You are on page 1of 46

Economic Development in China 1

Foreign Investment, Trade, and Economic Development in China


By Danie S. Samuel

Table of Contents
Acknowledgements...................................................................................................3
Abstract...................................................................................................................4
Introduction..............................................................................................................6
Literature Review......................................................................................................9
FDI as Driver of Economic Growth...........................................................................9
FDI and Technology Transfer.............................................................................13
Drivers of FDI Flows..........................................................................................14
International Trade as an Engine of Growth.............................................................15
Conclusion..........................................................................................................19
Trade and Investment in China's Economic Development: An Analysis...........................21
Economic Policy and Growth.................................................................................21
FDI and Exports in China......................................................................................24
Policy Initiatives on FDI.........................................................................................28
Acceleration of the Market Economy.......................................................................29
Sectoral Distribution.............................................................................................33
Regional Disparities in China’s Economic Growth.....................................................34
Trade and Investment in the Regional Context: China in the Asia Pacific Region...........37
Trade Imbalance Tensions....................................................................................39
Conclusion.............................................................................................................42
References............................................................................................................44
References
Economic Development in China 2

List of Tables

Table 1: Growth Indicators of the Chinese Economy

Table 2: Sector Growth of Chinese Exports

Table 3: China’s Trade with the World

Table 4: Total Foreign Trade and FIE Shares

Table 5: Top 10 Origins of Non-Financial FDI

Table 6: U.S. Trade with China

List of Figures

Figure 1: GDP, FDI, and Export Trends

Figure 2: FDI Flows to China

Figure 3: Sectoral Distribution of FDI in China – 2004

Figure 4: Inequality in FDI investments in China

Figure 5: Regional Inequality of FDI investments in China – 2003


Economic Development in China 3

Acknowledgements
Economic Development in China 4

Abstract

The emergence of China as a trading nation and manufacturing center


following the adoption of liberal economic policies in 1978-79 is perhaps the
single most important development affecting the world economy in the Twenty-
first century. Estimates put the gross domestic product (GDP) for 2006 at
20,940.7 billion Yuan, up 10.7 percent and a rate of growth 0.3 percent higher
than the previous year. China contributed more than a quarter of the global
GDP growth and has become the sixth largest trader in the world supplying six
percent of global exports.
Despite this phenomenal growth, criticisms leveled against China include its
inability to ensure regional equity in distribution of the benefits of economic
development among its people and across its geographic profile. However, the
new economic geography has championed regional inequality as a source of
economic growth because this would enable the exploitation of economies of
scale. Disparities in regional development continue to exist but one can see
that these will disappear over time as the benefits of progress diffuse across to
the less developed areas.
Foreign direct investments and trade have played a major role in the
transformation of China. This report explores the impact of these factors and
the emergence of China as a source of increasingly sophisticated goods not
produced in this country earlier.
FDI is the result of an internationalization process of the ‘multinational’ or
‘transnational’ corporations that now have cross-border multi-facility operations.
FDI certainly has the possibility of contributing to economic growth by
enhancing capabilities of the host nation to produce certain goods or services
competitively, and boost trade; but researchers have different views about the
impact of FDI on growth. The whether it does so, and the extent to which is
does depends significantly on other factors that are specific to the local
environment and the nature of the investment i.e. for new capital investment or
for the take-over of existing operations.
The positive impact of international trade on economic growth has been widely
documented as trade yields larger economies of scale to help local industry
Economic Development in China 5

leverage investment, increase human capital, and obtain higher technology to


drive sustained economic growth.
The result, for China is that it has arrested population growth on the one hand
and on the other, used FDI and trade as instruments to improve its per capita
GDP from US$45.77 in 1980 to US$1,053$ in 2004. Its exports also reveal a
strong trend towards higher technology use in manufacture. This growth has
also allowed it to attract more FDI at the cost of other countries; today China
holds the third highest stock of investment after the US and the UK.
This progress has come through a carefully worked out strategy that has
sought to open Chinese markets in stages. Many multinationals that have set
up their production houses here and created an environment of intense
competition that helps fuel further growth.
Economic Development in China 6

Foreign Investment, Trade, and Economic Development


in China

Introduction

Preliminary findings of our regression analysis on the impact of FDI on trade


suggests that for every 10 percent increase in U.S. FDI in China there was a
6.3 percent increase in the level of imports from China to the U.S., with no
statistically significant effect on the level of exports from the U.S. to China.

Kate Bronfenbrenner (2001)

The emergence of China as a trading nation and manufacturing center following the

adoption of liberal economic policies under Deng Xiao-Ping in 1978-79 is perhaps

the single most important development affecting the world economy in the 21st

century. While official statistics may exaggerate the true accomplishments of the

country (Sachs and Woo, 1997), they are stunning nevertheless. In 1979, the

Chinese government looked to decentralize its economy, and began to move from a

planned economy to a market economy (Xinzhong, 2005). The new reform policies

would increase economic growth and raise living standards. The central government

reforms “initiated price and ownership incentives for farmers” (Morrison, 2005:

CRS2), enabling them to sell portions of their crops to the free market; and

established four new economic zones to attract foreign investment, boost exports, as

well as allow importing of high-technology products into China. Many of the reforms

aimed at decentralizing the economy, involved opening the Chinese economy to

international trade (Morrison, 2005).

In 2006, the Chinese national economy maintained a steady and fast growth.

Estimates put the gross domestic product (GDP) for the year at 20,940.7 billion

Yuan, up by 10.7 percent; the increase was up 0.3 percent than that of the previous
Economic Development in China 7

year. Of this, the value of the primary industry was 2,470.0 billion Yuan, up by 5.0

percent; secondary industry stood at 10,200.4 billion Yuan, up by 12.5 percent; and

tertiary industry recorded 8,270.3 billion Yuan, up by 10.3 percent. In terms of the

four different quarters, the GDP growth was 10.4 percent, 11.5 percent, 10.6 percent

and 10.4 percent respectively (NBS, 2007).

Eichengreen and Tong (2005) cited reports to state that China contributed more than

a quarter of the global GDP growth in recent years and it has become the sixth

largest trader in the world supplying six percent of global exports. In 2004, China

was the third largest trader in the world after the US and Germany (NBS, 2005), and

its economic the growth has continued unabated while industrialized countries

struggle with the present economic crisis. This transformation from a poor nation,

almost completely cut off from the rest of the world economy, to a nation that

supplies the largest share of labor-intensive manufactured products, is subject of a

constant debate that seeks to understand the underpinnings of the change.

One change evident is that with the emergence of the Chinese economy and with

the country opening its doors to world trade, it has become the favored destination

for foreign direct investments (FDI) and trade. Companies seeking to capitalize on

the abundance of low-cost labor and the vast markets created by the large

population have flocked to China with investment and trading opportunities. What the

foreign investors sought from the economic liberalization are easy access to the local

market, and production incentives in the form of cheap land, raw materials, tax

exemptions, and ultimately attractive profits.

Asia leads the world in labor productivity growth at 3.4% between 1990 and 2002.

China leads the way in labor productivity growth, at 6.5% annually driven by massive

restructuring and privatization. This productivity increase is also associated with


Economic Development in China 8

foreign investment and trade that allowed import of better technologies and

management methods and their diffusion to the locally owned industries as well.

Despite this phenomenal growth, criticisms leveled against China include its inability

to ensure regional equity in distribution of the benefits of economic development

among its populace and across its geographic profile. However, the new economic

geography has championed regional inequality as a source of economic growth

because this would enable the exploitation of economies of scale. Porter (1998), for

example, has advocated the development of industrial clusters as geographical

centers of excellence. He posits that when faced with fierce competition, parts of the

production chains can gain comparative advantage by locating close to each other

thus forming industrial clusters.

This thesis seeks to develop an understanding of the role played by the FDI inflow

and international trade in China’s recent economic growth and transformation.

Specific data that highlights China’s achievements in the economic field is

presented, followed by an analysis to understand how this growth and transformation

occurred and to draw conclusions about the main drivers of economic change in

China.

However, there are limitations in this study due to the vastness of the subject matter

and many nuanced implications of different factors (e.g. labor, resources factors) so

that this thesis’ focus on FDI and trade reflect only part of the process of growth.

Nonetheless, given that China is experiencing considerable trade surplus with the

United States and European Union, and is the principal destination of inward FDI,

this project should shed some light on the importance of the aforementioned two

factors on its economic development.


Economic Development in China 9

Literature Review

This section reviews the findings of earlier research concerning the prime drivers of

economic development and growth of a nation. It pays attention to the role of FDI

and trade on the economic performance of China.

FDI as Driver of Economic Growth

FDI encompasses the transfer of physical capital and intangible assets such as

technology and knowhow between countries. According to economic theory,

accumulation of capital as well as technological innovation drives economic growth.

Robert Lucas Jr. (1988) analyses different models for understanding economic

development, and emphasizes the need for theory to explain existence of sustained

growth combined with sustained diversity in income levels. He stresses that

explanation of growth rates through analysis of shifts in trade is a possible route that

can help explain the ‘growth miracles’ of some emerging Asian economies. The

growth of these economies is related to increase in exports, “and more suggestively

still, with exports of goods not formerly produced in these countries” (Lucas, 1988:

38); this emphasizes the importance of technology growth.

The motivation for foreign direct investment (FDI) is the need to attain specializations

in key areas. Hence corporations go abroad to invest capital and knowledge, to

source goods and services from areas that offer such specialization, and to improve

competitiveness driven by the availability of cheaper labor, specialized skills,

availability of inputs, logistics etc. This in turn contributes to the economic

transformation of the host country as capital investments and trade increase.

Therefore, FDI is the result of an internationalization process of firms that now have

cross-border multi-facility operations (Alfaro et al, 2005) or the so-called

‘multinational’ or ‘transnational’ corporations (TNCs).


Economic Development in China 10

The debate on whether FDI contributes to economic growth has its supporters and

others who report inconclusive and even negative results. All these arguments have

one commonality; and that is that the effect of FDI on economic growth depends

largely on specific conditions prevailing in the host country and the tools used for

understanding economic growth and development. These conditions vary greatly

between countries and comparisons may lead to erroneous results if factors such as

the entrepreneurial approach of companies are not accounted for and a common set

of tools is not developed (Alfaro et al, 2004; Greenaway et al, 2007).

Many researchers report contrasting findings in their exploration of the impact of FDI

on growth. For example, Poon and Thompson (1998) report a positive influence of

FDI on economic growth (see also Mullen and Williams, 2005). Alfaro et al (2008)

conclude that FDI induces economic growth only in the presence of certain economic

conditions such as the presence of a threshold level of human capital, institutions,

and economic policies that encourage foreign investments and trade. Contrary to

these findings, Carkovic and Levine (2005) demonstrate that FDI has no significant

effect on the economic development of the receiving country. Mencinger (2003)

shows a negative relationship between inward FDI flow and economic growth.

The above suggests that there is controversy about some of the basic drivers of

economic growth. Some studies (e.g. de Long and Summers, 1991; 1992) show that

the rate of capital formation determines the rate of growth. On the other hand,

Blomstrom et al (1996) argue that fixed capital investment is important but other

factors are even more critical, for example, institutions, the political and economic

climate, inflow of FDI, low population growth, and efficient use of the investments.

Poon and Thompson (1998) analyzed FDI flows and growth based on data between

1987 and 1994, and concluded that Japanese manufacturing FDI to Asia, and the
Economic Development in China 11

US FDI to Latin America contributed to the economic growth of those regions. de

Mello (1999) shows that FDI results in technological upgrading and knowledge

spillovers, and this drives growth; also the effect is sensitive to the degree of

complementarities and exchangeability between FDI and domestic investment. de

Mello (1997) concluded that the final impact of FDI on output growth relies on the

scope for efficiency spillovers to domestic firms. Through such spillovers, FDI leads

to increasing returns from domestic production from better value added production

and thus improvement in the competitiveness of certain production in certain areas,

which in turn attracts more FDI.

Mencinger (2003) analyzes the impact of FDI on different East European countries

where FDI is concentrated in the tertiary sector, i.e. investment, insurance, finance

etc; or on mergers and acquisitions of existing companies. He finds very little

spillovers of technology; rather FDI resulted in more imports than exports and

increased the indebtedness of the local economies (see also Rodrick, 1999).

Mencinger (2003) thus concludes that FDI does not have a direct correlation with

development of human capital in an economy since this depends on the social and

political development of the country. Simply put, FDI certainly has the possibility of

contributing to economic growth, but whether it does so, and the extent to which is

does depends significantly on other factors that are specific to the local environment.

Most of the literature on the impact of FDI on the economy of the host nation ignores

the fact that FDI can take several forms. Other than pure investment in the stocks of

promising companies for a profit motive (an aspect that is not within the scope of the

present study), FDI can occur through mergers and acquisitions (M&A) of domestic

companies or through green-field investments. Wang and Sunny Wong (2009) use a

sample of 84 countries between 1987 and 2001 to differentiate the effects of the two
Economic Development in China 12

modes of investment. They find that investments that target setting up new industry

promote economic growth of the host country while M&A investments have a

negative relationship. Their study may explain the conflicting findings of previous

studies since the latter do not take modes of FDI into consideration (Wang and

Wong, 2009).Echoes of this thinking are seen in Mencinger (2003) who speculates

that the entry mode may be a factor that explains the negative relationship he finds

between FDI and economic growth. Support for the negative impact of FDI when it is

used to take over domestic industry may also be found in UNCTAD’s (2000: xxiii)

observation that, “… FDI entry through the takeover of domestic firms is less

beneficial, if not positively harmful, for economic development than entry by setting

up new facilities. At the heart of these concerns is that foreign acquisitions simply

transfer ownership and control from domestic to foreign hands.” This is because

layoffs of employees or the closing of some production or functional activities often

accompany such transfer.

Blonigen and Slaughter (2001) conclude that M&A is a better option compared to

new investments since the latter does not contribute to skill upgrading in the host

country. Conyon et al (2002) suggest that M&A helps improve productivity. Despite

these observations, most mergers and acquisitions do not yield long-term benefit for

the acquiring company or for the one taken over. For example, studies by

Ravenscraft and Scherer (1987) and Ravenscraft (1991), reveal that efforts to

enhance market position through mergers yield no better performance, and

sometimes worse. Statistics show the failure rate of most mergers and acquisitions

lies somewhere between 40 and 80%. If one were to define 'failure' as failure to

increase shareholder value, then statistics show these to be at the higher end of the

scale at 83% (Cnnfn.com 19991).


1 quoted in http://www.kwintessential.co.uk/cultural-services/articles/intercultural-
mergers.html accessed on July 15, 2009)
Economic Development in China 13

FDI and Technology Transfer

The above discussions highlighted the emphasis placed on technology transfer and

spillovers (Bransetter, 2006; and de Mello, 1997). While FDI does include the

transfer of technology, the results of such transfers are not as evident. Aitken and

Harrison (1999) looked at the affect of FDI for 4000 firms in Venezuela and found

that productivity did increase in small factories (less than 50 employees) with foreign

equity participation. Among large companies, the effect was not so evident. On the

other hand, the productivity of locally owned factories that engaged in the same

industry actually fell. The study also found no evidence of technology spillovers from

the foreign owned factories. The overall affect on productivity was quite small.

A report by Chuang and Lin (1999) reports completely contrary findings; these

researchers studied 8,846 Taiwanese firms and found beneficial technological

spillovers to domestic companies. Grouping the companies by industry, they point to

an average of 1.40 to 1.80% increase in the productivity of domestic firms for every

1% increase in FDI in that particular industry. Despite establishing this direct link

between productivity and FDI in an industry, this report concludes that the flow and

dispersion of technology reduces the incentive for domestic firms to conduct their

own R&D and increase their dependence on technology transfusions from the

foreign investing companies. Therefore, it is essential that developing countries

adopt policies that encourage local R&D once the country’s technological capacity

has reached a certain level.

One sees that technology transfer and spillovers is highly dependant on the market

structure and the level of interaction between the giver and receiver of FDI. In a

situation of intense competition, it is obvious that the transfer of higher and most

recent technologies could occur to the local affiliates to enable them to meet
Economic Development in China 14

competition. Introduction of the latest technologies may also result in the elimination

of the local competitors thereby reducing overall competition. This is especially true if

the foreign firms engage in unethical anti-competitive practices such as price rigging

through absorption of losses in their transnational operations to drive out local

competition.

Therefore, each country has to determine the appropriate role of FDI in the larger

context of domestic development strategy.

Drivers of FDI Flows

All companies confront cycles of competitiveness in their business. As

competitiveness diminishes, a company faces the challenge of increasing

competitiveness. A viable alternative is to establish facilities on foreign shores in

countries that offer benefits not available in the home country. This can take the form

of transfer of the entire operation, or the setting up of affiliates that take up part of the

business. This process cascades as the company faces decreasing competitiveness

in the new location leading to migration to other cost-effective and competitive

location. The result of these processes over time is the establishment of areas of

specialization in different parts of the world. As each area improves skills through

‘learning by doing’, the tendency is for the national income and its internal structure

to improve as local enterprise moves towards higher technology industrial products.

Some commentators have debated the benefits of FDI for economic development as

they looked at FDI as a form of neo-colonialism or neo-imperialism. However, these

ideas do not seem to have a significant impact on large-scale investment flows.

Major flows of capital took place from Britain and Europe to the US after the Civil

War for investment in production and infrastructure. Neoclassical economics sees

such capital accumulation as central to increase in productivity and new investments


Economic Development in China 15

as an essential condition for rapid and sustained economic growth. Developing

countries quickly recognized this. Suffering from capital shortages, they saw the

need to attract investments from rich countries. The result was the opening up of

their economies to foreign trade and foreign investment offering a diverse set of

incentives. The structure and the quality of institutional framework also have a

significant impact on the host country’s attractiveness for FDI and therefore

economic growth. While most East Asian countries attracted FDI in the 1960s and

saw rapid development, China followed this trend only in the late 1970s. This

‘liberalization’ transformed and continues to transform the Asian and Chinese

economies from their dependence on agriculture to industrial products as technology

levels gradually increase. Technology transfer is an integral part of investment flows

of multinational firms and is of vital importance for sustained growth in the host

country (Bransetter, 2006). A reverse causality also exists: High economic growth

attracts more foreign investment (Hansen and Rand, 2006).

International Trade as an Engine of Growth

International trade refers to the exchange of goods and services across international

borders. The importance of trade especially as it affects the economic growth and

development of trading nations is important for the purpose of this essay. As an

‘engine of growth’, it played a pivotal role in the growth of the economies of the

developed nations of today in the 19th and the 20th centuries. Trade revolved around

primary commodities e.g. wood from Sweden, coal from Australia, wheat from

Canada etc. As is evident, not all products are equal on the demand-supply

equation, and therefore their impact on the economy varies. Since the end of World

War II international trade has multiplied but the primacy of trade in primary products

has waned. However, there have been numerous examples of economic growth led
Economic Development in China 16

by trade in industrial or manufactured goods. Prominent examples since the 1970s

are Hong Kong, Singapore, Taiwan, South Korea, and more recently China.

In the works of David Ricardo, the 18th century British economist, we find the first

theory that links international trade to ‘comparative advantage’2. Ricardo theorized

that trade would take place when one country is relatively more efficient in the sense

of lower opportunity costs (i.e. relative prices) than the other is in the production of

the traded commodity. These gains come, Ricardo observed, because each country

specializes in producing the good for which its comparative cost is lower. However,

Ricardo considered only one factor of production – labor. Other factors like climate

and the environment could also determine comparative advantage. These thought

hold today also if we consider environmental ‘cost’ as a determinant of comparative

advantage.

The neo-classical theory extends the classical theory by adding capital as a second

factor of production leading to cost differences. This is vital from the viewpoint of this

essay since it shows the importance of capital as a determinant of comparative

(competitive) advantage and therefore international trade. With FDI flows enhancing

capabilities of the host nation to produce certain goods or services competitively,

they help boost trade.

Trade has expanded at an accelerating rate since the end of World War II. Statistics

show that between 1950 and 2004, global trade increased 145 times at a rate of

2.6% per year. Trade grew even faster over 2000-2004, increasing from US$13,069

billions to US$18,220 billions in 2004 at a rate of 9% p.a. (UNCTAD, 2005).

Evidently, global trade grew faster than the overall economy during the time. The

2 David Ricardo (1772-1823)The Concise Encyclopedia of Economics,


http://www.econlib.org/library/Enc/bios/Ricardo.html accessed on July 25, 2009
Economic Development in China 17

factors that affected this were advances in transportation and communication, and

improvement in the trading environment through different trade agreements.

Nevertheless, the most important factor was the opening of national economies to

international trade through the lowering of tariffs and trade barriers.

The perception of international trade as a driver of economic growth does not suffer

from the ambiguity associated with FDI. The positive impact of international trade on

economic growth has been widely documented (for example, see Grossman, and

Helpman, 1997 who examine the issue from a theoretical standpoint; and Keller,

2004 for a practical view). Keller (2004) pays special attention to the technology

spillovers that accompany trade, which makes it possible for less developed

countries to improve productivity within their own industry through examination of the

imported goods. This increase in knowledge assists in improving competitiveness in

world markets as the domestic companies learn how to produce better quality and

lower costs leading to more trade and thus enter a cycle of economic growth. An

additional benefit that accrues is the access to capital goods offering better

productivity without the need to invest in expensive R&D to develop them

indigenously.

Therefore, international trade can potentially play a crucial role in fueling the

economic growth of less developed countries, because of the dual effect of

improving the production of goods for export, and foreign exchange for importing

capital goods. The diffusion of knowledge helps harness local resources effectively

and efficiently. These three factors combine to increase the pace of economic growth

– international trade thus becomes an “engine of growth” (Cyper & Dietz, 1997).

The literature on economic growth through international trade suggests that it is

more likely that potential export capability must originate from a successful sector in
Economic Development in China 18

the domestic economy. For any developing nation with a large population,

indigenous production will remain an important factor for economic growth. Exports

that yield larger economies of scale could help local industry leverage investment,

increase human capital, and obtain higher technology to drive sustained economic

growth (Cyper and Dietz, 1997). Successful domestic production and international

trade complement each other to accelerate economic growth. With economic growth

comes improved capability to export and trade. Therefore, a positive relationship

exists between trade and growth.

Economic development also encompasses the concept of growth and equity in the

distribution of the benefits of growth amongst the population. Frankel and Romer

(1999) investigate how international trade affects standards of living. The findings of

their study show that trade appears to raise incomes by spurring the accumulation of

physical and human capital, and by increasing productivity. This is also true, the

researchers find, of trade within the country. As a result, larger countries have more

opportunities for internal trade that leads to higher incomes. However, these

researchers do not analyze equity issues related to the distribution of the income

among citizens.

Rehbar and Grega (2008), attempt to understand the ‘justice’ aspect of international

trade through an examination of intra-generational and inter-generational disparities.

In their definition, justice stands for judicial use of environmental resources keeping

future needs in view and “the balanced distribution of wealth among the present

generations (distributive justice)” (Rehbar and Grega, 2008: 476). Having defined

their concept of justice, these researchers conclude that current trade practices

across the world do not serve these two goals whether among nations or within the

countries themselves. Their recommendation for developing countries is that they


Economic Development in China 19

“concentrate their efforts on investment policies and projects with a special focus on

human capital, land, water, property rights, management, technology infrastructure,

and strengthening farmers’ organizations” (p: 476). This particular article is of

specific interest as we examine the industrial growth of the Chinese economy, the

decreased role of agriculture in its GDP, and the concentration of the growth and its

benefits within geographical pockets rather than across the entire country.

Conclusion

This section has provided a literature review of FDI and trade’s influence on the

economic growth of a country. While the FDI-growth relationship is more

controversial, the evidence for trade and growth appears on balance to be more

positive.

On matters of policy change, we find agreement that a country cannot exist in

isolation and must open its doors to world trade. However, there is emphasis on the

fact that each country must proceed with caution keeping its domestic environment

and its needs constantly in focus. Criticism of an open market across the entire

world, a market that provides a level playing field to unequal players, is also quite

strident.
Economic Development in China 20

Trade and Investment in China's Economic Development: An Analysis

This chapter seeks to describe China’s economic performance and to highlight some

of the salient features of this performance and growth.

Economic Policy and Growth

Before China’s reform policies began in 1978, the Chinese government had

embarked on a long mission to attain self-sufficiency without success. State-owned

enterprises (SOE) controlled three-quarters of China’s industrial production, and

there were little to no private enterprise or investment. Foreign trade was limited to

purchasing goods not made in China and there were “few profit incentives for firms

and farmers,” very little competition and severe production controls distorted the

economy; all these factors led to China’s living standards being one of the lowest

among developing countries (Morrison, 2005: 4).

The bottom-line of this debate is that China has emerged as a major trading nation

and center for manufacture, especially for goods and services requiring labor input.

More recently, its range in manufacturing ability has begun to include high-

technology products also. China joined the World Trade Organization (WTO) in 2001

and the threat it holds out to manufacturing activity in the developed countries

signals a major change in the economic balance of the world economy. China has

also attracted heavy net inflows of investment from other countries. These have

arguably led to the phenomenal and unprecedented growth of the Chinese economy

to make it one of the largest in the world.

Because of significant reforms, China’s economy grew at an average annual rate of

10.2% in the 1980s and by roughly 10% annually in the period of 1990–2004. This
Economic Development in China 21

was among the highest growth rates in the world. In 2004, China’s gross domestic

product (GDP) was 13687.6 billion Yuan, ranked sixth in the world, making China a

significant economic power. Secondary industry that includes manufacturing, mining,

and construction contributes the largest percentage of the country’s GDP, amounting

to 52% in 2004. Tertiary industry, which includes transportation, commerce, and

services together accounted for 40%. Agriculture, together with forestry and fishing,

contributed almost 8%. In fact, the secondary (industrial) industry contributes the

most in the process of the economic growth (NBS, 2007).

Table 1 below illustrates the turnaround of the Chinese economy in the past 25

years. While population growth, a constant worry earlier, has been arrested and

even stabilized, the gross domestic product (GDP) per capita increased from a

meager US$45.77 in 1980 to US$1,053$ in 2004.

Year Populati GDP/ Trade Industry % of


on Capita as % GDP
[million] [$] GDP Primar Second
y ary
1980 98705 45.77 12.62% 30.1 48.5
1985 105851 84.69 23.05% 28.4 43.1
1989 112704 150.03 24.58% 25.0 43.0
1990 114333 162.23 29.98% 27.1 41.6
1991 115823 186.65 33.43% 24.5 42.1
1992 117171 227.34 34.24% 21.8 43.9
1993 118517 292.23 32.54% 19.9 47.4
1994 119850 390.15 43.59% 20.2 47.9
1995 121121 482.81 40.19% 20.5 48.8
1996 122389 554.66 35.55% 20.4 49.5
1997 123626 602.32 36.22% 19.1 50.0
1998 124761 627.96 34.27% 18.6 49.3
1999 125786 652.44 36.43% 17.6 49.4
2000 126743 705.90 43.90% 16.4 50.2
2001 127627 762.49 43.35% 15.8 50.1
2002 128453 818.76 48.85% 15.3 50.4
2003 129227 908.40 60.04% 14.4 52.2
2004 129988 1,052.99 69.80% 15.2 52.9

Table 1: Growth Indicators of the Chinese Economy


Economic Development in China 22

Source: Calculated using data from China Statistical Yearbook 2005

Of special interest are the figures relating to the element of trade in the makeup of

the GDP. While trade, domestic and international, contributed only 12.62% of the

GDP in 1980, this grew to nearly 70% in 2004. Table 2 illustrates this through a

detailed breakdown of the items of exports.

Export volume
(unit: billion RMB, 1990 constant Ratio Ratio
Category of price) 2005 2005
commodity % % % over over
of of of
1985 1995 2005 1985 1995
Tot Tot Tot
al al al
Live animals and
4.5 4.3 20.9 3.0 23.7 0.9 5.27 1.13
animal products
Vegetables, fruits and
10.3 9.7 19.3 2.8 29.3 1.1 2.84 1.52
cereals
Animal and vegetable
0.6 0.6 2.1 0.3 1.0 0.0 1.67 0.48
oils
Food, beverages and
3.2 3.0 21.6 3.1 39.5 1.5 12.34 1.83
tobacco
Minerals 29.7 28.1 31.4 4.5 73.9 2.7 2.49 2.35
Chemicals and related
5.7 5.4 39.3 5.7 112.5 4.2 19.74 2.86
products
Plastics and rubber
N.A. 20 2.9 82.3 3.1 4.12
products
Leather and fur 110.
0.5 0.5 26.3 3.8 55.1 2.0 2.10
products 20
Wood and wooden
N.A. 10 1.4 26.7 1.0 2.67
products
Paper and paper
N.A. 5.2 0.7 18.1 0.7 3.48
products
Textile products 167.
26.8 25.3 24.1 380.3 14.1 14.19 2.27
4
Footwear 73.0
1.1 1.0 38.1 5.5 80.4 3.0 2.11
9
Cement, ceramic and 48.1
0.9 0.9 12.4 1.8 43.3 1.6 3.49
glass products 1
Pearls, precious
stones and precious N.A. 8.2 1.2 19.5 0.7 2.38
metals
Base metal products 201. 112.
1.8 1.7 56.4 8.1 7.5 3.58
7 06
Machinery, electric
129. 18. 1137 42. 758.
equipment and 1.5 1.4 8.81
1 6 .5 3 33
electronics products
Transportation 100. 91.2
1.1 1.0 19.1 2.8 3.7 5.26
equipment 4 7
Optical products and 100. 334.
0.3 0.3 21.9 3.2 3.7 4.58
precision instruments 3 33
Others 17.8 16.8 45.4 6.5 166.1 6.2 9.33 3.66
Economic Development in China 23

Total 694. 2691.


113.8 25.44 3.88
1 6

Table 2: Sector Growth of Chinese Exports


Source: Huang et al (2008)

The numbers indicate the waning of the importance of traditional sources of GDP

such as agriculture in favor of industry. While the share of industry in the GDP has

remained steady at around 50%, the shift from primary industry to secondary

industry is significant as China increasingly produces more of sophisticated goods

using higher technology. The numbers in the final two columns of table 2 show a

strong trend towards the manufacture and exports of items such as machinery,

electric equipment, and electronic products. The growth in this area appears to be

phenomenal from 1.5 billion RMB exports in 1985 (i.e. 1.4% of total exports) to

1137.5 billion RMB in 2005. This represents a 42.3% growth! The story is similar

when we examine the exports of optical products and precision instruments that

have grown substantially from 1985.

The above, combined with items including base metal products and cement, show

an increased capacity towards capital goods manufacture for domestic use.

Machinery that contributed 18.6% of China’s total exports in 1995 accounted for

42.3% in 2005 signaling the change in commodity distribution. Traditional product

exports have also grown substantially in absolute terms but their share in the basket

of export products has reduced considerably.

These observations support the theory that increasing trade and FDI has potential

benefits to improve technology and productivity through spillovers and learning-by-

doing. Growth itself has fueled further growth and the increasing sophistication and

acceptability of Chinese exports is manifest in the numbers.

FDI and Exports in China


Economic Development in China 24

Figure 1 below traces the growth of GDP and the exports over the past 10 years. FDI

inflow is plotted to demonstrate the connection between the three items. GDP growth

appears to be steadily moving upwards but one can observe a small connection to

the inflow of FDI. This relation is more evident in the case of exports if one considers

a logical time lag between the FDI and its results in terms of enhanced production

and thus exports.

Figure 1: GDP, FDI, and Export Trends


Source: Calculations using China Statistical Yearbook, 2005

However, one needs to add a note of caution in the interpretation of the trends. FDI

flow and exports have a large dependence on the international money markets and

other economical factors. Therefore, the changes may be response to other stimuli.

The share of FDI attracted by China compared to other countries in the world as

well as to other developing nations is more revealing. Figure 2 below evidences the

fact that increasingly China is emerging as the favored destination for FDI flows.

After the initial surge in 1991 to 1993, the share for China dropped due to the fears in

some quarters about the overheating of the Chinese economy and continued until

the world economic crisis in 2000-2001. Once that was over, inward investments

began to surge once again and China’s share in the total FDI flow across the world

rose to nearly 10% by 2003. The situation with regard to China’s share of FDI flows

to developing countries follows an almost exactly similar pattern indicating that

throughout the period under review the world FDI flows found a favorable place in

China.
Economic Development in China 25

Figure 2: FDI Flows to China


Source: (Eichengreen and Tong, 2005)

With all developing countries opening up their economies there arose intense

competition among them for attracting FDI. China, in this regard, has been an

exception. China has seen the result of ‘herd behavior’ – a term that is frequently

applied to behavior in financial speculation. First attracted by the enormous size of

the market, its large reservoir of cheap labor, and geographical proximity to the

markets in which the products were to be sold, such as Japan, the US, and South-

Asian countries as well as in China itself, companies began investing in China. The

economic growth built confidence and attracted more investments.

Eichengreen and Tong (2005) explored FDI flows between 1988 and 2002 to detect

patterns in the flow and to answer the question: “Has China’s emergence as a low-

cost production and export platform and its growing attractions as a destination for

FDI made it more difficult for other countries to attract FDI?” (p: 7). They found that

China has emerged as a major destination for FDI flows and the country held the
Economic Development in China 26

third highest stock of investment after the US and the UK. This increase has to be

read within the context of the overall growth of FDI flows across the world.

Net FDI flows to developing countries rose steadily over the 1990s, and China was a

favored geographical destination. The main sources of FDI remain Europe, the U.S.,

and Japan. Europe was the source of nearly 60 per cent of global FDI inflows in the

1990s. FDI flows increased from US$21 billion in 1989 to US$179 billion in 1999,

with most of the money going to four countries: China, Brazil, Argentina, and Mexico.

Other countries in Asia also benefitted from the broader regional spillovers of FDI to

China, “as if producers in these economies belong to a common supply chain”

(Eichengreen and Tong, 2005:1). Included in their findings is the fact that FDI flows

have even diverted from OECD countries to China. The researchers suggest that

this is due to the need to produce close to the final market for the products and the

need to concentrate efforts in one geographical area for better control of operations.

The result is a reduction of FDI flows to developing countries by 26% between 1999

and 2003 while those to China climbed rapidly.

Therefore, China has acted as a magnet for FDI investment based on its labor-

intensive manufacturing capabilities making it difficult for other developing countries

to attract investment (Wei, 2000). There are worries in Japan and Korea that the

rapid growth of Chinese industry, fed by foreign direct investment from these and

other countries, is “hollowing out” their own manufacturing sectors. These fears

deepen in face of the fact that even now there are 200 to 300 million underemployed

rural Chinese who are waiting to be integrated into China’s manufacturing system

(Eichengreen and Tong, 2005).

Policy Initiatives on FDI

China’s policies toward FDI can be roughly categorized into three stages:
Economic Development in China 27

• Gradual with limited opening


• Active promotion through preferential treatment
• Promoting FDI in accordance with domestic industrial needs (Fung et al.,
2002: 5)

Stage One: 1979-1991. Between 1979 and 1991, the Chinese government

implemented special incentive policies in Special Economic Zones (SEZ); three in

Guangdong and in Fujian provinces (Xinzhong, 2005). During this period, FDI inflow

was highly concentrated in SEZs alone, especially from 1979 to 1983. FDI inflows

were US$1.755 billion during this period. FDI inflows increased to US$10.301 billion

with the opening of the 14 coastal cities and other untapped regions within 10

provinces between the years of 1984 and 1988. Several more locations opened in

1988, resulting in a total FDI inflow of US$11.245 billion by 1991, even with a slow

period in 1989 and 1990 (Xinzhong, 2005). After the 20 years reform, and by the end

of 1991, China had already become the third largest FDI recipient among developing

countries.

Stage Two: 1992-1997. 1992 was a turning point in China’s economic reform and the

time when the Chinese premier, Deng Xiaoping set out on his famous tour of the

southern regions and SEZs of China (Xinzhong, 2005). Deng’s speech during his

tour emphasized his support for China’s economic development with the assistance

of FDI inflows in SEZ and expressed a desire for a fast-paced acceleration of the

market economy, which greatly pushed China’s overall economic reform process

(Wei, 2000). It was at this time that China’s government committed to the market-

oriented economic reform and the open-door policy. It was in 1992 that China began

to implement a policy of equal development of areas within the country from its past

policy of region-based growth. Deng’s speech greatly encouraged foreign

enterprises to invest in China, and beginning 1992, the flow of inward FDI was faster

and higher. This resulted in the quadrupling of inward FDI to reach US$58.1 billion in
Economic Development in China 28

1991, a figure that reflected China’s attraction to foreign investors since reforms

began in 1979. By the early 1990s, China had become the second largest recipient

of FDI in the world, next only to the United States.

Stage Three: 1998-2004. This stage is an important period for China’s economy,

much like stage two. Both the turnaround following the Asian financial crisis at the

end of 1997 and China’s accession into the World Trade Organization (WTO)

occurred during this period. Due to the impact of the Asian financial crisis in 1997,

China experienced a temporary setback in FDI inflows with an approximate 40%

decrease and a negative growth rate of almost 12% (Xinzhong, 2005).

As we will see later in this report, most of the FDI flow to China comes from Asian

countries and these countries themselves went through a major economic crisis

during this period. However, as economy of the region and the world began to pick

up and as confidence was restored in the Chinese economy the flow of FDI has

picked up again.

Acceleration of the Market Economy


Several factors are involved in accelerating China’s planned economy to a market

economy where FDI has played a vital role. FDI attracted:

• Capital formation
• Labor training
• Upgrading of industrial structure
• Technology transfer
• Spillovers
• International trade

Attracting foreign capital to compensate for China’s shortage of capital as well as the

engagement of technology transfer to China have been the two main aims for

pursuing a rigorous FDI policy by the Chinese leadership. In order to attract FDI,
Economic Development in China 29

Deng established two market promotion zones, and these zones promoted

investment through unique tax incentive packages (Fung et al, 2002: 5). The

promotion zones promoted are:

• Special Economic Zones – Shenzhen, Shantou, Zhuhai and Xiamen (1979-


1980)
• 14 Coastal Cities – such as Shanghai, Tianjin, Guangzhu, Qingdao and Delia
(1984-1985)
• Dozens of developmental zones (1985)
• Designated inland cities
• Free ports and tax bonded zones (2000)

The provincial and local government was given the economic control of various

enterprises as the central government decentralized industrial production so that

they were no longer under state planning or control, and could operate and compete

on free market principles (Morrison, 2005). Under provincial and local government,

open cities and development zones were created in coastal regions and cities where

experimentation of free market reform took place (Morrison, 2005).

The mid-1980s brought enhanced regulations and encouraged further FDI inflows

into the country. Emphasis was on “export-oriented joint ventures and joint ventures

using technology” (Fung et al, 2002: 3).

The three major sources of capital inflow in China are FDI, external loans and other

types of foreign investment, such as portfolio investment and international leasing

(OCED, 2000). Of the three capital sources, FDI has played the most important role

in economic growth because as pointed out by Poon and Thompson (2001), it is less

volatile compared to portfolio investment. In addition, FDI captures the equity of

foreign investment (e.g. factories) and this tends to be longer term in outlook. This is

because it is not easy to relocate or move networks with Chinese suppliers and

distributors, since they are the result of locally embedded relationships. Furthermore,
Economic Development in China 30

because much of the FDI are in special economic zones, they target for exports.

Table 3 shows the leaps in China’s export levels and growth from 1999 to 2004.

These figures continue to be quite high after 2004 but 2008 saw a much smaller

increase due to the current global economic recession.

1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008

Exports 194.9 249.2 266.2 325.6 438.2 593.3 762 969.1 1,218.6 1,428.5
% change 6.1 27.8 6.8 22.4 34.6 35.4 28.4 27.2 25.7 17.2
Imports 165.7 225.1 243.6 295.2 412.8 561.2 660 791.6 955.8 1,133.1
% change 18.2 35.8 8.2 21.2 39.8 36 17.6 20 20.8 18.5
Total 360.6 474.3 509.8 620.8 851 1,154.6 1,421.9 1,760.7 2,173.8 2,561.6
% change 11.3 31.5 7.5 21.8 37.1 35.7 23.2 23.8 23.5 17.8
Balance 29.2 24.1 22.5 30.4 25.5 32.1 102 177.5 262.2 295.5

Table 3: China’s Trade with the World


(In billion $)
Source: The US-China Business Council3 quoting PRC National Bureau of Statistics and PRC General
Administration of Customs, China's Customs Statistics

All of the above came about thanks largely to the development of industries through

foreign investment and industrial growth, and labor productivity has also increased

considerably. Many multinationals that have set up their production houses here pay

higher salaries than local companies and this also increases competition that could

help upgrade local supplier networks through improved inputs and products. China

manufactures most of the world’s clothing and over a third of cell phones. It has

become the biggest producer of steel in the world with output in excess of that of the

U.S. and Japan together4. There is no doubt that the low cost of goods and labor has

helped attract FDI in furniture making to electronic components manufacturing5.

The open-door policies and other economic reforms have reduced tariff barriers,

which has encouraged international trade. The boost in foreign trade is due to duty

3 http://www.uschina.org/statistics/tradetable.html accessed on July 26,2009


4 “Inside the new China,” Fortune, October 2004
5 “The China price,” Business Week, Dec. 6, 2004
Economic Development in China 31

exemptions for intermediate products used in the production of exports, according to

OCED & OCDE (2000). Table 4 shows the trends in exports and FIE contribution.

Year Total Total FIEs Shares Exports as %


Exports and Exports in of GDP
Imports and Imports Total
of FIEs Exports
and Imports
1993 1,957.1 670.7 34.3 32.6
1994 2,367.3 876.5 37.0 43.6
1995 2,808.5 1,098.2 39.1 40.2
1996 2,899.0 1,371.1 47.3 35.6
1997 3,250.6 1,526.2 47.0 36.3
1998 3,239.2 1,576.8 48.7 34.3
1999 3,606.5 1,745.1 48.4 36.4
2000 4,743.1 2,367.1 49.9 43.9
2001 5,097.7 2,591.0 50.8 43.3
2002 6,207.9 3,302.2 53.2 48.9
2003 8,509.9 4,721.7 55.5 60.0
2004 11,545.5 6,630.4 57.4 69.8
Table 4: Total Foreign Trade and FIE Shares
(100 million USD)
Source: Almanac of Chinas Foreign Economics & Relations 2003 and own
calculations based on data from China Statistical Yearbook, various years.

As of 2004, China was the third largest exporter in the world, up from number 19th in

1981 (The Almanac of China’s Economic Relations and Enterprises cooperation,

2003/2004). Trade is a major factor of China’s GDP; in 1993, the ratio of total export

and import in GDP was 32.6%. In 2004, this has increased to 69.8% as shown in

Table 4.

Sectoral Distribution

Figure 3 below shows the sectoral breakdown of FDI distribution in China in 2004.

Clearly it indicates that FDI is predominantly targeted at the manufacturing sector

(i.e. 71%) followed by real estate and leasing services (14%). The remaining sectors
Economic Development in China 32

contribute much smaller shares with the least amount of FDI going to the primary

sector.

Figure 3:

Sectoral Distribution of FDI in China – 2004

Note: Distribution industry includes transport, wholesale and retailing, Information transmission,
Computer services, Software, and Hotel services. The primary industry includes agriculture,
forestry, and fishing. Data from the China Statistical Yearbook, 2005.

Regional Disparities in China’s Economic Growth

Geographer Dennis Wei (1999) states that regional disparities within a nation

threaten unity and social stability and that it is surprising that not much debate has

addressed the regional disparities within China. Ever since the establishment of

Peoples Republic of China (PRC) in 1949, there have been increasing inequalities

between the coastal and inland regions in terms of resource allocation and local

autonomy (Kanbur and Zhang, 2005). There are many reasons underlying this. Wei

(1999) explains that this is because of the differentials in physical and human

resources inherited from the colonial period, the need for urban-centered

industrialization that limited resources available for development of the interior,


Economic Development in China 33

inefficiency in interior investments, access to foreign resources, and the lack of

favorable macro-conditions for economic growth in the interior. The government

encouraged coastal regions to “get rich quick” (Wei, 1999: 51). Hence, regions like

Jiangsun recorded dramatic growth while inland regions have lagged behind (Wei,

1999).The debate whether the gaps between the regions have narrowed or

increased in post-Mao China has supporters on both sides. However, many argue

for a greater attention to regional balance.

However, the new economic geography regards uneven regional development to be

the outcome of increasing returns. Hence, some regions are expected to grow faster

than others, which reinforce regional inequality – at least in the short run (Krugman,

1991). In particular, Porter (1998) has emphasized economic development through

the establishment of industrial clusters. Such clusters are groups of firms that have

commonalities in terms of trade interdependence (input-output relationship) and/or

shared social and cultural relationships that form around a core activity.

Geographical proximity is an important requirement because it lowers transportation

costs while encouraging inter-firm linkages. Such clusters help generate external

economies, and create opportunities for mutual learning, cooperation, trust, and

innovation through extensive networking (Camagni, 1991). Public intervention can

strengthen the competitiveness of the cluster in many cases. According to Amsden

(1989), in the later phases on industrialization, a big push from the state is the main

force behind successful industrialization. She notes that this has explained the

success of several East Asian nations’ rapid economic growth. Given this, it seems

that the Chinese government’s policy of building FDI clusters along the coast would

be consistent with Porter’s view that the state should use industrial clustering as a

means for rapid industrialization. In so doing, the state improves the properties for

continual learning (Scott and Storper, 2003).


Economic Development in China 34

Whether conscious public policy can actually affect the formation and development

of industrial clusters directly is discussed by Wolfe and Gertler (2004:4) who state

that the “evolutionary paths for cluster creation are highly variable. Public sector

decisions can affect cluster trajectories in a variety of ways, though the impacts are

often unpredictable and often unintended.” The Chinese have placed a lot of

emphasis on the development of industrial clusters (Chanye Jigun). However, China

needs to learn how to shape this process in the local arena, not only in adopting

lessons from other clusters but also in seeking to position local industries in the

global value chain and in strengthening their competitiveness in the global market.

As these clusters thrive, the diffusion process will bring about reduction in regional

inequality. Figures 4 and 5 reveal that regional inequalities in FDI clusters would

seem to have remained the same over 1999 to 2003 with the coastal or Eastern

region receiving the bulk of FDI.

FDI Stock in
China

Figure 4: Inequality in FDI investments in China


(Source: Bransetter, L.G. and R.C. Feenstra, 1999)
Economic Development in China 35

Figure 5: Regional Inequality of FDI investments in China – 2003

Source: Calculated using data from Data collected from Hunan Statistic Yearbook
2004, p.519

Trade and Investment in the Regional Context: China in the Asia Pacific Region

There is a strong evidence of the link between foreign direct investment and

manufacturing productivity growth in many Chinese provinces. Chen (2002) grouped

23 manufacturing sectors into three big industries and examined them in 29 Chinese

provinces between 1988 to 1994. They provided an estimate of the total factor

productivity (TFP) growth by manufacturing sector in relation to FDI inflows. The

results showed significant differences in TFP growth between manufacturing sectors

dominated by foreign direct investment and those dominated by domestic investment

in the consumer goods industry, confirming the positive impact of FDI on economic

growth.

FDI investments in China are substantially different from that of the rest of the world.

The majority of FDI in China is greenfield. Greenfield here is in reference to new

plants and equipment. The majority of FDI in the world, on the other hand, mostly

targets mergers and acquisitions (M&A) of existing businesses. During the economic

recession, there was a severe decrease in M&A, causing world FDI to decrease as
Economic Development in China 36

well (Song, 2005). As Song wrote in the ‘Executive Intelligence Review’, “while world

FDI suffered during the world economic recession, FDI inflow into China continues to

increase” (p: 1). He went on to say that the majority of green-field FDI in China

belonged to the category of labor-centric FDI. As we saw earlier in figure 3, the

manufacturing sector dominates in FDI sectoral composition. Of the total FDI into

China, 70% consists of labor sourcing FDI, especially for cheap Chinese labor. While

investment in labor-sourcing FDI would normally target low-income economies, this

was not the case in China despite substantial increase in wages there. Since 1996,

China has attracted over US$40 billion dollars in FDI, 95% of it targeting green-field

industries (Song, 2005).

Xinzhong (2005) suggests that China’s inward FDI tend to favor locations with the

following characteristics:

• Higher level of economic development (GDP)


• Higher density of population
• Better telecommunications
• Enhanced transport infrastructure

Table 5 below shows the top five FDI investors in China. It may not come as a

surprise, but Hong Kong, Japan and Taiwan are major contributors to China’s

economic development, with the US a distant seventh. Hsu (2006), and Yang (2006),

have documented the reasons for the high levels of Asian investments. Their studies

along with Table 5 suggest that geographical proximity explains much of these

investments. More importantly, Asian FDI is largely motivated by the operations of

overseas Chinese who are culturally familiar with China’s local business environment

and language. Hence, they have a competitive advantage over foreign investors

from Europe and the US.


Economic Development in China 37

Country/Region of Amoun Amoun Year-


Origin t t on-Year
Investe Invest Growth
d 2007 ed %
2008
Hong Kong 27.7 41.0 48.1
British Virgin Islands 16.6 16.0 -3.6
Singapore 3.2 4.4 39.3
Japan 3.6 3.7 1.8
Cayman Islands 2.6 3.2 22.3
South Korea 3.7 3.1 -14.8
United States 2.6 2.9 12.5
Western Samoa 2.2 2.6 17.5
Taiwan 1.8 1.9 7.0
Mauritius 1.3 1.5 12.1

Table 5: Top 10 Origins of Non-Financial FDI (Billion $)


Source: MOFCOM

Hong Kong is by far the largest investor in China. It supplies more than 48% of the

total FDI received by China in 2008. As we saw in an earlier section, FDI clusters are

mainly found on the coastal areas. Much of Hong Kong’s investment is located in

Guangdong and more recently, Dongguan coastal provinces. As these provinces are

adjacent to Hong Kong, they have seen an influx of Hong Kong capital as firms in the

city-state relocate their labor-intensive factories to the provinces (Yang, 2006).

Particularly interesting is that British Virgin Islands, and Cayman Islands are also two

of the top ten investors in Table 5. Both islands are tax havens to third countries but

it is possible to speculate here that some of that capital is being recycled through

China as FDI seek lower transaction costs. Surprisingly, none of the literature

reviewed makes any comment of this.

Trade Imbalance Tensions

Since trade exploits principles of comparative advantage and specialization, China’s

trade is intimately related to FDI. This is because a significant portion of FDI is in

China’s special economic export zones. This implies that corporations in these zones
Economic Development in China 38

are likely to use the incentives provided in these zones for export to the international

markets. In China’s case, the US has been a major destination for its exports.

Furthermore, some geographers have reported that comparative advantage may be

changing in China and trade has been credited with encouraging the rise of a high-

tech sector (Zhou and Xin, 2003). Huang et al (2008) examined 100,000 Chinese

manufacturing firms to find the reason for the surge of manufacturing exports from

China. Their findings indicate that this rise is not because of the role of low cost labor

and find that the results are inconclusive. According to them, the reasons lie in the

collaboration with foreign investors and fierce domestic competition. That is to say,

multinationals have contributed to Chinese hi-tech exports; evidenced by the fact

that foreign-funded enterprises control more than 70% of China’s high-tech exports

in recent years. Their share in total high-tech exports reached 87% in 2002 (China

Statistics Yearbook on High Technology Industry, 2003). China’s Ministry of

Commerce reports that of the approximate US$400 billion in high-tech export

products from China in 2005, less than 10% of the products bore the brand names of

the manufacturers or with independent intellectual property rights (Xinhua Net

20056).

As part of the Asia Pacific, the US shares strong commercial ties with China and

trade relations between the two countries have been strengthening since the

rapprochement in the early 1970s. This is due to the mutually attractive business

opportunities. On one side is China with its rapidly expanding markets and an almost

endless supply of cheap labor and on the other is the US that offers the best in

technology and some of the largest and strongest business organizations. Despite

this, large imbalances have occurred as exports from China far outstrip its imports

from the US (Table 6 below).

6 http://www.xinhua.net Accessed on July 25, 2009


Economic Development in China 39

The volume of trade between the two countries as a share of China’s total trade with

the world was about 12.6% in 1980 and rose to a peak in year 2000. Since then it

has again reduced to 20 % in 2005 and further to 15.9% in 2008. This is primarily

because of China’s diversification off trading partners across the world although the

US has also exerted considerable pressure to narrow the trade gap. Changes in oil

prices (China imports most of its energy requirements) have also affected this

equation though not significantly. On the other hand, China has emerged as one of

the top trading partners for the US.

Year Export Import Total Balance


of
Trade
1985 3,855.7 3,861.7 7,717.4 -6.0
1990 4,806.4 15,237.4 20,043.8 -
10,431.0
1995 11,753.7 45,543.2 57,296.9 -
33,789.5
2000 16,185.2 100,018. 116,203.4 -
2 83,833.0
2005 41,192.0 243,470. 284,662.1 -
1 202,278.
1
2008 69,732.8 337,772. 407,505.4 -
6 268,039.
8

Table 6: U.S. Trade with China (in million $)


Source: US Census Bureau7

While both countries enjoy the economic benefits of trade, the US trade deficit has

become a major economic and political issue. The primary tensions that exist are

China’s reluctance to open its domestic markets completely open to foreign

businesses and its adamancy of not allowing the Yuan to become a freely

convertible currency. Despite entry to the WTO, it has been difficult to make China

stick to its commitments towards market reforms. Hence, US investment in China

7 http://www.census.gov/foreign-trade/balance/c5700.html accessed on July 20,


2009
Economic Development in China 40

remains relatively low compared to its Asian counterparts even though its imports of

Chinese goods are high.

What this section suggests is that much of China’s economic growth may be driven

by Asian investment and US imports of Chinese goods. While Asian investors are

attracted by China’s cheap labor, exports of Chinese goods arising from these

investments, on the other hand, have been directed at the US market rather than at

their own markets.


Economic Development in China 41

Conclusion

Rapid growth and transformation of the Chinese economy since beginning of

economic reforms, driven by trade in the international and domestic arenas as well

as the massive injections of foreign direct investments (FDI) that came into the

country primarily to establish new industry, have underscored its transformation

since 1979. This has resulted in not only the growth of the national economy but also

the individual prosperity of its citizens and increase in its capability to produce

increasingly sophisticated and high-technology goods for the world markets. There

are some anomalies in the growth that has left behind the interior regions. However,

with time it is possible to expect that regional inequality may reduce as the benefits

of economic growth diffuse and filter down to the hinterlands as well.

Economic theory suggests that unfettered international capital flow fosters efficient

allocation of resources, which by itself should promote economic growth. The

economic benefits of FDI are twofold. First, FDI can help countries if domestic

savings are insufficient to finance economic expansion, and second, foreign

corporate presence is associated with positive externalities. However, as seen from

the Chinese example, the composition of the FDI is of vital importance. American

companies have invested only a fraction of the total FDI inflow into China and most

of this has sought to target the tertiary markets or acquisition of existing assets (that

is mergers and acquisition). On the other hand, FDI from Hong Kong, Japan and

Singapore have sought to create synergies through the establishment of new capital

assets (green-field enterprises). Investments have therefore borne fruits of different

kinds. The US is struggling with a massive trade deficit and the situation can get
Economic Development in China 42

worse if the Chinese capital markets were to deteriorate or if the Chinese decide to

call in their debts.

However, the data collected and presented in this thesis suggest that Chinese

economic growth may be driven by the inflow of capital from foreign investors and

the growth of it international trade. The empirical data would seem to support the

positive role of FDI and trade for its national development.

Nevertheless, rising wages may erode China’s advantage at least in the labor-

intensive industry. Problems related to loss of jobs in the West due to off-shoring of

work to less developed countries is also another factor that is going to force the

Western countries, particularly the US and United Kingdom, to bring back some of

these jobs and reduce reliance on foreign labor (NAPA, 2007). This may decrease

FDI to China. Moreover, FDI flows may taper down as businesses seek to hedge

their risks by diverting their finances to other developing countries. The trade

imbalance also remains a thorn, as there is a limit to which Chinese exports to the

US can continue unabated. It would seem that trade as an engine of growth has

benefitted China because of accessibility to the US market. But the political climate

in the US is also changing as the recession deepens.

A much larger problem is the artificially pegged currency rates. Despite pressure

from all quarters, the Chinese government has so far resisted floating its currency in

international money markets. If, and when this happens, the Yuan is likely to

appreciate through a huge margin making Chinese export less competitive in world

markets. This may address the trade imbalance to some extent but China may need

to expand its menu of growth engines beyond FDI and trade to maintain its high

growth rates in the end.


Economic Development in China 43

References

Aitken, B.J., and A.E. Harrison (1999): Do Domestic Firms Benefit from Direct
Foreign Investment? Evidence from Venezuela, American Economic Review,
Vol. 89(3) 605-618.

Alfaro, L., Ozcan, S.K., and Volosovych V. (2008): Why Doesn’t Capital Flow from
Rich to Poor Countries? An Empirical Investigation, The Review of Economics
and Statistics, 90: 347–368.

Amsden, A. (1989): Asia's Next Giant: South Korea and Late Industrialization. Oxford
University Press, New York.

Blomström, M., Lipsey, R.E. and M. Zejan (1996): Is Fixed Investment the Key to
Economic Growth?" Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 111(1) 269-276.

Blonigen, B. and M. Slaughter (2001): Foreign-Affiliate Activity and U.S. Skill


Upgrading, Review of Economics and Statistics 83: 362–376.

Branstetter, L. (2006): Is Foreign Direct Investment a Channel of Knowledge


Spillovers? Evidence from Japan’s FDI in the United States, Journal of
International Economics, 68(2): 325-344.

Bransetter, L.G. and R.C. Feenstra (1999): Trade and Foreign Direct Investment in
China: A Political Economy Approach, NBER papers.

Bronfenbrenner, K. (2001): Impact of U.S-China Trade Relations on Workers,


Wages, and Employment: Pilot Study Report, Accessed on June 25, 2009 from:
http://govinfo.library.unt.edu/tdrc/research/china1.pdf

Camagni, R. (1991): ‘Local ‘milieu’, uncertainty and innovation networks: towards a


new dynamic theory of economic space’ in Camagni, R. (Ed.) Innovation
Networks: spatial perspectives, London, Belhaven, pp. 121-142.

Carkovic, M. and Levine, R. (2005): Does Foreign Direct Investment Accelerate


Economic Growth? in: Moran, T., Graham, E. and Blomstrom M. (eds.), Does
Foreign Direct Investment Promote Development? Washington DC: Institute for
International Economics: 195–220.

China Statistics Yearbook on High Technology Industry (2003), National Bureau of


Statistics of China, National Development and Reform Commission, Ministry of
Science and Technology. Beijing: China Statistics Press.

Chuang, Y.C. and C.M. Lin (1999): Foreign Direct Investment, R&D and Spillover
Efficiency: Evidence from Taiwan’s Manufacturing Firms, Journal of
Development Studies, Vol. 35(4), 117-137.
Economic Development in China 44

Conyon, M., Girma, S., Thompson, S., and P. Wright (2002): The Productivity and
Wage Effect of Foreign Acquisition in the United Kingdom, Journal of Industrial
Economics 50:85–102.

Cypher, J. M., and J. L. Dietz (1997): The Process of Economic Development,


Routledge, London.

de Long, J.B. and Summers, L.H. (1991): Equipment Investment and Economic
Growth, Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 106, No. 2, pp. 445-502.

de Long, J.B. and Summers, L.H., (1992): Equipment Investment and Economic
Growth: How Strong Is the Nexus?, Brookings Papers on Economic Activity,
No. 2, pp. 157-199.

de Mello, L.R. 1997. Foreign Direct Investment in Developing Countries and Growth:
A Selective Survey”. Journal of Development Studies 34(1):1-34.

de Mello, L.R., Jr. (1999): Foreign Direct Investment-Led Growth: Evidence from
Time Series and Panel Data, Oxford Economic Papers, Vol. 51(1) 133-151.

Eichengreen, B. and H. Tong (2005): Is China’s FDI Coming at the Expense of Other
Countries? National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER) Working Paper
11335, Internet resource accessed on July 15, 2009 from:
http://www.nber.org/papers/w11335

Frankel, J. A., and D. Romer (1999): Does Trade Cause Growth? The American
Economic Review, June 1999, 379- 399.

Greenaway, D., Sapsford, D. and S. Pfaffenzeller (2007): Foreign Direct Investment,


Economic Performance and Trade Liberalization, World Economy 30(2): 197-
210.

Grossman, G. M., and E. Helpman (1997): Innovation and Growth in the Global
Economy, Cambridge: The MIT Press.

Hansen, H., and J. Rand (2006): On the Causal Links between FDI and Growth in
Developing Countries, World Economy 29(1): 21-4.

Hsu, J. (2006): The Dynamic Firm-Territory Nexus of Taiwanese Informatics Industry


Investments in China, Growth and Change, 37, 230-254.

Huang, C., Zhang, M., Zhao, Y., and Varum, C.A. (2008): Determinants of exports in
China: a micro-econometric analysis, The European Journal of Development
Research, Vol. 20(2) 299–317

Kanbur, R. and Chang, X. (2005): Fifty Years of Regional Inequality in China,


Review of Development Economics, 9, 87-106.

Keller, W. (2004): International Technology Diffusion, Journal of Economic Literature


42, 752-782.

Krugman, P. (1991): Increasing Returns in Economic Geography, Journal of Political


Economy, 99, 1983-99.
Economic Development in China 45

Lucas, R.E. Jr. (1988): On the Mechanics of Economic Development, Journal of


Monetary Economics 22, 3-42.

Mencinger, J. (2003): Does Foreign Direct Investment Always Enhance Economic


Growth? Kyklos 56: 491–508.

Morrison W. M. (2005): China’s Economic Conditions, CRS Issue Brief for Congress,
Accessed on July 25, 2009 from:
http://fpc.state.gov/documents/organization/50285.pdf

Mullen, J. K. and Williams, M. (2005): Foreign Direct Investment and Regional


Economic Performance, Kyklos, 58: 265–282.

NAPA (2007): National Academy of Public Administration, Off-Shoring: What Are its
Effects? Accessed on July 26, 2009 from: http://www.bea.gov/papers/pdf/Off-
Shoring_WhatAreitsEffects.pdf

NBS (2007): National Bureau of Statistics, The National Economy Maintained a


Steady, and Fast Growth in 2006, Accessed on July 25, 2009 from:
www.stats.gov.cn

OECD (2000): Main Determinants and Impacts of Foreign Direct Investment on


China’s Economy, Accessed on July 26, 2009 from:
http://www.oecd.org/dataoecd/57/23/1922648.pdf

Poon, J.P.H., and E.R. Thompson (1998): Foreign Direct Investment and Economic
Growth: Evidence from Asia and Latin America, Journal of Economic
Development, Vol. 23(2) 141-160.

____________________ (2001): Effects of the Asian Financial Crisis on


Transnational Capital, Geoforum, 32, 121-3.

Porter, M. E. (1998): The Competitive Advantage of Nations. New York: Free Press,
1998.

Ravenscraft, D. and Scherer, F.M. (1987): Life after Takeovers, Journal of Industrial
Economics, 36, 147-156.

Ravenscraft, D. (1991):“Gains and Losses from Mergers: The Evidence,” Managerial


Finance, 17, 8-13.

Rehbar, E. and L. Grega (2008): Agriculture, Trade and Sustainability, The


European Legacy, Vol. 13(4) pp. 463–479.

Rodrik, D. (1998). Who Needs Capital-Account Convertibility, in: Kenen, P. (ed).


Should the IMF Pursue Capital Account Convertibility? Essays in International
Finance 207, Princeton University.

Sachs, J. D., and Woo, W. T. (1997): Understanding China’s Economic


Performance, NBER Working Paper no. 5935.
Economic Development in China 46

Scott, A .J. and M. Storper (2003): Regions, globalization, development, Regional


Studies 37:579-593.

Song, H. Dr. (2005): China's Role in the World Economy, accessed on July 20, 2009
fromhttps://www.larouchepub.com/other/2005/site_packages/june28-
29_berlin/3229dr_song_hong.html

UNCTAD (2000): World Investment Report 2000, New York: United Nations.

UNCTAD (2005): World Investment Report 2005, New York: United Nations.

Wang, M. and M.C. S. Wong (2009): What Drives Economic Growth? The Case of
Cross-Border M&A and Greenfield FDI Activities, Kyklos, 62(2), 316–330.

Wei, D.Y. (1999): Regional inequality in China, Progress in Human Geography 23(1)
49–59.

______ (2000): Regional Development in China: States, Globalization and


Inequality. New York: Routledge.

Wolfe, D.A., and M. S. Gertler (2004): Clusters from the Inside and Out: Local
Dynamics and Global Linkages, Urban Studies, Special Issue.

Xinzhong, L. (2005): Foreign Direct Investment Inflows in China: Determinants,


Accessed on July 25, 2009 from: http://www.i-
conf.org/cnrs_cass/download.php?file=16_Li_Xinzhong.pdf.

Yang, C. (2006): Overseas Chinese Investment in Transition: The Case of


Dongguan, Eurasian Geography and Economics, 47, 604-22.

Yu Chen (2002): Foreign Direct Investment and Manufacturing Productivity in China,


Accessed on July 28, 2009 from: www.bm.ust.hk/~ced/Yu%20CHEN.pdf.

Zhou, Y. and T. Xin (2003): An Innovation Region in China: Interactions between


Multinational Corporations and Local Firms in a High-Tech Cluster in Beijing,
Economic Geography, 79, 129-52.

You might also like