You are on page 1of 19

Supply and Demand: The Market Mechanism

All societies necessarily make economic choices. Society needs to make choices
about, what should be produced, how should those goods and services be produced,
and whom is allowed to consumes those goods and services. For conventional
economics the market by way of the operation of supply and demand answer these
questions. Under conditions of competition, where no one has the power to influence
or set price, the market (everyone, producers and consumers together) determines the
price of a product, and the price determines what is produced, and who can afford to
consume it.

Price provides the incentive to both the consumer and producer. High prices
encouraged more production by the producers, but less consumption by the
consumers. Low prices discourage production by the producer, and encouraged
consumption by the consumers. Both incentives push the price to balance the forces of
consumption (demand) and production (supply). Economists call this
balance: equilibrium. This natural mechanism requires no external institution for
direction (or only a minimum amount), or any altruists’ motivation by either the
consumers or the producers.

The supply and demand mechanism (the economic model) besides being the natural
consequences of economic forces provides the most efficient economic outcomes
possible. Satisfaction for society is maximized, at minimum cost. The market
mechanism’s efficiency outcome is always located on the production possibility
curves frontier, where all resources are fully utilized (points within the production
possibility curves are inefficient by definition, since resources are not being utilized).
This core model of supply and demand explains why economists usually favor market
results, and seldom wishes to interfere with price. Setting minimum wages, for
instance, or interfering with trade, violate the spirit of the model, and lead to
inefficient outcomes.

Alternative Viewpoints
There are alternative viewpoints, however, that question just how efficient and natural
the market mechanism is. They argue that actual markets in any society is embedded
within a set of institutional rules, laws, and customs that determine how well the
market works. Only by looking at actual markets and their institutional rules can
efficiency be determined. They see a market as a game where the underlying rules as
well as the approaches of its participants determine the outcome. The variables that
matter are institutions and not only prices. Some markets work better, than others,
even within the same society, but certainly they differ between countries with
different rules and values.

This disagreement among economist is a matter of degree. Even Adam Smith, the
father of economic saw a role for government in the economy. Lassize faire
(government stay out) was never seen as absolute. The Government was needed to
provide some elements of the following; law and order, enforcement of private
contracts and property rights, public goods such as roads and other public
infrastructure, and defense from external military threats. Most economists believe
these roles continue. Most economists also believe that the market is a useful tool and
has a place in the economy. The real difference is the degree of faith in the efficiency
of the market, and whether society should take direction from the market, or society
should control and direct the market.

How are prices set? (The supply and demand model)

If no single seller or buyer can set prices and neither does government or any other
institution; how are goods and services allocated in competitive markets, and how are
resources allocated in the competitive factor markets? The answer is that there are two
independent factors that determine price in competitive markets (demand and
supply). If markets were not competitive by definition a single seller or buyer could
control and set price. Competition then needs flexible impersonal pricing. Suppliers
must not work together to influence prices, and each supplier must be able to enter or
exit a market at will. There are a number of other conditions necessary for full
competition, but let's look, first at the two principle components of the model, starting
with demand.

Demand (Substitution and Income effects)


The investigation of the market mechanism starts with a single consumer. A consumer
will respond to price. Demand is a set of relationships that show the quantity of a
good the consumer will buy at each price within a specific time period. To have an
effective demand a consumer must both desire the product and be able to afford the
good or service. Desire without the ability to afford a good or service is not
demand. Therefore not everyone can equally participate as consumers in all markets
(it depends on their wealth).

When the price of some item that is normally purchased increases or decreases, the
consumer will buy less or more of it. There are two reasons for this:
First, an increase in the price of something that the consumer wants to buy makes the
consumer poorer. It will now require a larger portion of income to purchase the same
amount that the consumer uses to buy at the lower price. This affect is referred to
as income effect. Price changes always affect one's real income (price increases
decrease real income while price decreases increase real income). Its importance,
however, varies with how large the cost of the item is relative to the consumer’s total
budget. The change in price of salt will have a minimal affect on real income, while a
change in the price of a car can be significant.
Second, you respond to the price of an item in relationship to other items. This effect
is called the substitution effect. As the price of a good falls (other prices remaining
unchanged), the good becomes relatively cheaper than other goods and you substitute
the good for others goods that are now relatively more expensive. As the price of a
good rises, you substitute other now less expensive goods for the one in question.

In general these two effects reinforce each other, with higher prices reducing the
quantity of demand, and lower prices increasing the quantity of demand. But there can
be exceptions. A Veblen good appeals to customers because of its high price (and
status). Russian caviar, large diamonds and large luxury cars or yachts may be
examples. Raising the price for these goods may not decrease quantity demanded.

Nonprice influences on demand


There are of course other factors, besides price changes that influences an individual’s
quantity demanded. These other factors are usually within the model of demand and
supply given less weight than price. These other factors are held constant
(Ceteris Paribus)===latin phrase other things held constant
to arrive at an equilibrium price level.
00B
These factors include; first, prices of other products, both complements and
substitutes. Complements our products used in conjunction with the good in question
(in the United States movie going, and popcorn consumption are complements). If the
price of a complement goes up, the demand for the good in question will decrease (as
well as the complement itself). Substitutes are goods that replace each other in
consumption (chicken, beef, and pork are substitutes). If the price of a substitute goes
up, the demand for the good in question will go up (while the demand for the
substitute declines). Second, changes in consumers’ income will affect the consumer's
ability to buy, and thus their demand. Third, is a catch all category, which includes the
preferences of the consumers. Changes in preferences will affect demand. These
changes in desire and taste are usually not addressed by economist as part of the
economic model of demand and supply. Economists usually refer to sociologist,
psychologist and other social sciences to model these changes. This category is
nonetheless important for the efficiency arguments of the model. If economists really
want to argue that the market produces just the right goods and services then they
have to implicitly believe that demand is innate to humans (not easily influence by
producers and our general environment). How preferences are really formed help
determine who is, in fact, in charge of the markets. The critics (alternative models)
believe that preferences are not innate, but preferences are learned and influenced by
producers (by using marketing strategies).

Law of demand
The quantity demanded for a consumer at different prices can be aggregated into a
market demand. Market demand then is simply, the sum of all individual demand
relationships. Figure 1, shows two individual demand relationships from different
consumers, which has quantities demanded combined (or sum up) to the market
quantities in the far right graph. The vertical axes always show price, which remains
the same for individual and market demand curves, while the horizontal axes shows
quantity. Because price remains the same for all three graphs, a single line (P)
representing the same price can be drawn horizontally across all three
graphs. Quantity demand changes units from the individual to the market demand
curve. Market quantities may be in thousands or millions of units depending on the
size of a market.

Figure 1. Individual and Market Demand Curves

The demab nd curve shows an inverse relationship between price and quantity
demanded. This relationship is considered so pervasive, particularly for the market
demand, that in economics it has been termed the law of demand. The higher the price
the lower the quantity demanded, and the lower the price the higher the quantity
demanded. Although the law of demand is not logically absolutely necessary, given
the case mentioned earlier of a Veblen luxury good, most goods or services are
believed to adhere to the law of demand.
Price elasticity of demand
The degree by which quantity changes as price changes is called the price elasticity of
demand. It is the percentage change in quantity to the percentage change in price (%
Change in Quantity / % Change in Price). Given the law of demand when price is
increasing quantity demanded is decreasing, elasticity’s of demand must be negative.
High absolute (ignoring the sign) values for elasticity (E>1) indicate that quantity
demanded is very sensitive to price, while low absolute values of elasticity (E<1)
suggest that the consumer is not sensitive and does not respond to price. Demand
relationships with low absolute values of elasticity’s (E<1) are considered inelastic
and not sensitive to price.

Inelastic demand would be expected for goods with the following characteristics;
goods or services with no close substitutes, goods that are seen as necessities (not
easily replaced), and goods that are inexpensive and a small part of a consumers
budget. Also the shorter the time period of adjustment to a price change, the less
elastic the market demand will be. For instance, gasoline is considered an inelastic
good. A 20 percent increase in its price would not in the United States result in a 20
percent decrease in quantity demanded, the response would be much less. Gasoline
has no close substitutes; gasoline (in much of the United States) is a necessity and has
only a moderate affect on budgets (for the non-poor). In the short term, given the
individual’s cars gasoline requirements, and the distance between home, job, and
school, there can be little adjustment of demand to gasoline price. Over a longer
period of time new more efficient automobiles could be manufactured, mass transit
could be developed, and distances traveled by consumers could be reduced (by
moving closer to one’s work or school etc.), which all would increase the elasticity of
the gasoline market (but only as measured in the long term).

In figure 1 above, the middle graph shows a consumer less sensitive to price (the
demand curve is closer to vertical), with a relatively inelastic demand, as compared to
the more elastic demand of the consumer represented by the graph to the left. The
value of the demand curves slope is not equal to its elasticity, since elasticity is
defined as the percentage changes (but it's close for our purposes). In figure 2,
perfectly elastic and inelastic cures are showed. Determining market elasticity is an
empirically important process for understanding how markets work. In general
markets work best when demand is elastic.

Figure 2, Inelastic and elastic demand curves


Shifting demand
The demand curve is never actually known, at best it can only be estimated. In a
dynamic world the demand relationship seldom remains static, but a single demand
curve, theoretically keeps all other effects on demand constant (ceteris paribus). A
change in these outside variables (anything but the price of the good in question) is
shown graphically by a new shifted demand curve. The other outside variables include
changes in the consumer’s income, other prices for substitutes or complements, or just
a change in taste for the good. To avoid confusion a change in these outside variables
or a shift in the curve is called a change in demand. With no shift in the curve and
only a change in price there is movement on the curve and this movement is called
a change in quantity demanded.

Figure 3, shows a hypothetical case for an increase in consumer income on the


demand relationship. This good is considered a normal good because as income
increases demand increases. An inferior good, in contrast, shows decrease demand as
income increases (in this case the shift in the demand curve would be to the
left). Examples of inferior goods in the United States might be the consumption of
macaroni and cheese, or used cars.

Figure 3, Shifting demand curve


In the real dynamic world, when nothing is, or can be held constant, calculating and
determining its elasticity is fraught with difficulty. All we really know at anyone time
is a combination of a single price and quantity of goods purchased (and even this is
not always possible). The theory of demand is a hypothetical one, which helps build
the dominant economic model, which is used to try to understand the operation of a
market system.

Supply (the other half)

Supply is the relationship showing the quantities of a goods or services, that will be
offered for sale at each price within a specific time period. The supply curve
presupposes competition among firms so that no one firm can set and influence
price. Firms are small relative to the market, and are price takers. Each small firm
would provide a quantity of output for each possible price. Combining each firm’s
quantity of output at each price for all firms provides a market supply relationship and
thus a supply curve. Large firms (large relative to their market) such as monopolies
and oligopolies set and influence price, and are not included in the supply curve, and
in the analysis below. Because of their control of price, they can set their quantity of
output to their advantage.

In contrast, to demand, the supply relationship shows a direct relationship between


price and the quantity supplied. High prices encourage firms to produce more, while
low prices discourage production. At high prices more resources can be used in
production, and more firms with higher costs can find it profitable to produce. The
reverse is true for low prices. This direct positive relationship between price and
quantity supplied is called the law of supply.
Change in quantity supplied verses change in supply
Figure 4, shows both, a movement on the supply curve called a change in quantity
supplied, as well as a shift in the supply curve, called a change in supply. A
movement on the supply curve or a change in quantity supplied can only be initiated
by a price change. Price changes first, and then quantity supplied changes as a
consequence. Elasticity of supply measures the degree of change in quantity supplied.

In contrast, a shift in the supply curve is a result of a number of outside variables


(other than price) that change. The following are some of the more important outside
variables.
First, improvements in technology which reduced costs and expand output make it
possible for firms to offer more products for sale at each price. This may be
particularly significant for certain technologically important market, such as
communications and computer products.
Second, a reduction in price of inputs in the production process can allow firms to
increase output at each and every price, while a increase in price of inputs reduce
supply at each possible price.
Third, the prices and profitability of using resources in other alternative production
processes can influence the firm’s production plans at each price level. For instance, if
the firm suddenly has an opportunity to produce, with its resources, a new more
profitable product, it may reduce the supply of other products.
Fourth, new firms may enter, while other firms may exit an industry. One of the
important features of globalization is the large expansion in number of producers in
the same enlarged worldwide market. There are other factors that cans shift a supply
curve. For instance, for agricultural products weather conditions can dramatically
affect the supply of a product. In the grain markets the variations in supply due to
weather conditions has a long history of affecting price and the supply curve.

Implicit within the model of supply and demand is the underlying contention that
price is the important variable, and not those external variables that shift the
curves. The graphics of supply and demand use price on the vertical axes to represent
the important causal variable. Many economic alternatives approaches imply with
their analysis, that price is not necessarily this primary variable in all markets. One
could argue, for instance, that in agricultural markets, and high-technology markets,
that price, and adjustments to price are not the causal variable. Other variables that
shift the curves, and help set price, and certainly influence price are the variables that
need to be understood first to understand the industry and the changing market.

Unfortunately, in most markets in the real world it is difficult to determine, if there


has been a shift in the curve, or a movement on the curve. The supply curve is only
hypothetical. Empirically with only a price and quantity at one point in time, it is
difficult to know what is causing what. Neoclassical economics generally assumes
that markets are driven by price and is the primary causal variable.

Figure 4, Movement on the supply curve, and a shift in the supply curve
Elasticity’s of supply
The law of supply indicates that as price increases quantity supplied also increases,
but it doesn't measure to what degree. As with demand, the degree of sensitivity to
price is measured with what's called supply elasticity. The elasticity of supply is the
percent change in quantity supplied given (divided by) the percent change in price (%
change in quantity / % change in price). Since both price and quantity are increasing
or decreasing elasticity’s of supply are always positive, whereas elasticity’s of
demand are always negative. High values of supply elasticity (E>1) indicate
sensitivity to price, while low values of elasticity (E<1) show little sensitivity to price.
Products with values of supply elasticity of less than one (E<1) are referred to as
inelastic markets. Markets that determine price, work best with elastic supply.

Grain markets usually suffer from inelastic supply conditions. To the extent that
farming is seen as a way of life, and not a business, adjustment to prices is difficult,
painful and slow. Grain prices that stay low, eventually have forced farmers off the
land. This migration off the farm has been going on for centuries and still continues
through the 20th century. But there are few alternative uses to farmland, so as farmers
leave the land, farms only grow in size. But land still stays in cultivation. So grain
supply may not change even with low prices, and once crops are planted each year,
little can be done during the year to adjust to low prices. Grain output in the short term
are not effected by price (resulting in an inelastic supply curve), but output is effected
by weather conditions, which shift the supply curve.
The market and equilibrium pricing

The market combines in exchange, both buyers and sellers. For economics it
combines the demand and the supply curve to determine price. This price is called an
equilibrium price, since it balances the two forces of supply and demand. An
equilibrium price is the price at which the quantity demanded is equal to the quantity
supplied. The quantity supplied and demanded is also referred to as the equilibrium
quantity. Figure 5, shows both demand and supply determining equilibrium price and
quantity.

Figure 5, Demand and supply and equilibrium

In figure 5, “A” is the equilibrium price and “Q” is the corresponding equilibrium
quantity. At the price “A” the quantity supplied and a quantity demanded are equal,
and at the “Q” quantity, demand and supply are equal.

If price were at “B” the quantity that suppliers would like to supply would be larger
than consumers would demand at that price, creating a surplus quantity. A surplus
would create forces among the many competitive suppliers to cut prices (supplier are
all relatively small). Those forces would push the price down to the equilibrium level
at “A”.
If prices were at “C” the quantity that suppliers would like to supply, would be less
than consumers would demand at that price, creating a shortage. Because of the
shortage and a competition among consumers, prices would tend to rise. Only at “A”
would there be no tendency for the price to change, and “A” is the equilibrium price.

This graph represents the objective impersonal operation of the market. No one sets
the price, and if the consumers don’t like the price, they have no one to blame, and no
recourse (over the price). If suppliers don’t like the price, they in turn have no one to
blame and no recourse (over the price). This is seen by many as one of the strength of
markets.

Shifting demand and supply curves


Although neoclassical economics suggest the most important forces in the market are
the forces that move the price to equilibrium, other forces that shift the curves are also
recognized. Figure 6, shows the affect of an increase in demand and a decrease in
supply.

Figure 6, Increase in demand and a decrease in supply

In figure 6, the first diagram on the left, shows an increase in demand with the new
demand curve shifted to the right. This increase in demand with increased quantity
demanded at each price could represent a case where income had increased, or where
product desirability increased. As a result the equilibrium price has shifted from price
level “A” to the higher price level “B”. The equilibrium quantity has also increased as
new output has been brought onto the market as firms react to the higher
prices. Therefore both prices and quantity has increased.

In figure 5, the second diagram on the right, shows a decrease in supply with a new
supply curve shifted to the left. This decrease in supply (less quantity supplied at each
price) could represent, poor weather in a crop growing area, or higher input prices due
to shortages of crude oil, or labor. Price again has increased from the price level “A”
to “B”, while quantity has declined as consumers react to the higher prices.

Not shown here are the other two cases where demand shifts to the left (decrease in
demand), and where supply shift to the right (increase in supply). The logical
consequences of these shifts are easily determined graphically. The difficulty in the
real world is determining what actually has changed, and what has not, and by how
much. In a dynamic changing market shifting curves, representing changing income,
tastes, technical conditions, weather conditions and other variables might all
overwhelm the forces pushing for equilibrium. In such an environment, equilibrium
would never be reached, and the tools of supply and demand curves and its
equilibrium analysis, would have minimum usefulness. To understand the market
would require understanding how the institutions, technologies and those other
outside variables are changing and evolving.

Figure 7, demand and supply curve with no equilibrium possible.


Figure 7, shows a case that is logically possible with no equilibrium price or
quantity. Neither the law of supply or the law of demand is violated. Graphically if
there was to be an equilibrium price it would have to be negative, which is impossible
in the real world. Both demand and supply curves show a relatively inelastic
relationship, where neither quantity demanded, or quantity supplied is sensitive to
price. These markets operate poorly with a continuous oversupply, and thus a
tendency for price to drop. Institutional factors (including government), depending on
the consequences to the suppliers or customers, would keep the price above zero, but
no conventional equilibrium would be possible.

Markets and their equilibrium price and quantity, function best with elastic demand
and supply conditions. Here no outside intervention is likely with price providing
enough incentive for both consumers and suppliers to reach equilibrium. Where price
is important for both consumers and suppliers it is also unlikely that outside variables
will overwhelm its impact. So in general markets function best when price is the focal
point for both consumers and suppliers. There are many different markets where these
price sensitivities differ among markets in both the long-term (many years) and over
the short term.

Economic efficiency and the market

In neoclassical economics the market has two distinct properties. The first, already
discussed was the development of market equilibrium. Most mainstream economic
models view the economy as sufficiently competitive, and as moving to
equilibrium. This movement is seen as inevitable in the long haul, and as natural
consequences of the economic forces of supply and demand. The movement to
equilibrium is also seen as good because it is considered economically
efficient. Although efficiency is not seen as the only criteria to judge the success of
the economy, it does have in economics of special role and prominence. There is a
belief among economists that economic theory can contribute to both an
understanding of, and a promotion of economic efficiency.

There are other criteria for judging the success of an economy. The most prominent is
equity or fairness. Fairness is seen as purely subjective. For economists, this criteria is
seen as purely a judgment call, were economic theory has no role. Markets are not
seen as particularly equitable or fair, they are just seen as objective phenomenon. And
although fairness as criteria should be seen as potentially equal to efficiency, but
because economists have little to add about fairness, fairness tends to be invisible in
much of economic analysis.

The second, property of neoclassical economics is that markets are economically


efficient. For economists, efficiency means that the economy is producing just the
right quantity of goods and services to satisfy society’s wants at minimum
cost. Economic efficiency is not the engineering or technical definition of
efficiency. Economic efficiency does not try only to minimize inputs in a production
process, or even minimize costs in a given operation, or maximize output given a level
of input, but determine for the whole economy what quantity of goods and services
are best (given the demand curve), and minimize all opportunity costs for those goods
and services.

Developing the full argument for economic efficiency in neoclassical economics


requires a more complete development of demand and supply (perfect
competition). These arguments are laid out more in the chapter on demand, and the
chapter on perfect competition. But we can summarize the essence of those chapters
on the meaning of demand and supply here. Given the assumptions of neoclassical
economics on the theory of demand, the market demand curve is re-interpreted as
the benefits to society (simply the addition of benefits to all individuals in society) in
the consumption of goods and services. The demand curve represents the importance
to society of these goods and services.

The other half of the efficiency equation comes from the supply curve. Here given the
appropriate assumptions of perfect competition on the theory of supply, the market
supply curve is re-interpreted as the cost to society for the consumption of goods and
services. These are opportunity costs (that which has to be given up, to get something
else) not necessarily only dollars. The supply curve represents the cost in production
of goods and services.

Figure 8, shows the interpretation of supply and demand, as costs and benefits in the
efficiency model. Economists measure these costs and benefits as marginal, (extra
costs and extra benefits) on the curves.

Figure 8, Marginal cost and benefits in the efficiency model


In figure 8, an ordinary market demand and supply curve are shown. The graph on the
left shows a demand curve with three quantity levels of demand. At the low quantity
level “A” the relative benefit for the good is high resulting in a high price. Price
measures the benefits of the extra unit (marginal) of this good and at low quantities
(“A”) price is high. As quantity increases to “B” and then to “C” the benefit or price
of another units declines (as shown on the graph). The common sense notion of this
relationship is simply that as quantity increases saturation decreases the value of
additional units. While total benefits (of all goods consumed) still increase the extra or
marginal value of each additional unit declines.

The graph on the right shows a supply curve with three quantity levels of supply. At
the low quantity level “D” the social cost for producing the good is low per unit,
resulting in a low price. Price for supply measures the cost of the extra unit (marginal)
of this good and with low quantities (“D”) price is low. As quantity increases to “E”
and then to “F” the social cost of supply, with additional units, increases (as shown on
the graph). The notion is simply that all social costs escalate with increased output
during a short period time, given limited capital resources (plant size and
infrastructure is limited).

In figure 9, the efficiency model of neoclassical economics combines the demand


curve or the benefits to consumption with the supply curve or the cost of that
consumption.

Figure 9, Efficiency model


In graph 9, the equilibrium price is “P” with the corresponding equilibrium quantity as
“A”. This result is seen as an automatic consequence of market behavior. The
efficiency argument adds that these equilibrium results also are economically
efficient. So that markets provided an efficient equilibrium outcome for society.

Quantity “B” is not efficient, because at quantity “B” the benefit to society for the
good in question, is larger than the cost to society for its production. The line with
arrows at “B” graphically represents this gap. If more quantity would be produced and
consumed benefits would be expanded more than costs and there would be a net gain
in value. The inefficiency would decrease as quantity increases and the gap
disappears. At “A” there is no gap and the benefits to society of consuming another
unit of this good is equal to the cost to society of producing another unit of this
good. Total benefits given cost are maximize (not shown directly on the graph).

Quantity “C” is not efficient, because at quantity “C” the cost to society for producing
this good is larger than the benefits to society for its consumption. The line with
arrows at “C” graphically represents this gap. If less quantity is produced and
consumed then cost will drop more than benefits with a net savings in value and thus a
net gain in efficiency. The inefficiency would decreases as quantity decreases and the
gap disappears. Again only at “A” is there no gap, and at this equilibrium quantity
economic efficiency is achieved.

Efficiency is optimum only where the extra costs and benefits are equal in production
and consumption. Here just the right number of houses, bicycles, and toothpaste is
being produce given their benefits to society, as well as their cost to society. The logic
of economic efficiency cannot be faulted given the assumptions from which it is
derived. Of particular importance is the nature of the demand and supply curve and
their reinterpretation into benefits and cost. This is why economists spend so much
effort deriving these curves (probably more than most students care for or think
necessary).

This market result of efficiency and equilibrium are very attractive, and is what attract
economists to market solutions. The assumptions underlying both curves are what
allows such attractive results, and thus requires those assumptions to be critically
examined. These underlying assumptions, and the theory be

You might also like