food
nomics and agribusiness management made nearly eight decades Manufacturing Industries (Connor et al. 1985),
later by Cook and Chaddad (2000). The Organization and Performance of the U.S.
560 April 2010 Amer. J. Agr. Econ.

Food System (Marion and NC-117 Commit- American Agricultural Economics Associa-
tee 1986), and Food Processing (Connor 1988). tion (AAEA) in 1987 and 1995, respectively,
This work has been the foundation for more but agricultural and applied economists were
recent research on antitrust issues (e.g.,Connor doing significant work on the economics of
2001), pricing policies (e.g., Cotterill, Putsis, supply chains long beforehand by posing ques-
and Dhar 2000), and generic advertising (e.g., tions that have advanced the study of supply
Kaiser et al. 2005). chains well beyond the simple description of
During the latter twenty years of the linked production–distribution activities and
twentieth-century globalization, industrializa- processes.
tion and consolidations accelerated changes One fundamental concern in supply chain
in the horizontal and vertical relationships research is how flows of product, informa-
between participants of the global food tion, and financial resources through the chain
and fiber system. Many of the organiza- can best be governed. Building on transac-
tional and transactional arrangements that tion cost concepts developed by Coase (1937)

Downloaded from ajae.oxfordjournals.org at University of Missouri-Columbia on May 10, 2010


emerged during this period addressed the andWilliamson (1975),Sporleder (1992) exam-
increasingly strategic nature of the market ined the determinants of vertical coordination
structure and growing strategic interdepen- arrangements, giving particular attention to
dence between chain and network rivals and strategic alliances. Several years later, Hobbs
partners. Agribusiness economics and manage- (1996) presented a more thorough overview
ment scholars seeking outlets for new concep- of transaction cost economics and outlined
tual frameworks, methodologies, and insights, methodological approaches for studying verti-
as well as more interdisciplinary-friendly out- cal coordination, including multi-industry eval-
lets,helped establish a plethora of new journals, uations using secondary data, industry-specific
including Agribusiness; International Food and investigations of transaction costs using sec-
Agribusiness Management Review; the Journal ondary data, and industry-specific investi-
of Agricultural & Food Industrial Organiza- gations of transaction costs using primary
tion; the Journal of Cooperatives; the Jour- data.
nal of Agribusiness; the Journal of Chain and Inter-firm incentives are also a key concern
Network Science; and the Journal of Supply in supply chain design. Embodied in formal
Chain Management. Perusal of the special edi- or informal contracts, these systems help align
tions of these journals (on topics such as incentives and reduce losses induced by infor-
eco-labeling, food retailer strategies, food vs. mation asymmetries. Contract design became
fuel, the hybridization of cooperative organi- an important focus for work in the mid-1990s,at
zational forms) demonstrates the complexity a time when first handlers and processors were
and expansion of the original issues identified expanding the use of contracts with farm pro-
in this subfield of agribusiness economics and ducers and were experimenting with a variety
management. of new contract forms. Knoeber and Thurman’s
(1995) work shed light on the risk-shifting role
of relative performance-based contracts in the
Contribution #5: Agricultural and applied broiler industry and offered important insights
economists have focused attention on key on methods for empirical analysis of contract
economic questions related to supply chain provisions. Sheldon’s (1996) review paper pro-
management and design vided an important overview of contract the-
ory and helped set the stage for later work
A supply chain or value chain, as defined by such as that by Goodhue (2000) on production
Boehlje (1999, p. 1032), is a set “of value cre- contracts and by Hueth and Ligon (2001) on
ating activities in the production-distribution relative performance contracts in the produce
process and the explicit structure of link- sector.
ages among these activities or processes.” The distribution of revenues, costs, and gains
The fundamental question in supply chain from improved system performance among
design and management is that of how a supply chain participants is another key issue
chain can most effectively deliver quality and in supply chain design and management. Mar-
value to consumers. The focus is on sys- keting margins were a subject of concern
temwide performance with an emphasis on and debate in the 1930s (Waugh 1934) as
information flows and coordination mecha- the farm share of consumer food expen-
nisms. The terms “value chain” and “supply ditures continued to shrink. Work at that
chain” first appeared in publications of the time was largely descriptive, but forty years
King et al. Agribusiness Economics and Management 561

later Gardner (1975) developed a model of Contribution #6: Agricultural economists have
simultaneous equilibrium in the markets for created robust methods and tools that foster
retail food, farm products, and marketing more efficient operations within the
services. That model motivated later work agribusiness sector
on price transmission by Wohlgenant (1989)
and others—research that can have impor- Transforming agricultural commodities into
tant implications for supply chain design. More food products typically requires conversion of
recently, in a very different analytical frame- large amounts of lower-value materials into
work, Hendrikse and Bijman (2002) showed more valuable products and transport (of agri-
how the allocation of ownership of essential cultural inputs and food product outputs) over
assets affects the distribution of returns across considerable distances. To address this eco-
the chain and investments that affect overall nomic challenge, managers need to be able
productivity. to assess both cost of production alternatives
Finally, members of our profession have also within a single production facility as well as

Downloaded from ajae.oxfordjournals.org at University of Missouri-Columbia on May 10, 2010


asked how public and private sector institu- the total cost-effectiveness of locating several
tional mechanisms—such as product and pro- facilities across a region. A similar challenge
cess quality standards or regulations—shape exists in terms of designing the most effec-
supply chain performance. Caswell, Bredahl, tive production and transportation system to
and Hooker’s (1998) paper on qualitative provide inputs to farm production operations.
management metasystems laid the founda- Greater operational efficiency results in higher
tion for work on this question. Food qual- performance levels for agribusiness firms and
ity metasystems are general strategies, such enhances social welfare through lower food
as ISO 9000 and “just in time” logistics, that costs and higher-quality food products.
are broadly applied across supply chains and Over the last 100 years, application of
across firms within a supply chain. Caswell, microeconomic principles along with use of
Bredahl, and Hooker (1998) note that the evolving quantitative analytical tools has pro-
development of quality metasystems, whether vided significant opportunity for innovation
through the public or private sector initia- throughout the agribusiness sector. Especially
tives, can stimulate structural change and influ- in the middle decades of the 1900s, agricul-
ence competitiveness. Subsequent work—e.g., tural economists led both intellectually and
by Starbird (2005) on sampling inspection and in application of these capabilities to enhance
by Carriquiry and Babcock (2007) on the repu- operational efficiency of supply, processing,
tational effects of quality assurance systems— and distribution in the sector.
has confirmed the importance of quality In the 1940s, the economic engineering
metasystems. approach to estimation of plant cost rela-
Research on these important economic tionships began to be employed to address
questions related to supply chain design and the more managerially relevant question of
management has been and will continue to optimal plant size for a specific commodity
be crucial in developing our ability to meet and setting. The work of R. G. Bressler and
the critical need that Boehlje (1999) identi- numerous colleagues made a particularly pro-
fies for ex ante rather than ex post analyses of found contribution to application of the eco-
structural change in the food system. It con- nomic engineering approach in the food sector.
tributes significantly to our ability to support Early work focused on Connecticut and the
both agribusiness economics and agribusiness dairy industry (Bressler 1952), while numerous
management. later efforts were conducted at the Univer-
sity of California. The economic engineering
approach focused on synthesizing cost func-
Agribusiness Management tions from engineering, biological, and other
sources of information, including accounting
data, based upon process level input-output
Agribusiness management is concerned with relationships.
decision making within the organizations Although an individual food manufactur-
that comprise the food system. This section ing facility might achieve exceptional internal
describes four areas in which members of efficiency, the overall economic performance
our profession have contributed significantly of that unit can be materially affected by
to understanding and supporting operational, the costs of obtaining agricultural inputs and
financial,and strategic decisions in agribusiness of distributing the factory’s output. As food
firms.
562 April 2010 Amer. J. Agr. Econ.

manufacturing firms are likely to have several tomato processing plant efficiency adopted
production facilities, the firm’s managers need a novel approach to estimation of response
to be able to optimize a system of facilities. surface identification. A cost-function meta-
One of the first rigorous efforts to address model is successfully applied to estimated
this challenge was detailed in Stollsteimer’s factor-demand equations, resulting in reduced
(1963) article focused on assessing plant num- specification error. A bootstrapping regres-
bers, size, and location for pear produc- sion approach was employed by Schroeder
tion and processing in California. He devel- (1992) to separately identify the extent of scale
oped a modeling specification consistent with and scope economies for a sample of sup-
the challenge of minimizing the combined ply and marketing cooperatives. Distinguish-
cost of assembling and processing agricul- ing between these types of potential economies
tural commodities. Essentially an extension provides relevant decision-making informa-
of the basic linear programming transporta- tion for agribusiness managers. These studies
tion model, Stollsteimer’s work included plant demonstrate the continuing commitment of

Downloaded from ajae.oxfordjournals.org at University of Missouri-Columbia on May 10, 2010


numbers and locations as internal variables agricultural economists to identify means for
and allowed for economies of size. Over time, measuring and enhancing productive efficiency
this basic approach was extended to more in agribusiness operations.
accurately reflect the circumstances of alterna-
tive agricultural commodities and the actual Contribution #7: Agricultural economists have
dynamics of the marketplace. For example, developed financing instruments and
Polopolus (1965) examined multiple-product arrangements tailored to the characteristics of
plants, and Ladd and Halvorson (1970) devel- the farm sector; loan portfolio, credit analysis,
oped means to assess the sensitivity of model and capitalization structures for financial
results. institutions serving the sector; and valuable
The post–World War II period saw an explo- public data resources on sector and firm
sion of activity relating to the study of oper- financial structure and performance
ational efficiency in the agribusiness sector.
This marked increase in academic productivity Early work in agricultural finance focused pri-
was the joint result of interacting forces such marily on how effectively lenders were serving
as changing societal needs, advances in theory their farm customers in terms of loan terms,
and computational capabilities, and the infu- interest rates, and credit standards and in gen-
sion of federal funding targeted to agricultural eral adequately fulfilling and responding to
marketing. French’s (1977) review article inter- farmers’ credit needs. Black (1930) argued that
preted the vast array of literature produced in “information should be uncovered to permit
that time period. In addition to comprehen- him [the farmer] to learn to use credit intelli-
sively documenting the productivity of prior gently, to control credit instead of being con-
works, this effort undertook an extensive and trolled by it” (p. 249). This focus on credit use
thorough interpretation of the challenges and dominated not only the research agenda, but
accomplishments of the stream of work relat- also data collection, outreach activities of the
ing to productive efficiency in agricultural mar- USDA and Land Grant System, and widely
keting. It thus provided the single reference used textbooks such as Murray’s (1941) early
point for legions of researchers, instructors, and editions of Agricultural Finance. Development
students working in this area. of amortization concepts, matching repayment
Agricultural economists have continued to terms to income/earnings capacity and view-
provide empirical assessments focused on ing credit as a resource that could be used
enhancing efficiency within individual process- (i.e. converted into debt) or held in reserve
ing facilities and among systems of facilities. to manage potential financial stress (Barry and
As computational capabilities and modeling Baker 1971), was the focus through the 1970s.
methods have advanced, these innovations It was not until the work on farm firm growth
have been incorporated within increasing models (Baker 1968; Boehlje and Eisgruber
sophisticated studies to inform decision mak- 1972) that capital allocation and investment
ers. Akridge’s (1989) analysis of multiple- decisions were added to the agenda. The focus
product fertilizer retailing plants employed a returned to appropriate use of credit and more
frontier multiproduct cost function to mea- accurate measurement and documentation of
sure productive efficiency. The potential for the financial performance of farm firms in the
significant reductions in variable costs was 1980s through the work of the Farm Financial
identified. Starbird’s (1990) assessment of Standards Council (1991).
King et al. Agribusiness Economics and Management 563

During the 1970s the structural changes in recent times, additional data on the financial
the financial markets and the pressures for and resource characteristics of the farm fam-
consolidation of the institutions in both the ily, including labor allocation, nonfarm income,
commercial banking sector and the FCS stim- and investments and family expenditures, have
ulated work on the cost and efficiency of been collected as part of this survey. As with
the consolidated/restructured financial institu- the earlier survey work of the Federal Reserve
tions, and the effectiveness and commitment Banks, the ARMS data set has been used
of these generally larger and less locally con- extensively by the USDA and Land Grant
trolled/owned institutions to serve the farm agricultural economists in their research pro-
sector and rural communities. Such work grams. The extensive financial data collected
is summarized by Ellinger, Hartarska, and and the numerous analyses that these data have
Wilson (2005) and Gustafson, Pederson, and supported document that although the agri-
Gloy (2005). Beginning in the 1990s, atten- cultural sector and farm businesses were char-
tion shifted to issues of capital structure, loan acterized by low incomes and weak financial

Downloaded from ajae.oxfordjournals.org at University of Missouri-Columbia on May 10, 2010


and asset portfolio composition, and credit risk performance earlier in the twentieth century,
management of the financial institutions serv- in recent times that performance has become
ing agriculture. This work was stimulated in more competitive with other industries.
part by the bank and FCS failures of the 1980s
combined with the deregulation of the finan- Contribution #8: Agricultural economics
cial markets, which placed more burdens on scholarship has informed business strategy
the individual institution to manage its finan- formation by monitoring, interpreting, and
cial risk in an increasingly competitive market. anticipating the changing business
Notable work on these issues is summarized by environment of agriculture
Gustafson, Pederson, and Gloy (2005).
Additionally, a mainstay of the agricultural Business strategy focuses on optimizing the
finance work since its early years has been linkages between the firm and its surround-
the collection and analysis of financial data. ing business environment (Porter 1985). This
This work started with the farm records/farm managerial function inherently incorporates a
accounts programs of Warren and colleagues at longer-run perspective, striving to ensure that
Cornell that were an integral part of their farm the firm not only is well aligned with current
management programs. It continues today in conditions but also is being positioned to adapt
the form of farm records programs and activ- to the dynamic and uncertain business environ-
ities of both the Land Grant System and the ment of tomorrow. A key element of strategy
private sector. can be paraphrased as a “how will we compete”
Data in the form of descriptive statistics for question (Aaker 1988). Business management
both the farming sector and the financial insti- concepts such as competitive advantage, dis-
tutions serving that sector, which were the focal tinctive competencies, and the resource-based
point of work by the USDA under the lead- view of strategy have been intertwined in the
ership of Garlock (1966) and Tostlebe (1957), scholarship addressing this question, especially
were used to characterize the changing finan- during the last three decades.
cial condition of agriculture early in the twenti- Understanding how to compete within the
eth century. Extension of this work resulted in context of a dynamic agricultural sector and
the USDA’s first publication of the sectorwide an evolving global economy is a key challenge
Balance Sheet of Agriculture and Farm Income for agribusiness decision makers. Throughout
Situation in 1940.These data sets continue to be the last 100 years, the scholarship of agricul-
developed today. The Federal Reserve System tural economists has contributed to improving
initiated surveys of farm lenders and their lend- decision-maker understanding of the business
ing activity late in the 1940s. Melichar (1979) environment of agriculture.
and colleagues issued their first Agricultural In addition to his seminal work with Davis,
Finance Data book in 1976, which continues Goldberg pioneered in employing the case
today to be an extensive and exhaustive data study method within agribusiness. He utilized
set summarizing the changing financial char- this form of scholarship to uncover relation-
acteristics of farm borrowers and lenders. The ships and to communicate the dynamics of
USDA implemented an annual Farm Cost and change to legions of decision makers. The more
Returns Survey in 1991, which is a forerunner than 300 Harvard Business School case stud-
to the current Agricultural Resource Man- ies he has coauthored address a vast array
agement Systems (ARMS) data set. In more of factors affecting global agriculture. The
564 April 2010 Amer. J. Agr. Econ.

Agribusiness Seminar he has led also has focused on the future structure of the
been a powerfully effective means of educating sector.
agribusiness managers. More recently, the methods of agricultural
Key empirical work, especially from the economists have advanced along with the gen-
1950s to the 1980s, focused on providing an eral management literature and the nature of
enhanced, quantitative understanding of the change in the sector. As a result, the scholarly
evolving production agriculture sector. These capabilities of agricultural economists have
developments were critically important as been directly applied to decision-making issues
the size and scope of input supply and commod- within agribusinesses. These efforts have nec-
ity marketing firms are inherently connected to essarily required explicit consideration of the
the regional nature of agricultural production. manager as more than only a strictly rational,
As the underlying technologies supporting pro- economic being (Mintzberg 1978).
duction agriculture evolved, the dynamics of An article by Fisher, Sonka, and Westgren
regional production underwent considerable (2004) sets a standard for work that contributes

Downloaded from ajae.oxfordjournals.org at University of Missouri-Columbia on May 10, 2010


change. to professional scholarship while investigat-
The development of mathematical program- ing strategically important issues with actual
ming allowed for detailed analysis of inter- decision makers. It reports on an intervention
regional competition in a “systematic and where sophisticated information technology
manageable way” (Jenson 1977, p. 47). From tools (animated, three-dimensional visualiza-
the 1950s into the 1980s, Heady and oth- tion techniques driven by estimates from a
ers at Iowa State University developed a system dynamics simulation model) were used
series of increasingly sophisticated mathe- to help managers assess future options and
matical models focused on the dynamics of chart strategic directions. Focused on potential
interregional competition. A primary build- scenarios for global protein needs, the article’s
ing block for those analyses, and for oth- more significant contribution was in empir-
ers conducted throughout the profession, was ically documenting the effect of the use of
described in USDA Technical Bulletin 1241, visualization techniques and economic mod-
Regional Adjustments in Grain Production: eling on strategic thinking. In addition to its
A Linear Programming Analysis (Egbert and research impact, this work was used in execu-
Heady 1963). That work was initiated in 1955, tive education programs for numerous decision
as soon as the 1954 Census of Agriculture was makers from throughout the global soybean
available. Grain production (shifts in location, industry.
resource use, and output levels) was the pri-
mary focus of this pioneering work. The direct Contribution #9: Educational programs in
output was explicit definition of comparative agribusiness have developed human capital
regional production efficiencies, as well as opti- that has contributed significantly to
mal production patterns, associated land rents, productivity growth in the food system
and prices for feed grains and wheat. Based
on that pioneer effort, numerous extensions Educational programs have been a central con-
and advancements were completed over the cern for our profession over the past century.
following decades. Long before the term “agribusiness” was intro-
Although technical change has been a con- duced, the key role of business education in
stant driving force within agriculture, the 1980s our undergraduate and graduate programs was
saw an intense interest in the potential for clearly recognized. For example, in a presenta-
biotechnology and information technology to tion at the 1926 annual meeting of our associa-
profoundly alter agricultural systems, in con- tion, Buechel (1927) discussed the importance
cert with other structural and financial chal- of business education and expressed concerns
lenges occurring in the sector. There was an that business administration programs might
urgent need for comprehensive analyses of draw students away from programs offered by
these interlinkages. One effort which accom- agricultural economics departments. Twenty
plished that goal was published as Technology, years later, Wood (1947) reported results of
Public Policy, and the Changing Structure of a survey of potential employers for gradu-
American Agriculture (US Congress 1986). ates from Purdue’s agricultural business pro-
Employing a mix of published research and gram and described a suggested curriculum
qualitative methods, this assessment speci- designed to meet the needs identified by poten-
fied scenarios of change for the agricultural tial employers. Several years later, John D.
sector, and it advanced policy prescriptions Black, who would soon be joined at Harvard
King et al. Agribusiness Economics and Management 565

by John Davis and Ray Goldberg, reported on budget restraints. There was great diversity in
findings from a survey of the profession on the the structure of agribusiness programs at that
role of economics in undergraduate curricula. time, reflecting historical and contextual differ-
Black (1953) concluded that ences as well as the recognition that there was
value in experimenting with new models.
Graduate and professional programs in
departments of agricultural eco-
agribusiness were somewhat slower to develop.
nomics in the larger colleges at least
Litzenberg, Gorman, and Schneider (1983)
should consider offering three cur-
identified four existing professional graduate
ricula, one of the general-agriculture
programs and two under development. In 1989
type to serve especially the needs of
the National Agribusiness Education Commis-
future farmers and extension work-
sion was organized “(a) to develop guidelines
ers, one in agricultural business to
for a masters degree in agribusiness manage-
serve the needs of young men looking
ment, (b) to suggest strategies for continuing

Downloaded from ajae.oxfordjournals.org at University of Missouri-Columbia on May 10, 2010


forward to a career in businesses serv-
education and executive development courses
ing farmers, and one to prepare agri-
for employees, and (c) to recommend steps
cultural economic specialists. (p. 491)
to cultivate faculty resources in agribusiness
education” (Woolverton and Downey 1999, p.
He went on to note that the agricultural busi- 1050). Woolverton and Downey reported that
ness curricula would often rely on coursework relatively little progress had been made in
in undergraduate business colleges. the decade following the commission’s report.
Stimulated by growing interest in agribusi- They went on to note (p. 1055) that the need for
ness within the profession and by growing well-trained agribusiness managers might be
demand from rapidly expanding agribusiness met by“continued expansion of undergraduate
firms, agricultural business programs contin- programs in agribusiness management coupled
ued to develop and evolve in the 1960s and with five to six top-quality agribusiness MBA
1970s. There were tensions as members of and continuing education programs.”
the profession developed stronger ties with In 2002 the USDA provided funding for the
the broader agribusiness sector. A. C. Hoff- National Food and Agribusiness Management
man, vice president of Kraft Foods Company, Education Commission to assess the current
criticized existing undergraduate programs for state of agribusiness management education
their emphasis on economics. He stressed that and develop recommendations for addressing
“the agribusiness economist should be trained key issues that face these programs. The com-
not only in economics but also for general busi- mission’s 2006 report (Boland and Akridge
ness management” and went on to note that 2006) presents specific recommendations in six
traditional agricultural economics programs key areas: (1) curriculum assessment and revi-
were not “adequate for this purpose” (Hoff- sion, (2) communication/writing/critical think-
man 1969, p. 449). Discussants responding to ing skills, (3) industry linkages, (4) student
Hoffman’s paper acknowledged problems but recruitment for food and agribusiness manage-
also emphasized positive accomplishments and ment programs, (5) introductory and capstone
changes under way at many universities. undergraduate courses, and (6) graduate pro-
Part 2 of the November 1973 issue of grams in food and agribusiness management.
the American Journal of Agricultural Eco- These recommendations will be a roadmap for
nomics was devoted to papers presented at campus-based agribusiness education as our
a workshop on the Improvement of Educa- profession enters its second century.
tion in Agricultural Economics by Defining Finally, our educational impact extends
Goals, Developing Curricula, and Improving beyond campus-based programs to include
Instruction. This issue includes descriptions of direct involvement with agribusiness deci-
undergraduate curricula at the University of sion makers. The Agribusiness Seminar at
California–Davis (Parker 1973), Southern Illi- the Harvard Business School has long been
nois University (Wills 1973), Michigan State recognized for its important contributions.
University (Connor 1973), and Texas A&M Other noteworthy programs include the Cen-
University (Grady 1973). The curriculum at ter for Agricultural Business at Purdue Uni-
each institution except Southern Illinois Uni- versity, the Executive Development Program
versity included some form of agribusiness of the George Morris Centre in Canada, the
track or concentration, and Wills noted that the Executive Program for Agricultural Produc-
lack of this option at his university was due to ers at Texas A&M University, the Food and
566 April 2010 Amer. J. Agr. Econ.

Agricultural Policy Research Institute at the patterns due to climate change, there are
University of Missouri–Columbia and at Iowa likely to be large shifts in relative prices
State University, and the Graduate Institute over the next quarter century. This could
of Cooperative Leadership at the University trigger an unpredictable, radical restruc-
of Missouri–Columbia. These and other pro- turing of the food system and critical
grams have been exemplary in their ability strategic positioning issues for agribusi-
to integrate research scholarship and outreach ness firms.
to advance strategic decision making in the
agribusiness sector. Understanding and anticipating the dynam-
ics of the global agribusiness environment
will be increasingly critical. These challenges—
Opportunities and Challenges for the Future along with advances in theoretical frameworks,
diagnostic tools, and empirical techniques
Our association’s first century was a period of

Downloaded from ajae.oxfordjournals.org at University of Missouri-Columbia on May 10, 2010


for addressing them—will afford agribusiness
unprecedented change in food production, dis- scholars an ample supply of issues, approaches,
tribution, and consumption. The following are and motives to expand and broaden inquiry
forces for future change. into an ever-increasing complex and impor-
tant global food system. They will also offer us
• The agricultural sector is increasingly a new opportunities to help students, managers,
source of raw materials for sectors out- and policymakers through agribusiness teach-
side of the traditional food and fiber ing and outreach programs. While economics
system. Agricultural products are being will continue to be the foundation for our work,
used to produce biofuels, industrial prod- concepts from other social science disciplines
ucts such as polymers and bio-based syn- and sophisticated new computational tools also
thetic chemicals and fibers, and pharma- will be necessary.
ceutical/health products such as functional
foods, growth hormones, and organ trans-
plants.This is blurring industry boundaries References
and creating new strategic and competi-
tive challenges for agribusiness firms, and Aaker, D. A. 1988. Strategic Market Manage-
it will have profound implications for the ment, 2nd ed. New York: John Wiley &
structure and operations of the supply Sons.
chains in the industry. Adams, D. W., D. H. Graham, and J. D. von
• Agribusiness organizations are becoming Pischke, eds. 1984. Undermining Rural
more flexible and complex, more decen- Development with Cheap Credit. Boulder,
tralized and yet reliant on collective action CO: Westview Press.
and cohesiveness. This poses challenges Ahrendsen, B. L., C. B. Dodson, B. L.
for managers designing the incentive sys- Dixon, and S. R. Koenig. 2005. Research
tems and internal institutions that are the on USDA Farm Credit Programs: Past,
foundation for intra-firm structure, strat- Present, and Future. Agricultural Finance
egy, and governance. At the same time, Review 65: 165–181.
technological change and the emergence Akridge, J. T. 1989. Measuring Productive Effi-
of new globalization–localization tensions ciency in Multiple Product Agribusiness
will stimulate changes in socioeconomic Firms. American Journal of Agricultural
relationships, reshape scope and scale Economics 71: 116–125.
economies, increase risks, introduce new Baker, C. B. 1968. Financial Organization
and novel interdependencies, give birth and Production Choices. American Journal
to new rivals and potential partners, and Agricultural Economics 50: 1566–1577.
mold more hybrid organizational forms. Barry, P. J., and C. B. Baker. 1971. Reser-
This will complicate inter-firm coordina- vation Prices on Credit Use: A Measure
tion for agribusiness managers and food of Response to Uncertainty. Ameri-
system policymakers. can Journal Agricultural Economics 53:
• With the approach of peak world oil pro- 222–227.
duction, the prospect for international Benedict, M. R. 1945. The Relation of Public to
agreements to reduce greenhouse gas Private Lending Agencies (in Agriculture)
emissions, and the potential for significant and Recent Trends in Their Development.
geographic shifts in food production Journal of Farm Economics 27: 88–103.
King et al. Agribusiness Economics and Management 567

Black, A. G. 1930. Research Methods in Farm Connor, J. M. 1988. Food Processing:An Indus-
Finance. Journal of Farm Economics 12: trial Powerhouse in Transition. Lexington,
248–256. MA: Lexington Books.
Black, J. D. 1953. Economics in Agricultural Connor, J. M. 2001. Global Price Fixing: Our
College Curricula. Journal of Farm Eco- Customers Are the Enemy. Norwell, MA:
nomics 35: 484–495. Kluwer Academic Publishers.
Boehlje, M. 1999. Structural Changes in the Connor, J. M., R. T. Rogers, B. W. Marion,
Agricultural Industries: How Do We Mea- and W. F. Mueller. 1985. The Food Man-
sure, Analyze, and Understand Them? ufacturing Industries: Structure, Strategies,
American Journal of Agricultural Eco- Performance, and Policies. Lexington, MA:
nomics 81: 1028–1041. Lexington Books.
Boehlje, M. D., and L. M. Eisgruber. 1972. Connor, L. J. 1973. Michigan State’s Cur-
Strategies for the Creation and Transfer of ricula in Agricultural Economics. Ameri-

Downloaded from ajae.oxfordjournals.org at University of Missouri-Columbia on May 10, 2010


the Farm Estate. American Journal Agri- can Journal of Agricultural Economics 55:
cultural Economics 54: 461–472. 752–754.
Boland, M., and J. Akridge, eds. 2006. Food Cook, M. L. 1995. The Future of U.S. Agri-
and Agribusiness Management Education: cultural Cooperatives:A Neo-Institutional
Future Directions. Final report of the Approach. American Journal of Agricul-
National Food and Agribusiness Man- tural Economics 77: 1153–1159.
agement Education Commission, Kansas Cook, M. L., and F. R. Chaddad. 2000. Agroin-
State University and Purdue University. dustrialization of the Global Agrifood
Brake,J. R.,and E. Melichar. 1970.Agricultural Economy: Bridging Development Eco-
Finance and Capital Markets. In A Sur- nomics and Agribusiness Research. Agri-
vey of Agricultural Economics Literature, cultural Economics 23: 207–218.
ed. L. Martin, pp. 413–494. Minneapolis: Cotterill, R. W., W. P. Putsis, Jr., and R. Dhar.
University of Minnesota Press. 2000. Assessing the Competitive Interac-
Brand, C. H. 1913. Marketing. Record of the tion between Private Labels and National
Proceedings of Annual Meeting. American Brands. Journal of Business 73: 109–137.
Farm Management Association, Washing- Davis, J. H. 1956. From Agriculture to
ton DC, November 14–15, 1913. Agribusiness. Harvard Business Review 34:
Brandow, G. E. 1966. The Food Commission: 107–115.
Its Product and Its Role. Journal of Farm Davis, J. H., and R. A. Goldberg. 1957. A Con-
Economics 48: 1319–1327. cept of Agribusiness. Boston: Division of
Bressler, R. G. Jr. 1952. City Milk Distribu- Research, Graduate School of Business
tion. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Administration, Harvard University.
Press. Detre, J. D., C. A. Wilson, and A. W. Gray. 2007.
Buechel, F. A. 1927. Land Grant College Buying Stock in Value-Added Companies:
Curricula. Journal of Farm Economics 9: An Alternative Choice for Vertical Diver-
53–62. sification? Agricultural Finance Review 66:
Carriquiry, M., and B. A. Babcock. 2007. Rep- 175–196.
utations, Market Structure, and the Choice Egbert, A. C., and E. O. Heady. 1963. Regional
of Quality Assurance Systems in the Food Adjustments in Grain Production: A Lin-
Industry. American Journal of Agricultural ear Programming Analysis. USDA Tech.
Economics 89: 12–23. Bull. 1294.
Caswell,J.A.,M. E. Bredahl,and N. H. Hooker. Ellinger,P. N.,V. Hartarska,and C.Wilson. 2005
1998. How Quality Management Meta- Structure, Performance, and Risk Manage-
systems Are Affecting the Food Industry. ment of Financial Institutions. Agricultural
Review of Agricultural Economics 22: Finance Review 65: 183–200.
547–557. Emelianoff, I. V. 1942. Economic Theory of
Chaddad, F., and M. L. Cook. 2004. Under- Cooperation. Ann Arbor, MI: Edward
standing New Cooperative Models: An Brothers.
Ownership-Control Rights Typology. Enke, S. 1945. Consumer Cooperatives and
Review of Agricultural Economics 26: Economic Efficiency. American Economic
1249–1253. Review 35: 148–155.
Coase, R. H. 1937. The Nature of the Firm. Erdman, H. E. 1924. The Commodity Coop-
Economica 4: 386–405. erative Association: Its Strength and
568 April 2010 Amer. J. Agr. Econ.

Weakness. Journal of Farm Economics, 6: Hendrikse, G., and J. Bijman. 2002. Owner-
106–116. ship Structure in Agrifood Chains: The
Erdman, H. E. 1927. The Cooperative Market- Marketing Cooperative. American Journal
ing Association as a Factor in Adjusting of Agricultural Economics 84: 104–119.
Production to Demand. Journal of Farm Hendrikse, G. W. J., and C. P. Veerman. 2001.
Economics 7: 73–81. Marketing Cooperatives: An Incomplete
———. 1950. Trends in Cooperative Expan- Contracting Perspective. Journal of Agri-
sion. Journal of Farm Economics 32: 1019– cultural Economics 52: 53–64.
1030. Herr, W. M. 1969. The Role of FHA’s Farm
Farm Financial Standards Council. 1991. Operating and Ownership Loan Programs
Financial Guidelines for Agricultural as Indicated by Borrower Characteristics.
Producers. Washington DC: American Agricultural Finance Review 30: 1–10.
Bankers Association. Hind, A. M. 1994. Cooperatives— Under-
Fisher, D. K., S. T. Sonka, and R. E. West-

Downloaded from ajae.oxfordjournals.org at University of Missouri-Columbia on May 10, 2010


Performers by Nature. Journal of Agricul-
gren. 2004. Strategic Decision Making in tural Economics 45: 213–219.
the Quasi-Government Sector:The Illinois Hobbs, J. E. 1996. A Transaction Cost
Soybean Program Operating Board Inter- Approach to Supply Chain Management.
national Journal of Organization Theory Supply Chain Management 1: 15–27.
and Behavior 7: 42–65. Hobson, A. 1921. Fundamentals of Cooper-
French, B. C. 1977. The Analysis of Produc- ative Marketing. Journal of Farm Eco-
tive Efficiency in Agricultural Marketing: nomics 3: 24–29.
Models, Methods, and Progress. In A Sur- Hoffman, A. C. 1940. Changing Organization
vey of Agricultural Economics Literature, of Agricultural Markets. Journal of Farm
Vol. 1, ed. L. R. Martin, pp. 94–206. Min- Economics 22: 162–172.
neapolis: University of Minnesota Press. ———. 1969. What Agribusiness Economists
Fulton, M. 2001. Leadership in Democratic Need from Theoretical and Empiri-
and Participatory Organizations. Cana- cal Agricultural Economics. American
dian Journal of Agricultural Economics 49: Journal of Agricultural Economics 51:
381–394. 448–456.
Gardner, B. L. 1975. The Farm–Retail Price Holland, S. J., and R. P. King. 2004. Trad-
Spread in a Competitive Food Industry. ing Mechanisms for New Generation
American Journal of Agricultural Eco- Cooperative Stock: The Architecture of
nomics 57: 399–409. Organizational Formation and Demise.
Garlock, F. L. 1966. Farmers and Their American Journal of Agricultural Eco-
Debts: The Role of Credit in the Farm nomics 86: 1262–1268.
Economy. USDA Agricultural Economics Hueth, B., and E. Ligon. 2001. Agricultural
Rep. 93. Markets as Relative Performance Eval-
Goodhue, R. E. 2000. Broiler Production Con- uation. American Journal of Agricultural
tracts as a Multi-Agent Problem: Common Economics 83: 318–328.
Risk, Incentives and Heterogeneity. Amer- Jenson, H. F. 1977. Farm Management and Pro-
ican Journal of Agricultural Economics 82: duction Economics. InA Survey ofAgricul-
606–622. tural Economics Literature, vol. 1, ed. L. R.
Grady, J. C. 1973. Texas A&M’s Curriculum. Martin, pp. 1–89. Minneapolis: University
American Journal of Agricultural Eco- of Minnesota Press.
nomics 55: 755–756. Jesness, O. B. 1925. The Plans and Organi-
Gustafson, C. R., G. D. Pederson, and B. A. zation of Cooperatives. Journal of Farm
Gloy. 2005. Credit Risk Assessment. Agri- Economics 7: 359–368.
cultural Finance Review 65: 201–218. Jolly, R. W., A. Paulsen, J. D. Johnson, K. H.
Harl, N. E. 1990. The Farm Debt Crisis of Baum, and R. Prescott. 1985. Incidence,
the 1980s. The Henry A. Wallace Series Intensity, and Duration of Financial Stress
on Agricultural History and Rural Studies. among Farm Firms. American Journal of
Ames: Iowa State University Press. Agricultural Economics 67: 1108–1115.
Helmberger, P. G., and S. Hoos. 1962. Coop- Kaiser, H. M., J. M. Alston, J. M. Crespi, and
erative Enterprise and Organization The- R. J. Sexton, eds. 2005. The Economics of
ory. Journal of Farm Economics 44: Commodity Promotion Programs: Lessons
275–290. from California. New York: Peter Lang.
King et al. Agribusiness Economics and Management 569

Knapp, J. G. 1950. Cooperative Expansion Phillips, R. 1953. Economic Nature of the


through Horizontal Integration. Journal of Cooperative Association. Journal of Farm
Farm Economics 32: 1031–1047. Economics 35: 74–87.
Knoeber, C. R., and W. N. Thurman. 1995. Polopolus, L. 1965. Optimum Plant Numbers
“Don’t CountYour Chickens . . .”:Risk and and Locations for Multiple Product Pro-
Risk Shifting in the Broiler Industry.Amer- cessing. Journal of Farm Economics 47:
ican Journal of Agricultural Economics 77: 287–295.
486–496. Porter, M. E. 1985. Competitive Advantage:
Koller, E. F. 1950. Vertical Integration of Agri- Creating and Sustaining Superior Perfor-
cultural Cooperatives. Journal of Farm mance. New York: Free Press.
Economics 32: 1048–1058. Price, H. B. 1923. Possibilities of Improv-
Ladd, G. W., and M. P. Halvorson. 1970. ing Marketing through Better Organi-
Parametric Solutions to the Stollsteimer zation. Journal of Farm Economics 3:

Downloaded from ajae.oxfordjournals.org at University of Missouri-Columbia on May 10, 2010


Model. American Journal of Agricultural 129–146.
Economics 52: 578–580. Robotka, F. 1947. A Theory of Cooperation.
Lee, V. P. 1925. The Intermediate Credit Journal of Farm Economics 29: 94–114.
Banks. Journal of Farm Economics 7: Royer, J. S., ed. 1987. Cooperative Theory:
425–434. New Approaches. ACS Service Report 18.
Litzenberg, K. K., W. D. Gorman, and V. E. Washington DC: U.S. Department of Agri-
Schneider. 1983. Academic and Profes- culture.
sional Programs in Agribusiness. Ameri- Schroeder, T. C. 1992. Economies of Scale and
can Journal of Agricultural Economics 65: Scope forAgricultural Supply and Market-
1060–1064. ing Cooperatives. Review of Agricultural
Marion, B. W., and NC 117 Committee, eds. Economics 14: 93–103.
1986. The Organization and Performance Sexton, R. J. 1990. Imperfect Competition
of the U.S. Food System. Lexington, MA: in Agricultural Markets and the Role of
Lexington Books. Cooperatives: A Spatial Analysis. Ameri-
Melichar, E. 1979. Capital Gains versus Cur- can Journal of Agricultural Economics 72:
rent Income in the Farming Sector. Amer- 709–720.
ican Journal Agricultural Economics 61: Shaffer, J. D. 1980. Food System Organization
1086–1106. and Performance: Toward a Conceptual
Miller, P. L. 1930. Modern Tendencies in Food Framework. American Journal of Agricul-
Distribution. Journal of Farm Economics tural Economics 62: 310–318.
12: 278–279. Sheldon, I. M. 1996. Contracting, Imper-
Mintzberg, H. 1978. Patterns in Strategy fect Information, and the Food System.
Formation. Management Science 24: Review of Agricultural Economics 18:
934–948. 7–19.
Moore, C. V., and J. E. Noel. 1995. Valuation of Sonka, S. T., and M. A. Hudson. 1989. Why
Transferable Delivery Rights for Market- Agribusiness Anyway? Agribusiness 5:
ing Cooperatives. Journal of Cooperatives 305–314.
10: 1–17. Sporleder,T. L. 1992. Managerial Economics of
Murray, W. G. 1941. Agricultural Finance. Vertically Coordinated Agricultural Firms.
Ames: Iowa State College Press. American Journal of Agricultural Eco-
Myers, W. I. 1934. The Program of the Farm nomics 74: 1226–1231.
Credit Administration. Journal of Farm Staatz, J. M. 1989. Farmer Cooperative The-
Economics 16: 30–40. ory: Recent Developments. ACS Research
Nicholls, W. H. 1940. Market-Sharing in the Report 84. Washington DC: U.S. Depart-
Packing Industry. Journal of Farm Eco- ment of Agriculture.
nomics 22: 225–240. Starbird, S. A. 1990. A Metamodel Specifica-
Nourse, E. G. 1922. The Economic Philoso- tion for a Tomato Processing Plant. Journal
phy of Cooperation. American Economic of the Operations Research Society 41:
Review 12: 577–597. 229–240.
Parker, E. H. 1973. New Directions in Agri- ———. 2005. Moral Hazard, Inspection
cultural Economics Curricula, University Policy, and Food Safety. American
of California–Davis. American Journal of Journal of Agricultural Economics 87:
Agricultural Economics 55: 748–749. 15–27.
570 April 2010 Amer. J. Agr. Econ.

Stollsteimer, J. F. 1963. A Working Model for Wills, W. J. 1973. SIU’s Curriculum in Agri-
Plant Numbers and Locations. Journal of cultural Economics. American Journal of
Farm Economics 45: 631–645. Agricultural Economics 55: 750–751.
Tostlebe, A. S. 1957. Capital in Agricul- Wohlgenant, M. K. 1989. Demand for Farm
ture: Its Formation and Financing since Output in a Complete System of Demand
1870. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Functions. American Journal of Agricul-
Press. tural Economics 71: 241–252.
U.S. Congress, Office of Technology Assess- Wood, G. B. 1947. Training Agricultural Eco-
ment. 1986. Technology, Public Policy and nomic Majors for Business Careers. Jour-
the Changing Structure of American Agri- nal of Farm Economics 29: 1341–1354.
culture. OTA-F-285. Washington DC: US Woolverton, M. W., and W. D. Downey.
Government Printing Office. 1999. A Look at Agribusiness Educa-
Waugh, F. V. 1934. Margins in Marketing. Jour- tion since the National Agribusiness

Downloaded from ajae.oxfordjournals.org at University of Missouri-Columbia on May 10, 2010


nal of Farm Economics 16: 233–245. Commission’s 1989 Report: The Lin-
Williamson, O. E. 1975. Markets and Hierar- coln Report Revisited. American
chies: Analysis and Antitrust Implications. Journal of Agricultural Economics 81:
New York: Free Press. 1050–1055.

View publication stats

You might also like