You are on page 1of 15

Ibn Khaldun

Ibn Khaldun (/ˈɪbən kælˈduːn/; Arabic: ‫أﺑﻮ زﻳﺪ ﻋﺒﺪ اﻟﺮﺣﻤﻦ ﺑﻦ ﻣﺤﻤﺪ ﺑﻦ ﺧﻠﺪون‬
Ibn Khaldun
‫اﻟﺤﻀﺮﻣﻲ‬, Abū Zayd ‘Abd ar-Raḥmān ibn Muḥammad ibn Khaldūn al-
Ḥaḍramī; 27 May 1332 – 17 March 1406) was a leading Tunisian Arab
historiographer and historian.[7] He is widely considered as a forerunner of the
modern disciplines of historiography, sociology, economics, and
demography.[n 1][8][n 2]

He is best known for his book, the Muqaddimah or Prolegomena


("Introduction"). The book influenced 17th-century Ottoman historians like
Kâtip Çelebi, Ahmed Cevdet Pasha and Mustafa Naima, who used the theories
in the book to analyze the growth and decline of the Ottoman Empire.[9] 19th-
century European scholars acknowledged the significance of the book and
considered Ibn Khaldun to be one of the greatest philosophers of the Middle
Ages.[10]

Contents
Family Bust of Ibn Khaldoun in the entrance
Education of the Kasbah of Bejaia, Algeria
Political career Personal
Later life
Born 27 May 1332
Works Tunis, Hafsid
Kitāb al-ʻIbar
Sultanate of Ifriqiya
Social thought
Minor works Died 17 March 1406
Legacy (aged 73)
Egypt Cairo, Mamluk
Ottoman Empire Sultanate of Egypt
Europe
Religion Islam
Modern historians
Public recognition Nationality Arab

Bibliography Denomination Sunni[1]


See also Jurisprudence Maliki[2]
Notes Creed Ash'ari[3]
References Main Historiography
Sources interest(s) Sociology
Further reading Economics
External links Demography
English Political science
Non-English
Notable Cyclical theory of
idea(s) Empires,
Asabiyyah,
Family
Economic Growth
Ibn Khaldun's life is relatively well-documented, as he wrote an autobiography Theory,[4] Supply
(‫اﻟﺘﻌﺮﻳﻒ ﺑﺎﺑﻦ ﺧﻠﺪون ورﺣﻠﺘﻪ ﻏﺮﺑﺎ وﺷﺮﻗﺎ‬, at-Taʻrīf bi-ibn Khaldūn wa-Riḥlatih and Demand
Gharban wa-Sharqan[12]) ("Presenting Ibn Khaldun and his Journey West and Theory,[5] Supply-
East") in which numerous documents regarding his life are quoted word-for- side economics
word.
Senior posting
Abdurahman bin Muhammad bin Muhammad bin Muhammad bin Al-Hasan bin Influenced by
Jabir bin Muhammad bin Ibrahim bin Abdurahman bin Ibn Khaldun, generally Ibn Jarir, Ibn Hazm, At-Turtushi,[6]
known as "Ibn Khaldūn" after a remote ancestor, was born in Tunis in AD 1332 Ibn Abi Zar, Muhammad ibn
(732 AH) into an upper-class Andalusian family of Arab descent,[7] the family's Zakarīya Rāzi
ancestor was from a Yemeni Arab who shared kinship with Waíl ibn Hujr, a
Influenced
companion of the Islamic Prophet Muhammad. His family, which held many
Ibn al-Khatib, Ibn al-Azraq, Ibn al-
high offices in Andalusia, had emigrated to Tunisia after the fall of Seville to the
Sakkak, Al-Maqrizi, Mahdi Amel
Reconquista in AD 1248. Under the Tunisian Hafsid dynasty, some of his family
held political office; his father and grandfather, however, withdrew from political
life and joined a mystical order. His brother, Yahya Khaldun, was also a historian who wrote a
book on the Abdalwadid dynasty and was assassinated by a rival for being the official
historiographer of the court.[13]

In his autobiography, Khaldun traces his descent back to the time of Muhammad through an
Arab tribe from Yemen, specifically the Hadhramaut, which came to the Iberian Peninsula in
the 8th century, at the beginning of the Islamic conquest: "And our ancestry is from
Hadhramaut, from the Arabs of Yemen, via Wa'il ibn Hujr also known as Hujr ibn 'Adi, from
the best of the Arabs, well-known and respected." (p. 2429, Al-Waraq's edition). However, the
biographer Mohammad Enan questions his claim and suggests that his family may have been
Muladis who pretended to be of Arab origin to gain social status.[14] Enan also mentions a
well-documented past tradition that certain Berber groups delusively "aggrandize" themselves Ibn Khaldun Life-size
with some Arab ancestry. The motive of such inventions was always the desire for political bronze bust sculpture of
Ibn Khaldun that is part
and societal ascendancy. Some speculate that of the Khaldun family and elaborate that Ibn
of the collection at the
Khaldun himself was the product of the same Berber ancestry as the native majority of his Arab American National
birthplace. A point supporting that posits that his unusual focus on and admiration Maharlika Museum (Catalog
Berbers reveals a deference towards them that is born of a vested interest in preserving them Number 2010.02).
in the realm of conscious history. Islamic scholar Muhammad Hozien contends, "The false Commissioned by The
[Berber] identity would be valid however at the time that Ibn Khaldun's ancestors left Tunisian Community
Center and Created by
Andulsia and moved to Tunisia they did not change their claim to Arab ancestry. Even in the
Patrick Morelli of Albany,
times when Berbers were ruling, the reigns of Al-Marabats and al-Mowahids, et. al. The Ibn NY in 2009. It was
Khalduns did not reclaim their Berber heritage."[15] Khaldun's tracing of his own genealogy inspired by the statue of
and surname are thought to be the strongest indication of Arab Yemenite ancestry.[7][16] Ibn Khaldun erected at
the Avenue Habib
Bourguiba (built in 1932)
Education in Tunis.[11]
His family's high rank enabled Ibn Khaldun to study with the best teachers in Maghreb. He
received a classical Islamic education, studying the Quran, which he memorized by heart,
Arabic linguistics; the basis for understanding the Qur'an, hadith, sharia (law) and fiqh (jurisprudence). He received certification
(ijazah) for all of those subjects.[17] The mathematician and philosopher Al-Abili of Tlemcen introduced him to mathematics,
logic and philosophy, and he studied especially the works of Averroes, Avicenna, Razi and Tusi. At the age of 17, Ibn Khaldūn
lost both his parents to the Black Death, an intercontinental epidemic of the plague that hit Tunis in 1348–1349.[18]

Following family tradition, he strove for a political career. In the face of a tumultuous political situation in North Africa, that
required a high degree of skill in developing and dropping alliances prudently to avoid falling with the short-lived regimes of the
time.[19] Ibn Khaldūn's autobiography is the story of an adventure, in which he spends time in prison, reaches the highest offices
and falls again into exile.

Political career
At the age of 20, he began his political career in
the chancellery of the Tunisian ruler Ibn Tafrakin
with the position of Kātib al-'Alāmah (seal-
bearer),[20] which consisted of writing in fine
calligraphy the typical introductory notes of
official documents. In 1352,
Abū Ziad, the sultan of
Constantine, marched on Tunis
and defeated it. Ibn Khaldūn, in
Birth home of Ibn Khaldoun at Tunis
any case unhappy with his
respected but politically
meaningless position, followed his teacher Abili to Fez. There, the Marinid
sultan, Abū Inan Fares I, appointed him as a writer of royal proclamations, but
Ibn Khaldūn still schemed against his employer, which, in 1357, got the 25-year-
old a 22-month prison sentence. Upon the death of Abū Inan in 1358, Vizier al-
Hasān ibn-Umar granted him freedom and reinstated him to his rank and offices.
Ibn Khaldūn then schemed against Abū Inan's successor, Abū Salem Ibrahim III,
with Abū Salem's exiled uncle, Abū Salem. When Abū Salem came to power, he
gave Ibn Khaldūn a ministerial position, the first position to correspond with Ibn
Khaldūn's ambitions.

The treatment that Ibn Khaldun received after the fall of Abū Salem through Ibn- The mosque in which Ibn Khaldoun
studied
Amar ʻAbdullah, a friend of Ibn Khaldūn's, was not to his liking, as he received
no significant official position. At the same time, Amar successfully
prevented Ibn Khaldūn, whose political skills he knew well, from allying
with the Abd al-Wadids in Tlemcen. Ibn Khaldūn, therefore, decided to
move to Granada. He could be sure of a positive welcome there since at
Fez, he had helped the Sultan of Granada, the Nasrid Muhammad V, regain
power from his temporary exile. In 1364, Muhammad entrusted him with a
diplomatic mission to the king of Castile, Pedro the Cruel, to endorse a
peace treaty. Ibn Khaldūn successfully carried out this mission and politely
Ibn Khaldun on the 10 Tunisian dinar bill
declined Pedro's offer to remain at his court and have his family's Spanish
possessions returned to him.

In Granada, Ibn Khaldūn quickly came into competition with Muhammad's vizier, Ibn al-Khatib, who viewed the close
relationship between Muhammad and Ibn Khaldūn with increasing mistrust. Ibn Khaldūn tried to shape the young Muhammad
into his ideal of a wise ruler, an enterprise that Ibn al-Khatib thought foolish and a danger to peace in the country. History proved
al-Khatib right, and at his instigation, Ibn Khaldūn was eventually sent back to North Africa. Al-Khatib himself was later accused
by Muhammad of having unorthodox philosophical views and murdered despite an attempt by Ibn Khaldūn to intercede on behalf
of his old rival.

In his autobiography, Ibn Khaldūn tells little about his conflict with Ibn al-Khatib and the reasons for his departure. Orientalist
Muhsin Mahdi interprets that as showing that Ibn Khaldūn later realised that he had completely misjudged Muhammad V.

Back in Africa, the Hafsid sultan of Bougie, Abū ʻAbdallāh, who had been his companion in prison, received him with great
enthusiasm and made Ibn Khaldūn his prime minister. Ibn Khaldūn carried out a daring mission to collect taxes among the local
Berber tribes. After the death of Abū ʻAbdallāh in 1366, Ibn Khaldūn changed sides once again and allied himself with the Sultan
of Tlemcen, Abū l-Abbas. A few years later, he was taken prisoner by Abu Faris Abdul Aziz, who had defeated the sultan of
Tlemcen and seized the throne. He then entered a monastic establishment and occupied himself with scholastic duties until 1370.
In that year, he was sent for to Tlemcen by the new sultan. After the death of ʻAbdu l-Azīz, he resided at Fez, enjoying the
patronage and confidence of the regent.

Ibn Khaldūn's political skills and, above all, his good relationship with the wild Berber tribes were in high demand among the
North African rulers, but he had begun to tire of politics and constantly switching allegiances. In 1375, he was sent by Abū
Hammu, the ʻAbdu l Wadid Sultan of Tlemcen, on a mission to the Dawadida Arabs tribes of Biskra. After his return to the West,
Ibn Khaldūn sought refuge with one of the Berber tribes in the west of Algeria, in the town of Qalat Ibn Salama. He lived there
for over three years under their protection, taking advantage of his seclusion to write the Muqaddimah "Prolegomena", the
introduction to his planned history of the world. In Ibn Salama, however, he lacked the necessary texts to complete the work.[21]
Therefore, in 1378, he returned to his native Tunis, which had meanwhile been conquered by Abū l-Abbas, who took Ibn
Khaldūn back into his service. There, he devoted himself almost exclusively to his studies and completed his history of the world.
His relationship with Abū l-Abbas remained strained, as the latter questioned his loyalty. That was brought into sharp contrast
after Ibn Khaldūn presented him with a copy of the completed history that omitted the usual panegyric to the ruler. Under
pretence of going on the Hajj to Mecca, something a Muslim ruler could not simply refuse permission for Ibn Khaldūn was able
to leave Tunis and to sail to Alexandria.

Later life
Ibn Khaldun said of Egypt, "He who has not seen it does not know the power of
Islam."[22] While other Islamic regions had to cope with border wars and inner
strife, the Mamluks let Egypt experience a period of economic prosperity and
high culture. However, even in Egypt, where Ibn Khaldūn lived out his days, he
could not stay out of politics completely. In 1384, the Egyptian Sultan, al-Malik
udh-Dhahir Barquq, made him professor of the Qamhiyyah Madrasah and the
grand qadi of the Maliki school of fiqh (one of four schools, the Maliki school
was widespread primarily in Western Africa). His efforts at reform encountered
resistance, however, and within a year, he had to resign his judgeship. A
contributory factor to his decision to resign may have been the heavy personal
blow that struck him in 1384, when a ship carrying his wife and children sank
off the coast of Alexandria. Ibn Khaldun now decided to complete the
pilgrimage to Mecca, after all.

After his return in May 1388, Ibn Khaldūn concentrated more strongly on a
purely-educational function at various Cairo madrasas. At court, he fell out of Ibn Khaldoun Statue and Square,
favor for a time, as during revolts against Barquq, he had, apparently under Mohandessin, Cairo
duress, with other Cairo jurists, issued a fatwa against Barquq. Later relations with Barquq returned to normal, and he was once
again named the Maliki qadi. Altogether, he was called six times to that high office, which, for various reasons, he never held
long.

In 1401, under Barquq's successor, his son Faraj, Ibn Khaldūn took part in a military campaign against the Mongol conqueror,
Timur, who besieged Damascus in 1400. Ibn Khaldūn cast doubt upon the viability of the venture and really wanted to stay in
Egypt. His doubts were vindicated, as the young and inexperienced Faraj, concerned about a revolt in Egypt, left his army to its
own devices in Syria and hurried home. Ibn Khaldūn remained at the besieged city for seven weeks, being lowered over the city
wall by ropes to negotiate with Timur, in a historic series of meetings that he reported extensively in his autobiography.[23] Timur
questioned him in detail about conditions in the lands of the Maghreb. At his request, Ibn Khaldūn even wrote a long report about
it. As he recognized Timur's intentions, he did not hesitate, on his return to Egypt, to compose an equally-extensive report on the
history of the Tatars, together with a character study of Timur, sending them to the Merinid rulers in Fez (Maghreb).

Ibn Khaldūn spent the next five years in Cairo completing his autobiography and his history of the world and acting as teacher
and judge. Meanwhile, he was alleged to have joined an underground party, Rijal Hawa Rijal, whose reform-oriented ideals
attracted the attention of local political authorities. The elderly Ibn Khaldun was placed under arrest. He died on 17 March 1406,
one month after his sixth selection for the office of the Maliki qadi (Judge).

Works

Kitāb al-ʻIbar
Ibn Khaldūn's main work is the Kitāb al-ʻIbar or "Book of Lessons" (full title: Kitāb al-ʻIbar wa-Dīwān al-Mubtadaʼ wa-l-
Khabar fī Taʼrīkh al-ʻArab wa-l-Barbar wa-Man ʻĀṣarahum min Dhawī ash-Shaʼn al-Akbār "Book of Lessons, Record of
Beginnings and Events in the History of the Arabs and the Berbers and Their Powerful Contemporaries"), originally conceived as
a history of the Berbers but later expanded in focus to a universal history.

Al-Muqaddimah is a complete history of the world and inspects the rise and fall of empires. The book touches on sociology,
geography, history, and economics.[24] The Kitāb al-ʻIbār divides into seven books. Al-Muqaddimah (Introduction),[25][26] is
considered the first book. Books Two to Five cover World History of Humanity up to the authors own time. Books Six and Seven
give the history of the Berber peoples and the Maghreb. Despite errors originating in the 14th century Fez work, Rawḍ al-Qirṭās,
(probably by Ibn Abi Zar), from which Khaldun drew upon, al-'Ibar remains an important source for Berber history. The
historiographical work has been further criticised for its synthesis of multiple (sometimes contradictory) sources in the absence of
original citations, and here Khaldun departs from the classical style of Arab historians such as Ibrahim ibn ar-Raqīq (~d.1028) or
al-Mālikī.[27]

Concerning the discipline of sociology, he described the dichotomy of sedentary life versus nomadic life as well as the inevitable
loss of power that occurs when warriors conquer a city. According to the Arab scholar Sati' al-Husri, the Muqaddimah may be
read as a sociological work. The work is based around Ibn Khaldun's central concept of 'aṣabiyyah, which has been translated as
"social cohesion", "group solidarity", or "tribalism". This social cohesion arises spontaneously in tribes and other small kinship
groups; it can be intensified and enlarged by a religious ideology. Ibn Khaldun's analysis looks at how this cohesion carries
groups to power but contains within itself the seeds – psychological, sociological, economic, political – of the group's downfall,
to be replaced by a new group, dynasty or empire bound by a stronger (or at least younger and more vigorous) cohesion. Some of
Ibn Khaldun's views, particularly those concerning the Zanj people of sub-Saharan Africa,[28] have been cited as a racist,[29]
though they were not uncommon for their time. According to the scholar Abdelmajid Hannoum, Ibn Khaldun's description of the
distinctions between Berbers and Arabs were misinterpreted by the translator William McGuckin de Slane, who wrongly inserted
a "racial ideology that sets Arabs and Berbers apart and in opposition" into his translation of the Muqaddimah.[30]
Perhaps the most frequently cited observation drawn from Ibn Khaldūn's work is the notion that when a society becomes a great
civilization (and, presumably, the dominant culture in its region), its high point is followed by a period of decay. This means that
the next cohesive group that conquers the diminished civilization is, by comparison, a group of barbarians. Once the barbarians
solidify their control over the conquered society, however, they become attracted to its more refined aspects, such as literacy and
arts, and either assimilate into or appropriate such cultural practices. Then, eventually, the former barbarians will be conquered by
a new set of barbarians, who will repeat the process. One contemporary reader of Khaldun has read this as an early business cycle
theory, though set in the historical circumstances of the mature Islamic empire.

There is some evidence that indicates western thinkers were aware, at least on some level, of Khaldun’s work and of those who
did few acknowledged his contributions, either on purpose or because they were not aware of the original source. It is therefore
unclear just how much the Classical Economist’s knew of Khaldun and his work. Georgetown University Professor Ibrahim
Oweiss, an economist and historian, states that Schumpeter and David Hume both mention Khaldun’s labor theory of value—it is
important to note that Khaldun did not refer to it as a labor theory of value or theory.[31]

Ibn Khaldun outlines an early example of political economy. He describes the economy as being composed of value-adding
processes; that is, labour and skill is added to techniques and crafts and the product is sold at a higher value. He also made the
distinction between "profit" and "sustenance", in modern political economy terms, surplus and that required for the reproduction
of classes respectively. He also calls for the creation of a science to explain society and goes on to outline these ideas in his major
work, the Muqaddimah. In Al-Muqaddimah Khaldun states, “Civilization and its well-being, as well as business prosperity,
depend on productivity and people’s efforts in all directions in their own interest and profit”.[32] Ibn Khaldun diverged from
norms that Muslim historians followed and rejected their focus on the credibility of the transmitter and focused instead on the
validity of the stories and encouraged critical thinking.[33] Ibn Khaldun strayed away from relying on religious dogma or
tradition, even though it was incorporated in the book, instead opting to use a more scientific approach.

Ibn Khaldun also outlines early theories of division of labor, taxes, scarcity, and economic growth.[34] Khaldun was also one of
the first to study the origin and causes of poverty; he argued that poverty was a result of the destruction of morality and human
values. [35] Even more interesting, he looked at what factors contribute to wealth such as consumption, government, and
investment—a precursor to our modern GDP-formula.[36] Khaldun also argued that poverty was not necessarily a result of poor
financial decision-making but of external consequences and therefore the government should be involved in alleviating
poverty.[37]

Ibn Khaldun also believed that the currency of an Islamic monetary system should have intrinsic value and therefore be made of
gold and silver (such as the dirham). He emphasized that the weight and purity of these coins should be strictly followed: the
weight of one dinar should be one mithqal (the weight of 72 grains of barley, roughly 4.25 grams) and the weight of 7 dinar
should be equal to weight of 10 dirhams (7/10 of a mithqal or 2.96 grams).[38]

Social thought
Ibn Khaldun's epistemology attempted to reconcile mysticism with theology by dividing science into two different categories, the
religious science that regards the sciences of the Qur'an and the non-religious science. He further classified the non-religious
sciences into intellectual sciences such as logic, arithmetic, geometry, astronomy, etc. and auxiliary sciences such as language,
literature, poetry, etc. He also suggested that possibly more divisions will appear in the future with different societies. He tried to
adapt to all possible societies’ cultural behavior and influence in education, economics and politics. Nonetheless, he didn't think
that laws were chosen by just one leader or a small group of individual but mostly by the majority of the individuals of a
society.[39]

To Ibn Khaldun, the state was a necessity of human society to restrain injustice within the society, but the state means is force,
thus itself an injustice. All societies must have a state governing them in order to establish a society. He attempted to standardize
the history of societies by identifying ubiquitous phenomena present in all societies. To him, civilization was a phenomena that
will be present as long as humans exist. He characterized the fulfillment of basic needs as the beginning of civilization. At the
beginning, people will look for different ways of increasing productivity of basic needs and expansion will occur. Later the
society starts becoming more sedentary and focuses more on crafting, arts and the more refined characteristics. By the end of a
society, it will weaken, allowing another small group of individuals to come into control. The conquering group is described as an
unsatisfied group within the society itself or a group of desert bandits that constantly attack other weaker or weakened societies.

In the Muqaddimah, his most important work, he thoughtfully and scrupulously discusses an introduction of philosophy to history
in a general manner, based on observable patterns within a theoretical framework of known historical events of his time. He
described the beginnings, development, cultural trends and the fall of all societies, leading to the rise of a new society which
would then follow the same trends in a continuous cycle. Ibn Khaldun did not create a perfect model for a society during his life,
but he did think there was a need for a new model to manage society to ensure its continuous economic growth. Also, he
recommended the best political approaches to develop a society according to his knowledge of history. He heavily emphasized
that a good society would be one in which a tradition of education is deeply rooted in its culture.[20] Ibn Khaldun (1987)
introduced word asabiya (solidarity, group feeling, or group consciousness), to explain tribalism. The concept of asabiya has been
translated as "social cohesion," "group solidarity," or "tribalism." This social cohesion arises spontaneously in tribes and other
small kinship groups (Rashed,2017).

Ibn Khaldun believed that too much bureaucracy, such as taxes and legislations, would lead to the decline of a society, since it
would constrain the development of more specialized labor (increase in scholars and development of different services). He
believed that bureaucrats cannot understand the world of commerce and do not possess the same motivation as a businessman.[20]

In his work the Muqaddimah, Ibn Khaldun emphasizes human beings' faculty to think (fikr) as what determines human behavior
and ubiquitous patterns. This faculty is also what inspires human beings to form into a social structure to co-operate in division of
labor and organization. According to Zaid Ahmand in Epistemology and the Human Dimension in Urban Studies, the fikr faculty
is the supporting pillar for all philosophical aspects of Ibn Khaldun's theory related to human beings’ spiritual, intellectual,
physical, social and political tendencies.

Another important concept he emphasizes in his work is the mastery of crafts, habits and skills. These takes place after a society
is established and according to Ibn Khaldun the level of achievement of a society can be determined by just analyzing these three
concepts. A society in its earliest stages is nomadic and primarily concerned with survival, while a society at a later stage is
sedentary, with greater achievement in crafts. A society with a sedentary culture and stable politics would be expected to have
greater achievements in crafts and technology.[20]

Ibn Khaldun also emphasized in his epistemology theory the important aspect that educational tradition plays to ensure the new
generations of a civilization continuously improve in the sciences and develop culture. Ibn Khaldun argued that without the
strong establishment of an educational tradition, it would be very difficult for the new generations to maintain the achievements
of the earlier generations, let alone improve them.

Another way to distinguish the achievement of a society would be the language factor of a society, since for him the most
important element of a society would not be land, but the language spoken by them. He was surprised that many non-Arabs were
really successful in the Arabic society, had good jobs and were well received by the community. "These people were non-Arab by
descent, but they grew up among the Arabs who possessed the habit of Arabic," Ibn Khaldun once recalled, "[b]ecause of this,
they were able to master Arabic so well that they cannot be surpassed."[40] He believed that the reason why non-Arabs were
accepted as part of Arab society was due to their mastery of the Arabic language.

Advancements in literary works such as poems and prose where another way to distinguish the achievement of a civilization, but
Ibn Khaldun believed that whenever the literary facet of a society reaches its highest levels it ceases to indicate societal
achievements anymore, but is an embellishment of life. For logical sciences he established knowledge at its highest level as an
increase of scholars and the quality of knowledge. For him the highest level of literary productions would be the manifestation of
prose, poems and the artistic enrichment of a society.[41]
Minor works
From other sources we know of several other works, primarily composed during the time he spent in North Africa and Al-
Andalus. His first book, Lubābu l-Muhassal, a commentary on the Islamic theology of Fakhr al-Din al-Razi, was written at the
age of 19 under the supervision of his teacher al-Ābilī in Tunis. A work on Sufism, Shifā'u l-Sā'il, was composed around 1373 in
Fes, Morocco. Whilst at the court of Muhammed V, Sultan of Granada, Ibn Khaldūn composed a work on logic, ʻallaqa li-s-
Sulṭān.

Legacy

Egypt
Ibn Khaldun's historical method had very few precedents or followers in his
time. While Ibn Khaldun is known to have been a successful lecturer on
jurisprudence within religious sciences, only very few of his students were aware
of, and influenced by, his Muqaddimah.[45] One such student, Al-Maqrizi,
praised the Muqaddimah, although some scholars have found his praise, and that
of others, to be generally empty and lacking understanding of Ibn Khaldun's A Laffer Curve with a maximum
methods.[45] revenue point at around a 70%, as
estimated by Trabandt and Uhlig
Ibn Khaldun also faced primarily criticism from his contemporaries, particularly (2009).[42] Laffer cites Ibn Khaldun's
Ibn Hajar al-`Asqalani. These criticisms included accusations of inadequate observation that "at the beginning of
historical knowledge, an inaccurate title, disorganization, and a style resembling the dynasty, taxation yields a large
revenue from small assessments. At
that of the prolific Arab literature writer, Al-Jahiz. Al-Asqalani also noted that
the end of the dynasty, taxation
Ibn Khaldun was not well-liked in Egypt because he opposed many respected
yields a small revenue from large
traditions, including the traditional judicial dress, and suggested that this may assessments." as a
have contributed to the reception of Ibn Khaldun's historical works.[45] The predecessor.[43][44]
notable exception to this consensus was Ibn al-Azraq, a jurist who lived shortly
after Ibn Khaldun and quoted heavily from the first and fourth books of the
Kitab al-‘Ibar, in developing a work of mirrors for princes.[45]

Ottoman Empire
Ibn Khaldun's work found some recognition with Ottoman intellectuals in the 17th century. The first references to Ibn Khaldun in
Ottoman writings appeared in the middle of the 17th century, with historians such as Kâtip Çelebi naming him as a great
influence, while another Turkish Ottoman historian, Mustafa Naima, attempted to use Ibn Khaldun's cyclical theory of the rise
and fall of empires to describe the Ottoman Empire.[45] Increasing perceptions of the decline of the Ottoman Empire also caused
similar ideas to appear independently of Ibn Khaldun in the 16th century, and may explain some of the influence of his works.[45]

Europe
In Europe, Ibn Khaldun was first brought to the attention of the Western world in 1697, when a biography of him appeared in
Barthélemy d'Herbelot de Molainville's Bibliothèque Orientale. However, some scholars believe that Ibn Khaldun's work may
have first been introduced to Europe via Ibn Arabshah's biography of Tamerlane, translated to Latin, which covers a meeting
between Ibn Khaldun and Tamerlane.[46] According to Ibn Arabshah, during this meeting, Ibn Khaldun and Tamerlane discussed
the Maghrib in depth, as well as Tamerlane's genealogy and place in history.[47] Ibn Khaldun began gaining more attention from
1806, when Silvestre de Sacy's Chrestomathie Arabe included his biography together with a translation of parts of the
Muqaddimah as the Prolegomena.[48] In 1816, de Sacy again published a biography with a more detailed description on the
Prolegomena.[49] More details on and partial translations of the Prolegomena emerged over the years until the complete Arabic
edition was published in 1858. Since then, the work of Ibn Khaldun has been extensively studied in the Western world with
special interest.[50]

Early European works on Ibn Khaldun suffered heavily from colonial influences and orientalism, as many sociologists considered
North Africa to be unworthy of studying in the19th century.[45] Additionally, many sociologists viewed Ibn Khaldun as the only
North African sociologist worth studying. Reynold A. Nicholson praised Ibn Khaldun as a uniquely brilliant Muslim sociologist,
but discounted Khaldun's influence.[46] Spanish Philosopher José Ortega y Gasset viewed the conflicts of North Africa as a
problem that stemmed from a lack of African thought, and praised Ibn Khaldun for making sense of the conflict by simplifying it
to the relationship between the nomadic and sedentary modes of life.[46]

Ibn Khaldun's contributions to economics were ignored by historians like Joseph Schumpeter, who wrote that "we may safely
leap over 500 years to the epoch of St Thomas Aquinas" as late as 1954.[46] While Ibn Khaldun lived after St Thomas Aquinas,
Schumpeter makes only passing references to Khaldun, and excludes Khaldun's predecessors.[46] However, modern historians
have recognized the contributions of Ibn Khaldun and many of his predecessors.[51]

Modern historians
Modern historians have also been complimentary in their analysis of Ibn Khaldun's works, and acknowledgement of his
contemporaries or standing compared to European scholars is increasingly common. Influential British historian and international
affairs specialist Arnold J. Toynbee has called Ibn Khaldun's Muqaddimah "the greatest work of its kind."[52] Ernest Gellner,
once a professor of philosophy and logic at the London School of Economics, considered Khaldun's definition of government[n 3]
the best in the history of political theory.[53]

More moderate views on the scope of Ibn Khaldun's contributions have emerged. Arthur Laffer, for whom the Laffer curve is
named, acknowledged that Ibn Khaldun's ideas, as well as others, precede his own work on that curve.[54] A focus on
understanding the nuances of Ibn Khaldun's contributions is present, with scholars commenting on the specifics of Khaldun's
work, such as "Ibn Khaldun chose to ignore all those crafts which are neither necessary...nor honorable" and that Ibn Khaldun
"depicts what really happens. ... he does not discuss whether the state ought, or ought not, to interfere".[55]

As a historian and sociologist, Ibn Khaldun was recognized by the British philosopher Robert Flint, who wrote: "as a theorist of
history he had no equal in any age or country until Vico appeared, more than three hundred years later. Plato, Aristotle, and
Augustine were not his peers, and all others were unworthy of being even mentioned along with him". Ibn Khaldun's work on
evolution of societies also influenced Egon Orowan, who termed the concept of socionomy.[56] While Ibn Khaldun's record-
keeping is usually passed over in favor of recognizing his contributions to the science of history, Abderrahmane Lakhsassi wrote
"No historian of the Maghreb since and particularly of the Berbers can do without his historical contribution."[57]

Public recognition
Public recognition of Ibn Khaldun has increased in recent years. In 2004, the Tunisian Community Center launched the first Ibn
Khaldun Award to recognize a Tunisian/American high achiever whose work reflects Ibn Khaldun's ideas of kinship and
solidarity. The Award was named after Ibn Khaldun for him being universally acknowledged as the Father of Sociology and also
for the convergence of his ideas with the organization's objectives and programs. In 2006, the Atlas Economic Research
Foundation launched an annual essay contest[58] for students named in Ibn Khaldun's honor. The theme of the contest is "how
individuals, think tanks, universities and entrepreneurs can influence government policies to allow the free market to flourish and
improve the lives of its citizens based on Islamic teachings and traditions."[58] In 2006, Spain commemorated the 600th
anniversary of the death of Ibn Khaldun, by orchestrating an exhibit titled "Encounter of Civilizations: Ibn Khaldun."[59] In 2011,
Ibn Khaldun's birthday was recognized by a Google Doodle, which was publicized in North Africa and the Arabian Peninsula.[60]
Bibliography
Kitāb al-ʻIbar wa-Dīwān al-Mubtadaʼ wa-l-Khabar fī Taʼrīkh al-ʻArab wa-l-Barbar wa-Man ʻĀṣarahum min Dhawī
ash-Shaʼn al-Akbār
Lubābu-l-Muhassal fee Uswoolu-d-Deen
Shifā'u-s-Sā'il
ʻAl-Laqaw li-s-Sulṭān
Ibn Khaldun. 1951 ‫ اﻟﺘﻌﺮﻳﻒ ﺑﺈﺑﻦ ﺧﻠﺪون ورﺣﻠﺘﻪ ﻏﺮﺑﺎ وﺷﺮﻗﺎ‬Al-Taʻrīf bi Ibn-Khaldūn wa Riħlatuhu Għarbān wa
Sharqān. Published by Muħammad ibn-Tāwīt at-Tanjī. Cairo (Autobiography in Arabic).
Ibn Khaldūn. 1958 The Muqaddimah : An introduction to history. Translated from the Arabic by Franz Rosenthal.
3 vols. New York: Princeton.
Ibn Khaldūn. 1967 The Muqaddimah : An introduction to history. Trans. Franz Rosenthal, ed. N.J. Dawood.
(Abridged).
Ibn Khaldun, 1332-1406. 1905 'A Selection from the Prolegomena of Ibn Khaldūn (https://archive.org/details/sele
ctionfrompro00ibnk/)'. Trans. Duncan Macdonald

See also
Asabiyyah Science in medieval Islam
Chanakya Social cycle theory
Egon Orowan Averroes
List of Muslim historians Abulcasis
Historiography of early Islam Ibn Arabi
Laffer curve Ibn Tufail
Muqaddimah

Notes
1. "...regarded by some Westerners as the true father of historiography and sociology".[61]
"Ibn Khaldun has been claimed the forerunner of a great number of European thinkers, mostly sociologists,
historians, and philosophers".(Boulakia 1971)
"The founding father of Eastern Sociology".[62]
"This grand scheme to find a new science of society makes him the forerunner of many of the eighteenth and
nineteenth centuries system-builders such as Vico, Comte and Marx." "As one of the early founders of the
social sciences...".[63]
2. "He is considered by some as a father of modern economics, or at least a major forerunner. The Western
world recognizes Khaldun as the father of sociology but hesitates in recognizing him as a great economist
who laid its very foundations. He was the first to systematically analyze the functioning of an economy, the
importance of technology, specialization and foreign trade in economic surplus and the role of government
and its stabilization policies to increase output and employment. Moreover, he dealt with the problem of
optimum taxation, minimum government services, incentives, institutional framework, law and order,
expectations, production, and the theory of value".Cosma, Sorinel (2009). "Ibn Khaldun's Economic
Thinking". Ovidius University Annals of Economics (Ovidius University Press) XIV:52–57 (http://www.ovidius-s
tec.ro/html/anale/ENG/cuprins%20rezumate/2009%20vol2.pdf)
3. "an institution which prevents injustice other than such as it commits itself"

References
1. "Ibn Khaldun – His Life and Work" (http://www.muslimphilosophy.com/ik/klf.htm#Intro). Retrieved 25 February
2017.
2. Ahmad, Zaid (2010). "Ibn Khaldun". In Oliver Leama (ed.). The Biographical Encyclopaedia of Islamic
Philosophy. Continuum. doi:10.1093/acref/9780199754731.001.0001 (https://doi.org/10.1093%2Facref%2F9780
199754731.001.0001). ISBN 9780199754731.
3. Doniger, Wendy (1999). Merriam-Webster's Encyclopedia of World Religions. Merriam-Webstar Inc. p. 82.
ISBN 978-0-87779-044-0.
4. Muqaddimah 2:272–73 quoted in Weiss (1995) p 30
5. Weiss 1995, p. 31 quotes Muqaddimah 2:276–78
6. In al-Muqaddima, Ibn Khaldun cites him as a pioneer in sociology
7. Savant, Sarah Bowen (2014). Genealogy and Knowledge in Muslim Societies: Understanding the Past (https://bo
oks.google.com/books?id=rySrBgAAQBAJ&lpg=PP1&pg=PA77#v=onepage&q&f=false). Edinburgh University
Press. p. 77. ISBN 978-0-7486-4497-1. "Banu Khaldun al-Hadrami (Yemen, but not Qahtan), to which belonged
the famous historian Ibn Khaldun. The family's ancestor was 'Uthman ibn Bakr ibn Khalid, called Khaldun, a
Yemeni Arab among the conquerors who shared kinship with the Prophet's Companian Wa'il ibn Hujr and who
settled first in Carmona and then in Seville." The Historical Muhammad, Irving M. Zeitlin, (Polity Press, 2007), 21;
"It is, of course, Ibn Khaldun as an Arab here speaking, for he claims Arab descent through the male line.". The
Arab World: Society, Culture, and State, Halim Barakat (University of California Press, 1993), 48;"The renowned
Arab sociologist-historian Ibn Khaldun first interpreted Arab history in terms of badu versus hadar conflicts and
struggles for power." Ibn Khaldun, M. Talbi, The Encyclopaedia of Islam, Vol. III, ed. B. Lewis, V.L. Menage, C.
Pellat, J. Schacht, (Brill, 1986), 825; "Ibn Khaldun was born in Tunis, on I Ramadan 732/27 May 1332, in an Arab
family which came originally from the Hadramawt and had been settled at Seville since the beginning of the
Muslim conquest...."
8. • Joseph J. Spengler (1964). "Economic Thought of Islam: Ibn Khaldun", Comparative Studies in Society and
History, 6(3), pp. 268 (https://www.jstor.org/pss/177577)-306.
• Jean David C. Boulakia (1971). "Ibn Khaldûn: A Fourteenth-Century Economist", Journal of Political Economy,
79(5), pp. 1105–18 (https://www.jstor.org/pss/1830276).
9. Lewis, Bernard (1986). "Ibn Khaldūn in Turkey". In Ayalon, David; Sharon, Moshe (eds.). Studies in Islamic
history and civilization: in honour of Professor David Ayalon. Brill. pp. 527–30. ISBN 978-965-264-014-7
10. Bernard Lewis: "Ibn Khaldun in Turkey", in: Ibn Khaldun: The Mediterranean in the 14th Century: Rise and Fall of
Empires, Foundation El Legado Andalusí, 2006, ISBN 978-84-96556-34-8, pp. 376–80 (376) S.M. Deen (2007)
Science under Islam: rise, decline and revival. p. 157. ISBN 1-84799-942-5
11. "Arab American National Museum : Online Collections" (http://arabamerican.pastperfect-online.com/33769cgi/mw
eb.exe?request=record;id=A9A7FFF1-3E51-46CC-8C72-966442091673;type=101). Retrieved 25 February
2017.
12. Published by Muḥammad ibn Tāwīt aṭ-Ṭanjī, Cairo 1951
13. ‹See Tfd›(in French) « Lettre à Monsieur Garcin de Tassy », Journal asiatique, troisième série, tome XII, éd.
Société asiatique, Paris, 1841, p. 491 (https://books.google.com/books?id=blQpAAAAYAAJ&pg=PA484&dq=Zak
ariya+Yahya+Ibn+Khaldoun&hl=fr#PPA491,M1)
14. A., Khaldun: His life and Works for Mohammad Enan
15. "Notes on Ibn Khaludn's Life" (http://www.muslimphilosophy.com/ik/knts.htm#n1). Retrieved 25 February 2017.
16. Al-Muqqadimah. Ibn Khaldun
17. Muhammad Hozien. "Ibn Khaldun: His Life and Work" (http://www.muslimphilosophy.com/ik/klf.htm). Islamic
Philosophy Online. Retrieved 2008-09-19.
18. "Saudi Aramco World: Ibn Khaldun and the Rise and Fall of Empires" (http://archive.aramcoworld.com/issue/200
605/ibn.khaldun.and.the.rise.and.fall.of.empires.htm). archive.aramcoworld.com. Retrieved 2017-12-06.
19. "Ibn Khaldun – His Life and Work" (http://www.muslimphilosophy.com/ik/klf.htm). www.muslimphilosophy.com.
Retrieved 2017-12-06.
20. "Ibn Khaldun: His Life and Works | Muslim Heritage" (http://muslimheritage.com/article/ibn-khaldun-his-life-and-w
orks). muslimheritage.com. Retrieved 2017-12-05.
21. Ibn Khaldun's Political and Economic Realism (http://alhassanain.org/english/?com=book&id=1008). 2016-03-26.
22. "Ibn Khaldūn | Muslim historian" (https://www.britannica.com/biography/Ibn-Khaldun#ref3458).
23. Bent, Josephine van den (2016-05-03). " "None of the Kings on Earth is Their Equal in ʿaṣabiyya:" The Mongols
in Ibn Khaldūn's Works". Al-Masāq. 28 (2): 171–86. doi:10.1080/09503110.2016.1198535 (https://doi.org/10.108
0%2F09503110.2016.1198535). ISSN 0950-3110 (https://www.worldcat.org/issn/0950-3110).
24. Schmidt, Nathaniel. Ibn Khaldun: Historian, Sociologist and Philosopher. Universal Books, 1900.
25. Ibn Khaldun the Muqaddimah. An Introduction to History.Translated from the Arabic by Franz Rosenthal. In Three
Volumes. First Volume. 606 pages. Bollingen Foundation Series xliii. Princeton University Press. 1958. Prof. Dr.
Darcy Carvalho. Feausp. Sao Paulo. Brazil. 2016
26. The Muqaddimah Volume 1 (https://archive.org/stream/THEMUQADDIMAHVOLUME1)
27. See articles by Modéran and Benabbès in Identités et Cultures dans l'Algérie Antique, University of Rouen, 2005
(ISBN 2-87775-391-3).
28. Southgate, Minoo (1984). "The Negative Images of Blacks in Some Medieval Iranian Writings". Iranian Studies.
17 (1): 15. doi:10.1080/00210868408701620 (https://doi.org/10.1080%2F00210868408701620).
JSTOR 4310424 (https://www.jstor.org/stable/4310424).
29. Kevin Reilly; Stephen Kaufman; Angela Bodino, eds. (2003). Racism: A Global Reader. M.E. Sharpe. p. 123.
ISBN 978-0-7656-1059-1.
30. Hannoum, Abdelmajid (2003). "Translation and the Colonial Imaginary: Ibn Khaldûn Orientalist". History and
Theory. 42 (1): 77–80. JSTOR 3590803 (https://www.jstor.org/stable/3590803).
31. Oweiss, Ibrahim M. “Ibn Khaldun, the Father of Economics.” Georgetown University, State University of New York
Press, 1988, faculty.georgetown.edu/imo3/ibn.htm.
32. Khaldun, Ibn, et al. Muqaddimah - an Introduction to History. Princeton University Press, 2015.
33. "The Amazing Arab Scholar Who Beat Adam Smith by Half a Millennium – Evonomics" (http://evonomics.com/am
azing-north-african-scholar-beat-adam-smith-half-millennium/). Evonomics. 2017-06-09. Retrieved 2017-12-05.
34. Irwin, Robert. Ibn Khaldun: an Intellectual Biography. Princeton University Press., 2018.
35. Affandi, Akhmad, and Dewi Puji Astuti. “Dynamic Model of Ibn Khaldun Theory on Poverty.” Humanomics, vol.
30, no. 2, 2014, pp. 136–161.
36. Affandi, Akhmad, and Dewi Puji Astuti. “Dynamic Model of Ibn Khaldun Theory on Poverty.” Humanomics, vol.
30, no. 2, 2014, pp. 136–161.
37. Affandi, Akhmad, and Dewi Puji Astuti. “Dynamic Model of Ibn Khaldun Theory on Poverty.” Humanomics, vol.
30, no. 2, 2014, pp. 136–161.
38. Ibn Khaldun, The Muqaddimah, ch. 3 pt. 34–35 (http://www.muslimphilosophy.com/ik/Muqaddimah/Chapter3/Ch_
3_34-35.htm)
39. Ahmad, Zaid (2003). The epistemology of Ibn Khaldun. New York: RoutledgeCurzon. ISBN 978-0-415-61275-3.
40. Umar Ibn Al Khattab (2 Volumes), Umar Ibn Al Khattab (2017-02-05). Umar Ibn Al Khattab (2 Volumes) (https://ar
chive.org/details/UmarIbnAlKhattab2Volumes).
41. "Full text of "Ibn Khaldun's Historiography" " (https://archive.org/stream/IbnKhaldunsHistoryalMuqaddimah/Ibn%2
0khaldun's%20History%20(al-muqaddimah)_djvu.txt). archive.org. Retrieved 2018-04-25.
42. "How Far Are We From The Slippery Slope? The Laffer Curve Revisited" (http://www.nber.org/papers/w15343) by
Mathias Trabandt and Harald Uhlig, NBER Working Paper No. 15343, September 2009.
43. Laffer, Arthur. "The Laffer Curve: Past, Present, and Future" (http://www.heritage.org/research/reports/2004/06/th
e-laffer-curve-past-present-and-future). The Heritage Foundation. Retrieved 4 July 2012.
44. Brederode, Robert F. van (2009). Systems of general sales taxation : theory, policy and practice. Austin [Tex.]:
Wolters Kluwer Law & Business. p. 117. ISBN 978-90-411-2832-4.
45. Simon, Robert (2002). Ibn Khaldun: History as Science and the Patrimonial Empire. Budapest: Akadémiai Kiadó.
pp. 18–20, 22–24. ISBN 978-963-05-7934-6.
46. Alatas, Syed Farid (2013). Ibn Khaldun. New Delhi: Oxford University Press. pp. 106–09. ISBN 978-0-19-
809045-8.
47. Fischel, Walter (1952). Ibn Khaldun and Tamerlane: Their Historic Meeting in Damascus, A.D. 1401 (A.H. 803).
Los Angeles: University of California Press.
48. Enan, Muhammed Abdullah (2007). Ibn Khaldun: His Life and Works. The Other Press. p. 118. ISBN 978-983-
9541-53-3.
49. Enan, Muhammed Abdullah (2007). Ibn Khaldun: His Life and Works. The Other Press. pp. 118–19. ISBN 978-
983-9541-53-3.
50. Enan, Muhammed Abdullah (2007). Ibn Khaldun: His Life and Works. The Other Press. pp. 119–20. ISBN 978-
983-9541-53-3.
51. Ameer Ali; Herb Thompson (1999). "The Schumpeterian Gap and Muslim Economic Thought". The Journal of
Interdisciplinary Economics. 10: 31–49. doi:10.1177/02601079X99001000104 (https://doi.org/10.1177%2F02601
079X99001000104).
52. Encyclopædia Britannica, 15th ed., vol. 9, p. 148.
53. Ernest Gellner, Plough, Sword and Book (1988), p. 239
54. Arthur Laffer (June 1, 2004). "The Laffer Curve, Past, Present and Future" (https://web.archive.org/web/2007120
1225944/http://www.heritage.org/Research/Taxes/bg1765.cfm). Heritage Foundation. Archived from the original
(http://www.heritage.org/Research/Taxes/bg1765.cfm) on December 1, 2007. Retrieved 2007-12-11.
55. Baali, Fuad (2005). The Science of Human Social Organization: Conflicting Views on Ibn Khaldun's (1332–1406)
Ilm Al-Umran. Lampeter: The Edwin Mellen Press. pp. 77–95. ISBN 978-0-7734-6279-3.
56. F.R.N. Nabarro; A.S. Argon (1996). Egon Orowan. 1901–1989. A Biographical Memoir (http://www.nap.edu/html/
biomems/eorowan.pdf) (PDF). Washington, DC: National Academies Press.
57. A. Lakhsassi (1996). "25 – Ibn Khaldun" (http://www.muslimphilosophy.com/ip/rep/H024.htm). In S.H. Nasr; O.
Leaman (eds.). History of Islamic Philosophy. London: Routledge. pp. 350–64.
58. "2008 Ibn-Khaldun Essay Contest" (https://web.archive.org/web/20080912062823/http://www.atlasusa.org/V2/ma
in/page.php?page_id=741). www.atlasusa. Atlas Economic Research Foundation.
59. "Encounter of Civilizations: Ibn Khaldun Exhibit Opens at Headquarters" (https://www.un.org/press/en/2006/note6
056.doc.htm). un.org. United Nations. Retrieved 25 April 2018.
60. "Google Doodle: Birthday of Ibn Khaldun" (https://www.google.com/doodles/birthday-of-ibn-khaldun).
google.com/doodle. Retrieved 25 April 2018.
61. Gates, Warren E. (1967). "The Spread of Ibn Khaldûn's Ideas on Climate and Culture". Journal of the History of
Ideas. 28 (3): 415–22. Bibcode:1961JHI....22..215C (http://adsabs.harvard.edu/abs/1961JHI....22..215C).
doi:10.2307/2708627 (https://doi.org/10.2307%2F2708627). JSTOR 2708627 (https://www.jstor.org/stable/27086
27).
62. Dhaouadi, M. (1 September 1990). "Ibn Khaldun: The Founding Father Of Eastern Sociology". International
Sociology. 5 (3): 319–35. doi:10.1177/026858090005003007
(https://doi.org/10.1177%2F026858090005003007).
63. Haddad, L. (1 May 1977). "A Fourteenth-Century Theory of Economic Growth And Development". Kyklos. 30 (2):
195–213. doi:10.1111/j.1467-6435.1977.tb02006.x (https://doi.org/10.1111%2Fj.1467-6435.1977.tb02006.x).

Sources
Fuad Baali. 2005 The science of human social organization : Conflicting views on Ibn Khaldun's (1332–1406) Ilm
al-umran. Mellen studies in sociology. Lewiston/NY: Edwin Mellen Press.
Walter Fischel. 1967 Ibn Khaldun in Egypt : His public functions and his historical research, 1382–1406; a study
in Islamic historiography. Berkeley: University of California Press.
Allen Fromherz. 2010 "Ibn Khaldun : Life and Times". Edinburgh University Press, 2010.
Ana Maria C. Minecan, 2012 "El vínculo comunitario y el poder en Ibn Jaldún" in José-Miguel Marinas (Ed.),
Pensar lo político: Ensayos sobre comunidad y conflicto, Biblioteca Nueva, Madrid, 2012.
Mahmoud Rabi'. 1967 The political theory of Ibn Khaldun. Leiden: E.J. Brill.
Róbert Simon. 2002 Ibn Khaldūn : History as science and the patrimonial empire. Translated by Klára Pogátsa.
Budapest: Akadémiai Kiadó. Original edition, 1999.

Further reading
Malise Ruthven, "The Otherworldliness of Ibn Khaldun" (review of Robert Irwin, Ibn Khaldun: An Intellectual
Biography, Princeton University Press, 2018, ISBN 9780691174662, 243 pp.), The New York Review of Books,
vol. LXVI, no. 2 (February 7, 2019), pp. 23–24, 26. "More than six centuries after Ibn Khaldun's death the modern
world has much to learn from studying him. After the Muqaddima itself, Irwin's intellectual biography... is an
excellent place to begin."

External links

English
Ibn Khaldun: His Life and Work, by Muhammad Hozien (http://www.muslimphilosophy.com/ik/klf.htm)
Ibn Khaldun (http://www.bbc.co.uk/programmes/b00qckbw) on In Our Time at the BBC
Rosenthal, Franz (2008) [1970–80]. "Ibn Khaldūn" (http://www.encyclopedia.com/doc/1G2-2830902289.html).
Complete Dictionary of Scientific Biography. Encyclopedia.com.
Complete Muqaddimah/Kitab al-Ibar in English (without Chapter V, 13) (http://www.muslimphilosophy.com/ik/Muq
addimah/)
The Tunisian American Center (US) (http://www.tunisiancommunity.org/)
Ibn Khaldun on the Web (https://web.archive.org/web/20040624080750/http://www.isidore-of-seville.com/ibnkhal
dun/)
Muslim Scientists and Scholars – Ibn Khaldun (https://web.archive.org/web/20040430064720/http://www.ummah.
net/history/scholars/KHALDUN.html)
Ibn Khaldun’s Philosophy of Management and Work (https://web.archive.org/web/20061014162414/http://www.di
narstandard.com/management/IbnKhaldun_Mgmt100206.htm)
Ibn Khaldun (al-Muqaddimah): Methodology & concepts of economic sociology (https://web.archive.org/web/2006
0831233452/http://home.online.no/~al-araki/index.html)
Ibn Khaldun. The Mediterranean in the 14th century: Rise and fall of Empires (https://web.archive.org/web/20070
928013846/http://www.ibnjaldun.com/index.php?L=7). Andalusian Legacy exhibition in the Alcazar of Seville
The Ibn Khaldun Community Service Award© (http://www.tunisiancommunity.org/wordpress/?page_id=834)
Ibn Khaldun meets Al Saud (http://cliodynamics.ru/index.php?option=com_content&task=view&id=151&Itemid=7
0)
The Ibn Khaldun Institute (http://www.tunisiancommunity.org/wordpress/?page_id=249)
The Tunisian American Day© (http://www.tunisiancommunity.org/wordpress/?page_id=246)

Non-English
Multilingual tunisian academic web site on Ibn Khaldun (https://sites.google.com/site/ibnkhaldun21/)
‹See Tfd›(in French) Exposé simplifié sur la théologie scolastique (https://web.archive.org/web/20120526102936/ht
tp://www.at-tawhid.net/article-expose-simplifie-sur-la-theologie-scolastique-al-ilm-ul-kalam-ibn-khaldun-4586874
1.html)
Chapters from the Muqaddimah and the History of Ibn Khaldun in Arabic (https://web.archive.org/web/20040507
183818/http://membres.lycos.fr/benikou/)
Ismail Küpeli: Ibn Khaldun und das politische System Syriens – Eine Gegenüberstellung (http://www.grin.com/e-b
ook/70021/ibn-khaldun-und-das-politische-system-syriens-eine-gegenueberstellung), München, 2007, ISBN 978-
3-638-75458-3 (German e-book about the politics of Syria with reference to the political theory of Ibn Khaldun)
Kuchinov A.M. Ibn Khaldun influence on social thought development (http://lomonosov-msu.ru/archive/Lomonoso
v_2013/2084/25645_8036.pdf) // Lomonosov-2013. – Moscow, 2013. In Russian.
Master's thesis on Ibn Khaldun published by FFLCH-USP in 2017 (http://www.teses.usp.br/teses/disponiveis/8/81
59/tde-03052018-091006/en.php) Roschel, Renato - São Paulo, 2017. In Portuguese.

Retrieved from "https://en.wikipedia.org/w/index.php?title=Ibn_Khaldun&oldid=902013084"

This page was last edited on 15 June 2019, at 22:05 (UTC).

Text is available under the Creative Commons Attribution-ShareAlike License; additional terms may apply. By using
this site, you agree to the Terms of Use and Privacy Policy. Wikipedia® is a registered trademark of the Wikimedia
Foundation, Inc., a non-profit organization.

You might also like