You are on page 1of 21

World Development Vol. 31, No. 3, pp.

403–423, 2003
Ó 2003 Elsevier Science Ltd. All rights reserved
Printed in Great Britain
www.elsevier.com/locate/worlddev 0305-750X/03/$ - see front matter
doi:10.1016/S0305-750X(02)00222-X

Conceptualizing Chronic Poverty


DAVID HULME
University of Manchester, UK

and

ANDREW SHEPHERD *
Overseas Development Institute, London, UK
Summary. — This paper provides a meaning for the term chronic poverty ‘‘in a nutshell’’ and
explores the concepts of poverty, vulnerability and poverty dynamics that underpin this meaning.
Subsequently, it reviews ‘‘who’’ is chronically poor, ‘‘why’’ they stay poor and what is known about
policies to reduce chronic poverty. Despite the limited knowledge available it is clear that hundreds
of millions of people are chronically poor, the causes are multifarious but can be analyzed through
livelihoods frameworks and that the scale and nature of chronic poverty will require an increase in
the levels of financing allocated to social protection in developing countries. Recent conceptual and
methodological advances, and the increasing availability of panel datasets, mean that the analysis
of deprivation can move on from poverty trends to poverty dynamics.
Ó 2003 Elsevier Science Ltd. All rights reserved.

Key words — chronic poverty, poverty dynamics, poverty reduction, deprivation, social welfare,
social protection

A small peasant and a landless laborer may both be lead, as a global rallying call is goal 1-target 1:
poor, but their fortunes are not tied together. In un- ‘‘halve, between 1990 and 2015, the proportion
derstanding the proneness to starvation of either we of people whose income is less than $1 a day.’’ In
have to view them not as members of the huge army
of the ‘‘poor,’’ but as members of particular classes,
terms of focusing public attention on the issue of
belonging to particular occupational groups, having poverty and mobilizing energy and resources for
different endowments, being governed by rather differ- its reduction, this primary goal has proved ex-
ent entitlement relations. The category of the poor is cellent. At other levels of activity, however, its
not merely inadequate for evaluative exercises and a consequences may not be so beneficial. In par-
nuisance for causal analysis, it can also have distorting ticular, it encourages the conceptualization of
effects on policy matters. (Sen, 1981) the poor as a single homogeneous group whose
prime problem is low monetary income and has
1. INTRODUCTION lead policymakers and their advisors to search
for ‘‘the policy’’ that increases the income of ‘‘the
In the last few years national and international poor.’’ When ambitions are high and time is
commitments to poverty-reduction have reached
levels that could barely have been imagined 10
years ago. Most world leaders have committed * This paper is partly based on an earlier paper (Hulme
their countries to ambitious targets for reducing et al., 2001). Comments and ideas from many people
global poverty, national governments are draft- have helped us in our thinking, particularly Chronic
ing Poverty Reduction Strategy Papers and in- Poverty Research Centre partners, participants at a
ternational agencies are focusing their attention workshop held at Church House, Westminster in Feb-
on mobilizing resources and influencing policies ruary 2002 and Bob Baulch, Tony German, Andy
that will provide pro-poor growth and alleviate McKay, Karen Moore, Judith Randel, Shahin Yaqub.
poverty. The central focus of this exercise has Particular thanks to Karen Moore for research assis-
become the Millennium Development Goals tance. Financial support from the Department for In-
(MDGs). These now comprise eight goals, 18 ternational Development Social Science Research Fund,
targets and 48 indicators (OECD, 2001). At their Grant number R7847, is gratefully acknowledged.
403
404 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

short simple solutions are sought. As Amartya strategies, roles for the state and forms and levels
SenÕs opening quote warns, pressures to view of international support would be needed for
poor people as a homogeneous group can both these two different hypothetical cases.
weaken analysis and distort policy. This paper addresses four main questions to
A particular problem of contemporary pov- create a background framework for the articles
erty analysis, seeking to rapidly reduce poverty that follow:
headcounts in an era of globalization driven by (a) What is chronic poverty? This section
a neoliberal vision, 1 is to see ‘‘the poor’’ as provides a short working definition of the
those who are not effectively integrated into the term so that the reader can understand the
market economy. This leads to a focus exces- particular focus of this collection ‘‘in a nut-
sively on the role that market forces can play in shell.’’ Subsequently, it examines in more
poverty-reduction. Without a doubt, such ap- detail different aspects of the conceptualiza-
proaches can help many poor people but there tion of chronic poverty.
are two problems with them. First, such a focus (b) Who is chronically poor? This is an
will not meet the needs of all the different types empirical question for which there are
of poor people. Second, such an approach en- few materials available. A brief summary
courages a focus on those poor whom the of the existing state of knowledge is pre-
market can ‘‘liberate’’ from poverty but neglects sented.
the needs of those who need different forms of (c) Why are people chronically poor? This
support, policy changes, or broader changes section provides a tentative framework
within society that take time. The chronic for examining the different factors and
poor––those who have experienced poverty for combinations of factors that explain why
long periods, or perhaps, all of their lives––are poverty persists. Inevitably, attempts to
likely to be neglected in such an era given the answer this question will always be con-
multiple factors that constrain their prospects tested.
and the likelihood that market-based factors (d) What are the implications of the answers
may contribute to their continued deprivation. to the earlier questions for poverty-reduction
While earlier ages sought to help the ‘‘deserving policy?
poor’’ the contemporary focus is on the ‘‘easy to
assist poor’’ (a focus that is encouraged by the
MDGs). This group desperately needs support, 2. WHAT IS CHRONIC POVERTY?
but not at the price of ignoring those whose
poverty is more problematic. In the first part of this section we provide a
In more specific terms, one can deductively working definition of chronic poverty and a set
identify big differences in the types of poverty of terms that facilitate the discussion of differ-
reduction strategy that are most appropriate for ent aspects of poverty and poverty dynamics.
countries (or regions) that have different mixes of In subsequent parts we explore important the-
chronic and transient poverty. In a country oretical issues that deepen the understanding of
where poverty is largely a transient phenomena, chronic poverty and/or reveal unresolved de-
with ‘‘the poor’’ at any particular time having a bates about the analysis of chronic poverty. It
high probability of improving their position, would be easier if we could provide a precise
then policies should focus predominantly on so- definition for chronic poverty, around which
cial safety nets that help people to manage their there is a broad consensus, and then proceed
present deprivation, rapidly return to a nonpoor to answer the other questions posed in the
status and reduce vulnerability. Limited term introduction. But, chronic poverty––like the
unemployment allowances, social grants, work- concept of poverty itself––is a portmanteau
fare, micro-credit and new skills acquisition term. Different meanings can be invested in
programs would be required. By contrast, in a the term, reflecting the differing personal
country where a significant proportion of the values––and often the disciplinary back-
poor are chronically poor, then policies to re- grounds––of particular analysts and schools of
distribute assets, direct investment toward basic thought.
physical infrastructure, reduce social exclusion
(from employment, markets and public institu- (a) Chronic poverty in a nutshell
tions) and provide long-term social security will
be necessary if poverty is to be significantly re- As a rough working definition we propose
duced. Quite different national development that chronic poverty be viewed as occurring
CONCEPTUALIZING CHRONIC POVERTY 405

when an individual experiences significant hold because this is the level at which data are
capability deprivations for a period of five collected. In some households all members may
years or more. Specific elements of this defini- experience poverty in similar ways over similar
tion are explored in detail in the sections that periods of time, but this should never be as-
follow. Here four main points need to be sumed. It is quite feasible that in nonpoor
noted. households certain members may suffer chronic
First, the distinguishing feature of chronic poverty because of their gender, age or social
poverty is its extended duration. The exact status and, conversely, that specific individuals
length of time that needs to elapse is, as with in chronically poor households may not be
the level chosen for an income poverty line, persistently deprived. At times it is useful to
somewhat arbitrary. Intuitively, we are talking identify social groups, communities or even the
about people who remain poor for much of their populations of spatial areas were chronic pov-
life course, and who may ‘‘pass on’’ their pov- erty is concentrated. The concept can even be
erty to subsequent generations (see Harper, applied to countries in which the majority of
Marcus, & Moore, this issue, for an examina- people have been persistently poor for many
tion of the intergenerational transmission years (UNCTAD, 2002). 2 In all of these cases
(IGT) of poverty). There are three arguments similar caveats must apply.
that can be used to support this crude five year Fourth, while it is possible to assess chronic
criterion. Five years is perceived as a significant poverty in either absolute or relative terms,
period of time, in an individualÕs lifecourse, in most existing work and virtually all of the
most cultures. There is often a five-year gap contributors in this issue, focus on chronic
between data collection points when panel data absolute poverty. Such a focus is consistent
are created so that in practical terms the study with the approach of most poverty analysis in
of the duration of poverty will often be based developing countries. But, it should be noted
on a five-year period (for example, see Carter & that Yaqub (2003) argues that chronic relative
May, 1999, for South Africa and Baulch & poverty (i.e., always being in the bottom quin-
Masset, this issue, for Vietnam). Finally, some tile of a countryÕs income distribution) may be
empirical materials indicate that people who as hard, or even harder to escape than chronic
stay poor for five years or more have a high absolute poverty.
probability of remaining poor for the rest of We propose a five-tier categorization for the
their lives (see Corcoran, 1995; Yaqub, 2000). If study of chronic poverty (Figure 1). While the
this is the case, the likelihood of IGT would measurement of poverty can be in terms of in-
also be high and the five-year criterion would come, expenditure or consumption we would
permit the identification of the most intense extend this so that other indicators (such as
forms of chronic poverty. assets or nutrition), or combinations of indi-
Second, the specific set of capability depri- cators (such as a household level human de-
vations that are used to identify chronic pov- privation index) could be utilized. 3 This
erty varies from study to study in this volume recognizes the always poor whose poverty score
and in the wider literature, as is the case with (income, consumption, nutritional status, hu-
general studies of poverty. But, relying on the man deprivation index, etc.) in each period is
usual income and consumption measures as below a defined poverty line; the usually poor
surrogates of chronic deprivation may not be whose mean poverty score over all periods is
enough where poverty is persistent, as multi- less than the poverty line but are not poor in
dimensional deprivation is likely to underpin every period; the churning poor with a mean
long-term poverty. Understanding the nature poverty score around the poverty line but who
and degree of multidimensionality is therefore are poor in some periods but not in others; the
an important task. As variables for poverty occasionally poor whose mean poverty score is
assessment, income and consumption are much above the poverty line but have experienced at
more likely to fluctuate over short periods of least one period in poverty; and, the never poor
time than are measures such as literacy or with poverty scores in all periods above the
tangible assets and thus to present poverty as a poverty line. These categories can be further
transient phenomena. aggregated into the chronic poor (always poor
Third, it is individuals who ultimately suffer and usually poor), the transient poor (churning
chronic poverty and whose life experiences poor and occasionally poor) and the nonpoor
should be tracked and analyzed. In most stud- (the never poor, continuing through to the al-
ies however the focus of analysis is the house- ways wealthy). 4
406 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

Mean score*

Poverty line* Poverty line*


Mean score*

Time Time Time Time Time


(Specific category) Always poor Usually poor Churning poor Occasionally poor Never poor (Specific category)

(Aggregate category) Chronic poor Transient poor Non- poor (Aggregate category)

Depending on data availability poverty could be assessed in terms of household expenditure, income, consumption, a nutritional measure,
a poverty index, a poverty scale or an assessment of assets/capitals.

Figure 1. The chronic poor, transient poor and nonpoor––a categorization. Source: Adapted from Jalan and Ravallion
(2000). Note that terms are used with different meanings than in Jalan & Ravallion.

While the study of chronic poverty is par- (b) Poverty concepts and chronic poverty
ticularly interested in the always poor and
usually poor, all of these categories can be used All of the general debates that surround the
in a dynamic sense to describe poverty transi- conceptualization of poverty 5 apply to chronic
tions. For example, a household can be seen as poverty. In particular, the question of whether
escaping chronic poverty (an escapee house- chronic poverty should be conceptualized as
hold) when it moves from being usually poor to income or consumption poverty or as some-
being only occasionally poor (Figure 2). Con- thing that has many dimensions, 6 has great
versely, a household can be viewed as de- significance. While it is now widely accepted by
scending into chronic poverty (a descending analysts and policy makers that poverty is de-
household) when its status shifts from being privation in terms of a range of capabilities in
never poor or transient poor to being always addition to income––education, health, human
poor over a period of time (Figure 2). The pa- and civil rights––and that these capabilities are
pers by Sen (this issue) and Matin and Hulme significant in their own right and in terms of
(this issue) explore the processes associated their contribution to economic growth and
with such transitions. Such processes are of income enhancement, the study of chronic
fundamental importance to policy formulation poverty has tended to focus on income/con-
to identify means by which the chronic poorÕs sumption poverty. The prime reason for this is
position can be improved and the probability that the analysis of poverty dynamics requires
of nonpoor and transient poor households panel data and virtually all the panel data sets
descending into chronic poverty can be re- available in developing countries have been
duced. based on surveys that have generally been used

Escapee
(occasionally poor) household
Level of
poverty (never poor)

Poverty line

Descending
(usually poor) (always poor) household

5 10 15
Time (years)

Figure 2. Poverty dynamics: escaping and descending households.


CONCEPTUALIZING CHRONIC POVERTY 407

to conceptualize poverty as material or physi- time. Only by including material and other as-
ological deprivation (Yaqub, 2003). 7 Such sets in the descriptive analysis can adequate
‘‘money-metric’’ approaches permit measure- explanations of persistence be achieved. This
ment 8 of changes in levels of household pov- has been a neglected aspect of poverty studies,
erty, comparisons over time (and, potentially but with the improvement in data availability
between regions or countries) and can be rig- from household surveys, censuses and demo-
orously analyzed to produce findings that can graphic and health surveys in many poor
be statistically tested (see McKay & Lawson, countries during the 1990s, it should now be
this issue, for a discussion of such quantitative possible to focus significantly more attention
analyses, and McCulloch & Calandrino, this on assets and asset change.
issue, for an example). In recent years the need to analyze poverty
Chronic poverty has typically been assessed from a multidimensional perspective has been
in two ways with income/consumption data: the increasingly recognized. This can be done by
‘‘spells approach,’’ which focuses on transitions more qualitative research methods, often with
into and out of poverty and is widely held roots in anthropology and sociology (for ex-
to overestimate transient poverty because of ample, see Wood, this issue, or Hulme, 2003) or
measurement error especially when the object by using nonmonetary variables in quantitative
of analysis is income or consumption; and the analyses (see McKay & Lawson, this issue, for
‘‘components approach,’’ which attempts to a discussion of this matter and Baulch &
isolate the permanent or underlying component Masset, this issue, for an example). Multidi-
of poverty from transitory shifts, and is mea- mensional conceptualizations are likely to be of
sured either by average income or consumption particular importance for the understanding of
over a period of time, or by a prediction of chronic poverty as the more dimensions on
income based on known household character- which an individual is deprived, the less likely s/
istics. The spells approach corresponds more to he is to escape poverty as the exit routes will be
the intuitive idea of chronic poverty as persis- limited. This argument has been used before to
tent poverty, while the identification of the explain extreme poverty:
chronic poor in the components approach is
also influenced by the depth of poverty––but Extreme poverty results when the lack of basic secu-
both provide valuable insights (McKay & rity simultaneously affects several aspects of peopleÕs
Lawson, this issue). Where both measures have lives, when it is prolonged, and when it severely com-
been used side by side, the components ap- promises peopleÕs chances of regaining their rights
proach typically produces 5–25% more chron- and reassuming their responsibilities in the foresee-
ically poor people (Yaqub, 2003). The spells able future. (Wresinski, 1987, quoted in Wodon,
2000, p. 3)
approach has often been used in studies con-
cerned with transient poverty and the policies
required to assist the transient poor emerge Whether the extremely or severely poor are
from poverty. The analysis of transitions be- also chronically poor remains an empirical
comes powerful when the factors underlying question (see below), but it is clear that a cu-
substantial and sustained transitions can be mulative lack of basic capabilities would make
isolated. While large sample surveys with a it extremely difficult for the poor to emerge
panel element can associate transitions with from poverty by their own efforts.
particular characteristics, they are usually weak Multidimensional poverty or deprivation has
in generating understanding of the processes most commonly been measured at national
involved. These require qualitative data (see level through the Human Development Index
Hulme et al., 2001, p. 15), or smaller scale, in- and other indices (for example, the physical
tensive surveys (e.g., Pryer, 1993) together with quality of life index). Measurement at individ-
judgments on the sustainability of the transi- ual or household level is not well developed.
tions observed. However, there is plenty of scope to revisit
While both spells and components ap- existing datasets, as demonstrated by Baulch
proaches represent essential aspects of chronic and Masset (this issue) for Vietnam. This shows
poverty, and have the advantage that plenty of that in a period of exceptionally high economic
quantitative data are available, it will be argued growth there was only modest overlap in the
below that a complete understanding of chronic subgroups of chronically poor people defined
poverty must also rely on developing a picture using expenditures, nutritional status and edu-
of peopleÕs assets and changes in assets over cational enrollments. A householdÕs chronic
408 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

monetary poverty was not a good predictor of living) and synchronically (with that of others)
chronic nutritional deficiencies or of chronic as an attempt to:
low educational status. This has significant
policy implications: effective education and psychologically mediate their experience . . . [This is] a
nutrition policies and interventions can be way for respondents to externalize the responsibility
considered to be interrupters of chronic poverty for the current situation. That is, by pointing to spe-
in their own right. This optimistic scenario cific events that impoverished everybody, by citing ex-
amples of those worse off than they, or the criminality
contrasts with developed countries where and duplicity of the wealthy, respondents feel that at
‘‘broader indicators of welfare seem to be more least to a certain extent their impoverishment was
strongly correlated across generations than not the result of personal failings, but of events utterly
narrow pecuniary indicators’’ (Yaqub, 2000, beyond their control, such as the transitions associ-
pp. 26–28). To gain a deeper understanding of ated with ‘‘independence,’’ or in some cases, with
chronic poverty, future quantitative research other shocks such as the earthquake in Armenia
will need to move beyond the money-metric . . . (Narayan et al., 1999, p. 57)
conceptualizations that have been dominant in
the past. According to Narayan et al. although they
In the last few years a strong case has been continue to battle against poverty, the long-
made that knowledge about poverty should term poor in developing countries tend to be
focus on the understandings of poor people relatively accepting of their poverty as com-
and the concepts that they utilize (Chambers, pared to the new poor in the transitional
1997). The most comprehensive study adopt- countries. The comparison generates important
ing a participatory approach, Voices of the questions surrounding the comparative psy-
Poor (Narayan, Patel, Schafft, Rademacher, & chological effects of chronic, transient and new
Koch-Schulte, 1999), did not specifically deal poverty in different contexts and on different
with the duration of poverty although some of generations, and the manner in which these
its materials suggest that poor people recog- relate to poor peopleÕs sense of vulnerability
nize an overlap between the persistence and and their coping strategies.
severity of poverty. In Ghana, for instance, Comparisons of ‘‘objective’’ (i.e., by external
the poorest people were described variously researchers) and ‘‘subjective’’ (i.e., by the poor
as: themselves) analyses of chronic poverty seem
likely to reach agreement on some issues but
. . . chronically hungry . . . extremely poor, the perenni- also to focus on causal factors operating at
ally needy and pathetic. This category was divided different scales. HulmeÕs (2003) study of a single
into two broad groups, first is ‘‘GodÕs Poor,’’ a group chronically poor household in Bangladesh
which includes factors for which there is no obvious concurs with Maymana that her husbandÕs
remedy––disability, age, widowhood and childless-
terminal illness, the depletion of household as-
ness. The second group is the ‘‘resourceless poor’’; this
includes . . . immigrant widowers and other landless sets to meet medical expenses, food costs, and
poor. (Narayan et al., 1999, pp. 28–29) the seizure of the householdÕs land by her
father-in-law were key factors in the descent of
A second relevant finding relates to the dif- her and her son into chronic poverty. But,
ferent way in which the newly poor in transi- where Maymana viewed these as being ulti-
tional countries approach poverty, as mately an act of God, Hulme highlights failures
compared with that of the poor in developing of public and private healthcare provision, a
countries. It is noted that while all the state- lack of social safety nets, a weak labor market,
ments gathered ‘‘reflect insecurity and material and governance failures (in both state and civil
deprivation,’’ the Eastern European and Cen- institutions) with regard to inheritance. While
tral Asian respondents ‘‘are filled with disbelief Maymana focused on causality at the micro-
and demoralization, and are much more likely and spiritual-level, Hulme emphasized the
to make comparative statements contrasting meso- and macro-level.
the better past with the intolerable present’’
(Narayan et al., 1999, p. 34). Expressing an (c) Vulnerability and chronic poverty
intense shame and humiliation often qualita-
tively different from that of the poor in devel- It can be argued that what poor people are
oping countries, the newly poor in transitional concerned about is not so much that their level
countries compare their standard of living both of income, consumption or capabilities are low,
diachronically (with their earlier standard of but that they are likely to experience highly
CONCEPTUALIZING CHRONIC POVERTY 409

stressful declines in these levels (Chambers, today HIV/AIDS is increasingly the associated
1983). This approach suggests that vulnerabil- diagnosis.
ity can be seen as the risk that a household will A key conceptual challenge for the study of
suddenly (but perhaps also gradually) reach a chronic poverty (and indeed poverty) is how to
position with which it is unable to cope, lead- treat those who die preventable deaths (Kan-
ing to catastrophe (hunger, starvation, family bur, 2002). These need to be incorporated in
breakdown, destitution or death). The litera- our analysis as they experience the most acute
ture on food security and insecurity is particu- form of deprivation (i.e., deprivation of all ca-
larly helpful in aiding the understanding of how pabilities) for all of the ‘‘lost’’ years of the life
vulnerability arises and strategies to reduce its they would have had (which in most cases is
impacts. more than five years). This must be included or
Vulnerability is not necessarily captured by a household whose young children die may be
income or consumption measures, though poor reported as escaping poverty when a similar
people according to these measures are likely to household that manages to raise all its children
have fewer buffers against shocks. Responses to (and thus achieve its developmental goals) is
shocks and the ability to cope with vulnerabil- seen as ‘‘failing’’ to escape from poverty as its
ity is very much dependent on assets, and the income/consumption levels per capita are lower
possession of or access to liquid assets are because of its larger size and higher dependency
particularly important to avoid impoverish- ratio. Theoretically this can be done by con-
ment. Liquid assets include disposable items tinuing to ‘‘count’’ the deprivation (i.e., total
(classically, jewelry and livestock) but could deprivation of all capabilities) that the dead
also refer to the resources people can draw person suffers for all of the lost years. Con-
down from social networks or the public purse. ceptually, this issue is of considerable impor-
People may become chronically poor as a result tance to the study of chronic poverty (and all
of one major or several smaller sequential aspects of poverty), but methodologically,
shocks that are not mitigated by their own ef- identifying preventable deaths, estimating how
forts or by public action. The absence of ef- many years of life were ‘‘lost’’ and placing a
fective public social protection characteristic of value on such years is enormously problematic.
poor and transitional countries puts a premium Concepts from the health sciences, such as
on social networks and private liquid assets. disability adjusted life years, may provide a
Wood (this issue) argues that some people stay basis for starting to think through this theo-
poor because their priority is to minimize vul- retical frontier.
nerability, and this is best achieved within a
patron-client relationship that in turn limits (d) Poverty dynamics and poverty severity
possible exit routes from poverty.
Many studies of poor people (for example The study of chronic poverty is the study of
Pryer, 1993; Hulme, 2003) find that vulnera- poverty dynamics with a focus on those who
bility to ill health is a particular problem. A are poor and have little or no mobility. The
common ‘‘cause’’ of chronic poverty in many goal of research is to understand the evolution
parts of the world occurs when a householdÕs of social structures, mobility within them, and
main income earner contracts a chronic or the particular immobility (if this is the case) of
terminal illness. This lowers household human the chronically poor at the bottom of the
assets and thus reduces income. To achieve structure. Social structures evolve little over
minimum consumption needs this is compen- five years, so even if available data limit
sated for by selling off natural and physical quantifiable measurement to such short peri-
assets, using any financial savings, taking on ods, analysis should take in a broader sweep.
debt, pulling children out of school to enter the Qualitative methods are likely to be critical
labor market, and mobilizing support from to the development of strong analytical models.
social networks. Consumption is also lowered, For example, in the United States several de-
but this still may not offset the additional costs cades of panel household survey data enabled
of medical (or funeral) expenses. A spiral of the identification of a four year threshold for
lowering income, rising expenses and liquidat- entry into chronic poverty: there was a 90%
ing assets reduces the household to a state of probability that an individual who was poor for
chronic poverty by the time the ‘‘bread winner’’ four years would be poor for their entire life
dies. In the past diseases such as tuberculosis (see also the analysis in Yaqub, 2003). In the
and cancer typified such ill-health spirals but majority of cases where such panel data are not
410 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

available, life history work across a range of (e) Summary


categories of individuals or households will
provide indications of where such thresholds To sum up, chronic poverty focuses on the
may lie. These can then be verified as quanti- durational aspect of poverty and has a partic-
tative panel data becomes available. Similarly, ular interest in poverty dynamics at individual
qualitative work will be needed to model life and household levels rather than aggregate
course poverty and IGT, in order to develop an and/or average poverty trends across popula-
understanding of the processes involved. The tions. The analysis of chronic poverty thus re-
degree of life course and intergenerational quires longitudinal data and, as most existing
poverty can of course be estimated from cross- datasets are quantitative and based upon in-
sectional data comparing the income, educa- come or consumption conceptualizations of
tional and other characteristics of different poverty, it has been dominated by money-
age groups and generations within the same metric approaches. It is arguably also for these
households, but this will not be an accurate money metric measures that the distinction
picture. It represents all the factors producing between chronic and transient poverty is most
poverty during a particular period for people at important, as their measurement at a point in
particular points in their lives. Nor will it be time does not provide information on dynam-
capable of supporting explanations. ics. But, there is a strong case that more mul-
In searching for explanations of patterns of tidimensional understandings of poverty are
mobility and the lack of it, asset change is likely required as income and consumption assess-
to be a central indicator in poor countries with ments have a tendency to underreport persis-
limited labor markets that could otherwise act tent deprivation and are unlikely to tease out
as mobility channels for people with low levels the complexity of the factors that keep poor
of assets. In this respect, patterns of mobility people poor. Quantitative analysis is now
in middle-income or transitional countries are moving beyond purely money-metric ap-
likely to be very different, if a growing formal proaches. The adoption of capital or assets
sector is able to absorb low skilled labor with based analytical frameworks can help to deepen
few alternative sources of income. Where such analyses as does the combination of quantita-
conditions do not obtain, improved well-being tive and qualitative research methods (given
depends critically on enhanced individual or that qualitative research methods offer new in-
household assets. Yaqub (2003) reports on re- sights, especially about processes, not easily
cent data from 23 developing countries showing captured by quantitative analysis).
that upward mobility was correlated with in-
creased landholdings and level of education, as
well as starting level of education; and down- 3. WHO IS CHRONICALLY POOR?
ward mobility correlated with increased house-
hold size and number of dependents. There is no body of theory at present that
Where chronically poor people have very allows a deductive answer to this question.
limited material assets (e.g., land, tools and Initial findings by the Chronic Poverty Re-
equipment, housing) it is particularly important search Centre identified a number of categories
to focus analysis on human assets such as of individuals, households and social groups
health and education, the accumulation or loss who are particularly likely to suffer chronic
of which make so much difference. Social and poverty: those experiencing deprivation be-
political networks and public policy may play cause of their stage in the life cycle (e.g., older
especially key roles in supporting or preventing people, children and widows: see Barrientos,
accumulation or loss, whereas the accumula- Gorman, & Heslop, this issue; Harper et al.,
tion of material assets is largely predicated on this issue); those discriminated against because
the development of and access to markets. of their social position at the local, regional or
Assets partly determine future income poten- national level, e.g., marginalized castes, ethnic,
tial, but also possibilities of ‘‘bounce back’’ racial or religious groups, refugees, indigenous
from crisis. Understanding the transformation people, nomads and pastoralists, migrants (see
processes (assets to income to assets to income Mehta & Shah, this issue; Sen, this issue);
etc.) over time is the central preoccupation of household members who experience discrimi-
livelihoods analysis suggesting that this body of nation within the household, e.g., female chil-
literature will contain much of relevance to the dren, children in households with many other
descriptive analysis of chronic poverty. children, daughters-in-law; those with long-
CONCEPTUALIZING CHRONIC POVERTY 411

term or severe health problems and highly and the chronically poor. The number of
challenging disabilities and impairments (see chronically poor in these countries ranges from
Yeo & Moore, this issue; Lwanga Ntale, 242 million to 580 million. It should be noted
Ndaziboneye, & Nalugo, 2002); people living in that the 10 countries include China and India,
remote rural areas, urban ghettos, and regions and thus the figures mainly reflect the ranges in
where prolonged violent conflict and insecurity those two countries. Without China and India
have occurred (see Amis, 2002; Bird & Shep- the range is 63 million to 80 million in eight
herd, this issue; Goodhand, this issue). Com- countries. Given the different incidences of both
monly the chronic poor experience several poverty and chronic poverty it is not possible to
forms of disadvantage at the same time. These extend these figures to make a global estimate
combinations keep them in poverty and block at present. The numbers are however clearly
off opportunities for improving their liveli- impressive and there is much supporting evi-
hoods. dence. Aliber (2001, this issue) estimates that
An inductive approach requires definitions of 18–24% of South AfricaÕs population suffered
chronic poverty which are relevant for local, chronic poverty during the 1990s and Sen (this
regional, or national contexts. Almost inevita- issue) illustrates that in Bangladesh tens of
bly it will be a heterogeneous group, though millions of people stayed poor in rural areas
there may be consistent findings across coun- between 1987–88 and 2000.
tries. At present the answer can only be sket- An alternative approach to this issue can be
ched as panel data are so rare and all attempts taken by making use of the UNCTAD Least
to measure poverty are fraught with prob- Developed Countries Report for 2002. The
lems. 9 least developed countries (LDCs) exclude most
At this point in time it is only possible to countries where there is reasonable poverty
‘‘guestimate’’ the number of chronically poor data based on household surveys. National
people. This is done very crudely in Table 1 for accounts data were used to estimate the inci-
10 low-income developing countries. In looking dence and absolute numbers of poor people
at this table though it is important to bear in over time. This showed substantial proportions
mind that the different studies on which it is and numbers in ‘‘extreme’’ poverty––living on
based use different methods to identify the poor less than $1 per day at 1985 purchasing power

Table 1. An indication of the percentages and numbers of chronically poor people in 10 low-income developing countries
Absolute (see note) Relative: Number of Number of
poorest absolutely relatively
quintile chronic poor chronic poor
Poor Poor (millions) (millions)
Duration Perm shortfall Duration
Bangladesh, rural (1970–77) 12 10
Bangladesh, rural (1987–89) 10 11
China, rural (1978–89) 8 88
China, rural Sichuan (1991–95) 6 72
China, rural southwest (1985–90) 20 220
China, urban (1997) 32
C^ote dÕIvoire (1987–88) 25 3
Egypt (1997–99) 19 12
El Salvador, rural (1995–97) 19 1
Ethiopia, rural (1994–95) 25 30 10 17 6
India, rural (1974–83) 3 n/a
India, rural (1968–70) 33 7 n/a n/a
India, rural Tamil Nadu (1977–85) 12 96
India, semi-arid rural (1975–83) 22 48 280
Indonesia, rural (1997–98) 9 11 19
Pakistan, rural 5 26 10 16 11
Papua New Guinea 15 1
Source: developed from Yaqub (2003, Table 1). The population denominators were taken from World Development
Indicators, 1990 and 2000. Figures have been rounded to nearest million. The number of absolutely poor has been
averaged where there are two incidence figures.
412 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

parity, including more than 50% of the popu- those around and below the US$1 a day level in
lation in 20 countries. If one assumes that in countries, where either economic growth or
such countries, where a majority of the popu- human development investments or both have
lation are usually extremely poor, those who been sluggish or even in decline, is unlikely to
are extremely poor at the present time are also have been substantially relieved during this
chronically poor, then an ‘‘order of magnitude’’ period. Indeed, 12 countries with a combined
of chronic poverty can be estimated. Clearly population of about 120 million saw increased
there are methodological problems in assuming poverty head counts over two decades––the
that poverty trends also reveal poverty dy- 1980s and 1990s (UNCTAD, 2002, p. 61).
namics––but here we are looking for an indi- Eleven of these were in Africa. In a further five
cation of the numbers of the chronic poor, African countries with a combined population
nothing more. Most of these were countries in of about 60 million, improvement in the 1990s
sub-Saharan Africa, in which both the inci- was not enough to offset decline which had
dence and numbers of poor people have in- occurred in the 1980s. A further six African
creased since the mid-1970s. The depth of countries had improved their poverty figures in
poverty has also increased in these countries. the 1980s but declined in the 1990s. Given that
233 million people subsisted on an average of these periods of time represent a minimum of
59 US cents per day in the late 1990s in African 10 years decline, including their populations
LDCs. This situation was significantly worse living on less than $1 a day in the chronically
than in Asian LDCs, where a further 44 million poor category seems justified. The total number
subsisted on an average of 90 US cents per day. of chronic poor in these LDCs was thus 147
This gives a total of 277 million. million. None of these countries was included
Table 2 provides details of the trends. Given in the earlier figures.
that around 80% of the population (nearer 90% Adding the two sets of figures together
in African LDCs) had lived on less than US$2 (which is undoubtedly methodologically prob-
per day, even the upwardly mobile within the lematic) gives a low estimate of 389 million and
poor would not have moved far. The poverty of a high estimate of 727 million chronically poor

Table 2. Poverty trends in LDCs and other developing countries, 1965–1999a


(1985 PPP $1-a-day international poverty line)
1965–69 1975–79 1985–89 1995–99
Population living on less than $1 a day (%)
39 LDCsb 48.0 48.5 49.0 50.1
African LDCs 55.8 56.4 61.9 64.9
Asian LDCs 35.5 35.9 27.6 23.0
22 other developing 44.8 32.5 15.0 7.5
countriesc
Number of people living on less than $1 a day (millions)
39 LDCsb 125.4 164.0 216.0 278.8
African LDCs 89.6 117.4 170.5 233.5
Asian LDCs 35.6 46.5 45.2 44.8
22 other developing 760.0 697.0 389.3 229.2
countriesc
Average daily consumption of those living below $1 a day (1985 PPP $)
39 LDCsb 0.70 0.71 0.69 0.64
African LDCs 0.64 0.66 0.64 0.59
Asian LDCs 0.84 0.85 0.89 0.90
22 other developing 0.86 0.91 0.96 0.93
countriesc
Source: UNCTAD (2002, p. 59).
a
Country group averages are weighted averages.
b
For LDCs sample composition see LDCs listed in UNCTAD (2002, Table 19).
c
Other developing countries are: Algeria, Cameroon, China, Congo, C^
ote dÕIvoire, Dominican Republic, Egypt,
Ghana, India, Indonesia, Jamaica, Kenya, Morocco, Namibia, Nigeria, Pakistan, Philippines, Sri Lanka, Thailand,
Tunisia, Turkey.
CONCEPTUALIZING CHRONIC POVERTY 413

people in 32 developing countries, including has been blamed for the low impact of growth
China and India. There are many countries on poverty in very low-income countries
with significant populations which do not yet (Naschold, 2002). But inequality at the societal
figure in this enumeration. 10 If these were in- level is a descriptive analytical construct; it has
corporated then the total number of chronically to be ‘‘unpacked’’ to gain explanatory power.
income poor people in the world (i.e., those Underlying unequal distribution of income is a
who have been poor for at least five years, but power structure, and a distribution of wealth
for many for all of their lives) would probably maintained by that power structure. Neither
range from 450 million to 900 million. Im- are static, but both must figure critically in the
proving on such crude estimates is a key task explanation of chronic poverty. Whether rich
for the CPRCÕs 2004 Chronic Poverty Report. people invest and create employment opportu-
nities, what their attitudes are to the poor (are
they seen as ‘‘deserving’’ or rather criminalized)
4. WHY DO PEOPLE STAY POOR? and how these shape public policy (Moore &
Devereux, 1999): these are critical questions
A vast range of theories seek to shed light on which will help determine the effects of in-
why poor people stay poor. These range from equality on poverty. In a globalized world the
the global level, highlighting the nature of rich are not only the local rich but also the
capitalist development, to the micro-level, fo- international rich (diasporas, expatriates) with
cusing on the personal characteristics and psy- feet in different worlds.
chology of poor individuals. Globally, there are The generalized poverty in the poorest
radicals who argue that the persistence of countries means that few resources are avail-
poverty is an inherent element of capitalist de- able for public or private investment. Income is
velopment (Fine, 2002). At the other extreme almost entirely dedicated to consumption of
come neoliberals who theorize that poverty basic necessities. Public expenditure per capita
persists because of obstacles to capitalism and is extremely low; the result is perpetuated
distortions in local, national and global mar- low levels of human development. Harnessing
kets (Dollar & Kraay, 2000). Lipton (1977), in external resources is thus critical. But, many of
an influential but highly criticized volume, ar- these countries endure ‘‘complex political
gued that ‘‘urban bias’’ was the underlying emergencies,’’ have weak or collapsed states,
source of continued poverty. While such broad provide little by way of investor confidence and
sweeping theories have great intellectual inter- have even scared off the international develop-
est there is no grand theoretical framework yet ment agencies, whose constituencies are con-
proposed that can explain the persistence of cerned about aid effectiveness and fiduciary
poverty in general, or the persistence of poverty risk, as well as employee security (Goodhand,
for countries or social groups in particular. The this issue). Some agencies 11 have been moving
nature of chronic poverty, and the causal fac- towards a policy of ‘‘aid selectivity,’’ privileging
tors that underpin it, differ from context to countries which ‘‘perform’’ better on economic
context and so explanations must also vary reform, citizen participation and increasing
(this point is argued through in Harper et al., public expenditure in the social sectors.
this issue). Where growth does occur in a very low-in-
At the national level theory has highlighted come country and is sustained (recent examples
‘‘bad governance’’ (Moore, 2001a, 2001b) and would be Uganda and Mozambique, but the
a lack of economic growth. Bad governance East Asian countries provide the longest and
leads to ‘‘bad’’ policies, which create a disabling best documented experiences) there are so
environment for savings, investment, risk-tak- many poor people that they are almost bound
ing and employment creation, and is often as- to benefit. But, this effect is reduced if growth
sociated with political instability, repression in GNP does not translate well into growth
and violent conflict. A lack of economic in private consumption, as when warlords or
growth, assuming that there is a positive foreign ventures seize the benefits; if growth
growth elasticity of poverty, means that poor depends on domestic resource mobilization or
people cannot raise their income or consump- saving, which reduces consumption and thus
tion. But, the growth elasticity of poverty in the degree of poverty reduction possible; and if
fact varies significantly (UNCTAD, 2002, p. the assets which poor people have are them-
74). Elasticities in the poorest developing selves poor and generate low returns (UNC-
countries are lowest. More recently inequality TAD, 2002, p. 75–76).
414 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

The result is some degree of differential ‘‘positive shock’’ or luck before relapsing. The
benefit from growth, with some people struc- transient poor were temporarily pushed below
turally excluded from participating in processes the poverty line by negative shocks to their
that lead to improved wellbeing. The micro- livelihoods (Aliber, this issue). Table 3 illus-
level accumulation or loss of assets, and what trates the importance of assets in the reported
influences this at local level, is key to under- experiences of households in Bangladesh as they
standing exclusion from the ‘‘demand side.’’ moved between poverty categories. Health,
Culture is also important at this level: the val- land and jobs feature prominently in these tales
ues and patterns of learned behavior shaping of upward and downward mobility. Underlying
attitudes, aspirations, coping strategies and re- health and acquisition of a job is education, an
sponses. While we do not wish to return to the unspoken asset in these stories; however, social
‘‘culture of poverty’’ debates as they were, re- networks may also be needed. Government
working the concept to fit into broader expla- makes little apparent difference. Luck and
nations of the persistence of poverty among judgment feature, as do negative aspects of the
certain groups is essential, particularly in the ‘‘culture of poverty’’ (drug addiction) and vul-
context of an increased focus on forms of ad- nerability to idiosyncratic shocks.
verse incorporation (see Wood, this issue). So- There are three particular dynamics central
cial exclusion theory offers other insights to the understanding of chronic poverty to
while also shedding light on wider political and which livelihood analysis can be applied. The
economic processes. But, those wider pro- first is the examination of households that start
cesses––the context––require standard political poor and stay poor: here the IGT of poverty is
economic analysis. the key process to be analyzed. Second, is the
At the meso- and micro-level there are several study of descending households (Figure 2) that
possible frameworks available for examining move from being nonpoor or occasionally poor
poverty and extensive listings of the economic, into chronic poverty. As illustrated below,
social, political and environmental factors that livelihoods analysis can deepen the under-
‘‘cause’’ chronic poverty (Hulme et al., 2001). In standing of why declines occur, why house-
common with many other researchers we be- holds strategies to gain security failed and of
lieve that livelihoods analysis (Ellis, 2000) has the ways in which different assets are depleted
particular relevance for understanding chronic when a household is unable to manage risk and
poverty as it permits the tracking over time of vulnerability. The third dynamic focus is on
a householdÕs assets (human, social, natural, ‘‘escape’’ (Figure 2). Again livelihoods analysis
physical and financial) in relation to its vulner- can help us to understand how household
ability context and the institutions, organiza- strategies and their interaction with other
tions and policies that mediate its external agents can achieve success.
economic and social relationships. A particular In order to understand the persistence of
strength of this approach is that it recognizes poverty over generations, it is possible to adapt
human agency and examines the way in which the livelihoods framework to take into account
household livelihood strategies are built around the intergenerational transfer, extraction, and
protecting, substituting, increasing and using absence of transfer of different forms of pov-
assets to produce security and achieve other erty-related assets, as well as the effects on such
goals. In addition, its focus on vulnerability is transfers of broader structures, processes, pol-
central to understanding chronic poverty. It is icies, and institutions; shocks and trends; and
not unproblematic, however, and is subject to livelihood strategies (see Table 4; Moore,
several critiques. The most significant of these is 2001a, 2001b). Table 4 should be conceived of
its failure to deal adequately with social rela- as a complex web of interactions rather than a
tionships and power (see Wood, this issue). At set of discrete factors.
the very least, when the framework is used it The descent of households into chronic
needs to be supplemented by an analysis of how poverty, from a position of being nonpoor or
any specific household fits into wider social transiently poor, can follow many trajectories
structures. and be associated with many factors and com-
Carter and MayÕs (1999) work based on the binations of factors (for example, see Table 3).
Kwazulu-Natal Income Dynamics Survey ar- Rapid descents can occur because of a cata-
gued that the chronically poor were character- strophic change in circumstances that depletes
ized by a structurally low asset base, and could household assets or places the household in a
only escape poverty temporarily due to some situation where its assets cannot be effectively
Table 3. Factors reported as leading to a change in the poverty status of households in Bangladesha
Status Present status
10 year
ago Always poor Usually poor Churning poor Occasionally poor Never poor

Always ––Continued landlessness ––Increased local demand ––Acquired a secure low ––A combination of ––No case found
poor ––Few assets for casual labour paid job events—head of household
––Continued poor health ––Remittances from daugh- ––Inherited small plot of acquired secure job, son got
status ter in garment factory land casual work and wifeÕs mi-
––Improved health status ––Mature child now work- cro-credit was successful
ing as rickshaw driver
––Remittances

CONCEPTUALIZING CHRONIC POVERTY


Usually ––Head of householdÕs ––Continuation of low level ––Child matures and gets ––Son acquires secure job ––No case found
poor health deteriorated of assets casual work with moderate pay
––Husband died ––Continuation of vulnera- ––Remittances from daugh- ––Increased crop produc-
––Cheated out of land bility blocks opportunity to ter in Dhaka tivity
––A run of mini-problems accumulate ––NGO micro-credit in-
creases wifeÕs earnings
Churn- ––Death of husband ––Son becomes a heroin ––Asset level continues at ––Head of household gets a ––Inheritance of land
ing poor ––Land washed away by addict—stops working and same level secure job ––A combination of good
river and had to migrate steals from family ––A mixture of good events ––Both sons get casual la- events (daughter gets gar-
––Serious long-term illness ––Major defraud by a bo- (son gets job) and bad bour on a regular basis ment factory job, head is
of head of household gus foreign employment events (wife is constantly ––Allocated khas land by able to lease more land)
contractor sick) local government
––Daughter loses job
Occa- ––Terminal illness of ––Terminal illness of head ––Health of husband and ––Assets level continues at ––Successfully establish new
sionally household head accompa- of household wife deteriorates roughly the same level business
poor nied by sale of land to pay ––Dowry payments for two ––Burning down of house ––A mixture of good events ––Saved, bought land, now
medical bills daughters ––Apparent land salinisa- and bad events secure income
––Catastrophic bad invest- ––A sequence of several tion
ment in a trading venture problems in close proximity
Never ––Terminal illness, sale of ––Terminal illness of head ––A combination of several ––Godown burns down ––Asset level continues
poor assets for medical bills, of household and asset de- factors ill health, bad in- with contents ––Bad events are more than
death of household head, pletion vestments, flooding ––Bad investment offset by good events
widow cheated out of land ––Loss of secure job due to ––Head of household age-
public sector retrenchment ing and no son

415
Source: Hulme, fieldnotes.
a
This table is illustrative as the poverty status is based on judgments from the information supplied by respondents and was not explicitly measured.
416 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

Table 4. The intergenerational transmission of poverty-related capital from ‘‘parent’’ to ‘‘child’’


What is transmitted? How is it transmitted?
Financial, material and environmental capital
––Cash ––Insurance, pensions
––Land ––Inheritance, bequests, dispossession
––Livestock ––Inter vivos gifts and loans
––Housing and other buildings ––Dowry, bridewealth
––Other productive/nonproductive physical assets ––Environmental conservation or
(e.g., rickshaw, plow, sewing machine, television) degradation
––Common property resources ––Labor bondage
––Debt
Human capital
––Educational qualifications, knowledge, skills, ––Socialization
coping and survival strategies ––Investment of time and capital in care
––Good mental and physical health ––Investment of time and capital in
––Disease, impairment education and training
––Intelligence? ––Investment of time and capital health,
nutrition
––Contagion, mother-to-child transmission
––Genetic inheritance
Social, cultural and political capital
––Traditions, institutions, norms of entitlement, and value systems ––Socialization and education
––Position in community (i.e., family, ‘‘name,’’ kin group, caste, ––Kinship
race, nationality, language, physical appearance) ––Locality
––Access to key decision-makers, political patrons, civil society ––Genetic inheritance
organizations and development agencies
––‘‘Culture of poverty?’’

What factors affect transmission?


––Norms of entitlement determining access to human capital, particularly education, health care and
nutrition
––Economic trends and shocks (e.g., commodification, shifts in terms of trade, hyperinflation)
––Access to and nature of markets. E.g., nature of labor market (employment opportunities for children,
young people and women; labor migration as livelihood strategy); access to financial market
––Presence, quality and accessibility of public, private, and community-based social services and safety nets
––Structure of household and family, including headship as well as gender, birth position, marital status and
age of ‘‘child’’ and ‘‘parent’’
––Child fostering practices
––Education and skill level of ‘‘parent’’
––Intent/attitude of ‘‘parent’’ and ‘‘child’’
––HIV/AIDS pandemic; other diseases regionally endemic; associated stigma
––Nature of living space e.g., security/conflict/violence, stigma, remoteness, sanitation

utilized. An unfortunately all too common ex- the context of a refugee camp there are few
ample of such a descent is when violent conflict opportunities to deploy human capital to earn
breaks out and a rural household flees to take an income and so dependency on food aid and
on refugee status. Its human capital is reduced handouts is required. If there are no health or
(deaths and impairments), physical capital is educational services available then the house-
destroyed (houses burned, equipment broken), holdÕs young people experience childhoods that
financial capital is rapidly used up (to pay for make it likely that they will be poor throughout
transport to flee and survival expenses), social their lifecourse.
capital is broken up (social networks are dis- For other households the slide into chronic
persed) and its natural capital is inaccessible. In poverty is more gradual and a set of processes
CONCEPTUALIZING CHRONIC POVERTY 417

and events erode assets until all opportunities to commonly they live in less accessible areas
improve household well-being are closed off. A (geographically or in terms of physical insecu-
detailed example is provided by Hulme (2003) rity), and have social positions that make con-
who charts the slide of Maymana and Mofizul tacting them problematic (for example, patrons
into chronic poverty. The terminal illness of the or male relatives stop them from meeting other
household head, the husband Hafeez, reduces people). Their ability to take up economic and
the householdÕs human capital and leads to the other opportunities is held back by intractable
selling off of physical assets to pay medical bills obstacles––individual and structural. This in-
and the withdrawal of children from school. At dicates that the ‘‘unit costs’’ of poverty reduc-
his death, his father takes control of the tion for chronically poor people will often be
householdÕs land (natural capital) and the higher, and sometimes much higher, than for
widow and impaired son (Maymana and Mo- those experiencing occasional spells of poverty.
fizul) survive by casual labor, gleaning, charity, Given these two points, at least one firm policy
borrowing and begging. Mechanisms for accu- conclusion can be reached: the serious pursuit
mulating assets, through a state food grant, are of chronic poverty reduction and the MDGs
blocked because of social relationships. The requires sustained financial support from
household becomes chronically poor, but is not wealthier countries and wealthier people on a
destitute. Destitution involves even ‘‘deeper’’ massive scale. Resource increases promised at
slides which usually involve the social outcast- Monterrey in 2002 12 fell well short of the ad-
ing of individuals (see Harriss-White, 2002, for ditional $50 billion a year thought to be needed
an excellent discussion of destitution). to achieve the MDGs. Even if the MDGs are
Ascending households experience the oppo- met in full, around a billion people will remain
site dynamic but they are not ‘‘ the flipside of the in poverty in 2015. If the vision of eliminating
coin.’’ Sen (this issue) finds that the factors as- absolute poverty, embraced at the 1995 Social
sociated with building up household assets and Summit, is to become reality, then the first steps
‘‘escape’’ from poverty are different from de- are to understand the problem and identify
clines. Of great importance are the householdÕs appropriate responses––both policy and prac-
stage in the life cycle, the dynamism and tice. But then comes the challenge of finding the
nature of the local economy and the capacity, or resources. This in turn, demands widespread
good fortune to avoid shocks. Combinations of political commitment by national governments
household agency and enterprise, in wider en- to finance poverty reduction for all––not just
vironments that are becoming more enabling for those in the best position to take up eco-
through market development and public action, nomic opportunities. For the wealthier do-
raise the prospects for positive trajectories. nor countries this goes beyond prescribing a
As the paragraphs above reveal, the under- development policy to direct actions on their
standing of why poor people stay poor is own economies. Opening up agricultural prod-
strengthening, but we need to extend this uct markets, removing subsidies to OECD
knowledge if policies to effectively tackle farmers, and improving the prospects for con-
chronic poverty are to be developed. flict prevention by reducing the arms trade can
reduce vulnerability to poverty and help to
tackle chronic poverty.
5. WHAT CAN BE DONE? CHRONIC In development policy terms, the intractable
POVERTY AND POLICY CHOICE nature of poverty must cause us to question
some of the orthodoxies of recent decades.
As the earlier sections have revealed, the Large numbers people who are poor now will
present knowledge base on the extent, nature still be poor in a generation. Poverty policies
and causes of chronic poverty in developing based on short-term interventions, focused on
countries is relatively rudimentary. There are creating opportunities for those who are able to
however, two firm observations that can be escape poverty and sustain themselves above
made. First, it is clear that hundreds of millions the poverty line, are clearly not enough. We
of people experience chronic poverty and that know that millions of people who are old, dis-
many are born poor, stay poor, die poor and abled, or disadvantaged by their remoteness,
have children that have a high probability ethnic group or multiple factors will never be
of impoverishment. Second, evidence from able to lift themselves out of poverty unaided.
the papers in this special issue shows that We know that for many people in chronic
‘‘reaching’’ the chronic poor is often difficult–– poverty, no amount of rhetoric on sustainability
418 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

can obscure the need for ongoing external as- Increasing ‘‘opportunity’’ so that economic
sistance for at least a generation. We must growth occurs, markets work for poor people
therefore design policies which respect the and the assets of the poor are built up should be
universal right to social protection and which beneficial for all poor people but there are im-
acknowledge the fact that some redistribution portant qualifications. The quality or type of
from rich to poor, within and between coun- economic growth, rather than the overall rate of
tries, must be part of the solution. growth, will be a key determinant of whether or
Beyond this ‘‘headline’’ policy implication not chronically poor people benefit. Pro-poor
things get more complicated because of the growth––increasing the demand for labor across
heterogeneity of the chronic poor and the many the economy, raising levels of public revenue
different factors and combinations of factors and raising the income levels of the chronic poor
that explain specific experiences of chronic (or, of their relatives, friends and neighbors)––
poverty in specific contexts. At a general level, could be beneficial. But rapid growth based on
it might appear that the orthodoxies of con- the exploitation of natural resources may well
temporary development policy (World Bank, weaken governance (Moore, 2001a, 2001b) and
2000) meet the needs of the chronic poor but thus work against the interests of the poor and
this needs a careful examination. The World chronic poor people. Where such resources are
Development Report 2000/2001 proposes that a concentrated at particular locations (diamonds,
strategy pursuing empowerment, opportunity oil, ores and minerals) ‘‘opening them up’’ may
and security (World Bank, 2000, pp. 6–11) initiate processes that undermine governance,
provides a comprehensive basis for poverty foster state collapse and create persistent de-
reduction. privation (see Goodhand, this issue). In con-
‘‘Empowerment’’ highlights issues of gover- texts where the benefits of growth are unequally
nance and social equity. While at a general shared then the chronic poor are the most likely
level the papers in this issue support the case to see no benefits or find that their livelihoods
that improved national and local governance are weakened (as in the UK over the 1980s and
would be good for the chronic poor, at more 1990s).
specific levels the analysis gets more compli- Three particular aspects of ‘‘opportunity’’
cated. While the World Bank (2000) highlights policy need careful consideration. First, as-
the benefits of decentralization to local and suming that simply deregulating markets will
community levels for the poor, the empirical open up opportunities for the chronic poor
proof for this is lacking. Indeed, there is con- shows a misunderstanding of the nature of
siderable evidence that local and community persistent poverty. Opening up markets for the
level institutions and leaders are as likely or chronic poor demands a context-specific strat-
more likely to exploit and manipulate the egy to work out what other barriers––gender,
chronic poor as are more centralized institu- ethnicity, caste, disability, etc.––constrain ac-
tions (see Bird, Moore, Hulme, & Shepherd, cess to markets, particularly labor markets,
2003; Hulme, 2003; Wood, this issue). The idea and working out what forms of intervention
of public, private, civic ‘‘partnerships’’ sounds are required to remove those constraints. As
comforting but it is so flexible it has little has been the case in South Asia and some
meaning in terms of which institutions will OECD countries, opening up labor markets
take on which responsibilities for assisting the for those who are discriminated against may
chronic poor. Recent thinking by some multi- require regulation. Second, the idea that
lateral and bilateral agencies about aid selec- ‘‘making markets work for poor people’’
tivity and governance (i.e., concentrating aid means that the bulk of services to poor people,
flows on countries that have ‘‘good’’ public including health, education and water, should
policies and policy processes) is an issue of be provided by the private sector needs to be
particular concern. Such a policy would reduce closely examined. While there are many and
aid flows to those countries with the deepest deep problems with state provided health, ed-
concentrations of long-term poverty. In par- ucation and water services in poorer countries
ticular, aid selectivity would divert interna- it is disingenuous of agencies and analysts
tional resources away from the bulk of AfricaÕs (e.g., Devarajan & ReinikkaÕs, 2002, draft of
chronic poor who, at least in some countries, the World Development Report 2004) to claim
are known to be increasing both in absolute that market-based provision (real markets not
numbers and in proportional terms (Aliber, hypothetical perfect markets) will more effec-
this issue). tively meet the needs of poor people. The great
CONCEPTUALIZING CHRONIC POVERTY 419

steps forward with health and educational chronic poor by reducing their access to health
standards in the developing world in the 20th and education services and causing rapid drops
century were closely associated with the public in income and consumption. The concept of a
provision of those services and commonly national system of social protection, rather than
showed some of the greatest gains––India, a tangle of social safety net ‘‘modules,’’ is more
China, Sri Lanka, Cuba––when state provision appropriate for understanding the ways in
was both dominant and effective. In practice, which chronically poor people, and those who
sustained action on chronic poverty is more are vulnerable to descending into persistent
likely to be in the public than the private sec- poverty, might achieve security. In addition,
tor. Consequently, making the public provision public actions that can tackle the social struc-
of basic services to poor people more effective tural relationships (see Wood, this issue) that
needs, at the very least, as much attention as trap people in poverty need to be formulated.
transferring such responsibilities to the mar- While much of the literature on risk and vul-
kets. 13 Third, policies to ‘‘. . . build their [the nerability highlights the ways in which poor
poorÕs] assets . . .’’ need an even greater em- people manage these largely through individual,
phasis if chronic poverty is to be addressed. household and community-based mechanisms
Chronic poverty is associated with low levels there is a vast ‘‘policy gap’’ about how to pro-
of assets (see Section 4). Building human cap- vide public and/or formal private sector secu-
ital, through education, health services and rity.
training may well need to be matched by The pressing priority for policy is to explore
building up the chronically poorÕs physical, how affordable old age pensions (contributory
natural and financial capital through grants, and noncontributory), unemployment and ill-
the redistribution of rights to land and natural ness grants and insurance, long-term savings
resources and by protecting rights to existing schemes, disability allowances, social assis-
assets. ‘‘Political and social difficulties often tance and emergency grants and loans can be
obstruct [such] change . . .’’ (World Bank, 2000, provided. Affordable means that––as in de-
p. 9), but these difficulties needed to be con- veloped countries––such social investment can
fronted, by recognizing that ‘‘empowerment’’ be paid for out of present and anticipated
is not about cosy ‘‘partnerships’’ but often future incomes and revenues. It does not mean
about raising the nonviolent capacities of without public subsidies and/or international
chronically poor people (and poor people) to transfers.
confront inequality and discrimination at local The policy emphasis of the 1980s and 1990s
and national levels. In addition, building up on livelihood promotion (Devereux, 2001)
the assets of the chronic poor is likely to in- and workfare (Peck, 2001) has advanced the
volve large-scale public investment in physical understanding of activities such as micro-fi-
infrastructure in the remote and less favored nance, micro-enterprise development, local
areas where the chronic poor are often con- infrastructural development through social
centrated. funds but means that there has been more
Improving the ‘‘security’’ of the livelihoods of limited experimentation with livelihood pro-
poor people and reducing the vulnerability of tection mechanisms. Indeed, in some circum-
chronically poor, poor and also nonpoor people stances the shift to promotional approaches
to shocks and adverse risks is central to tackling by governments, donors and nongovernmen-
chronic poverty. While ‘‘. . . a modular ap- tal organizations (NGOs) may have led to
proach to helping poor people manage risk . . .’’ resources being diverted from the chronically
(World Bank, 2000, p. 10) sounds neat, there is poor to the transient poor and vulnerable
a danger that such an approach exaggerates the nonpoor (Matin & Hulme, this issue). We
depth of understanding that we have about in- know that through the agency of the poor
security, views vulnerability as something that is livelihood promotion mechanisms can be con-
usually temporary and has a limited timeframe, verted to achieve livelihood protection (Hulme
and consequently, underestimates the scale of & Mosley, 1996) and vice versa (Lund, 2002)
resources and actions that will be needed. It also but how to link these formally remains a
fails to take account of the ways in which other challenge for policy design and institutional
policies can reduce or create insecurity. For provision.
example, structural adjustment programs in the At the heart of debates about social protec-
1980s and 1990s raised the vulnerability of tion will be questions of who pays and whether
many people and ‘‘created’’ many of todayÕs policies should be targeted or universal. The
420 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

findings of this volume point to the fact that tative analytical techniques and innovative
many chronically poor people actively con- qualitative approaches (participatory poverty
tribute (in terms of cash and labor) to their own assessments) and the growing number of panel
and their relatives and neighbors security. datasets available from developing countries
These resources are insufficient however, and now place researchers in a strong position to
there is a strong case for greater public (na- move beyond the study of poverty trends to the
tional and international) resourcing of social study of poverty dynamics.
protection programs. The question of whether The ultimate purpose behind this is to create
universal or targeted social protection mecha- knowledge that makes policy and social action
nisms are more or less likely to assist the more effective in poverty reduction and, in
chronic poor, and/or those vulnerable to be- particular, to ensure that those who are
coming chronically poor, is one for further in- chronically poor do not ‘‘miss out’’ from the
vestigation. Theoretically, strong cases can be benefits of global development. It would be
made for both positions. Empirically, the evi- ‘‘nice’’ if we could argue that this knowledge
dence is often contradictory 14 and is under will permit precision policy. At best however, it
researched. is a move toward making poverty-reduction
policy less crude, attempting to find specific
6. CONCLUSION interventions that can reach and assist the
chronic poor 15 and stopping interventions that
The understanding of poverty and human hurt, or increase the numbers, 16 of those
deprivation will always be partial but in recent trapped in poverty. While future policy must be
times the knowledge base has been greatly nuanced and much more research is required,
strengthened. An important aspect of this has one clear message does emerge. This is that the
been disaggregating the poor and examining the scale of resources needed to tackle contempo-
many factors and combinations of factors that rary chronic poverty must not merely achieve
cause the poverty of different poor people. One the promises made at Monterrey in 2002, but
component of this is understanding chronic move beyond them. Historically, chronic pov-
poverty: the poverty that persists for many years erty (including premature death) was the lot for
or a lifecourse and that may be transmitted much of humanity. With the resources and
across generations. This paper has sought to set a knowledge available today, however, there is
framework for analyzing chronic poverty. Con- no excuse for hundreds of millions still living in
ceptual advances (such as capability frame- chronic poverty. Knowledge and action must
works, vulnerability and livelihoods analysis), proceed hand in hand to ensure that poor
the development of more sophisticated quanti- people do not stay poor.

NOTES

1. Although the contemporary orthodoxy talks of 3. The reader should note that this is theoretically
‘‘partnerships’’ between the state, private sector and civil possible but operationally difficult because of the data
society it is underpinned by a neoliberal vision that sees the required and queries about which indicators to use and
private sector as the most effective means of achieving how to weight indicators. There is a need, however, for
economic growth and improved welfare. The state and experimentation with such measures and the construc-
civic action are allocated supplementary roles. For an tion of scoring systems that can capture key aspects
example, see the initial draft of the World Development of deprivation but are easy to collect accurate data about.
Report 2004 (Devarajan & Reinikka, 2002). This argues
that increased public expenditure will not improve services
for poor people despite the fact that in China and India–– 4. For a discussion of how this categorization can be
the two countries that account for the bulk of MDG adapted to incorporate the severity of poverty see Figure
achievement being close to target in the 1990s––the state 3 in Hulme, Moore, and Shepherd (2001, p. 13). The
has played a central role in service provision to the poor. reader should note however, that this categorization
needs further development. For example, a dramatic,
2. It should be noted that the methodology that short-term downturn or ‘‘spike’’ in the welfare of a
UNCTAD (2002) uses and the validity of the idea of churning poor or occasionally poor household could
chronically poor countries are both being challenged. lead to an event (e.g., wasting of children, a preventable
CONCEPTUALIZING CHRONIC POVERTY 421

impairment or death) that has long-term negative ity on performance grounds, but implementation has
implications for an individual or household and is thus been slow.
chronic.
12. International Conference on Financing for Devel-
5. These include whether poverty is seen as a lack of opment, Monterrey, Mexico, March 18–22, 2002. The
income or multidimensional deprivation, as an absolute Monterrey Consensus urged all donors to meet the 0.7%
or relative form of deprivation and whether poverty target and the United States and European Union
should be defined by technical specialists or by poor committed themselves to significantly increase aid levels,
people themselves. generating an estimated US$12 billion a year. See DFID
evidence to the UK Parliamentary Select Committee on
6. The work of Sen (1981, 1999) has been particularly International Development, Annex A.
influential in encouraging analysts to conceptualize
poverty in a multidimensional way, such that his ideas, 13. It should be noted that private sector provision of
explicitly or implicitly, underpin much of the relevant basic services is likely to need a public regulatory
literature. authority to oversee standards. Creating regulatory
capacity within the state may be more problematic than
7. In addition, the people who come along to ana- improving public service delivery.
lyze the raw data are most often economists trained
in the analysis of income, consumption and expenditure. 14. In South Africa (Aliber, this issue; Lund, 2002)
the noncontributory old age pension helps protect
8. The accuracy of the measurements made is of course many households from a descent into chronic poverty
dependent on the degree of measurement error within and/or keep them above the poverty line. In contrast,
any specific dataset. universal food subsidies in Sri Lanka provided social
protection but at an unsustainable cost (Hulme &
9. The widely utilized figures on US$1 a day poverty Sanderatne, 1995). Similarly, while some targeted
that are central to the MDGs and that have been schemes, such as food stamps in Sri Lanka, are riddled
allocated substantial resourcing for their preparation with Type 1 and 2 error (Hulme & Sanderatne, 1995)
and updating are subject to considerable doubts. See others reach the poor and needy effectively (Munro,
Reddy and Pogge (2002) and Wade (2002) for presen- 2000).
tations on the main criticisms.

15. For an example of these see Matin and Hulme (this


10. In Africa, Nigeria, Kenya, C^ ote dÕIvoire and
issue).
Zimbabwe to name a few. In South Asia, Pakistan.
Most of the rest of Asia has not been included, nor has
Latin America. 16. For example, as mentioned earlier, the shocks
created by the rapid implementation of structural
11. The World Bank, The European Union and the adjustment policies are the very mechanisms that drive
Netherlands have all declared commitments to selectiv- people into chronic poverty.

REFERENCES

Aliber, M. (2001). Study of the incidence and nature of Baulch, B., & Masset, E. (this issue). Do monetary
chronic poverty and development policy in South and non-monetary indicators tell the same story
Africa: an overview. CPRC Working Paper 3. about chronic poverty? A study of Vietnam in
Manchester: IDPM, University of Manchester. the 1990s. World Development, 31(3), 441–
Aliber, M. (this issue). Chronic poverty in South Africa: 453.
incidence, causes and policies. World Development, Bird, K., Moore, K., Hulme, D., & Shepherd, A. (2002).
31(3), 473–490. Chronic poverty and remote rural areas. CPRC
Amis, P. (2002). Thinking about chronic urban poverty. Working Paper 13. Manchester: IDPM, University
CPRC Working Paper 12. Manchester: IDPM, of Manchester.
University of Manchester. Bird, K., & Shepherd, A. (this issue). Livelihoods and
Barrientos, A., Gorman, M., & Heslop, M. (this issue). chronic poverty in semi-arid Zimbabwe. World
Old age poverty in developing countries: contribu- Development, 31(3), 591–611.
tion and dependence in later life. World Development, Carter, M. R., & May, J. (1999). One kind of freedom:
31(3), 555–570. poverty dynamics in post-apartheid South Africa.
422 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

Madison: IFPRI, University of Natal, University of Lwanga Ntale, C., Ndaziboneye, B., & Nalugo, J.
Wisconsin. (2002). Chronic poverty and disability in Uganda.
Chambers, R. (1983). Rural development: putting the last Mimeo at CPRC. Manchester: IDPM, University of
first. Essex: Longman. Manchester.
Chambers, R. (1997). Whose reality counts? Putting the Matin, I., & Hulme, D. (this issue). Programs for the
last first. London: ITDG. poorest: learning from the IGVGD program in
Corcoran, M. (1995). Rags to riches: poverty and Bangladesh. World Development, 31(3), 649–667.
mobility in the United States. Annual Review of McCulloch, N., & Calandrino, M. (this issue). Vulner-
Sociology, 21, 237–267. ability and chronic poverty in rural Sichuan. World
Devarajan, S., & Reinikka, R. (2002). Making services Development, 31(3), 613–630.
work for poorer people (Draft outline of World McKay, A., & Lawson, D. (this issue). Assessing the
Development F). Washington, DC: World Bank. extent and nature of chronic poverty in low income
Devereux, S. (2001). Social protection for the poor. IDS countries: issues and evidence. World Development,
Working Paper 142. Brighton, Sussex: IDS. 31(3), 425–439.
Dollar, D., & Kraay, A. (2000). Growth is good for the Mehta, A. K., & Shah, A. (this issue). Chronic poverty
poor. Policy Research Working Paper 2587. Wash- in India: incidence, causes and policies. World
ington, DC: World Bank. Development, 31(3), 491–511.
Ellis, F. (2000). Rural livelihoods and diversity in devel- Moore, K. (2001a). Frameworks for understanding the
oping countries. Oxford: Oxford University Press. intergenerational transmission of poverty and well-
Fine, B. (2002). Globalisation and development: the being in developing countries. CPRC Working Paper
imperative of political economy. In ‘Towards a new 8. Manchester: IDPM, University of Manchester.
political economy of development: globalisation and Moore, M. (2001b). Political underdevelopment: what
governance’ conference. Political Economy Research causes bad governance? Public Management Review,
Centre (PERC), University of Sheffield, July 2002. 3(3), 385–418.
Goodhand, J. (this issue). Enduring disorder and Moore, M., & Devereux, S. (Eds.). (1999). Nationalising
persistent poverty: a review of the linkages between the anti-poverty agenda. IDS Bulletin, 30(2).
war and chronic poverty. World Development, 31(3), Munro, L. (2000). Poverty, vulnerability and social safety
631–648. nets in Zimbabwe since 1990. PhD thesis, University
Harriss-White, B. (2002). A note on destitution. Oxford: of Machester, Unpublished data.
Queen Elizabeth House, University of Oxford. Narayan, D., Patel, R., Schafft, K., Rademacher, A., &
Harper, C., Marcus, R., & Moore, K. (this issue). Koch-Schulte, S. (1999). Can anyone hear us?
Enduring poverty and the conditions of childhood: Washington, DC: World Bank.
lifecourse and intergenerational poverty transmis- Naschold, F. (2002). Why inequality matters for poverty.
sions. World Development 31(3), 535–554. ODI/DFID-ERC Inequality Briefing Paper No. 2,
Hulme, D. (2003). Why does poverty endure? Maymana ODI, London.
and MofizulÕs story. CPRC Working Paper 22. OECD. (2001). The millennium development Goals.
Manchester: IDPM, University of Manchester. DAC, Paris: OECD.
Hulme, D., Moore, K., & Shepherd, A. (2001). Chronic Peck, J. (2001). Workfare states. New York: Guildford
poverty: meanings and analytical frameworks. Press.
CPRC Working Paper 2. Manchester: IDPM, Uni- Pryer, J. (1993). The impact of adult ill-health on
versity of Manchester. household income and nutrition in Khulna, Bangla-
Hulme, D., & Mosley, P. (1996). Finance against poverty. desh. Environment and Urbanisation, 5(2), 35–49.
London: Routledge. Reddy, S. G., & Pogge, T. W. (2002). How not to count
Hulme, D., & Sanderatne, N. (1995). Sri Lanka: the poor. Unpublished working paper. Available:
democracy and accountability in decline (1948–93). www.socialanalysis.org.
In J. Healy, & W. Tordoff (Eds.), Votes and budgets: Sen, A. (1981). Poverty and famines: an essay on
comparative studies in accountable governance in the entitlement and deprivation. Delhi: Oxford University
south (pp. 109–152). London: Macmillan. Press.
Jalan, J., & Ravallion, M. (2000). Is transient poverty Sen, A. (1999). Development as freedom. Oxford: Oxford
different? Evidence for rural China. Journal of University Press.
Development Studies, 36(6), 82–99. Sen, B. (this issue). Drivers of escape and descent:
Kanbur, R. (2002). Conceptual challenges in poverty changing household fortunes in rural Bangladesh.
and inequality: one development economistÕs per- World Development, 31(3), 513–534.
spective. In Cornell Conference on Conceptual Chal- UNCTAD. (2002). The least developed countries report
lenges in Poverty and Inequality, New York: Cornell 2002––escaping the poverty trap. Geneva: United
University, April 2002. Nations Conference on Trade and Development
Lipton, M. (1977). Why poor people stay poor: a study of (UNCTAD).
urban bias in world development. London: Temple Wade, R. (2002). Globalisation, poverty and income
Smith. distribution: does the liberal argument hold? Sheffield:
Lund, F. (2002). Crowding in care, security, and Political Economy Research Centre (PERC), Uni-
microenterprise formation: revisiting the role of the versity of Sheffield.
state in poverty reduction and development. Journal Wodon, Q. (2000). Extreme poverty and human rights:
of International Development, 14(6), 681–694. essays on Joseph Wresinski. Background Paper for
CONCEPTUALIZING CHRONIC POVERTY 423

the World Development Report 2000/2001. Wash- ties, new vulnerabilities’ workshop. Brookings Insti-
ington DC: World Bank. tution, Carnegie Endowment.
Wood, G. D. (this issue). Staying secure, staying poor: Yaqub, S. (2003). Chronic poverty: scrutinising pat-
the ‘‘Faustian bargain.’’ World Development, 31(3), terns, correlates, and explorations. CPRC Working
455–471. Paper 21. Manchester: IDPM, University of Man-
World Bank. (2000). World development report 2000/ chester.
2001 attacking poverty. Washington DC: World Yeo, R., & Moore, K. (this issue). Including disabled
Bank. people in poverty reduction work: Ônothing about us,
Yaqub, S. (2000). Intertemporal welfare dynamics: without usÕ. World Development, 31(3), 571–
extents and causes. In ‘Globalization: new opportuni- 590.

You might also like