You are on page 1of 14

Financial crisis and potential

output
Clemente De Lucia

T
he eurozone economy has faced the worst The rest of the article is as follows. The first section
recession on record since the 1970s. After puts the last recession into context, comparing it with
collapsing at the end of 2008 and in the first other severe financial crises experienced by other
quarter of 2009, GDP has gradually recovered, returning OECD countries. Then the channels though which the
to growth in Q3 2009. Nevertheless there is still a long current crisis has affected potential output are analysed.
road to recovery. History suggests that recessions Lastly, some considerations regarding uncertainty about
caused by financial distress tend to last longer and are potential output estimates and the implications for policy
particularly severe. Moreover, the 2009 recession was makers are presented.
also synchronized, an element which exacerbated the Even though the crisis has likely affected potential
fall in output. output in the short run, the effects on the medium term
The recession is also likely to have affected are more uncertain. Should the eurozone fail to
potential output. In particular, the significant fall in implement structural reforms to enhance product and
investment is likely to lead to a reduction in capital labour market flexibility, then the most likely medium-
stock, with negative effects on potential output in the term scenario is one where the growth rate of eurozone
short run. Financial turbulence can also have an impact potential output comes back to pre-crisis values, while
on Total Factor Productivity (TFP), which measures the level of potential output remains below.
efficiency in the use of production factors. Facing
significant drops in demand and profits, firms may have
reduced investment in research and development
(R&D), one of the main drivers of TFP. Last, but not Severity of the 2008/09 recession
least, the crisis may affect potential output through the
labour factor. Unemployment has already increased
significantly, notably in Spain and Ireland, two countries Unprecedented contraction
hit hard by the effects of the crisis. A particular concern
is that a large part of the increase in unemployment In 2008 the eurozone economy entered a very deep
could be transferred into structural unemployment, as a and severe recession. From the end of 2008, output fell
result of what is called the “hysteresis” effect (Blanchard significantly, with GDP dropping by almost 2% q/q in
and Summers 1986). Higher structural unemployment Q4 2008 and by 2.4% q/q in Q1 2009. Eurostat’s figures
reduces potential output. Moreover, a long and severe showed that GDP returned to growth in the third quarter
recession may reduce the labour participation rate, as of 2009, signalling the end of the recession. From an
discouraged people reduce their efforts to seek a job. historical point of view, this has been the most severe
The combination of all these effects has pushed GDP contraction experienced by the eurozone economy
down significantly short term eurozone estimates of since the early 1970s (see chart 1)1. The level of output
potential output growth rate. It is worth noting, however, has decreased faster and more steeply than in previous
that it was already moderating due to unfavourable recessions and the pace of recovery seems much more
demographic trends. moderate. (see chart 2).

March 2010 Conjoncture 3


A global financial crisis
Eurozone GDP growth (y-o-y % change)
The 2008 recession was caused by financial
6
distress. History suggests that such financial crises are
particularly acute and are associated with a very gradual 4

recovery. Financial distress is usually associated with 2


balance sheet adjustments which could lead to lower 0
domestic demand against a background of lower credit -2
growth. Vertical bars mean recessions as identified by the Euro Aera Business Cycle
-4
Chart 3 compares the 2008/2009 eurozone Dating Committee of the Centre for Economic Policy Research CEPR)

recession with other episodes of severe financial -6


71 73 75 77 79 81 83 85 87 89 91 93 95 97 99 01 03 05 07 09
distress affecting certain OECD countries2. This shows
Chart 1 Sources: ECB, Eurostat
that Eurozone GDP has contracted more sharply. The
2008/2009 recession was not only a regional financial
crisis but also a global crisis. This element clearly
exacerbated the fall in output, making the road to GDP during recession episodes
recovery longer as the economy cannot take advantage 110
1974Q3
of an external driver. 108
1980Q1
Impacts on investment, exports and imports have 106 1992Q1
104
been much more pronounced in the eurozone than in 2008Q1
102
the other countries which experienced severe financial 100
distress (see charts 4, 5, 6). As the crisis affected the 98
global economy, demand for eurozone exports 96
collapsed. Significant sharp falls in orders pushed down 94 Q= means the peak of activity prior
to the previous crisis
investment, the most cyclical component of domestic 92
90
demand and highly related to export dynamics. Q-8 Q-6 Q-4 Q-2 Q Q+2 Q+4 Q+6 Q+8 Q+10 Q+12 Q+14 Q+16
Moreover, as confidence plunged to historically low Chart 2 Sources: ECB, Eurostat, BNP Paribas calculations

levels and expectations of future activity collapsed, firms


drastically reduced their stocks with negative side potential output is not observable and can only be
effects on output and investments. In addition, drops in estimated with some uncertainty. For this reason it is
orders and income caused a significant fall in imports. quite often revised ex-post.
As financial markets and business cycles around the There are different methods for estimating potential
world are much more integrated today than was the output. The most commonly used is the production
case in previous decades, the contraction in global function approach, which links output to the level of
activity was even more pronounced. technology and factor inputs, usually labour and capital.
By contrast, the fall in private consumption was in The commonest functional form is the “Cobb –Douglas”
line with previous episodes of severe financial distress production function which can be written as
(see chart 7). The exceptional budgetary measures 1D
Y AK N
D
undertaken to cope with the crisis clearly favoured a (1.1) t t t 1 t
less dramatic contraction in private consumption. where K is the capital stock, N is labour, and A
is total factor productivity (TFP), measuring the level of
technology. D is the elasticity of labour with respect to
Potential output output.
One of the advantages of using a production
Potential output growth reflects the growth which function approach is that potential output forecasts can
can be achieved using available production factors easily be obtained as projections of input variables
without generating inflationary pressures. However, (employment, unemployment, investment and therefore

March 2010 Conjoncture 4


Financial crisis and GDP: Eurozone versus five
OECD countries affected by severe financial crisis Financial crisis and imports
4
Average of 5 OECD countries (*) 10 Average of 5 OECD countries (*)
3 8
Eurozone 6 Eurozone
2
4
1 2
0
0 -2
-4
-1
-6 (*) Spain 1978-79 Finland 1989-93 Sweden 1993
-2 -8 Norway 1988 Japan 1993
(*) Spain 1978-79 Finland 1989-93 Sweden 1993
-10
-3 Norway 1988 Japan 1993
-12
-14
-4
-16
-5 -18
Q-8 Q-6 Q-4 Q-2 Q Q+2 Q+4 Q+6 Q+8 Q+10 Q+12 Q+14 Q+16 Q-8 Q-6 Q-4 Q-2 Q Q+2 Q+4 Q+6 Q+8 Q+10 Q+12 Q+14 Q+16

Chart 3 Sources: Eurostat, OECD, BNP Paribas calculations Chart 5 Sources: Eurostat, OECD, BNP Paribas calculations

Financial crisis and exports Financial crisis and investment


10 8
8 Average of 5 OECD countries (*) Average of 5 OECD countries (*)
6 6
Eurozone
4 4 Eurozone
2 2
0
-2 0
-4 -2
-6
-4
-8 (*) Spain 1978-79 Finland 1989-93 Sweden 1993
-10 (*) Spain 1978-79 Finland 1989-93 Sweden 1993 -6 Norway 1988 Japan 1993
-12 Norway 1988 Japan 1993
-8
-14
-16 -10
-18 -12
Q-8 Q-6 Q-4 Q-2 Q Q+2 Q+4 Q+6 Q+8 Q+10 Q+12 Q+14 Q+16 Q-8 Q-6 Q-4 Q-2 Q Q+2 Q+4 Q+6 Q+8 Q+10 Q+12 Q+14 Q+16
Chart 4 Sources: Eurostat, OECD, BNP Paribas calculations Chart 6 Sources: Eurostat, OECD, BNP Paribas calculations

Financial crisis and consumption


4
Average of 5 OECD countries (*)
3

2 Eurozone

-1

-2
(*) Spain 1978-79 Finland 1989-93 Sweden 1993
-3 Norway 1988 Japan 1993

-4
Q-8 Q-6 Q-4 Q-2 Q Q+2 Q+4 Q+6 Q+8 Q+10 Q+12 Q+14 Q+16

Chart 7 Sources: Eurostat, OECD, BNP Paribas calculations

March 2010 Conjoncture 5


capital stock) are normally available. Nevertheless,
Eurozone: growth accounting decomposition
there are also disadvantages. Often the production
function approach relies on trend components of input 6
TFP Capital
variables3. 5
Labour GDP
4
Growth accounting
3

Assuming perfect competition and constant returns 2


to scale, D in equation (1.1) coincides with the labour
1
wN
share in value added: D , where 0
Y 1960-70 1971-1980 1981-1990 1991-2000 2001-2007 2001-2009

wage w wY is equal to the marginal labour


Chart 8 Sources: European Commission AMECO data set, BNP Paribas calculations

wN
productivity. In this case the GDP growth rate can be
The impact of demographic trends on growth
decomposed as:
'Y 'A 'K 'N Growth accounting analysis is also useful in
(1.2)  (1  D ) D
Y A K N understanding how demographic trends affect growth. In
Equation (1.2) is the key tool in “growth accounting” particular, higher population growth rates will have a
which analyses the contribution of supply-side factors to positive impact on output. Moreover, changes in the
working age population rate, measured as the ratio of
GDP growth. 1  D of equation (1.2) is the capital
working age population over total population, provides
share in value added. In most industrialized economies
information regarding the age structure of the economy.
capital shares vary between 0.3% and 0.4%, while the
Intuitively, the higher this ratio, the higher the proportion
labour share varies between 0.6% and 0.7% (see
of people able to work. A growing labour force will have
among others Cahn and Saint-Guilhem (2007)). After
a positive impact on growth.
calibrating D and knowing the growth rate of capital
§ 'A · Defining y Y as GDP per capita, where
P
and labour, the growth rate of technology ¨ ¸ is
© A ¹ P means population and Y real GDP, the growth rate
derived from equation(1.2). This is what is called the of the latter can be approximated by the sum of the
“Solow Residual”, that is the part of actual output not population growth rate and per-capita GDP growth rate.
explained by capital and labour developments. This is This can be expressed as in the following formula:
the normal procedure for obtaining an estimate of factor (1.3) gY | g y  g p
A in equation (1.1)4. In addition GDP in per capita terms can be written as:
Using this decomposition, chart 8 shows that the Y Wap N Y
GDP growth slowdown over recent decades among the (1.4) y ˜ ˜
largest economies of the eurozone and for the eurozone P P Wap N
as a whole was due to a decrease in total factor where Wap means “working age population” and N is
productivity.
the number of employed persons. Therefore, the growth
The contribution of capital also eased, albeit by a
rate of GDP per capita can be approximated as
smaller amount. Lastly the contribution of labour has
been always particularly weak. Since the 1990s, (1.5) g y | g wap  g er  g NP
however, the contribution of labour has slightly The components on the right hand side of equation (1.5)
increased. German reunification and an increase in are:
immigrant flows since the 1990s might have been 1) g wap , that is the growth rate of the ratio of
behind this phenomenon, particularly in Spain and to a
lesser extent in Italy and France. working age population (15-64 years) to total population,

March 2010 Conjoncture 6


The impact of demographic trend on GDP: Eurozone France
7 Population 7 Population
Labour productivity Labour productivity
6 6
Employment Rate Employment Rate
5 Working age Pop./Total Population 5 Working age Pop./Total Population
GDP GDP
4 4

3 3

2 2

1 1

0 0

-1 -1
1961-1970 1971-1980 1981-1990 1991-2000 2001-2007 2001-2009 1961-1970 1971-1980 1981-1990 1991-2000 2001-2007 2001-2009

Chart 9 Sources: European Commission AMECO data set, BNP Paribas calculations Chart 11 Sources: European Commission AMECO data set, BNP Paribas calculations

Germany Italy
6 Population 8 Population
Labour productivity 7 Labour productivity
5
Employment Rate 6 Employment Rate
4 Working age Pop./Total Population Working age Pop./Total Population
5
GDP GDP
3 4
3
2
2
1 1
0
0
-1
-1 -2
1961-1970 1971-1980 1981-1990 1991-2000 2001-2007 2001-2009 1961-1970 1971-1980 1981-1990 1991-2000 2001-2007 2001-2009
Chart 10 Sources: European Commission AMECO data set, BNP Paribas calculations Chart 12 Sources: European Commission AMECO data set, BNP Paribas calculations

Spain
10 Population
Labour productivity
8 Employment Rate
6 Working age Pop./Total Population
GDP
4

-2

-4
1961-1970 1971-1980 1981-1990 1991-2000 2001-2007 2001-2009
Chart 13 Sources: European Commission AMECO data set, BNP Paribas calculations

March 2010 Conjoncture 7


or what is called the “working age population rate”. This
element reflects the effect of changes in the
Effects of the crisis on potential
demographic structure on per capita GDP growth output
(Benalal et all (2006));
2) g er , that is the growth rate of employed persons Financial market turbulence, credit shortages and
in the working age population, called the “employment higher unemployment have likely affected potential
rate”; output in the short run through various channels:
3) g NP the growth rate of the GDP-employment Effects on capital
ratio, which is labour productivity.
By substituting equation (1.5) into equation (1.3), it As shown above, in the aftermath of the financial
is possible to analyse the effects of demographic distress, investment, one of the most cyclical
changes on real GDP growth. Chart 9 shows the results components of GDP, collapsed.
for the eurozone. A lower level of investment can decrease the stock
The population growth rate has played a quite of capital and its efficiency. Usually in growth theory
limited role in explaining growth over the past few capital stock, K , evolves as follows:
decades, while labour productivity has recorded (1.6) K t (1  G ) K t 1  I t
the largest contribution to growth. However, its
contribution has been decreasing over the past few where G is the depreciation rate and I is the level of
decades. investment in period t.
The contribution of the employment rate has been In 2009, eurozone investment contracted by almost
increasing over the last two decades. Labour market 10% compared with the previous year and is likely to
reforms implemented over recent years have clearly remain subdued throughout 2010. The capital-to-output
contributed to raising employment. The use of ratio has increased markedly over recent quarters (see
temporary contracts and part time jobs has chart 14), meaning that there is a large excess of
been increasing constantly since the 1990s (see spare capacity in the economy, limiting the need for
EC 2009a). further investments. Capacity utilization in the
By contrast, the working age population growth rate manufacturing sector, as measured by the European
has been rather weak and has been acting as a drag on Commission, was still close to its historical low in
growth over the last decade. This is a particularly Q4 2009.
worrying sign. It means that the age structure of the
population is not sustaining growth. This trend is likely
to strengthen in the future due to a more rapid increase Capital and output ratio
in the proportion of older persons to the total population.
1.35 Average four largest EZ countries
Germany seems particularly exposed to this problem.
1.30
Over the last decade the contribution of the population
growth rate to GDP growth has been nil. Moreover, 1.25

Germany recorded the largest drag on growth from 1.20

the working age population component among the 1.15


largest economies in the region. (see charts 10, 11, 1.10
12, 13). 1.05
To sum up, growth accounting analysis shows that 1.00
the demographic structure of the economy is weighing 1991 1993 1995 1997 1999 2001 2003 2005 2007 2009

on eurozone growth perspectives. Chart 14 Sources: OECD, BNP Paribas calculations

March 2010 Conjoncture 8


Higher debt funding costs and the collapse in efficiency in the use of production factors. Given current
demand were among the main factors causing the fall in circumstances, firms may have reduced investment in
investment. A proxy for the lower bound of banks’ research and development (R&D), one of the main
funding costs is given by the sum of the CDS premium drivers of TFP and long-term growth. The postponement
and the 5-year German government bond yield. The of key investment in innovation may have a lasting effect
spread between the refi rate and this measure was on productivity and, consequently on growth.
about 130 bp before the crisis, but is now around 325 bp Protracted Government support schemes risk
(see chart 15). This is a particularly worrying sign given delaying the restructuring process. “Zombie lending” in
that the banking system remains by far the most Japan is a clear example where large firms benefited
important source of funding for non-financial from political support and were able to find funds at the
corporations. expense of smaller, innovative but vulnerable firms
(Cabaillero et al 2006).
On the other hand, financial crisis may force firms to
Bank funding costs
abandon their least productive business lines. Contrary
7 Refi rate to what said above, this may increase the economy’s
6
Proxy for the lower bound of the average productivity.
5 banks’ funding costs

4 Effects on labour
3

2 Last but not least, the financial crisis may have a


1
significant impact on the labour factor. Eurozone
0
employment has been contracting since Q3 2008.
05 06 07 08 09 10 Survey data suggest that labour market conditions
Chart 15 Sources: Datastream, ECB, BNP Paribas calculations
continued to deteriorate in the last quarter of 2009. The
unemployment rate rose to 10% in December, the
In addition, two other factors could make conditions highest rate since June 1998, and could increase further
even tougher: On the one hand, budgetary measures throughout the year.
taken by national Governments to cope with the crisis A particular concern is that a significant increase in
have pushed up deficits and public debt significantly. unemployment may be transformed into structural
Concerns regarding the sustainability of country debt unemployment, a result of the so called “hysteresis”
dynamics could push long-term interest rates higher. On effect (Blanchard and Summers 1986). This occurs
the other hand, high levels of uncertainty lead to an because long unemployment periods may cause
increase in risk premia, with negative effects on destruction of human capital. The long-term unemployed
investment. Higher interest rates could thus crowd out therefore no longer compete with those in jobs and
private investment. Moreover, uncertainties about fiscal consequently do not exert downward pressure on
sustainability and expectations of future fiscal tightening wages, increasing the persistence of unemployment.
may prompt consumers to increase their saving, with a Under these conditions, the structural unemployment
negative feedback on demand and thus again on rate or NAIRU (non accelerating inflation rate of
investment. unemployment), that is the unemployment rate
Lastly, the rate of depreciation is likely to have consistent with stable inflation, could increase. In this
increased, at least temporarily, as existing equipment case an economy can be characterized by higher
becomes obsolete. unemployment and higher inflation rates.
In addition, a protracted recession may also
Effects on TFP discourage workers from seeking a job, reducing the
labour force participation rate. Higher structural
The financial crisis may also have an impact on unemployment will weigh on the labour input 5 ,
Total Factor Productivity (TFP), which measures decreasing potential output.

March 2010 Conjoncture 9


Long-term unemployment, defined as those who Long-term unemployment and
actual unemployment in the USA
remained unemployed for more than 12 months, is a key
determinant of the hysteresis effect and it tends to rise 0.4

Change long-term UN rate


with total unemployment. Charts 16 and 17 show the 0.3

relationship between changes in long-term 0.2

unemployment and changes in actual unemployment in 0.1

the US and the eurozone. The data seem to suggest 0

that the impact is stronger in the eurozone than in the -0.1

US. This is confirmed by a simple dynamic equation -0.2

relating the two variables (Table 1). -0.3


-1.0 -0.5 0.0 0.5 1.0 1.5 2.0
(1.7) Change UN rate
n n
LUN t ¦ i 1
D i LUN t i  ¦ i 0 E iUN t i  H i Chart 16 Sources: ECB, Eurostat

LUN is the long-term unemployment rate and UN is


the actual unemployment rate. The regression analysis Long-term unemployment and
shows that the long run impact of higher actual actual unemployment in the Eurozone
unemployment on long-term unemployment is much 0.4
stronger in the eurozone than in the US. After a
Change long-term UN rate

0.3
permanent unemployment shock, as many as 60% of 0.2

the unemployed become long-term unemployed in the 0.1


0
eurozone, compared with only 16% in the United States,
-0.1
in line with the OECD's findings (2009a). This is a result
-0.2
of the United States having a much more dynamic and -0.3
flexible labour market than the eurozone. -0.4
The relationship between long-term unemployment -0.4 -0.2 0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 1.2
Change UN rate
and NAIRU is more complex. A number of research
articles (see, for example, Llaudes (2005)) show that in Chart 17 Sources: OECD, BNP Paribas calculations

OECD countries, the long-term unemployed exert less


pressure on wages than the short-term unemployed and unemployment on NAIRU. From around 8% in Q2 2009,
that this pressure is much more moderate in Europe according to the latest OECD estimate (OECD 2009b),
than in the US. This implies that a larger part of any NAIRU could increase to around 8.8% in mid 2011. By
increase in long-term unemployment is translated into contrast, the rise of structural unemployment is
NAIRU in Europe than in the US. This impact may be projected to be less pronounced in the US. From 4.9%
estimated as 0.75% in the eurozone and 0.25% in Q2 2009 (OECD estimates), it is expected to increase
elsewhere (OECD 2009a). However, to take into to 5.1% at the end of 2011. Not surprisingly, both the
account labour market reforms implemented in Europe level of NAIRU and changes to it will be smaller in the
over recent decades, the OECD has reduced the impact US than in the eurozone.
of long-term unemployment on structural unemployment Taking into account all these factors, the estimated
to 0.66% (OECD 2009a). As a result, based on our potential output growth rate6 for 2009 and 2010 is in the
projections for the actual unemployment rate for this range of 0.6-0.7%, in line with the European
year and next (the unemployment rate is a lagging Commission Autumn forecasts (EC 2009a). This would
variable of activity and is expected to peak at around generate an output gap (defined as percentage of
10.6%-10.7% in mid 2010, then remain at that level or potential output) in the range of [-3;-4] % for 2009,
slightly below for a while), the estimated increase in around -3% in 2010, more than -2% in 2011 and more
long-term unemployment can be derived from equation than -1% in 2012. The European Commission output
(1.7). Then, using the rule suggested by the OECD, gap estimates are broadly similar. (see Table 2). The
we can forecast the impact of higher long-term OECD (2009b) has slightly higher estimates for the

March 2010 Conjoncture 10


potential output growth rate in both 2009 and 2010. Impact of actual unemployment rate on long term
However, like the European Commission, the OECD unemployment
has revised down its potential output estimates. Dep. Variable long term UN
rate
Eurozone United States
Policy implications Explanatory variables 0.18
(-1.88)
-0.03
(-1.76)
Long term UN rate (-1) 1.43 1.43
Nonetheless, some caution is needed. Since (13.40) (21.80)
potential output is not observable, it is subject to Long term UN rate (-2) -0.58 -0.49
significant uncertainty. Given that the financial crisis has (-6.83) (-7.87)
affected potential output from several channels, making UN rate 0.09
an estimate is even more complicated. Nevertheless, it (3.62)
is extremely useful for policy makers. The output gap, UN rate (-1) 0.05
defined as the percentage deviation of actual output (5.00)
from potential, can be seen as: UN rate (-2) -0.04
(-3.99)
i) a measure of the degree of utilization of
production factors
ii) an indicator of the state of the business Sample 1991 Q3 1970 Q1
2009 Q1 2009 Q1
cycle R2 0.98 0.97
iii) and an indicator of inflationary pressures.
DW 2.13 2.17
Statistically, there is a clear correlation between the
output gap and core inflation (see chart 18) which Table 1 Sources: OECD, BNP Paribas calculations
provides important information regarding future moves
in key monetary policy rates. A projected large and GDP growth, potential output growth and output gap
negative output gap for the eurozone in the quarters Potential
Actual GDP Output gap
ahead will continue to exert significant downward Output
pressure on core inflation. In addition, the ongoing 2009 -4.0 0.7 -2.9
deterioration in the labour market should limit wage European 2010 0.7 0.7 -3.0
inflation, one of the biggest drivers of core inflation. As a Commission 2011 1.5 1.2 -2.5
result, taking into account the continuing weakness of 2012 n.a. 1.5 n.a.
the economy, the ECB is likely to leave the refi rate 2009 -4.0 1.2 -4.5
unchanged for an extended period of time, and at least
2010 0.9 0.9 -4.5
until the end of 2010. OECD
2011 1.7 1.0 -3.8
2012 n.a. n.a. n.a.
Core inflation and output gap 2009 -3.9 0.6 -3.5
3.0 Output gap (12-month lag) 3.0 BNP 2010 1.3 0.7 -2.8
2.0 Core Inflation (% 1-year change) 2.0 Paribas 2011 1.5 0.9 -2.2
1.0 1.0 2012 2.5 1.4 -1.1
0.0 0.0 Table 2 Sources: European Commission, OECD, BNP Paribas
-1.0 -1.0

-2.0 -2.0 Nevertheless, uncertainty about estimates of


-3.0 -3.0 potential output could cause problems for monetary
-4.0 -4.0 authorities. Higher estimates of potential output, if
1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 proved to be wrong, risk overestimating the output gap.
Chart 18 Sources: Eurostat, BNP Paribas
As a result, monetary authorities might leave key policy

March 2010 Conjoncture 11


rates at lower levels for too long, creating upward
Projections of potential output
pressure on inflation and potentially inflating asset price
bubbles. On the other hand, lower estimates of potential Level shift
Trend
output could produce smaller output gap estimates. In Permanent loss
14.24 Full recovery
these circumstances, central banks could be tempted to
raise key policy rates too early, potentially undermining
an ongoing but still fragile recovery.
Measures of potential output are also used to derive
other indicators such as the cyclically-adjusted budget
balance, which provides information on a country’s fiscal
stance. In particular, a too small output gap estimates 14.14
2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012
will imply too high estimated structural components of
Chart 19 Source: BNP Paribas
fiscal deficits. This means that countries which aim to
stabilise their fiscal positions could implemented more
painful actions than actually needed. By contrast, the crisis could even trigger an
acceleration of structural reforms in the eurozone.
Making eurozone product and labour markets more
flexible and more open to competition could increase
growth prospects, creating the conditions for a “full
ˆ ˆ recovery”. Under this more optimistic scenario, the level
of potential output returns to its pre-crisis period.
ˆ
Finland, which faced a serious banking crisis in the early
1990s, is an example of output recovering completely
from losses due to financial distress. (see EC (2009b)
All in all, although useful for economic analysis and for details).
for policy makers, potential output is difficult to estimate Lastly there is an intermediate scenario where
and subject to ex-post revisions. The effects of the potential output growth might return to the pre-crisis
global financial crisis risk exacerbating the uncertainty rate, but not the potential output level, which will be
surrounding measures of potential output. While it is lower. This is what is called the “permanent level loss”
widely accepted that the financial crisis has affected scenario. In this case, financial sector problems are
potential output in the short run, estimating the impact resolved, but no further actions on structural reform are
on potential output over the medium term is undertaken.
complicated. It is currently very uncertain which the future path of
The impact on potential output in the medium term potential output will be over the medium term.
will depend crucially on policy factors. In particular, if the Nevertheless, the materialisation of one scenario rather
crisis were to lead to a new “equilibrium” with higher than another will depend on what policy reforms
public debt, this would mean that sooner of later the eurozone countries undertake over the coming years.
level of taxation has to be increased, with negative
effects on growth perspectives. Note that demographic
developments are already exerting downward pressure
on potential output. This is what is called a “continuous 26 February 2010
widening loss” scenario (EC 2009b), where both the clemente.delucia@bnpparibas.com
level and the growth rate of potential output are below
their pre-crisis levels (see chart 19). After the 1990
crisis, Japan experienced exactly this situation where
potential output was estimated to be well below the mid-
1990s period.

March 2010 Conjoncture 12


References

Benalal N. Diaz del Hoyo, J. L., Pierluigi B. Vidalis N. (2006) “Output Growth differentials across the Euro Area
Countries; Some Stylised Facts”, ECB Occasional Paper Series No. 45, May 2006

Blanchard, O. and Summers, L. (1986) “Hysteresis and the European Unemployment Problem” NBER Working
Paper Series, N. 1950

Caballero, R.J., T. Hoshi and A.K. Kashyap (2006), “Zombie lending and depressed restructuring in Japan”, NBER
Working Paper Series N. 12129

Cahn, C. and Saint-Guilhem, A. (2007) “Potential output growth in several industrialised countries: A comparison”
ECB Working Paper Series, N. 827, November

EC (2009a) “European Economic Forecasts, Autumn”, October

EC (2009b) “Impact of the current economic and financial crisis on potential output” Occasional Papers N. 49, June

ECB (2009) “The latest euro area recession in a historical context” Monthly Bulletin, November

ECB (2000) “Potential output growth and output gaps: concepts, uses and estimates”. Monthly Bulletin, October

Fagan, G. Henry, J. Mestre, R. (2001) “An Area-Wide Model (AWM) for the Euro Area” ECB Working Paper Series N.
42, January

IMF (2009a) “From Recession to Recovery: How Soon and How Strong?” Chapter 3, World Economic Outlook, April

IMF (2009 b) “Regional Economic Outlook: Europe”, October

Llaudes, R. (2005) “The Phillips Curve and Long-term Unemployment” ECB Working Paper Series, N. 441, February

OECD (2009a) “Beyond the Crisis: Medium-Term challenges relating to Potential Output, Unemployment and Fiscal
Positions”, Chapter 4, Economic Outlook N. 85

OECD (2009b) “Economic Outlook” N.86

March 2010 Conjoncture 13


NOTES

1 The Euro Area Business Cycle Dating Committee of the Centre for Economic Policy Research (CEPR) has
identified 3 recessions in the eruozone since the 1970s before the 2008/2009 recession. From peak to through the
periods are [1974Q3; 1975Q1]; [1980Q1; 1975Q1] [1992Q1; 1993Q1].
2 Five episodes of financial distress were considered: Spain (1978-79), Finland (1989-93); Sweden (1993), Norway

(1988), Japan (1993). See IMF (2009a) and or ECB (2009) for more details.
3 Statistical methods used to de-trend variables are subject to some uncertainty. Moreover these methods suffer from

end of period problems. Users normally add forecasts to the original series in order to avoid this problem. However,
this procedure adds uncertainty to the whole process (ECB 2000).
4 Once estimated the TFP as residual, the series is normally de-trended using the HP filter. To avoid end of period

problems, forecasts are normally added.


5 Potential employment is the employment level consistent with the unemployment rate being at the Nairu. It can be
P
computed as follows: Emp (1  Nairu ) LF where LF means labour force.
6 The capital series for the Eurozone has been derived starting from the Database of Fagan et all. (2001). Capital

evolves according to the equation(1.6). For investment, employment and the unemployment rate we used Eurostat
figures and BNP Paribas forecasts until the end of 2012. TFP series is derived as residual. Then the series has been
de-trended using the HP filter. To avoid end of period problems, forecasts have been added. D and G have been
parameterized as suggested by Fagan et all (2001). The production function used is a Cobb-Douglass as in
equation(1.1).

March 2010 Conjoncture 14


Economic Research Department
Philippe d'ARVISENET 01.43.16.95.58 philippe.darvisenet@bnpparibas.com
Chief Economist – OECD countries

Head of OECD countries


Structural issues, Single European Financial Market
Eric VERGNAUD 01.42.98.49.80 eric.vergnaud@bnpparibas.com
Country economics
Caroline NEWHOUSE-COHEN 01.43.16.95.50 caroline.newhouse-cohen@bnpparibas.com
UNITED STATES, CANADA
Jean-Marc LUCAS 01.43.16.95.53 jean-marc.lucas@bnpparibas.com
JAPAN, AUSTRALIA, NEW ZEALAND, BENELUX,
PENSIONS, LONG TERM FORECASTS
Raymond VAN DER PUTTEN 01.42.98.53.99 raymond.vanderputten@bnpparibas.com
EURO ZONE, ITALY, EUROZONE LABOUR MARKET
Clemente De LUCIA 01.42.98.27.62 clemente.delucia@bnpparibas.com
FRANCE, EURO ZONE PUBLIC FINANCES
Frédérique CERISIER 01.43.16.95.52 frederique.cerisier@bnpparibas.com
GERMANY, AUSTRIA, SWITZERLAND, EU ENLARGEMENT
Catherine STEPHAN 01.55.77.71.89 catherine.stephan@bnpparibas.com
SPAIN, PORTUGAL, GREECE
Philippe SABUCO 01.43.16.95.54 philippe.sabuco@bnpparibas.com
UNITED KINGDOM, NORDIC COUNTRIES
Caroline NEWHOUSE-COHEN 01.43.16.95.50 caroline.newhouse-cohen@bnpparibas.com

BANKING ECONOMICS
Laurent QUIGNON 01.42.98.56.54 laurent.quignon@bnpparibas.com
Head
Céline CHOULET 01.57.43.02.91 celine.choulet@bnpparibas.com
Philippe SABUCO 01.43.16.95.54 philippe.sabuco@bnpparibas.com

COUNTRY RISKS
Guy LONGUEVILLE
Head 01.43.16.95.40 guy.longueville@bnpparibas.com
François FAURE
Deputy Head 01 42 98 79 82 francois.faure@bnpparibas.com
Capital flows to emerging markets, Turkey
ASIA
Delphine CAVALIER 01.43.16.95.41 delphine.cavalier@bnpparibas.com
Christine PELTIER 01.42.98.56.27 christine.peltier@bnpparibas.com
LATIN AMERICA
Sylvain BELLEFONTAINE 01.42.98.26.77 sylvain.bellefontaine@bnpparibas.com
Thibault MERCIER 01.42.98.74.26 thibault.mercier@bnpparibas.com
AFRICA
Stéphane ALBY 01.42.98.02.04 stephane.alby@bnpparibas.com
Jean-Loïc GUIEZE 01.42.98.43.86 jeanloic.guieze@bnpparibas.com
EASTERN EUROPE
Central Europe, Baltic countries, Balkan countries
Alexandre VINCENT 01.43.16.95.44 alexandre.vincent@bnpparibas.com
RUSSIA, FORMER SOVIET REPUBLICS
Anna DORBEC 01.42.98.48.45 anna.dorbec@bnpparibas.com
MIDDLE EAST – SCORING
Pascal DEVAUX 01.43.16.95.51 pascal.devaux@bnpparibas.com

The bank for a changing world economic.research.bnpparibas.com


Our publications
ƒ Conjoncture focuses each month both on the main economic issues and structural problems.
ƒ Economic Market Monitor provides a detailed follow-up of the economic situation whilst analysing interest and exchange rate developments
in OECD countries (8 issues per year).
ƒ EcoWeek focuses on specific and current economic issues (every Friday).
ƒ EcoFlash comments and analyses the main economic events (data releases, economic policy decisions) in the hours following their release.
ƒ EcoTV the monthly broadcast programme from BNP Paribas economists. Each month, Philippe d'Arvisenet and his teams will help you to
make sense of the economic and financial news in both French and English. These interviews are available on our website.

To receive directly our publications, please subscribe on our website

BNP Paribas is regulated by the FSA for the conduct of its designated investment business in the UK and is a member of the London Stock Exchange.
The information and opinions contained in this report have been obtained from public sources believed to be reliable, but no representation or warranty, express or
implied, is made that such information is accurate or complete and it should not be relied upon as such. This report does not constitute a prospectus or other
offering document or an offer or solicitation to buy any securities or other investment. Information and opinions contained in the report are published for the
assistance of recipients, but are not to be relied upon as authoritative or taken in substitution for the exercise of judgement by any recipient, they are subject to
change without notice and not intended to provide the sole basis of any evaluation of the instruments discussed herein. Any reference to past performance should
not be taken as an indication of future performance. No BNP Paribas Group Company accepts any liability whatsoever for any direct or consequential loss arising
from any use of material contained in this report. All estimates and opinions included in this report constitute our judgements as of the date of this report. BNP
Paribas and their affiliates ("collectively "BNP Paribas") may make a market in, or may, as principal or agent, buy or sell securities of the issuers mentioned in this
report or derivatives thereon. BNP Paribas may have a financial interest in the issuers mentioned in this report, including a long or short position in their securities,
and or options, futures or other derivative instruments based thereon. BNP Paribas, including its officers and employees may serve or have served as an officer,
director or in an advisory capacity for any issuer mentioned in this report. BNP Paribas may, from time to time, solicit, perform or have performed investment
banking, underwriting or other services (including acting as adviser, manager, underwriter or lender) within the last 12 months for any issuer referred to in this
report. BNP Paribas, may to the extent permitted by law, have acted upon or used the information contained herein, or the research or analysis on which it was
based, before its publication. BNP Paribas may receive or intend to seek compensation for investment banking services in the next three months from an issuer
mentioned in this report. Any issuer mentioned in this report may have been provided with sections of this report prior to its publication in order to verify its factual
accuracy.
This report was produced by a BNP Paribas Group Company. This report is for the use of intended recipients and may not be reproduced (in whole or in part)
or delivered or transmitted to any other person without the prior written consent of BNP Paribas. By accepting this document you agree to be bound by the
foregoing limitations.
Analyst Certification
Each analyst responsible for the preparation of this report certifies that (i) all views expressed in this report accurately reflect the analyst's personal views
about any and all of the issuers and securities named in this report, and (ii) no part of the analyst's compensation was, is, or will be, directly or indirectly, related to
the specific recommendations or views expressed herein.
United States: This report is being distributed to US persons by BNP Paribas Securities Corp., or by a subsidiary or affiliate of BNP Paribas that is not
registered as a US broker-dealer, to US major institutional investors only. BNP Paribas Securities Corp., a subsidiary of BNP Paribas, is a broker-dealer registered
with the Securities and Exchange Commission and is a member of the National Association of Securities Dealers, Inc. BNP Paribas Securities Corp. accepts
responsibility for the content of a report prepared by another non-US affiliate only when distributed to US persons by BNP Paribas Securities Corp.
United Kingdom: This report has been approved for publication in the United Kingdom by BNP Paribas London Branch, a branch of BNP Paribas whose
head office is in Paris, France. BNP Paribas London Branch is regulated by the Financial Services Authority ("FSA") for the conduct of its designated investment
business in the United Kingdom and is a member of the London Stock Exchange. This report is prepared for professional investors and is not intended for Private
Customers in the United Kingdom as defined in FSA rules and should not be passed on to any such persons.
Japan: This report is being distributed to Japanese based firms by BNP Paribas Securities (Japan) Limited, Tokyo Branch, or by a subsidiary or affiliate of
BNP Paribas not registered as a financial instruments firm in Japan, to certain financial institutions permitted by regulation. BNP Paribas Securities (Japan) Limited,
Tokyo Branch, a subsidiary of BNP Paribas, is a financial instruments firm registered according to the Financial Instruments and Exchange Law of Japan and a
member of the Japan Securities Dealers Association. BNP Paribas Securities (Japan) Limited, Tokyo Branch accepts responsibility for the content of a report
prepared by another non-Japan affiliate only when distributed to Japanese based firms by BNP Paribas Securities (Japan) Limited, Tokyo Branch.
Hong Kong: This report is being distributed in Hong Kong by BNP Paribas Hong Kong Branch, a branch of BNP Paribas whose head office is in Paris,
France. BNP Paribas Hong Kong Branch is regulated as a Licensed Bank by the Hong Kong Monetary Authority and is deemed as a Registered Institution by the
Securities and Futures Commission for the conduct of Advising on Securities [Regulated Activity Type 4] under the Securities and Futures Ordinance Transitional
Arrangements.
Singapore: This report is being distributed in Singapore by BNP Paribas Singapore Branch, a branch of BNP Paribas whose head office is in Paris, France.
BNP Paribas Singapore is a licensed bank regulated by the Monetary Authority of Singapore is exempted from holding the required licenses to conduct regulated
activities and provide financial advisory services under the Securities and Futures Act and the Financial Advisors Act. © BNP Paribas (2010). All rights reserved.

Prepared by Economic Research – BNP PARIBAS


Registered Office: 16 boulevard des Italiens – 75009 PARIS
Tél : +33 (0) 1.42.98.12.34 – Internet : www.bnpparibas.com
Publisher: Michel Pébereau
Printed in France by: Ateliers J. Hiver SA – Dépôt légal : March 2010
ISSN 0224-3288 – Copyright BNP Paribas

The bank for a changing world economic.research.bnpparibas.com

You might also like