You are on page 1of 57

© 2015, American Marketing Association

Journal of Marketing
PrePrint, Unedited
All rights reserved. Cannot be reprinted without the express
permission of the American Marketing Association.

Washing Away Your Sins? Corporate Social Responsibility,


Corporate Social Irresponsibility, and Firm Performance

Charles Kang
Frank Germann
Rajdeep Grewal

_____________________
Charles Kang is Visiting Assistant Professor, A.B. Freeman School of Business, Tulane University,
Goldring/Woldenberg Hall, New Orleans, LA 70118, USA, Tel: +1 504 314 7554, Email:
ckang2@tulane.edu. Frank Germann is Assistant Professor of Marketing, 395 Mendoza College of Business,
University of Notre Dame, Notre Dame, IN 46556, USA, Tel: +1 574 631 4858, Email: fgermann@nd.edu.
Rajdeep Grewal is the Townsend Family Distinguished Professor, Kenan-Flagler Business School, University
of North Carolina, Chapel Hill, NC 27514, USA, Tel: +1 919 62 2149, Email: grewalr@unc.edu. The authors
thank Timothy Gilbride, Patrick Murphy, Arvind Rangaswamy, Hari Sridhar, and William Wilkie for their
helpful comments on an earlier version of this research. In addition, they gratefully acknowledge the
constructive guidance of the JM review team.
Washing Away Your Sins? Corporate Social Responsibility,
Corporate Social Irresponsibility, and Firm Performance

ABSTRACT

We address the questions of whether and how Corporate Social Responsibility (CSR) relates to firm
performance, and, in so doing identify four mechanisms pertaining to this relationship: (1) slack resources
lead to CSR, i.e., slack resources mechanism (2) CSR improves performance, i.e., good management
mechanism, (3) CSR makes amends for past Corporate Social Irresponsibility (CSI), i.e., penance mechanism,
and (4) CSR insures against subsequent CSI, i.e., insurance mechanism. We seek to be integrative in our
approach and incorporate the four mechanisms in our empirical model specification. Specifically, to model
the interplay among CSR, CSI, and firm performance, and to test the four mechanisms simultaneously, we
propose a structural panel vector autoregression specification. In support of the good management
mechanism, results from our unbalanced panel dataset of over 4,500 firms and up to 19 years suggest that
firms that engage in CSR are likely to benefit financially from their CSR investments. Moreover, we do not
find support for the slack resources or the insurance mechanism. In contrast, and in support of the penance
mechanism, often firms’ CSR seems to trail their CSI. However, our results also suggest that the penance
mechanism is ineffective at offsetting negative performance effects due to CSI.

Keywords: Corporate Social Irresponsibility, Corporate Social Responsibility, Firm Performance,


Mechanisms, Structural Panel Vector Autoregressive Model.

2
Corporate social responsibility (CSR) – company actions that advance social good beyond that which

is required by law (e.g., McWilliams and Siegel 2001) – continues to draw interest from practitioners and

academics alike. In 2013, Ipsos reported that 77% of consumers believe that companies should be doing more

to contribute to society (Ipsos 2013), while a study conducted by Reputation Intelligence found that 73% of

consumers across the 15 largest markets in the world will recommend companies that deliver on CSR

(Reputation Intelligence, 2013). Against this backdrop, most of the extant academic CSR-related research has

scrutinized the conception that companies do “well” by doing “good” (e.g., Barnett and Salomon 2012;

Bhattacharya and Sen 2004; Jayachandran, Kalaignanam, and Eilert 2013; Margolis et al. 2007). However, the

debate on how doing “good” and doing “well” converge has yet to be resolved (e.g., Chin, Hambrick, and

Treviño 2013; Groening, Swaminathan, and Mittal 2015; Hull and Rothenberg 2008; Mackey et al. 2007).

Specifically, our examination of the extant CSR literature reveals the following four mechanisms that have

been proposed – independently1 – regarding the relationship between CSR and (positive) firm performance:

1. Slack Resources Mechanism: Companies engage in CSR because they are doing well financially and have
slack resources (e.g., McGuire et al. 1988; Orlitzky, Schmidt and Rynes 2003).

2. Good Management Mechanism: CSR is part of “good management” and thus improves financial
performance (e.g., Hillman and Keim 2001; Hull and Rothenberg 2008).

3. Penance Mechanism: Companies engage in CSR as a form of penance to offset past Corporate Social
Irresponsibility (CSI)2 (e.g., Heal 2005; Kotchen and Moon 2012).

4. Insurance Mechanism: CSR builds a reservoir of goodwill to attenuate negative reactions if and when
things go wrong, i.e., CSR provides an insurance mechanism against CSI (e.g., Godfrey, Merrill, and
Hansen 2009; Flammer 2013).

The good management, penance, and insurance mechanisms, explicitly or implicitly, postulate

positive effects of CSR on firm performance whereas the slack resources mechanism suggests a positive

effect of firm performance on CSR. Thus, while not mutually exclusive, good management and slack

1 We are not aware of a study that has either identified or examined these four mechanisms simultaneously, as we do
here. We note, however, that some studies have examined the slack resources and good management mechanisms
simultaneously (e.g., Scholtens 2008).
2 We define CSI as firm-induced incidents that appear to hurt the social good, i.e., the antithesis of CSR. BP’s Deepwater

Horizon oil spill in 2010 is an example of a CSI incident. However, we do recognize that firm efforts drive both CSR
initiatives (which can be seen as efforts directly) and CSI incidents; thus, in Appendix A we present a theoretical model
that links CSR and CSI efforts to our measures of CSR initiatives and CSI incidents. As we have annual data, consistent
with our measure of CSR that counts the number of CSR initiatives, our measure of CSI counts the number of CSI
incidents.

3
resources mechanisms propose reverse causal paths. Likewise, while again not mutually exclusive, penance

and insurance mechanisms also propose reverse causal paths. Specifically, the penance mechanism suggests

that firms engage in CSR in time t to offset CSI that occurred in time 𝑡 − 𝑥, 𝑥 ≥ 1, whereas the insurance

mechanism proposes that firms engage in CSR in time 𝑡 − 𝑥, 𝑥 ≥ 1, to insure against CSI in time t.

The key purpose of our study is to investigate these four mechanisms simultaneously and identify

which of them is/are operative. Thus, we further the debate on how doing “good” and doing “well” converge.

Moreover, while addressing the how question, we also shed light on the at least equally important question of

whether doing “good” and doing “well” converge. We find that the answer to the whether question appears to

be “yes”; hence, the answer to the how question has substantial academic and managerial significance.

Of note is that the CSR literature provides empirical support for each one of the four mechanisms;

however, as indicated above, a limitation of the literature is that it has not yet studied the four mechanisms

simultaneously. Indeed, the studies only examine one, and at the most two of the mechanisms (i.e., slack

resources and good management) at a time. Such an approach of studying only one or two mechanisms at a

time might be problematic as important relationships that the unmodeled mechanisms suggest should result

in either a partial picture of the phenomenon or worse yet, false statistical findings (i.e., omitted variable bias).

We will show, for example, that CSR and CSI are significantly correlated. Thus, by modeling only CSR and

firm performance potentially important effects resulting from CSI cannot be teased out. Also, most studies

have employed econometric models that are simplistic and correlational (and not causal) in nature.

Highlighting the issues regarding these models, Margolis et al. (2007, p. 27) urge that “causal mechanisms

need to be […] tested”. Similarly, King and Lenox (2001, p. 107) suggest that if “one cares merely about

correlation and little about causation, these correlative studies are informative [….]. From the perspective of

corporate managers and policy analysts, however, the distinction is critical.” In this study, we follow an

integrative approach and examine all four mechanisms simultaneously. We also use what we deem to be

appropriate econometric techniques to move closer to causality.3 Specifically, recognizing that we have annual

3As we mention subsequently, we take several concrete steps to move closer to causality recognizing that we are relying
on real world data and that experimental data cannot be used to study such complex organizational phenomena.
Recognizing the time series data that we employ (e.g., Demiralp and Hoover 2003), we take the following steps: We

4
data on more than 4,500 firms across 19 years (i.e., large cross section and small time series), that there is a

need to model the interplay among CSR, CSI, and firm value simultaneously, and there might be

contemporaneous effects among the three variables in our annual data, we propose and estimate a structural

panel vector autoregressive (SPVAR) model.

Our results show support for good management and penance mechanisms and not for slack

resources and insurance mechanisms. That is, our empirical findings suggest that firms benefit financially

from CSR as CSR leads to positive financial performance. Moreover, we find that CSR frequently trails CSI

temporally, i.e., that firms seem to use CSR strategically to offset past CSI. Yet, our results also suggest that

the penance mechanism is not effective at compensating for negative effects of CSI.

We proceed as follows: We first elaborate on the four mechanisms that have been proposed in the

literature. Next, we develop our empirical model specification that allows us to examine the dynamic interplay

among CSR, CSI, and firm performance. Subsequently, we present our data and empirical results. We

conclude with a discussion of the implications, as well as limitations, of our research.

BACKGROUND

Extant CSR literature suggests four mechanisms of how CSR and firm performance relate to each

other. As shown in Figure 1, the first two mechanisms (i.e., slack resources and good management

mechanism) are concerned with the direct link between a firm’s CSR and its financial performance whereas

the last two mechanisms (i.e., penance and insurance mechanism) examine the link between CSR and CSI.

The performance implications of CSR are implicit in the latter two mechanisms as CSR is expected to

mitigate the adverse influence of CSI incidents. In the following, we describe the four mechanisms as well as

the relationship among the four mechanisms in more detail. Table 1 shows examples of empirical studies on

the four mechanisms.

ensure that our data are stationary, we simultaneously model CSR, CSI, and firm performance to ensure there is no
omitted simultaneity, and we include contextually grounded contemporaneous effects (which lead to the structural VAR
specification) based on literature to mitigate deleterious effects from temporal aggregation (as we have annual data).
Further, recognizing the panel nature of our data, we include firm- and time-specific fixed effects and adapt the Blundell
and Bond (1998) estimator that uses lagged values and change in lagged values for endogenous variables as instruments
to identify the causal effects.

5
[Insert Figure 1 and Table 1 about here]

Slack Resources Mechanism

A plethora of studies have examined the direct link between a firm’s CSR and its financial

performance (for a survey see, e.g., Margolis et al. 2007). Some of these studies posit that firms engage in CSR

because they are doing well financially. Generally referred to as the slack resources mechanism, supporters of

this link tend to argue that good financial performance provides firms with slack resources which, in turn,

provides the firms with the opportunity to invest in CSR related activities, such as community relations (e.g.,

Waddock and Graves 1997; Orlitzky, Schmidt and Rynes 2003). In addition, proponents of the slack

resources mechanism tend to view CSR activities as voluntary, meaning that managers have a high flexibility

to initiate or cease them. Accordingly, they argue that a firm’s decision to invest in CSR activities largely

depends on the availability of excess cash (McGuire et al. 1988; Chin, Hambrick, and Treviño 2013).

Similarly, advocates of the slack resources mechanism also tend to believe that CSR related activities are not

critical to the success of the firm, i.e., that they fall under the category of discretionary spending, and are

hence especially sensitive to the existence of slack resources (e.g., McGuire et al. 1988).

Supporters of the slack resources mechanism have used various examples to support their

mechanism. For example, Waddock and Graves (1997) reported that IBM had significant philanthropic

programs during good economic times but canceled many of those programs when the going got tougher.

Moreover, Chin, Hambrick and Treviño (2013) report that conservative CEOs pursue CSR only as

performance allows. Also, arguably the most cited scholarly article in support of the slack resources

mechanism is the one by McGuire et al. (1988) in which they find that a firm’s prior performance is more

closely related to its CSR than subsequent performance. Others, such as Preston and O’Bannon (1997),

conclude that the relationship between CSR and financial performance is bi-directional, while Scholtens

(2008) reports that only a few studies have used CSR as the dependent and financial performance as the

independent variable. Thus, empirical substantiation of the slack resources mechanism is relatively sparse.

Good Management Mechanism

6
Most of the extant empirical CSR related research has scrutinized the conception that companies do

“well” by doing “good” (e.g., Barnett and Salomon 2012; Bhattacharya and Sen 2004; Jayachandran,

Kalaignanam, Eilert 2013; Luo and Bhattacharya 2006; Margolis et al. 2007; McWilliams et al. 2006). Of these

studies, roughly 50% find a positive relationship between CSR and financial performance, 25% find no

relationship, 20% find mixed results, and 5% find a negative relationship (Margolis and Walsh 2001;

Scholtens 2008).

Proponents of the doing “well” by doing “good” viewpoint argue that the cost of CSR is lower than

the benefits that accrue from it (e.g., Hull and Rothenberg 2008) and that it is simply a part of good management

to engage in CSR. They suggest, for example, that superior CSR can attract and retain quality employees (e.g.,

Greening and Turban 2000), enhance the morale, productivity, and satisfaction of employees (e.g., Waddock

and Graves 1997), reduce costs by increasing operational efficiencies (e.g., Hart and Ahuja 1996), increase

customer satisfaction (e.g., Luo and Bhattacharya 2006), and help the firm market its products (e.g., Fombrun

1996). Advocates of this link have proposed that CSR can become a source of competitive advantage due to,

for example, the resulting positive stakeholder perceptions of the firm (e.g., Hull and Rothenberg 2008).

Accordingly, scholars who support the positive effect of CSR on financial performance have argued that CSR

improves stakeholder relationships, which leads to positive firm performance (e.g., Hillman and Keim 2001).4

Penance Mechanism

Historically, most research has examined the slack resources and\or good management mechanisms

to address how CSR and firm performance relate to each other; more recently, however, scholars are

beginning to explore other mechanisms. Building on Heal (2005), who proposed that CSR is a program of

actions for firms to reduce externalized costs, Kotchen and Moon (2012) argue that firms engage in CSR as a

form of penance to offset its past CSI. Specifically, Kotchen and Moon (2012) argue that CSR is a type of

4 As indicated above, a small fraction (i.e., about 5%) of the studies that have examined the CSR – financial performance
link reason that CSR results in negative financial performance (e.g., Margolis and Walsh 2001; Scholtens 2008).
Advocates of this negative effect usually argue that CSR unnecessarily raises a firm’s costs (e.g., Aupperle et al. 1985;
McWilliams and Siegel 1997), and that it draws resources away from the core areas of business (e.g., Jensen 2002) which
ultimately results in subpar performance. We note that such an effect would suggest a fifth mechanism -- bad management
mechanism. Yet, since there is little evidence in the literature for this effect, we do not include it here. We note, however,
that our empirical analyses will also test this mechanism.

7
Coasian solution that allows firms to efficiently reduce externalized costs, i.e., costs that the firm has caused

through CSI but that it does not pay back in full. CSR allows the firm to make amends for the unpaid bill.

For example, in the case of an oil spill, the company that caused the spill usually only pays a fraction

of the long-term costs that accrue from the spill, largely because it is impossible to estimate the precise long-

term costs and damage caused. Or when firms treat their workers poorly, it is difficult to gauge the negative

ripple-effect that this poor treatment can have on the individual workers, their families, and the communities

they live in. Yet, there is (primarily non-academic) empirical evidence that shows that firms are penalized if

they are perceived as not holding their end of the bargain, and, conducting their business in ways that conflict

with social norms and values. For example, following the Deepwater Horizon oil spill in 2010, US public

opinion polls were extremely critical of BP’s initial response to the spill, and sales at BP gas stations declined

by as much as 40% (WSJ, 2010). Thus, Kotchen and Moon (2012) argue that firms have an incentive to

engage in CSR because it acts as a penance mechanism that allows the firm to compensate for externalized

costs stemming from past CSI. The performance implications of this approach, of course, are implicit.

Insurance Mechanism

Similar to the penance mechanism, advocates of the insurance mechanism argue that it is imperative

to consider CSR and CSI as separate constructs. Moreover, proponents of the insurance mechanism also view

CSR as a strategic mechanism that can protect against (future) CSI (e.g., Godfrey, Merrill, and Hansen 2009;

Minor and Morgan 2011; Flammer 2013). The difference between the two mechanisms, however, is that the

proponents of the insurance mechanism posit that CSR should not be used as a form of penance to atone for

CSI but rather as insurance against CSI. Thus, compared to the penance mechanism, where CSI in time 𝑡 −

𝑥, 𝑥 ≥ 1, causes CSR in time t, proponents of the insurance mechanism propose that potential CSI in time t

should cause CSR in time 𝑡 − 𝑥, 𝑥 ≥ 1. The insurance mechanism is conceptually grounded in the literature

that suggests that a firm’s good reputation can serve as an intangible asset in times of crises and attenuate

negative stakeholder responses to bad news (e.g., Jones et al. 2000; Schnietz and Epstein 2005; Godfrey,

Merrill, and Hansen 2009), i.e., CSR presumably helps build a reservoir of goodwill among the firm’s

8
stakeholders that endows the firm with idiosyncrasy credits that act as safeguards, i.e., as an insurance, when

bad things, i.e., CSI, happens.

Klein and Dawar (2004) provide empirical support for the notion that CSR acts as an insurance

mechanism against CSI. Specifically, they found that CSR attenuates negative consumer responses in the case

of a product harm crisis. Also, Flammer (2013) finds that the negative stock market reaction to eco-harmful

events is smaller for companies with higher levels of environmental CSR. Further, Minor (2011) and Minor

and Morgan (2011) propose that the primary role of CSR is to increase a firm’s value by insuring the firm

against potential losses caused by future CSI. The performance implications of this mechanism are thus again

implicit; while the returns to CSR during “normal times” might be insignificant, the financial benefits of CSR

during adverse events might be substantial.

Relationship among the Four Mechanisms


Although the four mechanisms described above suggest different causal paths, it is important to note

that they are not necessarily mutually exclusive. For example, while the good management and slack resources

mechanisms propose reverse causal paths (i.e., CSR -> financial performance vs. financial performance ->

CSR), it is possible that both mechanisms are active in a firm. Indeed, while a firm might believe that it will

benefit financially from engaging in CSR, the firm might be more inclined to do so if it is already doing well

financially. Likewise, while the penance and insurance mechanisms also propose reverse causal paths,

respectively, they are again not necessarily mutually exclusive and firms might engage in both. Moreover, it

could also be that firms invest in CSR to build goodwill (i.e., invoke insurance) during times when they have

financial slack. Hence, the insurance and penance mechanisms are also not mutually exclusive. In general,

interdependencies might exist among all four mechanisms, and it hence becomes important to study them

simultaneously.

Summary and Initial Evidence


Although our literature review suggests four mechanisms regarding the relationship between CSR

and firm performance, there has been no attempt to simultaneously study these mechanisms (nor to

summarize these mechanisms as we do here). The majority of the literature focuses on one mechanism at a

9
time (typically on the direct influence of CSR on firm performance outcomes) and thus only paints a partial

picture for the influence of CSR. Further, the dichotomization of CSR into CSR and CSI is a recent

phenomenon (e.g., Groening, Swaminathan, and Mittal 2015; Jayachandran, Kalaignanam, and Eilert 2013;

Kotchen and Moon 2012).5 Finally, as King and Lenox (2001) observe, the methods used in the extant CSR

literature have been either too simplistic, perhaps because they focus on only one mechanism, or simply

inappropriate (also see Margolis et al. 2007; Scholtens 2008).

To further corroborate the misgiving that can stem from correlational analysis focusing on only one

relationship at a time, we resort to model free analysis of our data. As we elaborate subsequently, we have

firm level annual data for up to 19 years (i.e., unbalanced panel) from multiple sources on number of CSR

initiatives, CSI incidents, firm performance (Tobin’s q), and other variables. In Figure 2 (Panel A) we show

the pairwise correlation between a firm’s lagged CSR (i.e., t-1) and its current financial performance (i.e., t) as

well as the pairwise correlation between a firm’s CSR (i.e., t) and its lagged financial performance (i.e., t-1).

As can be seen, the correlation between lagged CSR and financial performance (solid line) is positive

from 1992 to 2002 and close to zero from 2003 to 2009. Thus, one might conclude that firms benefit

financially from CSR (i.e., that the data provides support for the good management mechanism) given the

positive correlation between the two constructs up until 2002. However, a look at the dotted line in Figure 2

(Panel A) reveals that the correlation between lagged financial performance (i.e., t-1) and CSR (i.e., t) looks

quite similar. Indeed, financial performance in t-1 is positively correlated with CSR from 1992 to 2005.

Therefore, based on this “evidence”, one might conclude that companies engage in CSR because they are

doing well financially (i.e., support for the slack resources mechanism).

[Insert Figure 2 about here]

Similarly, in Figure 2 (Panel B) we present the correlation between CSR and CSI. Specifically, the

solid line shows the pairwise correlations between a firm’s lagged CSR (i.e., t-1) and its CSI (i.e., t). As can be

5 Several studies have subtracted a firm’s CSI scores from the firm’s CSR scores to arrive at the firm’s (net) CSR score
(e.g., Waddock and Graves 1997; McWilliams and Siegel 2000; Hull and Rothenberg 2008; Servaes and Tamayo 2013).
However, such an approach assumes that CSR and CSI are equivalent and, e.g., that a good deed fully “writes off” a bad
deed, which is likely not the case.

10
seen, the correlation between lagged CSR and CSI (solid line) increases from .03 in 1993 to .43 in 2003, and

remains at around .40 until 2009. Further, the dotted line in Figure 2 (Panel B) shows the pairwise correlation

between CSR (i.e., t) and lagged CSI (i.e., t-1) and shows a very similar pattern. Thus, paradoxically, these

patterns suggest that firms increasingly tend to do both “good” and “bad”, and, it hence seems sensible to

examine which comes first – CSI or CSR? We note that the correlational analysis again does not shed much

light on whether CSR antecedes CSI or vice versa. The high correlation between CSI and CSR also

emphasizes the importance of including CSI as an additional variable in the CSR – firm performance

framework. Indeed, it is possible that the close to zero correlation between CSR and firm performance

starting around 2003 (as discussed above and shown in Figure 2, Panel A) can be explained by the high

correlation between CSR and CSI starting around that same time, i.e., that the prevalence of CSI canceled out

the otherwise positive performance effects of CSR.

We next develop an empirical model specification that allows us to test for the existence of the four

mechanisms simultaneously.

MODEL

Motivation

Our data is similar to extant CSR literature (e.g., Margolis et al. 2007), in that we have annual

information on CSR initiatives and CSI incidents. We believe that these initiatives and incidents are linked

together by the basic economic concept of firm efforts – where efforts are reflected in initiatives and

determine the incidents. Thus, it is important to provide microeconomic foundations for the relationship

between CSR and firm performance, as such a foundation helps develop “a better understanding of economic

activities and outcomes,” where for us activities relate to CSR and CSI and outcomes to firm performance

(Kreps 1990, p. 7). We thus develop a model based on economic theory (which is an exercise in spirit similar

to Hanssens and Ouyang 2001), which (1) builds on theory of the firm primitives (i.e., profits, sales, and

costs) to view the firm as maximizing net present profit and (2) uses optimal control theory to model the

costs associated with CSR. In the economic theory model we recognize how CSR and CSI influence sales and

costs and, as a result, the optimal solution involves a complex interplay among CSR, CSI, and firm

11
performance. The economic theory model also suggests that our empirical model specification should capture

the simultaneous interplay among CSR, CSI, and firm performance. For exposition purposes we provide

details on the economic theory model in Appendix A.

Model Development

As already mentioned earlier, we have annual panel data on firms, where we observe firm

performance (Tobin’s q) and the firms’ levels of CSR and CSI. Recognizing that we have panel data on a large

number of firms as well as a system of equations, and that we seek to model dynamics, we employ a panel

vector autoregression (PVAR) specification (e.g., Holtz-Eakin et al. 1988, Love and Zicchino 2006). Further,

as we have annual-level data, it seems reasonable to assume that there are contemporaneous effects among

some of the focal variables (i.e., CSR, CSI, and firm performance). Hence, we employ a structural PVAR

(SPVAR) specification where a vector of endogenous variables is linearly represented by its current and

lagged effects (e.g., Cooley and Dwyer 1998, Enders 2004). In particular, we specify the relationship among

CSR, CSI and firm performance through a system of three equations. The first equation assesses the effect of

prior CSR, prior CSI, and prior firm performance on current CSI. The second equation assesses the effect of

prior CSR, prior and current CSI, and prior firm performance on current CSR. Finally, the third equation

assesses the effect of prior and current CSR, prior and current CSI, and prior firm performance on current

firm performance. We note that we control for several other variables (e.g., ROA, firm size) that may also

have an impact on the three focal variables. In summary, the three equations form a system of equations that

allows us to understand the dynamic interplay among CSR, CSI and firm performance, and we estimate the

following SPVAR model:


𝑃 𝑃 𝑃 𝐶𝑆𝐼𝑖(𝑡−𝑝)
𝐶𝑆𝐼𝑖𝑡 𝜆11 𝜆12 𝜆13
(1) A × [ 𝐶𝑆𝑅𝑖𝑡 ] = ∑𝑃𝑝=1 [𝜆𝑃21 𝜆𝑃22 𝑃
𝜆23 ] [ 𝐶𝑆𝑅 𝑖(𝑡−𝑝) ]
𝑇𝑜𝑏𝑖𝑛′ 𝑠 𝑞𝑖𝑡 𝜆𝑃31 𝜆𝑃32 𝑃
𝜆33 𝑇𝑜𝑏𝑖𝑛 ′
𝑠 𝑞𝑖(𝑡−𝑝)

θ𝑐𝑜𝑛,𝐶𝑆𝐼 𝑋𝑖𝑡 + 𝜂𝐶𝑆𝐼,𝑖 + ΓCSI 𝐷 𝜑𝐶𝑆𝐼 𝑖𝑡


+[ θ𝑐𝑜𝑛,𝐶𝑆𝑅 𝑖𝑡𝑋 + 𝜂𝐶𝑆𝑅,𝑖 + ΓCSR 𝐷 ] +[ 𝜑𝐶𝑆𝑅 𝑖𝑡 ]
θ𝑐𝑜𝑛,𝑇𝑜𝑏𝑖𝑛′ 𝑠𝑞 𝑋𝑖𝑡 + 𝜂 𝑇𝑜𝑏𝑖𝑛′ 𝑠𝑞,𝑖 + Γ𝑇𝑜𝑏𝑖𝑛′ 𝑠𝑞 𝐷 𝜑 𝑇𝑜𝑏𝑖𝑛′ 𝑠 𝑞 𝑖𝑡

𝑃 𝑃 𝑃 𝐶𝑆𝐼𝑖(𝑡−𝑝)
𝑃 𝜆11 𝜆12 𝜆13
= ∑ [𝜆𝑃21 𝜆𝑃22 𝑃
𝜆23 ] [ 𝐶𝑆𝑅 𝑖(𝑡−𝑝) ] + Θcon 𝑋𝑖𝑡 + Ηi + Γ𝐷 + 𝜑𝑖𝑡 ,

𝑝=1 𝜆𝑃
31 𝜆𝑃32 𝑃
𝜆33 𝑇𝑜𝑏𝑖𝑛 𝑠 𝑞𝑖(𝑡−𝑝)

12
1 0 0
where, A = [−𝛼21 1 0] and 𝑖 = 1,2, … , N is the firm index, 𝑡 ∈ {T0 , T1 , … , T} is the time period
−𝛼31 −𝛼32 1

index, 𝐶𝑆𝐼, 𝐶𝑆𝑅, and 𝑇𝑜𝑏𝑖𝑛′ 𝑠 𝑞 are the endogenous variables in the system, yit =

[𝐶𝑆𝐼𝑖𝑡 , 𝐶𝑆𝑅𝑖𝑡 , 𝑇𝑜𝑏𝑖𝑛′ 𝑠 𝑞𝑖𝑡 ]′ , A is the (3 × 3) matrix which indicates the contemporaneous relationships

among the endogenous variables, where 𝛼21 , 𝛼31 , and 𝛼32 represent the contemporaneous effect of CSI on

CSR, the contemporaneous effect of CSI on Tobin’s q, and the contemporaneous effect of CSR on Tobin’s
𝑃 𝑃 𝑃
𝜆11 𝜆12 𝜆13
𝑃
q, respectively, [𝜆21 𝑃 𝑃 are the coefficient matrices of the lags of the endogenous variables where
𝜆22 𝜆23 ]
𝜆𝑃31 𝜆𝑃32 𝜆𝑃33

𝑃 𝑃
𝜆12 , 𝜆13 , 𝜆𝑃21, and 𝜆𝑃31 (𝑝 = 1, … , 𝑃) are associated with the four mechanisms, i.e., slack resources, good

management, penance, and insurance mechanism, respectively, 𝑃 is the number of lags, 𝑋𝑖𝑡 is the (K × 1)

vector of the control variables for firm 𝑖 at time 𝑡 (i.e., ROA, log(employee), financial leverage, advertising-to-

sales, and R&D-to-sales), where K is the number of control variables, Θcon =



[θ𝑐𝑜𝑛,𝐶𝑆𝐼 , 𝜃𝑐𝑜𝑛,𝐶𝑆𝑅 , 𝜃𝑐𝑜𝑛,𝑇𝑜𝑏𝑖𝑛′𝑠𝑞 ] where θcon,. are the (1 × K) vector of coefficients of the control variables


for each equation, Ηi = [𝜂𝐶𝑆𝐼,𝑖 , 𝜂𝐶𝑆𝑅,𝑖 , 𝜂 𝑇𝑜𝑏𝑖𝑛′ 𝑠𝑞,𝑖 ] where 𝜂.,𝑖 is the unobserved firm-specific fixed effect for

firm 𝑖, D = [𝑑1991 , ⋯ , 𝑑2009 ]′ is the (T × 1) vector of year dummies where 𝑑𝑡 = 1 if year = 𝑡; 𝑑𝑡 =

0 𝑜𝑡ℎ𝑒𝑟𝑤𝑖𝑠𝑒, Γ = [ΓCSI , ΓCSR , Γ𝑇𝑜𝑏𝑖𝑛′ 𝑠𝑞 ]′ where Γ. is the (1 × T) vector of coefficients of the year-fixed


effect, T is the number of time periods, and 𝜑𝑖𝑡 = [𝜑𝐶𝑆𝐼 𝑖𝑡 , 𝜑𝐶𝑆𝑅 𝑖𝑡 , 𝜑𝑇𝑜𝑏𝑖𝑛′ 𝑠 𝑞 ] is the error term for the
𝑖𝑡


system of equations. Also the composite error term 𝜔𝑖𝑡 = [𝜔𝐶𝑆𝐼 𝑖𝑡 , 𝜔𝐶𝑆𝑅 𝑖𝑡 , 𝜔 𝑇𝑜𝑏𝑖𝑛′ 𝑠 𝑞 ] is expressed as the
𝑖𝑡

usual ‘fixed effect’ decomposition, where 𝜔𝑖𝑡 ≡ 𝐻𝑖 + 𝜑𝑖𝑡 .

Further, we assume that 𝜑𝑖𝑡 is independently and identically distributed across 𝑖 and 𝑡 with the

assumption that 𝐸(𝜑𝑖𝑡 |𝑦𝑖(𝑡−1) , … , 𝑦𝑖(𝑡−𝑝) ) = 0 𝑓𝑜𝑟 0 ≤ 𝑡 ≤ 𝑇 and, 𝐸(𝜑𝑖𝑡 𝜑𝑖𝑡 ′|𝑦𝑖(𝑡−1) , … , 𝑦𝑖(𝑡−𝑝) ) =

Σ , 𝑓𝑜𝑟 𝑖 = 𝑗 𝑎𝑛𝑑 𝑡 = 𝑠
{ 𝜑 } , 𝑓𝑜𝑟 0 ≤ 𝑡 ≤ 𝑠 ≤ 𝑇
0, 𝑜𝑡ℎ𝑒𝑟𝑤𝑖𝑠𝑒

13
where Σ𝜑 is a positive definite matrix.6

Contemporaneous Effects

Compared to the reduced-form PVAR specification, our SPVAR model is multiplied by the matrix A

to account for potential contemporaneous effects. We use theoretical elaboration, as suggested by Iyengar,

Van den Bulte, and Lee (2015), to identify the contemporaneous relationship among firm performance, CSR

and CSI. In particular, we assume that CSI has a contemporaneous effect on CSR (i.e., 𝛼21 ≠ 0) as at least

some firms should engage in CSR activities shortly after CSI occurred to attenuate negative consumer

responses (e.g., following its toy recall in late 2007, Mattel started testing every production batch of toys for

containing potentially dangerous levels of chemicals and toxins). However, we do not see any reasons why

CSI incidents should occur immediately after the firm engaged in CSR. Of note is also that firms often do not

time and/or have control over when CSI occurs. Oil spills, for example, almost always happen by accident,

and the likelihood of them occurring before or after CSR would hence be the same.

Further, we also assume that CSI has a contemporaneous effect on firm performance (i.e., 𝛼31 ≠ 0).

Indeed, firms’ stock prices often decrease after a significant CSI incident occurred (e.g., BP’s stock price

decreased after the oil spill in 2010; also see Flammer 2013). Yet, although firm performance might have a

longer-term effect on CSI (i.e., when firm performance keeps declining, firms might eventually take shortcuts

which could increase the likelihood of CSI occurring in the future) short-term firm performance should not

have a contemporaneous effect on CSI. Finally, we assume that CSR has a contemporaneous effect on firm

performance (i.e., 𝛼32 ≠ 0), but not vice versa. As shown by Chollet and Cellier’s (2011) event study, CSR

announcements can influence short-term firm performance. However, our discussions with numerous senior

executives suggest that firms evaluate and plan their CSR activities and goals annually (or even less

frequently). Hence, it is highly unlikely that they would change their CSR strategy based on short-term firm

performance. Moreover, as mentioned previously, we employ Tobin’s q to capture firm performance in this

6This assumption ensures that the equation-by-equation estimator (e.g., Arellano and Bond 1991; Blundell and Bond
1998) is asymptotically equivalent to the corresponding system-of-equations estimator of PVAR models (Cao and Sun
2011).

14
study. Considering that Tobin’s q is a market-based performance measure, any changes in CSR or CSI should

get captured by it contemporaneously.

We conducted a survey among twenty-five US-based senior executives to validate our identification

restrictions. The survey results provided strong support for our assumptions. For example, in support of the

contemporaneous effect from CSI to CSR, most executives confirmed that they would engage in CSR

immediately after CSI occurred because, in their opinion, stakeholders would want to see the company “make

things right again”. Moreover, in support of our argument that firm performance does not have a

contemporaneous effect on CSR, we asked the executives how often they change their CSR strategy. 80% of

the respondents reported that, unless CSI occurred, they change their CSR strategy “annually” or even less

frequent, and that short-term firm performance does not affect their firm’s CSR.

In summary, we let the matrix A be a lower triangle matrix since we believe there are no

contemporaneous effects on CSI from CSR and firm performance and on CSR from firm performance.

Thus, we use this recursive causal ordering to identify the structural parameters in the matrix A (please see the

Web Appendix for details regarding our estimation procedure).

DATA AND METHOD

KLD Social Ratings Database

We obtained corporate social performance data from the Kinder, Lydenberg, and Domini (KLD)

Social Ratings Database. This database has been widely used in the academic literature (e.g., Hull and

Rothenberg 2008; Kotchen and Moon 2012), and it provides annual data on firms’ performance in seven

social issue areas, including community, corporate governance, diversity, employee relations, environment,

human rights and product quality and safety. Further, the KLD database provides multiple indicators

regarding a firm’s strengths and concerns in each of the seven social issue areas. For instance, the community

area consists of eight strength indicators (e.g., charitable giving, support for housing, support for education)

and six concern indicators (e.g., investment controversies, negative economic impact). The KLD data begins

in 1991, and we used the complete KLD dataset up until 2009. We note that KLD substantially changed its

inventory of strength and concern indicators in 2010, making comparability to prior years very tenuous (e.g.,

15
Chin, Hambrick, and Treviño 2013).Hence, all firms for which KLD provides data for the time period

between 1991 and 2009 constituted our initial sample. In Table 2 we list all strength and concern indicators

across the seven issue areas. Overall, the database covers around 80 indicators.

[Insert Table 2 about here]

Consistent with Kotchen and Moon (2012), we consider all strength indicators as CSR and all

concern indicators as CSI of the firm. Further, the KLD database provides a yearly binary summary of a

firm’s strengths (i.e., CSR) and concerns (i.e., CSI) for each indicator belonging to the seven social issue areas.

For example, if a firm has consistently given over 1.5% of trailing three-year net earnings before taxes to

charity, then the “charitable giving” CSR indicator for the firm and year is coded as 1, otherwise 0. To

determine each firm’s CSR in a given year, we followed Kotchen and Moon’s (2012) approach and summed

up the firm’s scores of all “strength” items in and across all seven issue areas. We repeated the same

procedure to determine each firm’s CSI in a given year summing up the scores of all “concern” items in and

across all seven issue areas. Thus, for each year, we calculated two scores for each firm – one representing the

firm’s overall CSR and the other one its overall CSI. We note that this procedure places equal weight on each

item. Next, we created the standardized overall CSR and CSI scores for each firm and year: Z(CSR(I))it =

̅̅̅̅̅̅̅̅̅̅̅𝑡
𝐶𝑆𝑅(𝐼)𝑖𝑡 −𝐶𝑆𝑅(𝐼)
s.d.(CSR(I)t )
), where Z(CSR(I))it is the standardized CSR(I) score for firm 𝑖 and year 𝑡, 𝐶𝑆𝑅(𝐼)𝑖𝑡 is the

̅̅̅̅̅̅̅̅̅̅̅𝑡 is the average CSR(I) score in year 𝑡, and s. d. (CSR(I)t )


original CSR(I) score for firm 𝑖 and year 𝑡, 𝐶𝑆𝑅(𝐼)

is the standard deviation of CSR(I) score in year 𝑡.

Following recent CSR and CSI research (e.g., Kotchen and Moon 2012), we standardized the scores

for two reasons: First, some of the CSR and CSI items were added and/or removed over the years. Thus, the

total number of CSR and CSI items varies over time (as mentioned earlier, we include time fixed-effects in

our model specification which also controls for this change in items). For example, the support for education

(CSR) item, which is one of the strengths in the community area, exists only since 1994. Second, the number

of firms included in the KLD database also varies over time. For instance, the KLD database includes

approximately 650 firms from 1991 to 2000, approximately 1,100 firms from 2001 and 2002, and

16
approximately 3,100 firms from 2003 onwards. Hence, we used standardized CSR and CSI scores in our

analysis to minimize the effect of different samples sizes.

Financial Variables

We obtained financial performance data as well as control variables for as many of our initial sample

firms and years as possible using COMPUSTAT, our second data source. We selected Tobin’s q as our firm

performance measure because it is a market-based measure which reflects the investors’ long-term

expectation of the firm’s future earnings (Miller 2004). In contrast to short-term marketing efforts, such as

promotions, the financial benefits of CSR activities might only manifest over time. For example, Cox et al.

(2004) argue that improved corporate social performance should lead to significant financial gains only in the

long run. Hence, compared to accounting-based financial performance measures such as return on asset

(ROA) or return on equity (ROE) which only capture short-term performance, Tobin’s q is a more

appropriate financial performance measure to understand the benefits as well as potential costs of a firm’s

social performance (see Germann, Ebbes, and Grewal 2015). We calculated Tobin’s q using the method

proposed by Chung and Pruitt (1994).

Control Variables

It is important to account for firm-, industry-, and economy-specific variables, because the market

valuation of a firm (Tobin’s q) can depend on these factors (e.g., Lee and Grewal 2004). To account for firm-

specific variables, we include financial leverage, ROA, and firm size as control variables. Financial leverage

should be negatively related with Tobin’s q, ROA, which reflects current period profitability, should be

positively related with Tobin’s q, and firm size should be negatively related with Tobin's q (Jayachandran,

Kalaignanam, and Eilert 2013). Moreover, we also include R&D intensity (i.e., the ratio of R&D to sales) as a

control variable because extant research has shown that product innovations positively impact Tobin’s q (e.g.,

Sorescu and Spanjol 2008) as well as a firm’s CSR strategy (Luo and Bhattacharya 2009). We also control for

advertising intensity (i.e., the ratio of advertising to sales) because advertising intensity is known to, on the

one hand, positively impact sales and brand equity and thus Tobin’s q (e.g., Sethuraman, Tellis, and Briesch

2011; Sorescu and Spanjol 2008; Sridhar, Narayanan, and Srinivasan 2014), and, on the other hand, impact

17
the firm’s CSR strategy (Luo and Bhattacharya 2009). Finally, as already mentioned earlier, we include firm

and time fixed-effects in our model specification to tease out industry idiosyncrasies (including those that

might impact Tobin’s q calculations) with firm fixed-effects and boom and bust periods with time fixed-

effects.

Our final sample, which is an unbalanced panel with time gaps, consists of approximately 4,500

firms, 24,500 data points, and data from 1991 to 2009 after removing several outliers whose Tobin’s q is

greater than 15. In addition, our sample firms are publically traded firms from a wide range of industries. We

present the descriptive statistics in Table 3.

[Insert Table 3 about here]

Data Analysis Approach

We performed our analysis as follows: First, we tested for stationarity and unit roots. Second, we

estimated the dynamic panel GMM model using the Blundell and Bond estimator. Third, we applied these

estimators to each equation in the reduced-form PVAR system and recovered the contemporaneous effects

based on the identification restrictions. Finally, we estimated the dynamics of the carryover effects (over time)

using generalized impulse response functions.

Stationarity in time series. To ensure that our analysis does not produce spurious results, we used the

Augmented Dickey-Fuller test (ADF; Dickey and Fuller 1979) to examine stationarity and unit root for each

time series to determine whether the underlying data generation process of each variable is evolving over time

or is stationary (Granger and Newbold 1974). We note that since we have unbalanced panel data with time

gaps, the Im-Pesaran-Shin (2003) unit root test, which has been widely used to test individual unit root

processes, cannot be used. We also note that we tested stationarity after first-differencing as our model

estimation is based on the first-difference.

Impulse response functions. To examine the dynamic effect of one endogenous variable on another, we

used impulse response functions (IRFs). Generalized IRFs (Dekimpe and Hanssens 1999; Pesaran and Shin

1998) trace the effect that a one unit (e.g., one standard deviation) shock to one variable in the system has on

another variable over subsequent time periods while holding all other variables’ shocks equal to zero. We

18
derived the generalized orthogonal IRFs by using the panel GMM estimates and the variance-covariance

̂𝜐 ).7 Further, we used Monte Carlo simulation to obtain upper and


matrix of the reduced-form residual (Σ

lower 95% confidence bands (see Doan 1992).

RESULTS

We present the results in the following order: (1) unit root tests, (2) SPVAR estimates, and (3) IRF

results, and follow this with a post-hoc analysis.

Stationarity and Unit Root Tests

As we show in Table 4, the null hypothesis of unit root is rejected for all three variables of interest.

Further, ADF test statistics of the first-differenced CSI, CSR and Tobin’s q variables are -74.937, -97.229, and

-50.413, respectively (p < .05); thus, our focal variables are first-difference stationary.

[Insert Table 4 about here]

Model Estimation and Optimal Lags Selection

In the first step of our two-step estimation procedure (see Web Appendix), we estimated a reduced-

form VAR model using the Blundell and Bond estimator. We first determined the optimal number of lags 𝑝,

where, consistent with research on dynamic panel data models (e.g., Huang et al. 2008), we use the mj statistic

(where j stands for the order of autocorrelation) suggested by Arellano and Bond (1991). The idea behind the

mj statistic is that the residual from the dynamic panel data model should be free of serial autocorrelation.

Doornik et al. (2006) propose that if the error term υit is not serially correlated, there would be significant

and negative first order serial correlation in the differenced residuals (i.e., 𝜐̂ 𝑖(𝑡−1) ) and no significant
𝑖𝑡 − 𝜐̂

second order serial correlation. Thus, we examined the m1 and m2 statistic and obtain the optimal number of

lags when the m1 statistic is negative and statistically significant and the m2 statistic is not statistically

significant. Table 6 (AB Test rows) illustrates the first and second order serial autocorrelation results. In the

equation in which CSI is the dependent variable, the m1 statistic is negative and statistically significant (m1 = -

7 We derived the impulse response functions based on the variance-covariance matrix of the reduced-form residual (Σ ̂𝜐 )
̂
rather than the structural-form residual (Σ𝜑 ) because this approach allows us to relax the need to impose a recursive
ordering (Dekimpe and Hanssens 1999).

19
3.21) while the m2 statistic is not significant at the .05 level (m2 = -1.72) when the number of lags specified is

2. Similarly, in the equation in which CSR is the dependent variable, a two lags specification satisfies the

criterion suggested by Arellano and Bond (1991) (m1 = -2.35 and m2 = -.94) at the .05 significance level. The

two lags specification in the equation in which Tobin’s q is the dependent variable is also sufficient to remove

the serial autocorrelation in the residual (m1 =-4.80 and m2 =.29). Thus, the optimal lag length for our

dynamic panel data model is two.

In the second step of our two-step process, we estimated the contemporaneous effects from the

variance-covariance matrix of residuals from the reduced-form PVAR model. The results in Table 5 suggest

that as the level of CSI increases, the level of CSR increases (α21 = 1.522, p < .05 ); thus, it seems that firms

increase the level of CSR engagement reactively to cope with their current CSI practices. This result suggests

that the penance mechanism holds contemporaneously. Further, the level of CSR has a positive impact on

firm performance ( α32 = .395, p < .05) which suggests doing “good” leads to doing “well” immediately in

support of the good management mechanism. The contemporaneous effect of CSI on firm performance is

negative, which suggests the current level of CSI practices decreases firm performance ( 𝛼31 = −.962, 𝑝 < .05).

[Insert Table 5 about here]

We present the estimation results from the reduced-form PVAR model with a two lags specification

in Table 6. We test the validity of the instruments using the Hansen (1982) test of over-identifying

restrictions. The null hypothesis that instruments are over-identified is not rejected for all three estimations.

Yet, it is difficult to understand the effect of one endogenous variable on another variable by examining the

estimates in Table 6. Instead, to understand the dynamic effect of the independent variables on the dependent

variable, we need to investigate IRFs which take into account the dynamic interplay among the variables.

[Insert Table 6 about here]

Impulse Response Functions (IRFs)

As we are interested in testing the four mechanisms, i.e., whether and how doing “good” and doing

“well” converge, we focus on the relationship between CSR and CSI and the relationship between CSR and

firm performance for generating IRFs. In Figure 3, we present the graphs of the IRFs for these two

20
relationships along with the 95% confidence bands generated by the Monte Carlo simulation. In Panel A of

Figure 3 we show the relationship between CSR and firm performance, where in Graph 1 of Panel A we

show the response of firm performance to a CSR shock. In support of the good management mechanism,

Graph 1 shows that CSR influences firm performance positively in the short run (.75% increase) and that this

positive effect fades away after about a year. Further, in Graph 2 we show that a shock to Tobin’s q does not

seem to have a positive impact on CSR. Hence, the slack resources mechanism is not supported.

In Panel B of Figure 3 we depict the relationship between CSR and CSI. As Graph 1 in Panel B

shows, CSR does not have a positive effect on CSI. Thus, the insurance mechanism which suggests that CSR

antecedes CSI in a positive manner is not supported. This result implies that an increase in a firm’s CSR effort

does not lead to an increase in the level of future CSI. Further, in support of the penance mechanism, in

Graph 2 in Panel B we show that there is a positive impact of CSI on CSR that lasts for about 1 year.

[Insert Figure 3 about here]

In summary, our results provide empirical support for the good management and penance

mechanisms. In contrast, our results do not support the slack resources and insurance mechanisms. We

elaborate on these findings in the discussion section.

Post-hoc Analysis: Is CSR a Potent Penance Mechanism?

Given that our empirical results suggest that firms tend to engage in the penance mechanism, we

next sought to investigate whether the penance mechanism actually makes amends for firms’ past CSI. To

that end, we first investigated the performance implications of CSI using IRFs. The black line in Figure 4

shows the response of firm performance to a CSI shock. As one would expect, CSI has a negative influence

on firm performance.

[Insert Figure 4 about here]

To examine the effectiveness of the penance mechanism, we next estimated a restricted (as opposed

to an unrestricted) IRF, i.e., we estimated the effect of CSI on firm performance without allowing CSR to have

an impact on either CSI or performance. While (unrestricted) IRFs examine the effect of one variable on the

full dynamic system, restricted impulse response functions pose a restriction on a subset of the endogenous

21
variables and thus allow researchers to investigate the effect of one variable on the partial dynamic system

(see Pauwels (2004) for technical details).8

The gray line in Figure 4 illustrates the effect of CSI on firm performance under the dynamic system

without CSR. Of note is that the largest negative effect of CSI on firm performance is the same in the

restricted as well as the unrestricted estimation (i.e., -.338 at year 0). In addition, the negative effect of CSI on

firm performance fades away between year 1 and 2, regardless of whether the firms’ CSR is considered in the

dynamic system or not. These findings suggest that CSR does not shield from or attenuate the negative

performance implications of CSI. Thus, while firms seem to strategically use CSR to compensate for past CSI

(i.e., engage in the penance mechanism), the effort seems fruitless from a firm performance perspective.

DISCUSSION
To address the questions of whether and how CSR relates to firm performance, we seek to

simultaneously model four mechanisms that have been proposed in the literature: slack resources, good

management, penance, and insurance. Given the identified mechanisms and the KLD and performance data

available, we propose a SPVAR empirical specification to empirically model the interplay among CSR, CSI,

and firm performance, and to simultaneously test for the four mechanisms. We now discuss the theoretical

and managerial contributions and implications of our research.

Theoretical Contributions

The literature on why firms engage in CSR is quite scattered. We summarize the varying propositions

and integrate them into four mechanisms, and we test and model these four mechanisms simultaneously.

Existing literature (e.g., Kotchen and Moon 2012; Luo and Bhattacharya 2006; Margolis et al. 2007) has

studied and modeled only one or at best two mechanisms simultaneously; such an approach, however, is

cumbersome as it does not permit addressing concomitant effects among the four mechanisms resulting in

either a partial picture or even false statistical findings. As our model-free evidence showed, CSR and CSI are

8 The use of restricted IRFs might be subject to Lucas’ (1976) critique (e.g., Franses 2005; van Heerde, Dekimpe, and
Putsis 2005), as the restriction changes the underlying data generation process by putting an (arbitrary) assumption on
the data generation process. Cognizant of this critique, we want to emphasize that we use restricted IRFs in addition to
generalized IRFs.

22
(paradoxically) fairly highly correlated (r ≈ .4) starting around the year 2003, indicating that omitting CSI from

the CSR-firm performance link might yield misleading findings. Thus, we separate CSI from CSR, and, more

importantly, integrate the CSI construct into the CSR-financial performance framework. As should be

evident, separating CSI from the CSR construct is meaningful because failure to do so can effectively cancel

out important granularities in the data. We note that many past studies have simply averaged a firm’s CSR and

CSI scores into one overall CSR score (e.g., Waddock and Graves 1997; McWilliams and Siegel 2000; Hull

and Rothenberg 2008). However, such an approach assumes that one bad deed (i.e., CSI) effectively cancels

out one good deed (i.e., CSR; and vice versa), which is highly questionable.

Our modeling approach, new to the CSR literature, offers several advantages. As already mentioned

above, we model the four mechanisms simultaneously thus allowing for the possibility of finding evidence for

each of the mechanisms and correcting for the possibility of any statistical simultaneity bias. Also, we use the

SPVAR model for a large number of firms (around 4,500) up to a period of 19 years. Thus, the SPVAR

specification enables us to benefit from the time series and panel nature of our data and get as close to

causality as possible with non-experimental data. With stationary, time series data we can account for

simultaneity, one source of identification issue, by simultaneously modeling CSR, CSI, and firm performance

and also mitigate deleterious effects from temporal aggregation (as we have annual data) by including

contemporaneous effects (which lead to the structural VAR specification; e.g., Demiralp and Hoover 2003).

The panel nature of our data also enables us to include firm-specific fixed-effects to account for unobserved

heterogeneity, and the Blundell and Bond (1998) estimator, which we adapt, uses lagged values and change in

lagged values for endogenous variables as instruments to identify the causal effects. Thus, we do establish

near causality for the influence of CSR (and CSI) on firm performance. In the process, we provide insights

for Margolis et al.’s (2007, p. 4) assertion that “if only doing “good” could be connected to doing “well”, then

companies might be persuaded to act more conscientiously.” Specifically, we provide empirical evidence that

CSR investments have a positive impact on firm performance. We consider this a highly noteworthy finding

given, on the one hand, the rigorous methods we use and, on the other hand, the ongoing, complex debate

about whether doing good implies doing well.

23
Managerial Implications

We summarize the managerial implications of our research in Table 7. Foremost, our finding that

“doing good” leads to “doing well” should be of particular relevance to managers. Hopefully it will encourage

managers and their respective firms to act more conscientiously. Moreover, our study also shows that CSI has

a significant negative effect on firm performance. Although not necessarily surprising, aside from event studies

(e.g., Chen et al. 2009; Flammer 2013), there is little empirical evidence that demonstrates the negative

performance effects of CSI using a largescale dataset as we do here.

[Insert Table 7 about here]

To further assess the negative impact of CSI on firm performance, we estimated a two-variable

SPVAR model including only CSR and Tobin’s q, and excluding CSI. The resulting positive performance

effects of CSR were roughly four-times larger when not considering CSI in the system (we present the results

in Figure WA1 in the Web Appendix). On the one hand, this finding illustrates that not including all three

variables in the system results in significantly biased estimates, in support of our integrated approach. On the

other hand, this result also suggests that firms without CSI incidents might see a significantly greater

performance boost from their CSR investments than what the (average) positive effect of our three-variable

SPVAR indicates.

Increasingly, however, firms appear to engage in both CSR and CSI, i.e., as mentioned above,

increasingly firms do both “good” and “bad”. Indeed, Figure 2 (Panel B) shows that the correlation between

firms’ CSR and CSI has increased significantly since the year 2000. So the question becomes: How do CSR

and CSI converge? Our integrated analysis of the four mechanisms allows us to shed light on that question.

Specifically, our model results indicate that many firms ramp up their CSR shortly after a CSI incident

occurred. While we can only speculate, we conjecture that recent consumer trends, and in particular

consumers wanting firms to be better corporate citizens (e.g., Ipsos 2013), have significantly contributed to

the increase in correlation between CSR and CSI. This consumer trend is further revealed in the media

attention CSR has received over the years. We searched through Factiva and, considering the years 1979 –

2014, counted the number of newspaper articles that referenced the term “CSR” in each year. As depicted in

24
Figure WA2 in the Web Appendix, the results revealed that there has been a significant increase in the

number of articles on CSR over the years. Moreover, the number of CSR-related articles has increased

exponentially since the year 2000, i.e., when the correlation between CSR and CSI started increasing as well.

Hence, firms might engage in CSR following CSI in an effort to make amends for their past missteps thereby

hoping to appease their stakeholders. However, because we simultaneously model CSR, CSI, and firm

performance, and based on the results from our restricted IRF, our results indicate that using CSR for

penance reasons does not pay off financially.

A few potential explanations for the ineffectiveness of the penance mechanism come to mind.

Perhaps stakeholders interpret firms’ CSR efforts following CSI as unauthentic or even as deceitful, seeking

to “greenwash” their past mistakes. Furthermore, when firms engage in CSR to make amends for past CSI,

perhaps stakeholders view those efforts as a sign that the CSI is more severe than they had initially thought.

Such an interpretation would be consistent with Chen et al. (2009) who show that when product recalls occur,

proactive recall strategies result in more severe negative stock market responses than reactive ones. Future

research should investigate these conjectures.

Rather than following CSI with CSR, firms might be better advised to use CSR to build a reservoir of

goodwill to insure against CSI if and when it happens. Indeed, Flammer (2013) shows that the negative stock-

market reactions to eco-harmful events are smaller for companies with higher levels of previous

environmental CSR. Similarly, Godfrey, Merrill, and Hansen’s (2009) research suggests that CSR leads to

positive attributions from stakeholders who then temper their negative judgments and sanctions towards

firms when CSI occurs because of the accrued goodwill (also see Minor and Morgan 2011). Yet, our results

indicate that most firms do not employ CSR in this manner. That is, we do not find empirical support for the

insurance mechanism. Instead, firms that engage in both CSR and CSI tend to invest in CSR after CSI

occurred. Perhaps our findings pertaining to the ineffectiveness of the penance mechanisms coupled with

those of Flammer (2013) and Godfrey, Merrill, and Hansen (2009) and others will encourage firms to

consider CSR as a form of insurance in the future. A word of caution, however, seems warranted: While CSR

might insure a firm against relatively harmless (future) CSI, it might act as a liability if severe CSI occurs.

25
Indeed, Germann et al. (2014) find that high levels of brand commitment attenuate negative consumer

responses in low-severity product recalls but augment them in high-severity product recalls. Correspondingly,

while a reputation for CSR might provide a reservoir of goodwill against non-severe CSI, it might increase

scrutiny, akin to a contrast effect, if severe CSI occurs. We hope that future research will examine this

proposition.

Finally, we show that the slack resources mechanism is not active. In fact, our results indicate that

slack resources might actually lead to a decrease in CSR, although not until a few years later. Post-hoc

interviews with eleven executives shed at least some light on this somewhat puzzling finding: In a nutshell, all

executives acknowledged that when their firms’ performance increases suddenly, they will generally not

increase their “non-business-related” investments (e.g., CSR) in an effort to not jeopardize the pending

lucrative annual compensation (e.g., high boni due to the strong performance). Future research should further

investigate this potential explanation.

In summary, our model results indicate that there are two types of firms that pursue CSR. On the

one hand, there are firms that invest in CSR not because they are doing well financially but (we speculate)

because they believe that it is the “right” thing to do. While these companies might engage in CSR for

seemingly altruistic reasons, they can expect to see significant financial returns from their CSR investments.

On the other hand, there appear to be firms that engage in CSR to make amends for their past CSI. Yet,

these firms likely see little if any positive effects from their CSR investments.

Limitations

While we believe that we have broken some new ground with this research, there are clear

limitations, some of which might provide fruitful avenues for future research. For example, a potential

limitation that we must acknowledge is the CSR and CSI data that we employ. Although the KLD data has

been used extensively in existing research, the CSR and CSI measures are based on somewhat subjective

rather than objective evaluations. Future research should try to replicate our findings using different CSR and

CSI data. Unfortunately, as we write this, we are not aware of a source that could provide such data (other

than KLD, of course).

26
Further, although we believe that the identification restrictions we imposed to estimate the SPVAR

model are sensible, we need to acknowledge that our results are sensitive to them (e.g., Uhlig 2005).

Moreover, we ignore normative issues, such as the question of whether ethical behavior has value regardless

of the financial payoff. Correspondingly, we do not reference the large normative literature on corporate

ethics and social responsibility. Also, we treat all CSR and CSI as equally “good” and “bad”. However,

treating, for example, a substantially underfunded defined pension plan the same way as a deep water oil spill

is likely a stretch. Future research should develop a way to classify the various CSI captured in the KLD data

in terms of their severity.

Conclusion
Scholars have scrutinized the conception that companies do “well” by doing “good” for decades

(e.g., McWilliams et al. 2006). However, debates on whether and how doing “good” and doing “well” converge

continue to rage (e.g., Mackey et al. 2007). While our study might not resolve the ongoing, complex debates,

we believe that our selection of the four mechanisms and the three-way fit among those mechanisms, the

KLD data, and our chosen methods and analyses, sheds new light on an old problem. We hope that our

research helps firms make better CSR decisions, and that it also encourages academics to further explore the

performance implications of CSR.

27
Appendix A
Economic Theory Model

Overview

We suggest that firms seek to maximize the present value of their future profits where these profits

depend on sales and costs. We also suggest that efforts related to CSR and CSI avoidance9 influence sales and

that there are costs associated with these efforts. Costs associated with CSR are the direct costs the firm

expends on CSR efforts such as donating to a charitable cause (e.g., Coca Cola donating bottled water during

hurricane Katrina). It is important to note that the costs of CSR efforts are private information for the firm,

while the outcomes are publically observed; however, efforts should drive observed outcomes. Thus, our

economic theory model focuses on CSR efforts and our empirical model on observed CSR; the link between

the two should be apparent. Similar to CSR, costs associated with CSI avoidance efforts are also direct costs

(e.g., Exxon Mobil reinforcing the hulls of its crude oil transportation ships to reduce the probability of oil

leaks when accidents occur). Further, here again CSI avoidance efforts are private information for the firm

while level of CSI is publically observed. Nonetheless, CSI avoidance efforts should relate directly (and

negatively) to CSI incidents and thus, the link between the economic theory model that focuses on CSI

avoidance efforts and the empirical model that focuses on CSI incidents is similar to that for CSR. The

distinction between CSR efforts and CSI avoidance efforts is in the outcomes; while CSR efforts seek to do

good, CSI avoidance efforts seek to avoid the bad. For our CSR-CSI context, we model the costs associated

through the expected loss and buffering effects of CSR efforts and CSI avoidance efforts.

As we conclude, the solution to the economic theory model should have a structure where optimal

CSR efforts are a function of CSI avoidance efforts and sales, and, in turn, where optimal CSI avoidance efforts

depend on CSR efforts and sales. Recognizing that firm values depend on these two efforts, we can conclude

that an empirical model to study CSR, CSI, and firm value should incorporate the dynamic interplay among

CSR, CSI, and firm value.

Economic Model

9We include what we refer to as CSI avoidance efforts in our economic theory model to capture the costs associated
with avoiding CSI.

28
We rely on the basic economic notion that firms seek to maximize utilities and profits to develop a

theoretical model for the effect of CSR and CSI; specifically, we use primitives from theory of the firm (e.g.,

Becker 2007, Chapter 5). Within the theory of the firm framework, profit maximizing can be subsumed

within utility maximization, such that a “firm may act as if it maximized a utility function that depends not

only on its profits, but also on color, sex, and family background of employees” i.e., CSR and CSI (Becker

2007, p. 70); thus, we focus on long-term profit maximization. In this framework, we define profits (π) at a

given time t as:

(A1) 𝜋𝑡 = ℝ𝑡 − ℂ𝑡 ,

where, ℝ and ℂ represent revenues and costs, respectively.

With the profit function described in equation A1, we seek to develop a dynamic optimization

problem for a firm where the firm chooses an optimal level of efforts for CSR and efforts to avoid CSI. To

lay out this specification we represent revenues as (where × is the product operator): ℝ𝑡 = 𝑚 × 𝑆𝑡 (e.g., Naik

and Raman 2003), where m represents the margins that account for all expenses other than those associated

with CSR and CSI and 𝑆𝑡 is the sales at time t; thus ℂ𝑡 can be seen as the costs associated with CSR and CSI.

If ρ represents the discount rate and 𝑟𝑡 and 𝑖𝑡 CSR efforts and efforts to avoid CSI respectively, ∀ 𝑡 ∈

[0, ∞), then the firms net present value of its current and future profits (Ψ) can be given as:
∞ ∞ ∞
(A2) Ψ(𝑟, 𝑖) = ∫0 𝑒 −𝜌𝑡 × 𝜋𝑡 𝑑𝑡 = ∫0 𝑒 −𝜌𝑡 × (ℝ𝑡 − ℂ𝑡 ) 𝑑𝑡 = ∫0 𝑒 −𝜌𝑡 × (𝑚 × 𝑆𝑡 − ℂ𝑡 ) 𝑑𝑡

Equation A2 represents continuous time infinite horizon profit flows and, as is common in this

literature (e.g., Rao 1986), we will not index variables by t to facilitate reading. As is typical in dynamic

optimization (e.g., Kamien and Schwartz 1991; Sethi and Thompson 2006), we seek to maximize equation A2

subject to constraints that emanate due to the dynamic response function of sales 𝑆; that is:

(A3a) max ∫ 𝑒 −𝜌𝑡 × (𝑚 × 𝑆 − ℂ(𝑟, 𝑖)) dt
𝑟≥0,𝑖≥0 0

subject to:

𝑑𝑆
(A3b) 𝑑𝑡
= 𝑔𝑆 (𝑆, 𝑟, 𝑖)

where, 𝑔𝑆 (. ) is an appropriate dynamic response function for sales.

29
In the parlance of optimal control theory (e.g., Kamien and Schwartz 1991), S represents the state

variable and r and i are the control variables (i.e., variables that firms make decisions on). To maximize the

system in equation A3, we define the Hamiltonian ℋ(𝑟, 𝑖, 𝜇) as:

(A4) ℋ(𝑟, 𝑖, 𝜇) = (𝑚 × 𝑆 − ℂ(𝑟, 𝑖)) + 𝜇 × (𝑔𝑆 (𝑆, 𝑟, 𝑖))

where, 𝜇 is the costate variable.

At optimality, the necessary conditions, which are sufficient when ℋ is concave in 𝑟 and 𝑖, are (e.g.,

Kamien and Schwartz 1991):

𝜕ℋ 𝜕ℋ 𝑑𝜇 𝜕ℋ
(A5) = 0; = 0; 𝑎𝑛𝑑 =𝜌×𝜇− =0
𝜕𝑟 𝜕𝑖 𝑑𝑡 𝜕𝑆

With this dynamic CSR decision problem in place, we now seek to develop the specification for cost
𝑑𝑆
ℂ(𝑟, 𝑖) and evolution of sales as specified in = 𝑔𝑆 (𝑆, 𝑟, 𝑖).
𝑑𝑡

Cost Function Specification

There are three components for the CSR relevant costs that we need to consider. First we need to

consider the direct costs associated with CSR efforts r. Firms exert such efforts to promote social causes; for

example, for every pair of shoes that TOMS sells, it donates one to a child in need (known as the “one for

one” model). Thus, we use the function 𝑔𝑅 (𝑟) to represent these costs, where 𝑔𝑅 (. ) is a typical continuous

twice differentiable indirect cost function that satisfies properties of cost functions (e.g., Kreps 1990, p. 251-

253). As costs typically increase with efforts and are convex, a popular form for costs is quadratic (e.g., Naik
1
and Raman 2003), such that one could specify 𝑔𝑅 (𝑟) = 2 𝑟 2 .

Second, similar to CSR efforts r, one needs to consider costs associated with direct CSI avoidance

efforts i. Firms exert these CSI avoidance efforts to reduce the probability of CSI incidents. For example,

accidents during the transportation of crude oil are imminent; thus, oil firms such as Exxon Mobil reinforce

the hulls of their transportation ships to reduce the probability of oil leaks when such accidents occur. Thus,

CSR efforts represent doing social good, while CSI avoidance efforts serve to reduce harm from CSI

incidents. Similar to CSR efforts, we use the function 𝑔𝐼 (𝑖) to represent costs associated with CSI avoidance

1
efforts. Again, a quadratic functional form can be used for such costs, i.e., 𝑔𝐼 (𝑖) = 𝑖 2 .
2

30
Third, we need to consider the costs that firms can expect to incur when CSI incidents occur;

examples of such incidents include oil spills as in the case of BP or unforeseen product harm crises. As CSI is

associated with incidents, we model the costs associated through expected loss 𝕀 and the buffering effects of

CSR and CSI avoidance efforts. Expected loss 𝕀 can be seen as a firm-specific typical or average loss

associated with a CSI incident; for example, for a firm in a particular business, 𝕀 could represent the average

over the last 10 years. To specify these buffering effects we recognize that the buffering effects should

increase as efforts increase and there should be some difference in the buffering between CSR efforts and

CSI avoidance efforts. Thus, we specify the costs due to such incidents as: 𝑔𝕀 (𝑟, 𝑖) = 𝕀 × 𝑒 −𝜃×(𝑟+𝜆×𝑖) , where

𝜃, 𝜆 ∈ [0, ∞). As efforts r and i are positive and θ and λ are positive, the expression “𝜃 × (𝑟 + 𝜆 × 𝑖)” is

positive and thus as efforts increase, 𝑒 −(𝑟+𝜆×𝑖) → 0; thus efforts reduce the costs associated with CSI

incidents. Further, θ instruments the nature of the buffering effect of efforts; 𝜃 = 1 implies that the level of

CSR efforts proportionally reduce expected loss; 𝜃 < 1, implies that the translation of efforts for expected

loss is lower than when 𝜃 = 1; 𝜃 > 1 implies an amplification of efforts such that the translation of efforts is

higher than 𝜃 = 1. λ ensures that the effects of CSR efforts r are different from those of CSI avoidance

efforts i. If λ is less than 1, then CSR efforts buffer more than CSI avoidance efforts; if λ is equal to 1, then

both efforts buffer equally; and if λ is greater than 1, then CSI avoidance efforts buffer more than CSR

efforts.

With the above discussion, we can write the costs as:


1 1
(A6) ℂ(𝑟, 𝑖) = 𝑔𝑅 (𝑟) + 𝑔𝐼 (𝑖) + 𝑔𝕀 (𝑟, 𝑖) = 2 𝑟 2 + 2 𝑖 2 + 𝕀 × 𝑒 −𝜃×(𝑟+𝜆×𝑖)

Sales Function Specification

As is typical in optimal control applications in marketing, we need to specify the evolution of the

sales function S (e.g., Naik and Raman 2003), which serves as a constraint in the Hamiltonian specification

(equation A3b). Thus, now we elaborate on the functional form of 𝑔𝑆 (𝑆, 𝑟, 𝑖). We recognize that change in

𝑑𝑆
sales ( ) should be a function of CSR efforts and CSI avoidance efforts and the level of sales (i.e., consistent
𝑑𝑡

with extant research, we do expect persistence in sales; e.g., Sridhar et al. 2011). Further, it is reasonable to

31
expect that the efficacy of CSR efforts and CSI avoidance efforts depends on the level of sales. For example,

larger firms (i.e., firms that have higher sales) tend to be better known, and better known firms tend to get

scrutinized, i.e., condemned, more often by the media than smaller firms (e.g., Brooks et al.2003). Thus, it

seems reasonable to assume that larger firms’ CSR efforts and CSI avoidance efforts also receive greater

𝑑𝑆
scrutiny by the media. Hence, in our specification for 𝑑𝑡 , we include the interaction between CSR efforts and

sales and CSI avoidance efforts and sales, i.e.,:

𝑑𝑆
(A7) 𝑑𝑡
= 𝑔𝑆 (𝑆, 𝑟, 𝑖) = 𝛽𝑟 × 𝑟 + 𝛽𝑖 × 𝑖 + 𝛽𝑆 × 𝑆 + 𝛽𝑟𝑆 × 𝑟 × 𝑆 + 𝛽𝑖𝑆 × 𝑖 × 𝑆

Profit Maximization

Optimal efforts for CSR and CSI avoidance , i.e., r and i respectively, can be obtained by maximizing

infinite horizon profits, i.e., firm value given in equation A2. To maximize firm value in equation A2, the cost

function and evolution of sales function in equations A6 and A7 are substituted into the Hamiltonian in

equation A4, which gives us:

(A8) ℋ(𝑟, 𝑖, 𝜇) = (𝑚 × 𝑆 − ℂ(𝑟, 𝑖)) + 𝜇 × (𝑔𝑆 (𝑆, 𝑟, 𝑖)) = 𝑚 × 𝑆 − (𝑔𝑅 (𝑟) + 𝑔𝐼 (𝑖) + 𝑔𝕀 (𝑟, 𝑖)) + 𝜇 ×

1 1
(𝑔𝑆 (𝑆, 𝑟, 𝑖)) = 𝑚 × 𝑆 − ( 𝑟 2 + 𝑖 2 + 𝕀 × 𝑒 −𝜃×(𝑟+𝜆×𝑖) ) + 𝜇 × (𝛽𝑟 × 𝑟 + 𝛽𝑖 × 𝑖 + 𝛽𝑆 × 𝑆 + 𝛽𝑟𝑆 × 𝑟 ×
2 2

𝑆 + 𝛽𝑖𝑆 × 𝑖 × 𝑆)

With the Hamiltonian in equation A8, the first order conditions would be:

𝜕ℋ
(A9a) = −𝑟 + 𝕀 × 𝜃 × 𝑒 −𝜃×(𝑟+𝜆×𝑖) + 𝜇 × (𝛽𝑟 + 𝛽𝑟𝑆 × 𝑆) = 0
𝜕𝑟

𝜕ℋ
(A9b) 𝜕𝑖
= −𝑖 + 𝕀 × 𝜃 × 𝜆 × 𝑒 −𝜃×(𝑟+𝜆×𝑖) + 𝜇 × (𝛽𝑖 + 𝛽𝑖𝑆 × 𝑆) = 0

𝑑𝜇 𝜕ℋ
(A9c) 𝑑𝑡
=𝜌×𝜇− 𝜕𝑆
= −𝑚 − 𝜇 × (𝜌 + 𝛽𝑆 + 𝛽𝑟𝑆 × 𝑟 + 𝛽𝑖𝑆 × 𝑖)

In theory one could solve equations A9a and A9b for efforts r and i as functions of other parameters

including the costate variable 𝜇. However, due to the presence of the exponent (with both r and i in the

exponent), these equations are referred to as transcendental equations that require the use of the Lambert W

function and thus, numerical methods to solve them (e.g., Hayes 2005). To solve for 𝜇 one has to use the

32
𝑑𝑆
transversality conditions obtained from steady-state conditions on state and costate variables, i.e., 𝑑𝑡 = 0 and

𝑑𝜇
𝑑𝑡
= 0 respectively.10

Although we cannot derive the analytic solution from equations A9a-c, based on optimal control

theory literature (e.g., Naik, Raman, and Winer 2005), we can speculate on the structure of the possible

solution. For example, the solution for optimal CSR efforts r* from equation A9a would suggest these

optimal efforts are a function of CSI avoidance efforts i and sales S. A similar conclusion can be reached for

optimal CSI avoidance efforts i*. Further, recognizing that firm values depend on these two efforts, we can

conclude that the empirical model to study CSR, CSI, and firm value should incorporate the dynamic

interplay among the three variables.

10We consider two alternate specifications for costs associated with CSI incidents, i.e., 𝑔𝕀 (. ). For both these
specifications, we do not make changes to expected loss 𝕀 but argue that the buffering effect depends only on CSR
efforts r. As expected losses 𝕀 can be seen as a typical or average firm-specific loss associated with a CSI incident, CSI
avoidance efforts should reduce the probability of CSI incidents, and, as a result, the benefits of CSI avoidance efforts i
are built into 𝕀. Thus, buffering effects only depend on CSR efforts r. To specify these buffering effects we recognize
that the buffering effects should increase as efforts increase. Thus, there are two options to specify these efforts: (1)
similar to our earlier specification we use the exponential function to specify 𝑔𝕀 (𝑟) = 𝕀 × 𝑒 −(𝜆𝑟 ×𝑟) and (2) we can use a
𝜃 ×𝕀
much simpler inverse function, such that: 𝑔𝕀 (𝑟) = 𝑟 , where 𝜃𝑟 ∈ [0, ∞). In this second specification, as efforts r are
𝑟
𝜃 ×𝕀
positive, the expected loss 𝕀 is positive, 𝜃𝑟 is positive, and the expression 𝑟 is positive and decreases as effort r
𝑟
increases; thus CSR efforts reduce the costs associated with CSI incidents. If 𝜃𝑟 is less than 1, then the buffering effect
of CSR efforts is amplified, if 𝜃𝑟 equals 1 then the CSR efforts proportionally reduce expected loss, and if 𝜃𝑟 is greater
than 1, then CSR efforts do not have much of a buffering effect. The solution to the first specification, where 𝑔𝕀 (𝑟) =
𝕀 × 𝑒 −(𝜆×𝑟) , would still involve the Lambert W function and the use of numerical methods. The solution to the second
𝜃×𝕀
specification, where 𝑔𝕀 (𝑟) = , would lead to a cubic functional form for r and a linear functional form for i; thus
𝑟
there would be three solutions for r and one for i.

33
REFERENCES
Arellano, Manuel and Stephen Bond (1991), “Some Tests of Specification for Panel Data: Monte Carlo
Evidence and an Application to Employment Equations,” The Review of Economic Studies, 58(2), 277–
297.
Aupperle, Kenneth E., Archie B. Carroll, and John D. Hatfield (1985), “An Empirical Examination of the
Relationship between Corporate Social Responsibility and Profitability,” Academy of Management
Journal, 28(2), 446-463.
Barnett, Michael L., and Robert M. Salomon (2012), “Does It Pay to Be Really Good? Addressing the Shape
of the Relationship between Social and Financial Performance,” Strategic Management Journal, 33(11),
1304–20.
Becker, Gary S. (2007), Economic Theory, New Brunswick, NJ, Transaction Publishers.
Bhattacharya, C.B. and Sankar Sen (2004), “Doing Better at Doing Good: When, Why, and How Consumers
Respond to Corporate Social Initiatives,” California Management Review, 47(1), 9 – 24.
Blundell, Richard, and Stephen Bond (1998), “Initial Conditions and Moment Restrictions in Dynamic Panel
Data Models,” Journal of Econometrics, 87(1), 115–143.
Brooks, Margaret E., Scott Highhouse, Steven S. Russell, and David C. Mohr (2003), “Familiarity,
Ambivalence, and Organization Reputation: Is Corporate Fame a Double-Edged Sword?” Journal of
Applied Psychology, 88(5), 904-914.
Cao, Bolong, and Yixiao Sun (2011), “Asymptotic Distributions of Impulse Response Functions in Short
Panel Vector Autoregressions,” Journal of Econometrics, 163(2), 127–143.
Chin, M. K., Donald C. Hambrick, and Linda K. Treviño (2013), “Political Ideologies of CEOs: The
Influence of Executives’ Values on Corporate Social Responsibility,” Administrative Science Quarterly, 58,
197-232.
Chen, Yubo, Shankar Ganesan, and Yong Liu (2009), “Does a Firm’s Product-Recall Strategy Affect Its
Financial Value? An Examination of Strategic Alternatives during Product-Harm Crises,” Journal of
Marketing, 73 (6), 214–26.
Choi, In (2001), “Unit Root Tests for Panel Data,” Journal of International Money and Finance, 20 (2), 249–72.
Chollet, Pierre and Alexis Cellier (2011), “The Impact of Corporate Social Responsibility Rating
Announcements on European Stock Prices,” International Conference of the French Finance Association
(AFFI), May 11-13.
Chung, Kee H., and Stephen W. Pruitt (1994), “A Simple Approximation of Tobin’s q,” Financial Management,
23(3), 70–74.
Cooley, Thomas F., and Mark Dwyer (1998), “Business Cycle Analysis Without Much Theory A Look at
Structural VARs,” Journal of Econometrics, 83(1-2), 57–88.
Cox, Paul, Stephen Brammer, and Andrew Millington (2004), “An Empirical Examination of Institutional
Investor Preferences for Corporate Social Performance,” Journal of Business Ethics, 52(1), 27–43.
Dekimpe, Marnik G., and Dominique M. Hanssens (1999), “Sustained Spending and Persistent Response: A
New Look at Long-Term Marketing Profitability,” Journal of Marketing Research, 36(4), 397–412.
Demiralp, Selva and Kevid D. Hoover (2003), “Searching for Causal Structure in Vector Autogregression,”
Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, 65, 745-767.
Dickey, David A., and Wayne A. Fuller (1979), “Distribution of the Estimators for Autoregressive Time
Series With a Unit Root.” Journal of the American Statistical Association, 74(366), 427–431.

34
Doan, Thomas A. (1992), RATS user’s manual, version 4. Evanton, IL: Estima.
Doornik, Jurgen A., Manuel Arellano, and Stephen Bond (2006), “Panel Data Estimation using DPD for
Ox,” Mimeo
Enders, Walter (2004), Applied Econometric Time Series, Wiley, Hoboken, NJ.
Flammer, Caroline (2013), “Corporate Social Responsibility and Shareholder Reaction: The Environmental
Awareness of Investors,” Academy of Management Journal, 56(3), 758-781.
Fombrun, Charles J. (1996), Reputation: Realizing Value from the Corporate Image. Harvard Business Press.
Franses, Philip Hans (2005), “On the Use of Econometric Models for Policy Simulation in Marketing,”
Journal of Marketing Research, 42 (1), 4-14.
Granger, Clive W. J. and Paul Newbold (1974), “Spurious Regressions in Econometrics,” Journal of
Econometrics, 2(2), 111–120.
Greening, Daniel W., and Daniel B. Turban (2000), “Corporate Social Performance As a Competitive
Advantage in Attracting a Quality Workforce,” Business & Society, 39(3), 254–280.
Germann, Frank, Peter Ebbes, and Rajdeep Grewal (2015), “The Chief Marketing Officer Matters!,” Journal of
Marketing, 79(3), 1-22.
_____, Rajdeep Grewal, William T. Ross Jr, and Rajendra K. Srivastava (2014) "Product Recalls and the
Moderating Role of Brand Commitment," Marketing Letters, 25(2), 179-191.
Godfrey, Paul C., Craig B. Merrill, and Jared M. Hansen (2009), “The Relationship between Corporate Social
Responsibility and Shareholder Value: An Empirical Test of the Risk Management Hypothesis,”
Strategic Management Journal, 30(4), 425–45.
Groening, Christopher, Vanitha Swaminathan, and Vikas Mittal (2015), “A Contingency Framework of
Firm’s Corporate Social Responsibility Profile and Firm Value,” Working Paper.
Hansen, Lars Peter (1982), “Large Sample Properties of Generalized Method of Moments Estimators,”
Econometrica, 50 (4), 1029–54.
Hanssens, Dominique M. and Ming Ouyang (2001), “Hysteresis in market response: When is marketing
spending an investment?,” Review of Marketing Science, Vol. 419. Social Science Research Network
Electronic Library (SSRN).
Hart, Stuart L., and Gautam Ahuja (1996), “Does It Pay to Be Green? An Empirical Examination of the
Relationship Between Emission Reduction and Firm Performance,” Business Strategy and the
Environment, 5(1), 30–37.
Hayes, Brian (2005), “Why W?” American Scientist, 93 (March-April), 104-108.
Heal, Geoffrey (2005), “Corporate Social Responsibility: An Economic and Financial Framework,” The
Geneva Papers on Risk and Insurance - Issues and Practice, 30(3), 387–409.
Hillman, Amy J., and Gerald D. Keim (2001), “Shareholder Value, Stakeholder Management, and Social
Issues: What’s the Bottom Line?” Strategic Management Journal, 22(2), 125-139.
Holtz-Eakin, Douglas, Whitney Newey, and Harvey S. Rosen (1988), “Estimating Vector Autoregressions
with Panel Data,” Econometrica, 56(6), 1371–1395.
Huang, Bwo-Nung, M.J. Hwang, and C.W. Yang (2008), “Causal Relationship Between Energy Consumption
and GDP Growth Revisited: A Dynamic Panel Data Approach,” Ecological Economics, 67(1), 41–54.
Hull, Clyde Eiríkur, and Sandra Rothenberg (2008), “Firm Performance : the Interactions of Corporate Social
Performance with Innovation and Industry Differentiation,” Strategic Management Journal, 29(7), 781-
789.

35
Im, Kyung So, M.Hashem Pesaran, and Yongcheol Shin (2003), “Testing for Unit Roots in Heterogeneous
Panels,” Journal of Econometrics, 115(1), 53–74.
Ipsos (2013), “Eight out of ten Australians Rate Corporate Social Responsibility as Important,” accessed July
20, 2014 [available at http://ipsos.com.au/wp-content/uploads/2013/06/Corporate-social-
responsibility-media-release-FINAL.pdf].
Iyengar, Raghuram, Christophe Van den Bulte, and Jae Young Lee (2015),"Social Contagion in New Product
Trial and Repeat," Marketing Science, 34(3), 408-429.
Jayachandran, Satish, Kartik Kalaignanam, and A. Meike Eilert (2013), “Product and Environmental Social
Performance: Varying Effect on Firm performance,” Strategic Management Journal, 35, 1255-1264.
Jensen, Michael C. (2002), “Value Maximization, Stakeholder Theory, and the Corporate Objective
Function,” Business Ethics Quarterly, 12(2), 235-25.
Jones, Gary H., Jones, Beth H., & Philip Little (2000), “Reputation as Reservoir: Buffering Against Loss in
Times of Economic Crisis,” Corporate Reputation Review, 3(1), 21–29.
Kamien, M. and N. Schwartz (1991), Dynamic Optimization: The Calculus of Variation and Optimal Control in
Economics and Management, Amsterdam, Elsevier.
Kotchen, Matthew J., and Jon Jungbien Moon (2012), “Corporate Social Responsibility for Irresponsibility,”
The B.E. Journal of Economic Analysis & Policy: Vol. 12: Iss. 1 (Contribution), Article 55.
King, Andrew, & Michael J. Lenox (2001), “Does it Really Pay to be Green? Accounting for Strategy
Selection in the Relationship Between Environmental and Financial Performance,” Journal of Industrial
Ecology, 5(1), 105-116.
Klein, Jill and Niraj Dawar (2004), “Corporate Social Responsibility and Consumers’ Attributions and Brand
Evaluations in a Product-harm Crisis,” International Journal of Research in Marketing, 21(3), 203-217.
Kreps, D. M. (1990), A Course in Microeconomic Theory, Princeton, NJ Princeton University Press.
Lee, Ruby P. and Rajdeep Grewal (2004), "Strategic Responses to New Technologies and Their Impact on
Firm Performance," Journal of Marketing, 68(4), p. 157-171.
Love, Inessa, and Lea Zicchino (2006), “Financial Development and Dynamic Investment Behavior:
Evidence from Panel VAR,” The Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance 46(2), 190–210.
Lucas, Robert E. (1976), “Econometric Policy Evaluation: A Critique,” Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on
Public Policy, 1 (1), 19-46.
Luo, Xueming, and C.B Bhattacharya (2006), “Corporate Social Responsibility, Customer Satisfaction, and
Market Value,” Journal of Marketing, 70(4), 1–18.
_____, and _____ (2009), “The Debate over Doing Good: Corporate Social Performance, Strategic
Marketing Levers, and Firm-Idiosyncratic Risk,” Journal of Marketing, 73(4), 198–213.
Mackey, Alison, Tyson B. Mackey, and Jay B. Barney (2007), “Corporate Social Responsibility and Firm
Performance: Investor Preferences and Corporate Strategies,” Academy of Management Review, 32(3),
817-835.
Margolis, Joshua, and James Walsh (2001), People and Profits: The Search for A Link Between A Company’s Social
and Financial Performance. Psychology Press.
_____, Hillary Elfenbein, and James Walsh (2007), “Does It Pay to be Good? A Meta-Analysis and
Redirection of Research on the Relationship Between Corporate Social and Financial Performance,”
Working Paper Harvard University.
McGuire, Jean B., Alison Sundgren, and Thomas Schneeweis (1988), “Corporate Social Responsibility and
Firm Financial Performance,” The Academy of Management Journal, 31(4), 854–872.

36
McWilliams, Abagail, and Donald Siegel (1997), “Event Studies in Management Research: Theoretical and
Empirical Issues,” The Academy of Management Journal, 40(3), 626–657.
_____ and _____ (2000), “Corporate Social Responsibility and Financial Performance: Correlation or
Misspecification?” Strategic Management Journal, 21(5), 603–9.
_____ and _____ (2001), “Corporate Social Responsibility: A Theory of the Firm Perspective,” The Academy
of Management Review, 26(1), 117–127.
_____, _____, and Patrick M. Wright (2006), “Corporate Social Responsibility: Strategic Implications*,”
Journal of Management Studies, 43(1), 1–18.
Miller, Douglas J. (2004), “Firms’ Technological Resources and the Performance Effects of Diversification: A
Longitudinal Study,” Strategic Management Journal, 25(11), 1097–1119.
Minor, Dylan (2011), “Corporate Citizenship as Insurance: Theory and Evidence,” working paper.
_____, and John Morgan (2011), “CSR as Reputation Insurance: PRIMUM NON NOCERE,” California
Management Review, 53(3), 40–59.
Muller, Alan, and Roman Kräussl (2011), "Doing Good Deeds in Times of Need: A Strategic Perspective on
Corporate Disaster Donations," Strategic Management Journal, 32(9), 911-929.
Naik, P. A. and K. Raman (2003), “Understanding the Impact of Synergy in Multimedia Communications,”
Journal of Marketing Research, 40(4), 375-388.
_____, _____, and Russell S. Winer (2005), “Planning Marketing-Mix Strategies in the Presence of
Interaction Effects,” Marketing Science, 24(1), 25-34.
Orlitzky, Marc, Frank L. Schmidt, and Sara L. Rynes (2003), “Corporate Social and Financial Performance: A
Meta-Analysis,” Organization Studies, 24(3), 403–41.
Pauwels, Koen (2004), “How Dynamic Consumer Response, Competitor Response, Company Support, and
Company Inertia Shape Long-term Marketing Effectiveness,” Marketing Science, 23(4), 596-610.
Pesaran, H. Hashem, and Yongcheol Shin (1998), “Generalized Impulse Response Analysis in Linear
Multivariate Models,” Economics Letters, 58(1), 17–29.
Preston, Lee E. and Douglas P. O’Bannon (1997), “The Corporate Social-Financial Performance
Relationship,” Business and Society, 36(4), 419-429.
Rao, R. C. (1986), “Estimating Continuous Time Advertising-Sales Models,” Maketing Science 5(2), 125-142.
Reputation Intelligence (2013), “Too Many Feelings and not Enough Facts in CSR Strategy,” accessed July
27, 2014 [available at http://reputationinstitute.com/frames/knowledge-
center/intelligence_files/v5n5/RepIntel_v5n5_csr_strategy.pdf].
Schnietz, Karen E., and Marc J. Epstein (2005), “Exploring the Financial Value of a Reputation for Corporate
Social Responsibility During a Crisis,” Corporate Reputation Review, 7(4), 327–345.
Scholtens, Bert (2008), “A Note on the Interaction Between Corporate Social Responsibility and Financial
Performance,” Ecological Economics, 68(1–2), 46–55.
Servaes, Henri, and Ane Tamayo (2013), “The Impact of Corporate Social Responsibility on Firm Value: The
Role of Customer Awareness,” Management Science, 59(5), 1045-1061.
Sethi, S. P. and G. L. Thompson (2006), Optimal Control Theory: Applications to Management Science and Economics,
Norwell, MA, Kluwer Academic Publishers.
Sethuraman, Raj, Gerard J. Tellis, and Richard Briesch (2011), “How Well Does Advertising Work?
Generalizations from a Meta-Analysis of Brand Advertising Elasticity,” Journal of Marketing Research,
48(3), 457-471.

37
Sorescu, Alina B. and Jelena Spanjol (2008), “Innovation’s Effect on Firm Value and Risk: Insights from
Consumer Packaged Goods,” Journal of Marketing, 72(2), 114-132.
Sridhar, Shrihari, M. K. Mantrala, P. A. Naik and E. Thorson (2011), “Dynamic Marketing Budgeting for
Platform Firms: Theory, Evidence, and Application,” Journal of Marketing Research, 48(6), 929-943.
_____, Sriram Narayanan and Raji Srinivasan (2014), “Dynamic Relationships Among R&D, Advertising,
Inventory and Firm Performance,” Journal of the Academy of Marketing Science, 42(3), 277-290.
Uhlig, Harald (2005) “What Are the Effects of Monetary Policy on Output? Results from an Agnostic
Identification Procedure,” Journal of Monetary Economics 52(2), 381–419.
van Heerde, Harald J., Marnik Dekimpe, and William P. Putsis Jr. (2005), “Marketing Models and the Lucas
Critique,” Journal of Marketing Research, 41 (1), 15-21.
Waddock, Sandra A., and Samuel B. Graves (1997), “The Corporate Social Performance-Financial
Performance Link,” Strategic Management Journal, 18(4), 303-319.

38
Table 1
EXAMPLES OF EMPIRICAL STUDIES ON THE FOUR MECHANISMS

Other
Representative Empirical Key Insights Pertaining to
Mechanism Mechanisms Empirical Basis
Papers Approach the Four Mechanisms
Examined
Data on 131 publically
traded firms’ CSR
covered in the Fortune A firm’s prior performance is
McGuire
Good Ordinary Least survey of corporate more closely related to CSR
Sundgren, and
Management Squares (OLS) reputations between than is subsequent firm
Schneeweis (1988)
1983 and 1985; firm performance.
performance from 1977
Slack Resources
and 1984.
Data on up to 249 Conservative CEOs pursue
publically traded firms’ CSR initiatives only as
Chin, Hambrick, Generalized
Good CSR initiatives between performance allows whereas
and Treviño Estimating
Management 2005 and 2009. Authors liberal CEOs emphasize CSR
(2013) Equation
use KLD data to capture even when recent firm
the firms’ CSR. performance is low.
CSR is a driver of customer
Data on 113 publically
satisfaction which in turn
traded firms for the
drives firm performance.
Luo and Structural 2001-2004 periods; firms
Notably, CSR reduces
Bhattacharya Slack Resources Equation are covered in the ACSI
customer satisfaction and
(2006) Modeling and Fortune’s America’s
hence performance among
Most Admired
firms with low innovativeness
Good Corporations survey
capability
Management
Product social performance
Data on 518 publically (PSP) has a positive impact on
Jayachandran, traded firms (3701 firm- financial performance. Also,
Hierarchical
Kalaignanam, and years). Authors use KLD PSP weakness harms firm
Linear Modeling
Eilert (2013) data to capture the firms’ performance more than PSP
CSR. strength helps firm
performance.
Performance and CSR
Pooled OLS,
data on all firms listed in
Kotchen and between-effects Firms engage in CSR in order
Insurance the KLD database
Moon (2012) and fixed-effects to offset past CSI.
(~3,000) from 1991 to
models
2005.
Penance Firms’ reputation for CSI was
Data on 354 publically associated with the greatest
Muller and Kräussl Event Study and traded firms. Authors likelihood of making a
(2011) OLS use KLD data to capture subsequent charitable donation
the firms’ CSI. in response to Hurricane
Katrina.
Data on 178 negative
events caused by
Prior CSR provides insurance-
Godfrey, Merrill, Event Study and publically traded firms
like benefits to the firms that
and Hansen (2009) OLS between 1993 and 2003.
caused negative events.
Author uses KLD data
to capture firms’ CSR.
Insurance Data on 156 eco-
harmful events caused Negative stock-market
by publically traded reactions to eco-harmful
Event Study and
Flammer (2013) firms between 1980 and announcements are smaller for
OLS
2009. Author uses KLD firms with higher levels of
data to capture firms’ environmental CSR.
CSR.

39
Table 2
STRENGTH AND CONCERN ITEMS OF THE KLD SOCIAL RATINGS DATABASE

Qualitative Issue Type Categories # of


Area Categories
Charitable giving, Innovative giving
Non-US Charitable giving
Support for Housing
Strengths Support for Education (added ‘94) 8
Indigenous Peoples Relations (added ‘00, moved ‘02)
Community Volunteer Programs (added ‘05)
Other Strength
Investment Controversies
Negative Economic Impact
Concerns Indigenous Peoples Relations (‘00-’01) 5
Tax Disputes (added ‘05)
Other Concerns
Limited Compensation
Ownership Strength
Strengths Transparency Strength (added ‘05) 5
Political Accountability Strength (added ‘05)
Corporative Other Strength
Governance High Compensation
Ownership Concern
Accounting Concern (added ‘05)
Concerns 6
Transparency Concern (added ‘05)
Political Accountability Concern (added ‘05)
Other Concerns
CEO
Promotion
Board of Directors
Work/Life Benefits
Strengths 8
Women & Minority Contracting
Diversity
Employment of the Disabled
Gay & Lesbian Policies
Other Strength
Controversies
Concerns Non-Representation 3
Other Concerns
Union Relations
No-Layoff Policy (ended ‘94)
Cash Profit Sharing
Strengths 7
Employee Involvement
Employee Retirement Benefits Strength
Relations Health and Safety Strength / Other Strengths
Union Relations
Health and Safety Concern
Concerns Workforce Reductions 5
Retirement Benefits Concern (added ‘92)
Other Concerns

40
Beneficial Products and Services
Pollution Prevention
Recycling
Clean Energy
Strengths 8
Communications (added ‘96, moved ‘05)
Property, Plant, and Equipment (ended ‘95)
Management Systems
Environment
Other Strength
Hazardous Waste
Regulatory Problems
Ozone Depleting Chemicals
Concerns Substantial Emissions 7
Agricultural Chemicals
Climate Change (added ‘99)
Other Concerns
Positive Record in South Africa (‘94-’95)
Indigenous Peoples Relations Strength (added ‘02)
Strengths 4
Labor Rights Strength (added ‘02)
Other Strength
South Africa (ended ‘94)
Human Rights
Northern Ireland (ended ‘94)
Burma Concern (added ‘95)
Concerns Mexico (‘95-’02) 7
Labor Rights Concern (added ‘98)
Indigenous Peoples Relations Concern (added ‘00)
Other Concerns
Quality
R&D/Innovation
Strengths 4
Benefits to Economically Disadvantaged
Product Other Strength
Product Safety
Marketing/Contracting Concern
Concerns 4
Antitrust
Other Concerns

41
Table 3
DESCRIPTIVE STATISTICS

Variables CSI CSR Tobin’s q Log(emp) FinLev ROA AdtoSales RDtoSales


CSI 1.0000
CSR .3643 1.0000
Tobin’s q -.0869 .0059 1.0000
Log(Number of Employees)
.4074 .3817 -.1323 1.0000
(Log(emp))
Financial Leverage (FinLev) .0778 -.0474 -.0996 .0543 1.0000
ROA .0270 .0697 .0621 .2039 -.1008 1.0000
Advertising-to-Sales Ratio (%)
-.0189 .0440 .1047 .0080 -.0139 -.0385 1.0000
(AdtoSales)
R&D-to-Sales Ratio (%) 1.0000
-.0222 -.0213 .0747 -.0857 -.0012 -.1645 .0037
(RDtoSales)
Mean 1.7938 1.4851 1.6209 1.2247 .1926 .0196 .0120 .3469
Standard Deviation 1.9112 2.0549 1.4342 1.9240 .2050 .1731 .0441 6.3368
The means, standard deviations, and pairwise correlations reported here are based on “unstandardized” CSR and CSI scores. Note that we used
“standardized” CSR and CSI scores in our empirical analysis.

42
Table 4
SUMMARY OF UNIT ROOT AND STATIONARITY TESTS OF THE VARIABLES

Variable Statistics P-value Conclusion


Δ𝐶𝑆𝐼 -74.937 .000 Stationary
Δ𝐶𝑆𝑅 -97.229 .000 Stationary
Δ𝑇𝑜𝑏𝑖𝑛′ 𝑠 𝑞 -50.413 .000 Stationary
We use lags of one in the ADF regression. The reported statistic is the inverse normal Z statistic. Choi’s (2001)
simulation results suggest that this statistic offers the best trade-off between size and power.

43
Table 5
ESTIMATION RESULTS OF CONTEMPORANEOUS EFFECTS

Independent Dependent
CSI CSR Tobin’s q
CSI 1 1.5216 (.0351) -.9618 (.0230)
CSR 0 1 .3954 (.0100)
Tobin’s q 0 0 1
Standard errors are reported in parentheses. They are calculated based on 1,000 bootstrap samples.

44
Table 6
ESTIMATION RESULTS FROM THE REDUCED-FORM PVAR MODEL

Independent Dependent
CSI(t) CSR(t) Tobin’s q(t)
CSI(t-1) .1620** -.2256 -.1718**
CSI(t-2) .1250* -.1825** .0723
CSR(t-1) -.0231 .4530*** .0154
CSR(t-2) .0251 .0332 -.0593
Tobin’s q(t-1) -.0421 -.2986* .3935***
Tobin’s q(t-2) -.0003 -.1440 .0028
ROA -.0430 .0975 -.1103
Log(Emp) -.0195 -.1489 -.2583***
Financial Leverage .0841 .1074 .0409
Ad-to-Sales 2.9651 23.1109 2.0771
R&D-to-Sales -.0009*** .0009 -.0015
Year-fixed effect^ Included Included Included
AB Test (m1) -3.21*** -2.35** -4.80***
#
AB Test (m2) -1.72 -.94 .29
Hansen Test of 2
𝜒 = 123.36 2
𝜒 = 12.56 2
𝜒 = 163.59
Over-identification p-value: .095* p-value: .961 p-value: .084*
Restrictions&
***, **, and * represent 1%, 5%, and 10% significance level, respectively
^We use first-differencing in all three models to control for firm- and industry-specific fixed-effects.
# The AB test (m2) is a test for autocorrelation of the residuals for the first-differenced model. In a valid
model, residuals should not exhibit significant AR(2) behavior.
& The Hansen test of over-identification restriction examines whether the instruments are valid.

45
Table 7
SUMMARY OF MANAGERIAL IMPLICATIONS

1. Firms can expect negative financial performance implication from their CSI.
2. Increasingly, many firms engage in both CSR and CSI.
3. Firms that engage in both CSR and CSI tend to engage in CSR after CSI occurred.
4. Many firms appear to engage in CSR after CSI occurred to offset their past CSI.
5. Using CSR to offset past CSI does not attenuate the negative performance implication of CSI.
6. Few firms invest in CSR just because they are doing well financially.
There appear to be two types of firms:
 Some firms engage in CSR to offset their past CSI.
7.  Other firms engage in CSR because (we speculate) it is simply part of what they do.
The latter firms can expect to see significant financial returns from their CSR investments. However,
the former firms likely see little if any positive financial returns from their CSR investments.
CSR = Corporate Social Responsibility; CSI = Corporate Social Irresponsibility

46
Figure 1
THE FOUR MECHANISMS

time (t) time (t)


Financial Performance CSR CSI CSR

Mechanism 1 Mechanism 3:
Slack Resources: Penance:
Financial performance in (t - x, x ≥ 1) CSI in (t - x, x ≥ 1)
causes CSR in t causes CSR in t

time (t) time (t)


CSR Financial Performance CSR CSI

Mechanism 2: Mechanism 4:
Good Management: Insurance:
CSR in (t - x, x ≥ 1) CSI in t
causes financial performance in t causes CSR in (t - x, x ≥ 1)

CSR = Corporate Social Responsibility; CSI = Corporate Social Irresponsibility

47
Figure 2
PANEL A: PAIRWISE CORRELATION BETWEEN CSR AND
FINANCIAL PERFORMANCE (FP = Tobin’s q)
0.15

0.1
Correlation

0.05

0
1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008

-0.05
Year

lagged CSR & FP lagged FP & CSR

PANEL B: PAIRWISE CORRELATION BETWEEN CSR AND CSI


0.5

0.4
Correlation

0.3

0.2

0.1

0
1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008
Year

lagged CSR & CSI lagged CSI & CSR

The correlations shown are based on the unbalanced panel dataset of over 4,500 firms. We also examined the
correlations considering only firms for which we have full data across the 19 years (i.e., balanced panel; n =
190) and the results are similar. The CSR and CSI scores are from the Kinder, Lydenberg, and Domini (KLD)
Social Ratings Database.

48
Figure 3
PANEL A: IMPULSE RESPONSE FUNCTIONS FOR THE DYNAMIC RELATIONSHIP
BETWEEN CSR AND FINANCIAL PERFORMANCE (Tobin’s q)

Response of Tobin's q to CSR shock Response of CSR to Tobin's q shock

0.7 0.05
0
Percent Change

0.5 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10

Percent Change
-0.05
-0.1
0.3
-0.15

0.1 -0.2
-0.25
-0.1 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 -0.3
-0.35
-0.3 -0.4
Year
Year

PANEL B: IMPULSE RESPONSE FUNCTIONS FOR THE DYNAMIC RELATIONSHIP


BETWEEN CSR AND CSI

Response of CSI to CSR shock Response of CSR to CSI shock


0.3 1.5

0.2
1
Percent Change

Percent Change

0.1

0
0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 0.5
-0.1

-0.2
0
-0.3 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10

-0.4 -0.5
Year
Year

The graphs show the 2.5% and 97.5% confidence band (dotted line) on either side of the response function
(solid line). The confidence band is obtained from 1,000 Monte Carlo simulations.

49
Figure 4
UNRESTRICTED VS. RESTRICTED IMPULSE RESPONSE FUNCTIONS FOR THE
DYNAMIC RELATIONSHIP BETWEEN CSI AND
FINANCIAL PERFORMANCE (Tobin’s q)

Response of Tobin's q to CSI shock

0.05

0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10
-0.05

Year

-0.15
Percent Change

-0.25

-0.35

-0.45 Restricted Unrestricted

-0.55

The graph shows the results from the restricted (gray solid line) and unrestricted (black solid line) impulse
response function, as well as the 2.5% and 97.5% confidence bands of the response functions (dashed line for
the restricted impulse response; dotted line for the unrestricted impulse response).

50
WEB APPENDIX

Washing Away Your Sins? Corporate Social Responsibility,


Corporate Social Irresponsibility, and Firm Performance

Charles Kang
Frank Germann
Rajdeep Grewal

Estimation Procedure

We follow a two-step approach to estimate the structural VAR model (e.g., Blanchard and Perotti

2002; Blanchard and Quah 1989; Sims 1980). That is, we first estimate the reduced-form VAR model and

then estimate the structural parameters from the variance-covariance matrix of residuals from the reduced-

form VAR estimation. First, we multiply equation (1) [see main document for equation (1)] by A−1 (the

inverse of the contemporaneous effect matrix) and derive the reduced-form representation of the equation:
𝑃 𝑃 𝑃 𝐶𝑆𝐼𝑖(𝑡−𝑝)
𝐶𝑆𝐼𝑖𝑡 𝛾11 𝛾12 𝛾13
𝑃 𝑃
(WA1) [ 𝐶𝑆𝑅𝑖𝑡 ] = ∑𝑝=1 [𝛾21 𝑃
𝛾22 𝛾23 ] [ 𝐶𝑆𝑅𝑖(𝑡−𝑝) ]
𝑃

𝑇𝑜𝑏𝑖𝑛′ 𝑠 𝑞𝑖𝑡 𝑃
𝛾31 𝑃
𝛾32 𝑃
𝛾33 𝑇𝑜𝑏𝑖𝑛′ 𝑠 𝑞𝑖(𝑡−𝑝)

𝜐𝐶𝑆𝐼 𝑖𝑡
+Φ𝑋𝑖𝑡 + Ψ𝑖 + 𝛫𝐷 + [ 𝜐𝐶𝑆𝑅 𝑖𝑡 ]
𝜐𝑇𝑜𝑏𝑖𝑛′ 𝑠 𝑞
𝑖𝑡

𝑃 𝑃 𝑃 𝑃 𝑃 𝑃
𝛾11 𝛾12 𝛾13 𝜆11 𝜆12 𝜆13
𝑃 = A−1
𝑃
where, [𝛾21 𝑃
𝛾22 𝛾23 ] [𝜆𝑃21 𝜆𝑃22 𝜆𝑃23 ], Φ = A−1 Θcon , Ψ𝑖 = 𝐴−1 H𝑖 =
𝑃 𝑃 𝑃
𝛾31 𝛾32 𝛾33 𝜆𝑃31 𝜆𝑃32 𝜆𝑃33

[A−1 𝜂𝐶𝑆𝐼,𝑖 , 𝐴−1 𝜂𝐶𝑆𝑅,𝑖 , 𝐴−1 𝜂 𝑇𝑜𝑏𝑖𝑛′ 𝑠𝑞,𝑖 ]′, 𝐾 = 𝐴−1 Γ, 𝜐𝑖𝑡 = 𝐴−1 𝜑𝑖𝑡 , and 𝜐𝑖𝑡 =


[𝜐𝐶𝑆𝐼 𝑖𝑡 , 𝜐𝐶𝑆𝑅 𝑖𝑡 , 𝜐𝑇𝑜𝑏𝑖𝑛′ 𝑠 𝑞 ] ~𝑁(0, Σ𝜐 ).
𝑖𝑡

From the mapping between 𝜐𝑖𝑡 and 𝜑𝑖𝑡 , we can derive the relationship between the variance-

covariance matrix of the reduced-form residual (Σ𝜐 ) and the variance-covariance matrix of the structural-form

residual (Σ𝜑 ) such that Σ𝜐 = A−1 Σ𝜑 𝐴−1 ′. Second, we obtain estimates of A and Σ𝜑 by using the estimate of

51
Σ𝜐 . In general, several identification restrictions are needed since there are n(n + 1)/2 knowns (the distinct

elements of Σ𝜐 ) and n(3n + 1)/2 unknows (the n2 elements of A and the n(n + 1)/2 distinct elements of

Σ𝜑 ). For identification, we set the diagonal elements of A equal to 1 by scaling and let A be the lower triangle

matrix based on our recursive causal ordering. Thus, we impose some short-run restrictions which rely on the

contemporaneous effect assumptions. In addition, as suggested in the literature (e.g., Bernanke 1986; Sims

1986), we assume that Σ𝜑 is a diagonal matrix. Thus, our SPVAR model is just identified and we can obtain

structural parameter estimates of A and Σ𝜑 .

When estimating equation (WA1), we have to consider the following three econometric issues: (1)

endogeneity, (2) unobserved heterogeneity, and (3) dynamic panel bias. First, CSI, CSR and firm performance

are assumed to be endogenous because, as discussed above, the causality may run in both directions. Thus, it

is possible that our variables of interest can be explained by their lagged values and/or by the lagged values of

the respective other endogenous variables (e.g., Pauwels et al. 2004). These potential feedback effects among

the regressors may be correlated with the error term. Dynamic panel GMM estimators such as the Blundell

and Bond (1998) estimator account for this type of endogeneity that arises from direct and indirect feedback

effects among the regressors. Specifically, by using lagged values of the endogenous regressors (e.g., CSI𝑡−1 )

and lagged first-differences of the regressors (e.g., ∆CSI𝑡−1) as additional instruments, the endogenous

variables become pre-determined and are therefore not correlated with the error term (Arellano and Bond

1991; Arellano and Bover 1995; Holtz-Eakin et al. 1988).

Second, unobserved heterogeneity may play a critical role in determining a firm’s CSR and CSI

scores. For example, companies operating in the oil and gas industry may engage in more environmentally

harmful activities than companies that operate in the food and beverage industry. Thus, we need to control

for this unobserved heterogeneity to detect the true relationship among CSI, CSR and firm performance. We

use first-differencing which allows us to control for unobserved heterogeneity stemming from firm-specific

and industry-specific effects (Cameron and Trivedi 2005). In short, by first-differencing, time-invariant firm-

specific and industry-specific effects are removed. In other words, the unobserved firm-specific effect Ψ𝑖

52
cancels out of the model and, considering the iid assumption of 𝜐𝑖𝑡 , our estimation gives consistent slope

estimates.

Third, our panel data has a relatively short time series dimension (T) and a large cross-sectional

dimension (N). Estimating equation (2) using a first-difference ordinary least square approach or a least

square dummy variable approach would give inconsistent and biased estimates (i.e., result in a dynamic panel

bias; Nickell 1981). That is, in the dynamic panel models, the first-difference OLS estimator is inconsistent

because the regressors include lagged dependent variables (Cameron and Trivedi 2005). In contrast, the

dynamic panel GMM estimator allows us to overcome the dynamic panel bias. To obtain consistent

estimates, Anderson and Hsiao (1981) proposed an instrumental variable (IV) approach that estimates the

first-difference model using the lags of the dependent variable as an instrumental variable. Later, Holtz-Eakin

et al. (1988) and Arellano and Bond (1991) extended Anderson and Hsiao’s (1981) idea and proposed a panel

GMM estimator using not only the additional lags of the dependent variables but also the lags of the

difference of the dependent variables as instruments. Subsequently, Arellano and Bover (1995) and Blundell

and Bond (1998) developed a system GMM estimate which uses lags of differences for equations in levels and

also lags of levels as instruments for equations in first differences. They showed that an efficiency gain in

estimation is possible even when the time series is nearly unit root. Thus, we use the Blundell and Bond

(1998) estimator to deal with the weak instruments problem in first-differenced models as well as the dynamic

panel bias which is a common problem in small 𝑇 and large 𝑁 panels such as the one we are using. We also

note that the Blundell and Bond (1998) estimator has been widely used to test causal relationships when using

panel data (e.g., Huang et al. 2008). In the following, we briefly present the Blundell and Bond (1998)

estimator as well as the moment conditions.

We first derive the first-difference of equation (WA1) to remove the unobserved firm-specific time

invariant effect Ψ𝑖 :

𝑃 𝑃 𝑃 Δ𝐶𝑆𝐼𝑖(𝑡−𝑝)
Δ𝐶𝑆𝐼𝑖𝑡 𝛾11 𝛾12 𝛾13
𝑃 𝑃
(WA2) [ Δ𝐶𝑆𝑅𝑖𝑡 ] = ∑𝑝=1 [𝛾21 𝑃
𝛾22 𝛾23 ] [ Δ𝐶𝑆𝑅𝑖(𝑡−𝑝) ] + ΦΔ𝑋𝑖𝑡 + 𝛫Δ𝐷 + Δ𝜐𝑖𝑡
𝑃

Δ𝑇𝑜𝑏𝑖𝑛′ 𝑠 q𝑖𝑡 𝑃
𝛾31 𝑃
𝛾32 𝑃
𝛾33 Δ𝑇𝑜𝑏𝑖𝑛′ 𝑠 q𝑖(𝑡−𝑝)

where Δ is the first-difference operator.

53
For identification, we assume the standard initial conditions on yi1 = [ 𝐶𝑆𝐼𝑖1 , 𝐶𝑆𝑅𝑖1 , 𝑇𝑜𝑏𝑖𝑛′ 𝑠 q𝑖1 ]′

that E(yi1 𝜐𝑖𝑡 ) = 0 for i = 1, … , N and t = 2, … , T (e.g., Ahn and Schmidt 1995). The standard moment

condition is the orthogonality condition between the dependent variable and the lagged error term:

E(yi(t−s) Δ𝜐𝑖𝑡 ) = 0 𝑓𝑜𝑟 𝑡 = 3, … , 𝑇 𝑎𝑛𝑑 𝑠 ≥ 2. In addition, we impose two extra moment conditions for

the GMM estimation. These are 𝑇 − 3 linear moment conditions: E(uit , Δyi(t−1) ) = 0 for t = 4,5, … , T and

E(ui3 , Δyi2 ) = 0. Due to these two moment conditions, the lagged differences of the dependent variable can

be used as a possible instrument. In general, the asymptotically efficient GMM estimation based on the set of

moment conditions is as follows: Γ ′ = (Γ1 , Γ2 , … , Γ𝑝 ) where Γ ′ is a (3 × 3p) matrix of stacked coefficients

of lagged dependent variables. The GMM estimator of γ = 𝑣𝑒𝑐(Γ), where 𝑣𝑒𝑐 denotes the column stacking

operator, is given by Cao and Sun (2011):



γ̂𝐺𝑀𝑀 = 𝑣𝑒𝑐(Γ̂) ≔ vec ((Γ̂1 , Γ̂2 , … , Γ̂𝑝 ) )

′ )𝑊 (I ′ −1 ′
= [(I3 ⊗ 𝑆𝑍𝑋 𝑁 3 ⊗ 𝑆𝑍𝑋 )] [(I3 ⊗ 𝑆𝑍𝑋 )𝑊𝑁 𝑣𝑒𝑐(𝑆𝑍𝑌 )]

1 𝑁 1 𝑁 1 −1
′̂ ̂
where 𝑆𝑍𝑋 = ∑ 𝑍 ′ 𝑋̃ , 𝑆𝑍𝑌 = ∑ 𝑍 ′ Δ𝑦𝑖 , 𝑎𝑛𝑑 𝑊𝑁 = 𝐼3 ⊗ ( ∑𝑁
𝑖=1 𝑍𝑖 Δ𝜐𝑖 Δ𝜐𝑖 ′𝑍𝑖 )
𝑁 𝑖=1 𝑖 𝑖 𝑁 𝑖=1 𝑖 𝑁

̂𝑖 are consistent
𝐼3 is a (3 × 3) identity matrix, ⊗ is the Kronecker product, 𝑊𝑁 is the weight matrix, and Δ𝜐

estimates of the first-differenced residual obtained from a preliminary consistent estimator (this is known as a

two-step GMM estimator). 𝑋̃𝑖 is a (T − 2) × (K + 1) matrix with t-th row (Δyi(t−1) , Δ𝑋𝑖𝑡′ ), t = 3, … , T, Δ𝑦𝑖

is a (T − 2) × 1 vector with t-th row Δ𝑦𝑖𝑡 , and Zi is the instrument matrix such that, Zi =

𝑄𝑖 0 0 ⋯ 0
𝑞𝑖3 ′ 0 ⋯ 0
0 Δ𝑦𝑖2 0 ⋯ 0
0 𝑞𝑖4 ′ ⋮
0 0 Δ𝑦𝑖3 ⋯ 0 , where 𝑄𝑖 = ( ) and q′it =
⋮ ⋱ 0
⋮ ⋮ ⋮ ⋯ 0
⋯ Δ𝑦𝑖(𝑇−1) ) 0 ⋯ 0 𝑞𝑖𝑇 ′
(0 0 0

[𝑦𝑖(𝑡−2) , 𝑦𝑖(𝑡−3) , … , 𝑦𝑖1 , Δ𝑋𝑖𝑡 ′].

To estimate the dynamic relationship among CSR, CSI and firm performance, we calculate the

orthogonalized impulse response function. To do so, we need to estimate the covariance matrix of the error

Σ𝜐 . The estimator of Σ𝜐 is given by:

54
𝑁 𝑇
1
̂𝜐 =
Σ ∑ ∑ 𝜐̂
𝑖𝑡 𝜐
̂′
𝑖𝑡 ,
𝑁𝑇
𝑖=1 𝑡=0

where 𝜐̂ 𝑦𝑖 . ) − Γ̂ ∑𝑃𝑝=1(𝑦𝑖(𝑡−𝑝) − ̅̅̅


𝑖𝑡 = (𝑦𝑖𝑡 − ̅̅̅
̂ (𝑋𝑖𝑡 − ̅𝑋̅̅𝑖̅. ) 𝑓𝑜𝑟 𝑡 = 0, … , 𝑇, and ̅̅̅
𝑦𝑖 . ) − 𝛷 𝑦𝑖 . 𝑎𝑛𝑑 ̅𝑋̅̅𝑖̅. are the

averages of the dependent variables and the control variables over time, respectively.

Figure WA1
TWO-VARIABLE VS. THREE-VARIABLE IMPULSE RESPONSE FUNCTIONS
FOR THE DYNAMIC RELATIONSHIP BETWEEN CSR
AND FINANCIAL PERFORMANCE (Tobin’s q)

Response of Tobin's q to CSR shock


6

2
Percent Change

0
0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10

-2

-4

Year

-6

CSI is not in the system CSI is in the system

The graph shows the impulse response functions based on the three-variable SPVAR model (CSR, CSI, and
Tobin’s q; black line) and the two-variable SPVAR model (CSR and Tobin’s q; gray line). It also shows the
2.5% and 97.5% confidence bands (dashed line for the two-variable SPVAR model; dotted line for the three-
variable SPVAR model). As the graph shows, when CSI is not in the system (gray line), the effect of CSR on
Tobin’s q is about four times larger in time 0 than when CSI is in the system (black line).

55
Figure WA2
EVOLUTION OF MEDIA ATTENTION RELATED TO CSR

35000

30000

25000

20000

15000

10000

5000

Newspaper articles

We searched through Factiva and, considering the years 1979 – 2014, counted the number of newspaper articles
that referenced the term “CSR” in each year. The results from that search are shown in Figure WA2.

56
References
Ahn, Seung C., and Peter Schmidt (1995), “Efficient Estimation of Models for Dynamic Panel Data,” Journal
of Econometrics, 68(1), 5–27.
Anderson, T. W., and Cheng Hsiao (1981), “Estimation of Dynamic Models with Error Components,” Journal
of the American Statistical Association, 76(375), 598–606.
Arellano, Manuel and Stephen Bond (1991), “Some Tests of Specification for Panel Data: Monte Carlo
Evidence and an Application to Employment Equations,” The Review of Economic Studies, 58(2), 277–
297
_____ and Olympia Bover (1995), “Another Look at the Instrumental Variable Estimation of Error-
components Models,” Journal of Econometrics, 68(1), 29–51.
Bernanke, Ben S. (1986), “Alternative explanations of the money-income correlation,” Carnegie-Rochester
Conference Series on Public Policy, Elsevier,25(1), 49-99.
Blanchard, Olivier Jean, and Danny Quah (1989), “The Dynamic Effects of Aggregate Demand and Supply
Disturbances,” American Economic Review,79(4), 655–73.
_____ and Roberto Perotti (2002), “An Empirical Characterization of the Dynamic Effects of Changes in
Government Spending and Taxes on Output,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 117, 1329-1368
Blundell, Richard, and Stephen Bond (1998), “Initial Conditions and Moment Restrictions in Dynamic Panel
Data Models,” Journal of Econometrics, 87(1), 115–143.
Cameron, A. Colin, and Pravin K. Trivedi (2005), Microeconometrics: Methods and Application. Cambridge
University Press.
Cao, Bolong, and Yixiao Sun (2011), “Asymptotic Distributions of Impulse Response Functions in Short
Panel Vector Autoregressions,” Journal of Econometrics, 163(2), 127–143.
Holtz-Eakin, Douglas, Whitney Newey, and Harvey S. Rosen (1988), “Estimating Vector Autoregressions
with Panel Data,” Econometrica, 56(6), 1371–1395.
Huang, Bwo-Nung, M.J. Hwang, and C.W. Yang (2008), “Causal Relationship Between Energy Consumption
and GDP Growth Revisited: A Dynamic Panel Data Approach,” Ecological Economics, 67(1), 41–54.
Nickell, Stephen J. (1981), “Biases in Dynamic Models with Fixed Effects,” Econometrica, 49(6), 1417–26.
Pauwels, Koen, Jorge Silva-Risso, Shuba Srinivasan, and Dominique M. Hanssens (2004), “New Products,
Sales Promotions, and Firm Value: The Case of the Automobile Industry,” Journal of Marketing, 68(4),
142–156.
Sims, Christopher A. (1980), “Macroeconomics and Reality,” Econometrica, 48(1), 1–48.
_____ (1986), “Are Forecasting Models Usable for Policy Analysis,” Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis
Quarterly Review, 10, 2-16.

57

You might also like